ArticlePDF Available

Economics - The promise of prediction markets

Authors:

Abstract

The ability of groups of people to make predictions is a potent research tool that should be freed of unnecessary government restrictions.
www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 320 16 MAY 2008
877
POLICYFORUM
P
rediction markets are forums for trad-
ing contracts that yield payments based
on the outcome of uncertain events.
There is mounting evidence that such markets
can help to produce forecasts of event out-
comes with a lower prediction error than con-
ventional forecasting methods. For example,
prediction market prices can be used to
increase the accuracy of poll-based forecasts
of election outcomes (1) (see the figure), offi-
cial corporate experts’ forecasts of printer
sales, and statistical weather forecasts used
by the National Weather Service.
Several researchers emphasize the poten-
tial of prediction markets to improve deci-
sions (25). The range of applications is vir-
tually limitless—from helping businesses
make better investment decisions to helping
governments make better fiscal and mone-
tary policy decisions.
Prediction markets have been used by
decision-makers in the U.S. Department of
Defense (6), the health care industry (7), and
multibillion-dollar corporations such as
Eli Lilly, General Electric, Google, France
Telecom, Hewlett-Packard, IBM, Intel, Micro-
soft, Siemens, and Yahoo (8). The prices in
these markets reflect employees’ expecta-
tions about the likelihood of a homeland
security threat, the nationwide extent of a flu
outbreak, the success of a new drug treat-
ment, the sales revenue from an existing
product, the timing of a new product launch,
and the quality of a recently introduced soft-
ware program.
These markets could assist private firms
and public institutions in managing economic
risks, such as declines in consumer demand,
and social risks, such as flu outbreaks and
environmental disasters, more efficiently.
Unfortunately, however, current federal
and state laws limiting gambling create sig-
nificant barriers to the establishment of
vibrant, liquid prediction markets in the
United States. We believe that regulators
should lower these barriers by creating a legal
safe harbor for specified types of small-
stakes markets, stimulating innovation in
both their design and their use (9).
How and Why Prediction Markets Work
An example will help to clarify the prediction
market concept. Consider a contract that pays
$1 if Candidate X wins the presidential elec-
tion in 2008. If the market price of an X con-
tract is currently 53 cents, an interpretation is
that the market “believes” X has a 53%
chance of winning. Prediction markets reflect
a fundamental principle underlying the value
of market-based pricing: Because informa-
tion is often widely dispersed among eco-
nomic actors, it is highly desirable to find a
mechanism to collect and aggregate that
information. Free markets usually manage
this process well because almost anyone can
participate, and the potential for profit (and
loss) creates strong incentives to search for
better information. To be sure, a lively debate
has arisen about whether prediction market
prices are subject to various biases, which
might diminish their accuracy as an aggrega-
tion mechanism (1014). However, predic-
tion markets have been used with success in a
variety of contexts.
Legal Impediments
The use of prediction markets has been
greatly deterred by state and federal laws
restricting Internet gambling because at
least some of these laws are plausibly under-
stood to cast serious doubts on prediction
The ability of groups of people to make
predictions is a potent research tool that should
be freed of unnecessary government restrictions.
Kenneth J. Arrow,
1
Robert Forsythe,
2
Michael Gorham,
3
Robert Hahn,
4
* Robin Hanson,
5
John O. Ledyard,
6
Saul Levmore,
7
Robert Litan,
8
Paul Milgrom,
1
Forrest D. Nelson,
9
George R. Neumann,
9
Marco Ottaviani,
10
Thomas C. Schelling,
11
Robert J. Shiller,
12
Vernon L. Smith,
13
Erik Snowberg,
14
Cass R. Sunstein,
7
Paul C. Tetlock,
15
Philip E. Tetlock,
16
Hal R. Varian,
17
Justin Wolfers,
18
Eric Zitzewitz
19
ECONOMICS
The Promise of Prediction Markets
1
Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford,
CA 94305, USA.
2
College of Business, University of South
Florida, Tampa, FL 33620, USA.
3
Stuart School of Business,
Illnois Institute of Technology, Chicago, IL 60661, USA.
4
Reg-Markets Center at American Enterprise Institute,
Washington, DC 20036, USA.
5
Department of Economics,
George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030, USA.
6
Department of Economics, California Institute of
Technology, Pasadena, CA 91125, USA.
7
University of
Chicago Law School, Chicago, IL 60637, USA.
8
Kauffman
Foundation, Kansas City, MO 64110, USA.
9
Department of
Economics, University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA.
10
Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern
University, Evanston, IL 60208, USA.
11
School of Public
Policy, University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742,
USA.
12
Department of Economics, Yale University, New
Haven, CT 06520, USA.
13
Chapman University School of
Law, Orange, CA 92866, USA.
14
Graduate School of
Business, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305, USA.
15
Yale School of Management, New Haven, CT 06520,
USA.
16
Haas School of Business, University of California,
Berkeley, CA 94720, USA.
17
School of Information,
University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720, USA.
18
The
Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia,
PA 19104, USA.
19
Department of Economics, Dartmouth
College, Hanover, NH 03755, USA.
*Author for correspondence. E-mail: rhahn@aei.org.
Information Revelation Through Time
0
2
4
6
0306090120150
Days until election
Average absolute forecast error
(Vote share %)
Information revelation through time. Data are from the Iowa Electronic Markets for markets predicting the
two-party vote shares from the 1988, 1992, 1996, and 2000 presidential elections (19). The vertical axis
plots the average absolute difference between the market prediction and the actual vote share. In the week
immediately before the election, the market erred by an average of 1.5 percentage points compared with an
average error of 2.1 percentage points for the final Gallup poll. The longer-run forecasting performance of
the market is also impressive, with an average error of only 5 percentage points 150 days before the election,
a time when polls have much larger errors when interpreted as predictions. Calculations are based on data
available at www.biz.uiowa.edu/iem.
Published by AAAS
on May 15, 2008 www.sciencemag.orgDownloaded from
16 MAY 2008 VOL 320 SCIENCE www.sciencemag.org
878
POLICYFORUM
markets. Currently, eight states bar Internet
gambling outright. In 2006, President Bush
signed the Unlawful Internet Gambling
Enforcement Act, designed to crack down
on such gambling.
The legal questions here are complex, but
to create a prediction market in the United
States that is unambiguously legal, one must
run a regulatory gauntlet (15). In principle,
these difficulties could be avoided by creat-
ing prediction markets outside the United
States, but this approach could suppress inno-
vation and reduce opportunities to aggregate
information and improve decisions. It would
be better for U.S. authorities to clarify the cir-
cumstances under which prediction markets
are plainly legal.
Breaking the Legal Impasse
We suggest that two steps should be taken to
facilitate the use of prediction markets while
still meeting the legitimate concerns of law-
makers and regulators.
(i) The Commodity Futures Trading
Commission (CFTC), the federal regulatory
agency that oversees futures market activity,
should establish safe-harbor rules for selected
small-stakes markets. One limited safe harbor
is the no-action letter, in which the CFTC mar-
ket oversight staff confirms in writing that it
will not recommend enforcement action if the
recipient acts in specified ways. The only pre-
diction market to receive a no-action letter (in
1992) is the Iowa Electronic Markets (16),
which is run by professors at the University of
Iowa and which initially focused on presiden-
tial elections. Although such no-action letters
reduce the chances of legal action under other
state and federal laws, they may not be ade-
quate. We would therefore urge the CFTC to
explore other approaches to ensuring safe har-
bors, for example, formal rules or guidance
approved by the commission.
We suggest that three types of entities be
eligible for safe harbor treatment. The first
would be not-for-profit research institutions,
including universities, colleges, and think
tanks wishing to operate exchanges similar to
the Iowa Electronic Markets. The second
would be government agencies seeking to do
research similar to that of nongovernmental
research institutions. The third group would
consist of private businesses and not-for-
profits that are not primarily engaged in
research, which would only be allowed to
operate internal prediction markets with their
employees or contractors.
In all cases, markets would be limited to
small-stakes contracts. Although the defini-
tion of small stakes is somewhat arbitrary, we
use the term to mean an exchange in which
the total amount of capital deposited by any
one participant may not exceed some modest
sum, perhaps something like $2000 per year.
The exchanges themselves would be not-
for-profit but would be allowed to charge
modest fees to recoup administrative and reg-
ulatory costs. Brokers and paid advisers
would be barred, reducing the risks that con-
tracts would be sold to inappropriate or vul-
nerable customers or that customers would be
charged fees above the amounts needed to
maintain the markets. Exchanges would be
self-regulated, leaving them with the respon-
sibility to make reasonable efforts to keep
markets free from fraud and manipulation.
For its part, the CFTC should allow con-
tracts that price any economically meaningful
event. This definition could allow for
contracts on political events, environmental
risks, or economic indicators, such as those
offered by the Iowa Electronic Markets, but
would presumably not include contracts on
the outcomes of sports events.
The contracts qualifying under this safe
harbor would also create opportunities
for more efficient risk allocation (17).
Although the small-stakes nature of these
markets would necessarily limit their use-
fulness for hedging risk, they could serve as
proofs of concept for larger-scale markets
that could be developed under alternative
regulatory arrangements.
The CFTC should allow researchers to
experiment with several aspects of prediction
markets—fee structures, incentives against
manipulation, liquidity requirements and the
like—with the goal of improving their design.
Prediction markets are in an early stage, and if
their promise is to be realized, researchers
should be given flexibility to learn what kinds
of design are most likely to produce accurate
predictions. Of course, exchanges would
need to inform their customers so that they
are aware of the risks and benefits of partici-
pating in these markets.
(ii) Congress should support the CFTC’s
efforts to develop prediction markets (18). To
the extent that the CFTC incurs costs in pro-
moting innovation, Congress should provide
the necessary funding. More fundamentally,
Congress should explore alternative ways of
securing a legal framework for prediction
markets if the CFTC’s existing authority
proves inadequate. In particular, Congress
should specify that a no-action letter, or simi-
lar mechanism, preempts overlapping state
and federal antigambling laws. Because
Congress did not intend the CFTC to regulate
gambling, it is important to design new regu-
lations so that socially valuable prediction
markets easily qualify for the safe harbor but
gambling markets do not.
Conclusion
We have suggested some modest reforms at
the federal level that we hope will facilitate
the development of prediction markets.
These markets have great potential for im-
proving social welfare in many domains.
American leadership in this area is likely to
encourage parallel efforts in other countries,
speeding the development of this tool. The
first step in helping prediction markets
deliver on their promise is to clear away regu-
latory barriers that were never intended to
inhibit socially productive innovation.
References and Notes
1. J. Berg, F. Nelson, T. Rietz, Int. J. Forecast., in press.
2. R. Hanson, IEEE Intell. Syst. 14, 16 (1999).
3. R. Hahn, P. Tetlock, Harvard J. Law Pub. Pol. 28, 213
(2005).
4. C. Sunstein, Infotopia: How Many Minds Produce
Knowledge (Oxford Univ. Press, New York, 2006).
5. E. Snowberg, J. Wolfers, E. Zitzewitz, Q. J. Econ., 122,
807 (2007).
6. R. Hanson, T. Ishikida, J. Ledyard, C. Polk, Proceedings of
the ACM International Conference on Electronic
Commerce, Pittsburgh, PA, 30 September to 3 October
2003 [Association for Computing Machinery (ACM),
New York, 2003], p. 272.
7. P. M. Polgreen, F. Nelson, G. Neumann, Clin. Infect. Dis.
44, 272 (2007).
8. B. Cowgill, J. Wolfers, E. Zitzewitz, “Using prediction
markets to track information flows: Evidence from
Google,” Dartmouth College (2008); www.bocowgill.com/
GooglePredictionMarketPaper.pdf.
9. K. Arrow et al., “Statement on prediction markets,”
AEI-Brookings Joint Center Related Publication No. 07-11
(May 2007); available at Social Science Research
Network (SSRN), http://ssrn.com/abstract=984584.
10. J. Wolfers, E. Zitzewitz, “Interpreting prediction market
prices as probabilities,” Stanford Graduate School of
Business (2005).
11. C. Manski, Econ. Lett. 91, 425 (2006).
12. C. Sunstein, Infotopia: How Many Minds Produce
Knowledge (Oxford Univ. Press, New York, 2006).
13. M. Ottaviani, P. N. Sørensen, J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 5, 554
(2007).
14. P. Tetlock, “Liquidity and prediction market efficiency”
(March 2008); available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/
abstract=929916.
15. R. Hahn, P. Tetlock, J. Regul. Econ. 29, 265 (2006).
16. No-action letter from Andrea M. Corcoran, Director,
Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) Division
of Trading and Markets, to George R. Neumann, Professor
of Economics, University of Iowa (5 February 1992);
www.cftc.gov/files/foia/repfoia/foirf0503b002.pdf.
17. R. Shiller, Macro Markets: Creating Institutions for
Managing Society’s Largest Economic Risks (Oxford Univ.
Press, Oxford, 1993).
18. On May 1, 2008, the CFTC requested public comment on
the appropriate regulatory treatment of prediction mar-
kets. “Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Concept
release on the appropriate regulatory treatment of event
contracts” (May 2008); www.cftc.gov/stellent/groups/
public/@lrfederalregister/documents/file/e8-9981a.pdf.
19. J. Wolfers, E. Zitzewitz, J. Econ. Perspect. 18, 107 (2004).
20. The views expressed here represent those of the authors
and do not necessarily represent the views of the institu-
tions with which they are affiliated. Support provided by
the Reg-Markets Center at AEI (www.reg-markets.org).
10.1126/science.1157679
Published by AAAS
on May 15, 2008 www.sciencemag.orgDownloaded from
... This aligns with previous research that underscores the limited validity of expert predictions based on Delphi studies and underscores the complexity of migration processes, as well as the lack of consensus among experts regarding key drivers. Irrespective of the subject matter, alternative approaches like prediction markets (e.g., Arrow et al. 2008) may offer more reliable results. ...
... Our results suggest that framing migration tasks differently will only marginally improve consensus among experts. Overall, the findings underscore previous concerns regarding predictions (Colson and Cooke 2018;Morgan 2014), particularly in the field of migration, and highlight the need to continue exploring how expert opinion can be best leveraged to inform anticipatory decision-making, including through further testing of the Delphi method and alternative approaches such as prediction markets (e.g., Arrow et al. 2008). ...
... As previously highlighted and according to the literature (see, e.g., Arrow et al., 2008), in a prediction market prices can be thought as probability distributions. Hence, in line with the literature (Blume and Easley, 2009;Bottazzi and Giachini, 2019b;Dindo and Massari, 2020), we choose the negative of the average relative entropy of prices with respect to the truth as our measure of informative efficiency. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
For the Bayesian learner, updating priors based on observation is the path that improves the beliefs and this, in turn, affects the efficiency of prices. Or so was believed until agents with no learning advantage, that is zero-intelligence, produced near-optimal levels of efficiency. We design a market environment characterized by model misspecification in which agents update their initial probabilistic guesses with increasing sophistication in incorporating observations. In this designed environment, the market pe-nalizes divergence from the truth, measured in relative entropy. We show that a non-linear U-shaped relation brings together individual rationality in learning and quality of pricing (i.e. informative efficiency). Efficiency first takes a dip with learning sophistication, then converges toward the full information limit (i.e. Bayesian learning). We argue that the results emerge from the particular interaction of two evolutionary forces operating at different levels: learning (individual level) and selection (market level). JEL Classification: C60, D53, D81, D83, G11, G12
... As previously highlighted and according to the literature (see, e.g., Arrow et al., 2008), in a prediction market prices can be thought as probability distributions. Hence, in line with the literature (Blume and Easley, 2009;Bottazzi and Giachini, 2019b;Dindo and Massari, 2020), we choose the negative of the average relative entropy of prices with respect to the truth as our measure of informative efficiency. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
For the Bayesian learner, updating priors based on observation is the path that improves the beliefs and this, in turn, affects the efficiency of prices. Or so was believed until agents with no learning advantage, that is zero-intelligence, produced near-optimal levels of efficiency. We design a market environment characterized by model misspecification in which agents update their initial probabilistic guesses with increasing sophistication in incorporating observations. In this designed environment, the market penalizes divergence from the truth, measured in relative entropy. We show that a non-linear U-shaped relation brings together individual rationality in learning and quality of pricing (i.e. informative efficiency). Efficiency first takes a dip with learning sophistication, then converges toward the full information limit (i.e. Bayesian learning). We argue that the results emerge from the particular interaction of two evolutionary forces operating at different levels: learning (individual level) and selection (market level). JEL Classification: C60, D53, D81, D83, G11, G12
Article
Prediction markets are renowned for their accuracy in forecasting. However, it is not fully clear how the predication market aggregates the traders’ beliefs. In “Price Interpretability of Prediction Markets: A Convergence Analysis,” Gao, Wang, Wu, and Yu introduce a novel multivariate utility (MU)-based mechanism that consolidates various existing automated market-making schemes. This mechanism establishes convergence results for markets consisting of risk-averse traders with diverse beliefs who interact repeatedly with the market maker. Furthermore, the study delivers analytical and numerical insights into the limiting price across different market models. Building on these results, the authors offer an efficient approximation scheme for the limiting price, shedding light on how traders’ beliefs shape market prices. These discoveries provide valuable guidance to market designers, enabling them to refine and optimize market-making mechanisms for more efficient opinion elicitation.
Article
Digitally enabled means for judgment aggregation have renewed interest in “wisdom of the crowd” effects and kick-started collective intelligence design as an emerging field in the cognitive and computational sciences. A keenly debated question here is whether social influence helps or hinders collective accuracy on estimation tasks, with recent results on the role of network structure hinting at a reconciliation of seemingly contradictory past results. Yet, despite a growing body of literature linking social network structure and collective accuracy, strategies for exploiting network structure to harness crowd wisdom are underexplored. We introduce one such strategy: rewiring algorithms that dynamically manipulate the structure of communicating social networks. Through agent-based simulations and an online multiplayer experiment, we provide a proof of concept showing how rewiring algorithms can increase the accuracy of collective estimations—even in the absence of knowledge of the ground truth. However, we also find that the algorithms’ effects are contingent on the distribution of estimates initially held by individuals before communication occurs. CCS Concepts •Human-centered computing → Collaborative and social computing• Applied computing → Psychology.
Article
Full-text available
Background. General practitioners (GPs) work in an ill-defined environment where diagnostic errors are prevalent. Previous research indicates that aggregating independent diagnoses can improve diagnostic accuracy in a range of settings. We examined whether aggregating independent diagnoses can also improve diagnostic accuracy for GP decision making. In addition, we investigated the potential benefit of such an approach in combination with a decision support system (DSS). Methods. We simulated virtual groups using data sets from 2 previously published studies. In study 1, 260 GPs independently diagnosed 9 patient cases in a vignette-based study. In study 2, 30 GPs independently diagnosed 12 patient actors in a patient-facing study. In both data sets, GPs provided diagnoses in a control condition and/or DSS condition(s). Each GP’s diagnosis, confidence rating, and years of experience were entered into a computer simulation. Virtual groups of varying sizes (range: 3–9) were created, and different collective intelligence rules (plurality, confidence, and seniority) were applied to determine each group’s final diagnosis. Diagnostic accuracy was used as the performance measure. Results. Aggregating independent diagnoses by weighing them equally (i.e., the plurality rule) substantially outperformed average individual accuracy, and this effect increased with increasing group size. Selecting diagnoses based on confidence only led to marginal improvements, while selecting based on seniority reduced accuracy. Combining the plurality rule with a DSS further boosted performance. Discussion. Combining independent diagnoses may substantially improve a GP’s diagnostic accuracy and subsequent patient outcomes. This approach did, however, not improve accuracy in all patient cases. Therefore, future work should focus on uncovering the conditions under which collective intelligence is most beneficial in general practice.
Article
One of the problems in supply chain management (SCM) is the bullwhip effect, a phenomenon that amplifies fluctuations in the quantity purchased or ordered. Fluctuations in the quantity ordered by customers are small, fluctuations in the quantity ordered by retailers to wholesalers are large, and fluctuations in the quantity ordered by wholesalers to manufacturers are even larger. The amplification of demand fluctuation makes supply-demand management and production management difficult, making it an important issue for copier manufacturers and their component manufacturers located upstream in the supply. The bullwhip effect is supposedly affected by factors such as inaccurate demand forecasting, long production and logistics lead times, and minimum order quantities. This study developed a demand forecasting method for production control by clarifying and improving the factors that make it difficult to accurately forecast demand for products sold by copier manufacturers. Furthermore, we developed a demand forecasting method based on a voting system using a collective intelligence mechanism. The proposed method was devised to overcome problems such as the “beauty voting” problem in existing forecasting methods (prediction markets) using collective intelligence. A comparison of six months of data during the study period showed the amount of inventory by approximately 80% and reduced the shortages to zero for the product under consideration.
Article
This paper studies the impact of political risk on exchange rates. We focus on the Brexit Referendum as it provides a natural experiment where both exchange rate expectations and a time‐varying political risk factor can be measured directly. We build a portfolio model that relates changes in the Leave probability to changes of the British pound's market price, both via expectations and via a political risk factor. We estimate the model for multilateral and bilateral British pound exchange rates. We find that the Leave probability predicts a depreciation of the pound, consistent with the outcome post‐referendum, and that the time‐varying political risk affects exchange rates independently.
Book
The rise of the "information society" offers not only considerable peril but also great promise. Beset from all sides by a never-ending barrage of media, how can we ensure that the most accurate information emerges and is heeded? In this book, Cass R. Sunstein develops a deeply optimistic understanding of the human potential to pool information, and to use that knowledge to improve our lives. In an age of information overload, it is easy to fall back on our own prejudices and insulate ourselves with comforting opinions that reaffirm our core beliefs. Crowds quickly become mobs. The justification for the Iraq war, the collapse of Enron, the explosion of the space shuttle Columbia--all of these resulted from decisions made by leaders and groups trapped in "information cocoons," shielded from information at odds with their preconceptions. How can leaders and ordinary people challenge insular decision making and gain access to the sum of human knowledge? Stunning new ways to share and aggregate information, many Internet-based, are helping companies, schools, governments, and individuals not only to acquire, but also to create, ever-growing bodies of accurate knowledge. Through a ceaseless flurry of self-correcting exchanges, wikis, covering everything from politics and business plans to sports and science fiction subcultures, amass--and refine--information. Open-source software enables large numbers of people to participate in technological development. Prediction markets aggregate information in a way that allows companies, ranging from computer manufacturers to Hollywood studios, to make better decisions about product launches and office openings. Sunstein shows how people can assimilate aggregated information without succumbing to the dangers of the herd mentality--and when and why the new aggregation techniques are so astoundingly accurate. In a world where opinion and anecdote increasingly compete on equal footing with hard evidence, the on-line effort of many minds coming together might well provide the best path to infotopia.
Article
Macro Markets puts forward a unique and authoritative set of detailed proposals for establishing new markets for the management of the biggest economic risks facing society. Our existing financial markets are seen as being inadequate in dealing with such risks and Professor Shiller suggests major new markets as solutions to the problem. Shiller argues that although some risks, such as natural disaster or temporary unemployment, are shared by society, most risks are borne by the individual and standards of living determined by luck. He investigates whether a new technology of markets could make risk-sharing possible, and shows how new contracts could be designed to hedge all manner of risks to the individual's living standards. He proposes new international markets for perpetual claims on national incomes, and on components and aggregates of national incomes, concluding that these markets may well dwarf our stock markets in their activity and significance. He also argues for new liquid international markets for residential and commercial property. Establishing such unprecedented new markets presents some important technical problems which Shiller attempts to solve with proposals for implementing futures markets on perpetual claims on incomes, and for the construction of index numbers for cash settlement of risk management contracts. These new markets could fundamentally alter and diminish international economic fluctuations, and reduce the inequality of incomes around the world. Available in OSO: http://www.oxfordscholarship.com/oso/public/content/economicsfinance/0198294182/toc.html
Article
Prediction markets are markets for contracts that yield payments based on the outcome of an uncertain future event, such as a presidential election. Using these markets as forecasting tools could substantially improve decision making in the private and public sectors. We argue that U.S. regulators should lower barriers to the creation and design of prediction markets by creating a safe harbor for certain types of small stakes markets. We believe our proposed change has the potential to stimulate innovation in the design and use of prediction markets throughout the economy, and in the process to provide information that will benefit the private sector and government alike.
Article
I investigate the relationship between liquidity and market efficiency using data from short horizon binary outcome securities listed on the TradeSports exchange. I find that liquidity does not reduce, and sometimes increases, deviations of prices from financial and sporting event outcomes. One explanation is that limit order traders are naïve about other traders' knowledge and unwittingly bet against them, which can slow the response of prices to information. Consistent with this explanation, the limit orders that execute during informative time periods have negative expected returns; and limit orders often execute against traders who exploit the well-known favorite-longshot bias in prices.
Conference Paper
Since 2005, Google has conducted the largest corporate experiment with prediction markets we are aware of. In this paper, we illustrate how markets can be used to study how an organization processes information. We show that market participants are not typical of Google’s workforce, and that market participation and success is skewed towards Google’s engineering and quantitatively oriented employees. We document a number of biases in Google’s markets, most notably an optimistic bias. Newly hired employees are on the optimistic side of these markets, and optimistic biases are significantly more pronounced on days when Google stock is appreciating. We also document a reverse favorite longshot bias, where rare events are underpriced by the market. Lastly, we find a bias against “extreme” events: In markets about a continuous variable, traders underprice the high and low ends of the spectrum and overprice the middle. In the final section of our paper, we document correlated trading among employees who sit within a few feet of one another and employees with social or work relationships. These findings are interesting in light of recent research on the role of optimism in entrepreneurial firms, as well as recent work on the importance of geographic and social proximity in explaining information flows in firms and markets. The current draft of the full paper can be read at http://bocowgill. com/GooglePredictionMarketPaper.pdf
Article
We analyze the extent to which simple markets can be used to aggregate disperse information into efficient forecasts of uncertain future events. Drawing together data from a range of prediction contexts, we show that market-generated forecasts are typically fairly accurate, and that they outperform most moderately sophisticated benchmarks. Carefully designed contracts can yield insight into the market’s expectations about probabilities, means and medians, and also uncertainty about these parameters. Moreover, conditional markets can effectively reveal the market’s beliefs about regression coefficients, although we still have the usual problem of disentangling correlation from causation. We discuss a number of market design issues and highlight domains in which prediction markets are most likely to be useful.
Chapter
This book explores the human potential to pool widely dispersed information, and to use that knowledge to improve both our institutions and our lives. Various methods for aggregating information are explored and compared, including surveys, deliberation, markets (including prediction markets), blogs, open source software, and wikis. The success of surveys, in establishing what is true, can be explained by reference to the Condorcet Jury Theorem; but when most people are less than 50% likely to be right, the failures of surveys, in establishing what is true, can be explained in the same way. Deliberation is often celebrated as likely to counteract the problems in surveys. But deliberation itself creates serious risks, including amplification of errors, cascades, and group polarization. These risks produce blunders in many domains, including legislative institutions and the blogosphere; hence it is too simple to celebrate the Internet or the blogosphere by reference to Hayekian arguments about the dispersed nature of information in society. By contrast, markets, including prediction markets, often do remarkably well, for reasons sketched by Hayek in his examination of the price mechanism. Because of their ability to aggregate privately held information, prediction markets substantial advantages over group deliberation. Open source software and wikis have their own dynamic and create their own puzzles. Steps are explored by which deliberating groups obtain the information held by their members. These points bear on discussion of normative issues, in which deliberation might also fail to improve group thinking.
Article
In the last three years, Google has conducted the largest corporate experiment with prediction markets we are aware of. In this paper, we illustrate how markets can be used to study how an organization processes information. We document a number of biases in Google’s markets, most notably an optimistic bias. Newly hired employees are on the optimistic side of these markets, and optimistic biases are significantly more pronounced on days when Google stock is appreciating. We find correlated trading among employees who sit within a few feet of one another and employees with social or work relationships. The results are interesting in light of recent research on the role of optimism in entrepreneurial firms, as well as recent work on the importance of geographic and social proximity in explaining information flows in firms and markets.
Article
Analyses of the effects of election outcomes on the economy have been hampered by the problem that economic outcomes also influence elections. We sidestep these problems by analyzing movements in economic indicators caused by clearly exogenous changes in expectations about the likely winner during election day. Analyzing high frequency financial fluctuations following the release of flawed exit poll data on election day 2004, and then during the vote count we find that markets anticipated higher equity prices, interest rates and oil prices, and a stronger dollar under a George W. Bush presidency than under John Kerry. A similar Republican-Democrat differential was also observed for the 2000 BushGore contest. Prediction market based analyses of all presidential elections since 1880 also reveal a similar pattern of partisan impacts, suggesting that electing a Republican president raises equity valuations by 2–3 percent, and that since Ronald Reagan, Republican presidents have tended to raise bond yields.
Article
This paper presents a framework for applying prediction markets to corporate decision-making. The analysis is motivated by the recent surge of interest in markets as information aggregation devices and their potential use within firms. We characterize the amount of outcome manipulation that results in equilibrium and the impact of this manipulation on market prices. (JEL: D71, D82, D83, D84) (c) 2007 by the European Economic Association.