ArticlePDF Available

Assessing Different Drivers of the GreatModeration in the U.S.

Authors:

Abstract

This paper employs a calibrated new-Keynesian DSGE model to assess the relative importance of two different, potentially important drivers of the Great Moderation in the U.S., namely 'good policy' vs. 'good luck'. The calibrated model is capable to replicate the actual standard deviations of inflation and output. Factual and counterfactual simulations are run in order to gauge the relative importance of the systematic monetary policy vs. the stochastic shocks hitting the economic system in shaping some macroeconomic volatilities. Importantly, under the bad policy scenario sunspots may influence the equilibrium values of the macroeconomic variables of interest, and distortions in the transmission mechanism going from the structural shocks to the variables of interest are allowed for. Our findings support the relevance of both drivers in causing inflation volatility. By contrast, output volatility can hardly be explained by a monetary policy switch like the one occurred in the U.S. at the end of the '70s.
UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI PADOVA
Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche “Marco Fanno”
ASSESSING DIFFERENT DRIVERS OF THE
GREATMODERATION IN THE U.S.
EFREM CASTELNUOVO
Università di Padova
August 2006
“MARCO FANNO” WORKING PAPER N.25
Assessin g Dierent Drivers of the
GreatModerationintheU.S.
Efrem Casteln uovo
University of Padua
August 2006
Abstract
This paper employs a calibrated new-Keynesian DSGE model to assess the
relative importance of two dierent, potentially important drivers of the Great
Moderation in the U.S., namely ’good policy’ vs. ’good luck’. The calibrated
model is capable to replicate the actual standard deviations of ination and out-
put. Factual and counterfactual simulations are run in order to gauge the relative
importance of the systematic m o netary policy vs. the stochastic shocks hitting
the economic system in shaping some macroeconomic volatilities. Importantly,
under the bad policy scenario sunspots may inuence the equilibrium values of the
macroeconomic variables of interest, and distortions in the transmission mecha-
nism going from the structural shocks to the variables of interest are allo wed for.
Our ndings support the relevance of both drivers in causing ination volatil-
ity. By contrast, output volatility can hardly be explained by a monetary policy
switch like the one occurred in the U.S. at the end of the ’70s.
JEL classication: E30, E52.
Keywords: Great Moderation, indeterminacy, good policy, good luck, coun-
terfactual simulations.
First version: June 2006. Paper presented at the Society for Computational Economics 2006 (Li-
massol) and the Far Eastern Meeting of the Econometric Society 2006 (Beijing). We thank Margherita
Fort, Francesco Lisi, Giovanni Lombardo, Fabio Milani, Mic hael Reiter, and Paolo Surico for help-
ful discussions. All remaining errors are ours. Address for correspondence: Efrem Castelnuovo,
Department of Economics, Univ ersity of Padua, Via del Santo 33, I-35123 Padova (PD). E-mail:
efrem.castelnuo vo@unipd.it.
1 Introduction
One of the most debated topics in modern macroeconomics is undiscussably the ’Great
Moderation’, i.e. th e strik ing r edu ctio n o f ination and ou tput volatilities occurred
in the last two decades in sev eral industrialized economies. This fact, common across
several countries, is surely a feature of the U.S. economy. Table 1 displays the boot-
strapped v ola tilities of annualized G D P ination and detrended output in two dieren t
samples, i.e. 1960Q1-1979Q3 , 1984Q1-1999Q4.
1
,
2
Quite evidently, there is some insta-
bility regarding these vo latilities. For instance, let’s take the statistics regarding the
subsamples reported in the rstrowoftheTable.
3
Notab ly, the median value of the
volatility of the ination rate falls from 2.48 to 0.95, while its 90% condence interval
evidently shrinks, and its standard deviation (not shown in th e Table) d rop s from 0.65
to 0.14. As far as detrended output is concerned, the median value of its bootstrapped
volatilit y lo wers from 1.69 to 0.92, while also its condence interval tightens, and its
standard deviation mo v es from 0.5072 do wn to 0.3435. Table 1 shows that this ten-
dency nds empirical support also when employing the CBO output trend. Ov era ll,
these gures suggest that since the beginning of the 80s the U.S. econom y has show n
a m u ch calmer behavior, a conclusion supported b y several recen t studies (Kim and
Nelson [1999], McConnel and P erez-Quiros [2000], Blanchard and Simon [2001], Stock
and Watson [2003], and Kim, Nelson, and Piger [2004] for o utput; Mumtaz and Surico
[2006] for the ination rate).
[Table 1 about her e]
1
The beginning of the second subsample is suggested by several studies on the Great Moderation
(see references cited later). The exclusion of the period 1979Q4-1983Q4 is due to the ’experiment’
conducted by the Fed in that period. The choice of cutting the sample in 1999Q4 is justied by the
apparen t ’disconnect’ between ination and output volatilities that has been observed in the U.S. since
the beginning of the current century (Gordon, 2005). However, our results are robust to the extension
of the second subsample to 2005Q3, or when starting our inv estigation in 1982Q4.
2
These distributions were computed with a semiparametric bootstrap procedure. First, we esti-
mated sub-sample specic AR(3) processes for the series under investigation (rst subsample: 1960Q1-
1979Q3; second subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4), specically x
t
= c
x
+
3
X
j=1
α
x
j
x
tj
+ ε
x
t
(with x standing
either for ination or for detrended output). Next, the bootstrapped distributions were computed by
simulating 10,000 pseudo-series with the estimated models, keeping xed the estimated autoregres-
sive parameters. The errors w ere sampled with replacement from the urns of the estimated residuals.
Following Davidson and MacKinnon (2006, eq. 23.11 page 821) the latter were rescaled to make the
variance of the sampled errors equal to that of the estimated autoregressive process. AR(2) models for
the t ime-series at hand delivered very similar results.
3
We mainly concentrate on annualized ination - 4 times the quarterly ination computed on the
PGDP c hain-weighted price index - and detrended real output - HP-ltered real log-GDP (1 decimal).
Following Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), w e computed the HP lter by considering as initial observation
the quarter 1955Q1. As an alternative measure of stochastic trend for the real GDP, we employ the
potential output computed by the Congressional Budget Oce. In this study we also consider a
measure of the short-term interest rate, i.e. the federal funds rate (quarterly averages). The data
used in our analysis were downloaded on January 2006 from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis’
web-site, i.e. http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/.
2
If this decline in ination and output volatilities is mainly due to ’good policy’ ac-
tions (say a better monetary policy managem ent), then the low volatilities scenario
w e ha ve been observing for about two decades now could be maintained such b y keep
ghting ination wit h the ’righ t’ systematic monetary policy. E v idence of a rem arkable
policyswitchattheendofthe’70sisprovided - among the others - by Judd and Rude-
busch (1998), Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (2000), Lubik and Sc horfheide (2004), Boivin
and Giannoni (2005), and C ogley and Sargent (20 05). B y constrast, if the Great M od-
eration is mo stly d ue to ’good luc k ’ (to be inter pre ted as m o re benign macroeconom ic
shocks), then nothing in principle can prev ent the U.S. economy to return to the high
volatilities scenario already liv ed in the ’60s and ’70s. Supporters of th e ’good lu ck’
view include Stock and Watson (2003), Primiceri (2005), Canova and Gam betti (2005),
Hansen (2005), C anova, Gambetti, and Pa ppa (2006), Sims and Zha (2006), Gordon
(2005), Arias, Hansen, and Ohanian (2006), and Ju stiniano and Prim iceri (2006).
4
Most o f the above cited studies concentrate on the estim ation of VAR-type or bac k-
ward looking models, as we ll as on their emplo ym ent for running factual and coun t erfac-
tual exercises. Th ese models un derscore the role pla yed by in ation expectations in in-
ue ncing the realizations of the variables of in terest, an aspect that is of k ey-im portance
when performing coun terfactual experiments. Moreo ver, the VAR -ba sed empirical evi-
dence on Great Moderation is challenged by Benati and Surico (2006), who show that
model-misspecication may lead to a severe up ward bias in the assessment of the merits
of the ’good luc k ’ hypothesis.
Of course, structural models in whic h agents ar e rational allow for the study of pol-
icy changes. Unfortunately, the few counterfactual experimen ts conducted with modern
DSGE monetary-policy models (e.g. Stock and Watson [2003] and Justiniano and Prim-
iceri [2006], who employ a Smets and Wouters (2003)-type model in their inv estiga tions)
ha v e neglected the role potentially pla yed by indeterminacy / sunspot shocks in the ’60s
and ’70s in the United States, a role whose statistical signicance has been certied b y
Lubik and Schorfheide (2004).
5
,
6
If the mo ve from a ’passiv e’ to an ’activ e’ moneta ry
policy (implying the m ove from a multiple-equilibria scenario to a uniqu e equilibrium )
dram atic ally reduces the volatility of ination expectations (and, con sequently, of ina-
tion and outp ut), then the om ission of the ’passive’ monetary policy h ypothesis might
lead a researc her to underestima te the role that systematic mon etary policy has possibly
4
Bernanke (2004) - among the others - also discusses the role potentially played by changes in the
(non-policy) economic s tructure for the reduction of the observed volatilities. In this paper we line up
with most of the literature and concentrate on the ’good policy’ vs. ’good luck’ drivers. We leave the
study of the structural change issue to future research.
5
For a contribution pointing towards the role of indeterminacy in explaining the dynamics of ination
in reaction to a monetary policy shock in VAR models, see Castelnuovo and Surico (2006). Beyer and
Farmer (2005) point out how the support of the indeterminacy hypothesis in the ’60s and ’70s in the
U.S. might be driven by the imposition of untestable restrictions on the structure of the new-Keynesian
economic model employed by Lubik and Schorfheide (2004). For a reply, see Lubik and Schorfheide
(2006).
6
A notable exception is provided by Boivin and Giannoni (2005), that allow for indeterminacy in
their simulations but miss to gauge the role played by exogenous volatilities’ shifts in shaping the
macroeconomic scenario.
3
played as a driv er of the Great M oderation.
This paper works with a calibrated standard DSGE new-Keyn esian model to per-
form factual and coun ter factual sim ulation s in order to assess the relativ e importance
of ’policy’ vs’ luc k ’ in explaining the Grea t Moderation. Importantly, in modeling the
mon etary policy break, w e allow for sunspots and distortions in the moneta ry trans-
missio n mechanism under passive’ monetary policy, i.e. whe n the Taylor principle is
not met. To our know ledge, this is the rst con tributio n that allows for indeterm inacy
when running counterfactua ls aimed at assessing the relativ e role of ’good policy’ vs.
’good luck’ in the U nited States.
Our results suggest that systematic monetary policy is lik ely to have played an
important role in stabilizing ination in the ’80s and ’90s. Ho wever, it turns out that
outpu t stabilit y is hardly linked to an improv em ent in the monetar y policy managem ent.
Moreov er, the relative importance of the role pla yed by mor e benign macroeconom ic
shock s in inuencing both ination and the business cycle is likely to be higher than
the one pla yed by the monetary policy switch occurred at the end of the ’70s.
The p aper is structured as follo w s. Section 2 describes the m odel employ ed as DGP
for our factual and counter factual exercises, and describes our calibration strategy.
Section 3 explains the alternative scenarios w e concentra te on, and presents our results,
whose robustness is discussed in Section 4. Section 5 conclud es, and R eferen ces follo w .
2 M acroeconomic fram ework
As poin ted out in the Introduction, in performing our sim ulations w e emplo y the stan-
dard new-Keynesian framew ork survey ed by Clarida et al (1999). A key-element for
thechoiceofthismodelisthefactthatitistheonlynew-Keynesianmonetarypolicy
model estimated by allo wing for indeterminacy (see the w ork by Lubik and Sc horfheide
[2004]).Themodelreadsasfollows:
7
π
t
= βE
t
π
t+1
+ κ(x
t
z
t
) (1)
x
t
= E
t
x
t+1
τ(R
t
E
t
π
t+1
)+g
t
(2)
R
t
=(1 ρ)[ρ
π
π
t
+ ρ
x
(x
t
z
t
)] + ρR
t1
+ ε
MP
t
(3)
z
t
= ρ
z
z
t1
+ ε
z
t
,g
t
= ρ
g
g
t1
+ ε
g
t
(4)
where x stands for real output, π represen ts ination, R is the short term nominal
interest rate, z captures exogenous shifts of the marginal costs of production, g is a
7
The variables of the model are expressed in percentage deviation with respect to their steady state
values, or in the case of output from a trend path.
4
demand disturbance,
8
and ε
MP
is a mon etary policy shock . The random variables z
and g follow AR(1) processes whose roots are - respectively - ρ
z
and ρ
g
.Theshocks
ε
z
g
, and ε
MP
are white noise stoc hastic elements whose variance is, respectively,
σ
2
ε
z
2
ε
g
,andσ
2
ε
MP
.
Eq. (1) is the Euler equation maximizing the prot of the representativ e, m on opo-
listically competitiv e rm whose discoun t factor is iden tied by the p ar am eter β.Prices
are sticky due to a Calv o-t ype rigidity that allow s only a fraction of rms to r eoptimize
their prices or to quad ratic adjustment costs. The slo pe coecient κ relates output and
the m arginal costs to the ination rate.
Eq. (2) is a log-linearized IS curv e stemm ing from the household’s in tertem poral
problem in which consumption and bond holdings are the control variables. Con tem-
poraneou s output is ca used both by expectations on future realiza tion s of the b usiness
cycle and by the ex-ante real interest rate, the impa ct of the latter being regulated b y
the intertemporal elasticit y of substitution τ .
Eq. (3) is an interest rate rule accordin g to whic h th e central bank adjusts th e
policy rate in response to uctuations in ination and output. We in terpret the random
variable ε
MP
t
as the monetary policy shock.
It is well kno w n that this linear rational expectations model can be associated
to a unique solution as long as the Taylor principle is satised, i.e. the condition
ρ
π
> 1
(1β)
κ
ρ
x
is met (Clarida et al, 2000; Woodford, 2003). If this condition does
not hold, m onetary authorities are unable to uniquely pin down private sector’s expec-
tations. Follo w ing Lubik and Schorfheide (2003,200 4), under indeterminacy w e allow
both for i) a zero-mean i.i.d. sunspot shock ζ
t
- who se variance is σ
2
ζ
-toinuence the
equilibrium values of the variables of interes t, and for ii) a distortion in the transmissio n
mechanism going from the v ecto r of structural shocks to the endogen ous variables under
consider ation.
9
Notice that, giv en its simplicity, this model is lik ely to give systema tic
monetary policy a more importan t role than the one that other framew orks - sa y Sm ets
and Wouters (2003)’s - acknowledge it.
Model calibration
We emplo y the new-Keynesian model (1)-(4) to run simulations in order to compute
the v olatilities of ination and output. To do so, we need to calibrate the model. We
divide the vector θ of the parameters of the model in three groups: policy parameters
8
Since the underlying model has no investment, output is proportional to consumption up to an
exogenous process that can be interpreted as time-varying government spending or, more broadly, as
preference change.
9
Technically, s uch a distortion is implemented by considering a vector
f
M aecting the transmission
from the structural shocks ε
t
to the endogenous forecast errors η
t
=[(x
t
E
t1
x
t
), (π
t
E
t1
π
t
)]
0
.
Lubik and Schorfheide (2003,2004) propose to compute the vector
f
M so to minimize the distance
between the on-impact reactions of the endogenous variables s
t
to the shocks ε
t
under indeterminacy
and those computed at the frontier dividing the parameter space into determinacy and indeterminacy.
We adopt this identication strategy, labeled as ’continuity’, as also done by Castelnuovo and Surico
(2006) and Benati and Surico (2006). A Technical Appendix containing further details is available
upon request.
5
θ
pol
= {ρ
π
x
}, vo latilities θ
vol
= {σ
ε
z
ε
g
ε
MP
ζ
}, and non-policy, ’structural
parameters θ
npol
=
©
τ,κ,ρ
z
g
ª
. For calibrating the Taylor rules, we employ the poin t
estimates b y Clarida , Galí, and Gertler (2000, Table 2 p. 157). These estimates are
fairly in line with those provided by other authors on the U.S. monetary policy conduct
(see e.g. Judd and Ru debusch [1998], Lubik and S chorfheide [2004]). As far as th e
macr oeconomic shock s are concerned, in our bench m ark calibration we employ Lubik
and Schorfheide (2004)’s estimated volatilities. Interestin gly, the magn itudes of the
supply shocks are v ery similar to those one may obtain by estimating a VAR -type
model a la Rudebusch and Sv en sson (1999), w hile those of the dem an d shock s seem to
be slightly underestimated.
10
For calibrating the remaining ’non-policy’ parameters, we
follo w Canova (1994) and employ some (independen t) prior’ distributions for each of
the parameters of such vector. A recent study by Fuhrer and Rudebusch (2004) points
to wards a relatively small value of the in tertem poral elasticity of substitution τ for the
U.S. economy (spanning from 0.002 to 0.081 when the HP detrended real log-GDP is
considered), slightly smaller than the one provided by Rudebusch (2002). Follo wing
Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), w e c hoose (for τ
1
) a gamma distribu tion h aving mean
19.94 (corresponding to
τ =0.05) and a fairly large standard, deviation, i.e. 14.07,in
order to allow for at tails and a fairly wide range of drawn values in the calibration
exercise. To take into a ccount the large uncertain ty surround ing the value of the slope
coecient κ (w hich, acco rd ing to Lu bik and Sch orfheide [2004]’s posterior me ans, may
span from .27 u p to 1.1 2), we co n sid er a gamma distribution ha vin g mean 0.75 and
standard deviation 0.31. Finally, we sample the values of the autoregressive parameters
ρ
z
and ρ
g
by imposing - respectively- a beta prior with mean 0.95 and standard deviation
0.05 and a beta prior with mean 0.50 and standard deviation 0.09.
11
Fixed the priors,
w e implement the following algorithm:
1. we sam p le a tuple j :
©
τ
j
j
j
z
j
g
ª
from the giv en distributions;
2. giv en the remaining parameters of the model (calibr ated as discussed abov e) and
the tuple j coming from step 1, w e simulate 500 times the new-Keynesian model
(1)-(4), and compute the medians of the sim ulated distributions of the endogenou s
variables of interest;
12
3. given the medians computed at step 2, we compute the following measure of
10
In particular, we OLS estimated the supply curve π
t
=
P
4
i=1
α
i
π
ti
+α
x
x
t1
+ε
π
t
and the demand
curve x
t
=
P
2
i=1
β
i
x
ti
β
r
(i
t1
π
t1
)+ε
x
t
(where the upper-barred variables identify backward-
looking MA(4) processes) for the two subsamples 1960Q1-1979Q3, 1984Q1-1999Q4, and obtained:
dσ
ε
π
=1.18, dσ
ε
x
=0.89 (rst sample); dσ
ε
π
=0.71, dσ
ε
x
=0.43 (second sample). We concentrate on
these point-estimates in our Robustness check.
11
The means of the beta distributions were selected on the basis of a preliminary grid-search we
performed by considering the following discrete domains (step-length: 0.05): τ[0 0.35][0.55
1.0]
z
[0.4 0.95]
g
[0.4 0.95].
12
For all the model simulations we consider, we produce 1,000 pseudo-subsamples of a lenght compa-
rable to the historical one, i.e. 78 observations for the rst subsample, and 65 for the second one. The
model simulations are stochastically initialized, and the rst 100 pseudo-observations are discarded.
6
distance:
D
j
(ξ
nkm,j
(θ
j
)
act
,V)=
h
¡
ξ
nkm,j
(θ
j
) ξ
act
¢
0
V
1
¡
ξ
nkm,j
(θ
j
) ξ
act
¢
i
(5)
where ξ
nkm,j
=
£
σ
nkm,j
π
σ
nkm,j
y
¤
0
and ξ
act
=
£
σ
act
π
σ
act
y
¤
0
are (2x1) vectors con-
taining the medians of the distributions of the standard deviations of time-series of
interest, nkm’and’act stand respectively for ’new-K eynesian’ (simulated) an d ’ac-
tual’ (bootstrapped), and V is a (2x2) diagonal matrix whose non-zero elements are
represented by the standard deviations of the bootstrapped distributions of the actual
time-series in the sample under analysis;
4. we store the so computed distance D
j
and the tuple j, and go bac k to step 1.
We repeat steps 1-4 1,000 times. A t the end of the loop, we pin do w n the tuple
j
that minimizes the distance (5) in the subsamp le at hand. In order to have a
calibration robust to sample uncertainty, w e consider the best (in terms of minimum
distance) 5% tuples and co m pute a weighted average of their elements, the weights
being the inv erse of the distance (5) for all the considered j
s
.Noticethatourmeasure
of distance is sample-specic, i.e. we perform t he minimum-distance searc h for each of
the two subsamp les.
The results of our calib r at ion are displaye d in Table 2.
13
It turns out that to match
the vola tilities of ination and output one m ust impose a lo w degree of in tertemporal
elasticit y of substitution τ, very muc h in line with the above m entioned literature.
The slope coecient κ is higher than the one suggested b y the posterior means b y
Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), and it is in terestingly outside the 90%-in terval of our
prior, so suggesting that the d ata (and not the prior) is actually driving the result.
The autoregressive coecient of the demand shock is very similar to the posterior m ean
(rstsubsample)providedbyLubikandSchorfheide (2004), while the one of the shocks
to mar gin al costs is low er. Given the similarity of the two sets of subsamp le ’estim a tes’
we obtained, we constraint the vector
©
τ,κ,ρ
z
g
ª
to assume the sam e values in both
the subsam ples of our in terest.
14
We summarize our calibration choices for the whole
vector of pa ram eters identifying the structure of the model (1)-(4) in Table 3.
15
[Tables 2 and 3 about here ]
13
Thesameexerciseperfomedwiththevectorξ
x,j
=
£
σ
x,j
π
σ
x,j
y
σ
x,j
i
¤
0
,withx {nkm, act},
delivered very similar results, i.e. τ=0.0488, κ=1.3335, ρ
g
=0.9479, ρ
z
=0.4988 for the rst subsample,
and τ=0.0328, κ=1.0563, ρ
g
=0.9500, ρ
z
=0.5374 for the second one.
14
We employ the battery of the point-estimates obtained for the second subsample. The alternative
choice implies very similar results.
15
Notice that in terms of number of structural shocks there is an asymmetry between the rst and
the second subsample due to the presence of the sunspot shock in the former but not in the latter.
Nevertheless, our results are robust to the ’elimination’ of the sunspot shock from the picture.
7
3 ’Good polic y ’ or good luck’? Co u nterfa ct ua l sim-
ulations
Once calibrated, the model is ready for perform ing factual and coun terfactual simula-
tions. In pa rticular, we rst w ant to understand if this framework is able to deliver
’factual’ sim u lated volatilities wh ich are in line with the ’a ctu al’ bootstrapped ones.
For ’factual’ we mea n the volat ilities compute d with the m odel calibrat ed as de scribed
in the previous Section.
Table 4 reports the results of our factual sim ulations. The new-Keynesian model
at hand seems to oer a fairly good t of the facts; in particular, all the medians
of the sim u lated vo latilities fall inside the bootstrapped interval d ened by the [5th;
95th] percen tiles. We tak e this calibration and the implied factual simulations as our
benchmark against which to confront the outcome of our conterfactual simulations.
We simulate four dierent coun ter factual scenarios: i) ’Good P olicy’, implemented
by ’plan ting’ the Volcker-Greenspan monetary policy conduct in the ’60s and ’70s; ii)
’Good Luc k’, featured by the presence of the more benign shoc ks of the 80s and ’90s also
in the t wo earlier decades; iii) ’Bad Po licy’, ch a racte rized b y a passive’ monetary policy
in both the simula ted subsamples; and iv) ’Bad Luck ’, a scenario in wh ich the econ omy
is h it by highly vo latile shoc k s all time long. What w e expect is a better e con om ic
outcome - i.e. lower medians and tigh ter intervals - under the ’Good’ scenarios, and a
worse one - i.e. higher media ns and v o latilities - under the ’Bad’ ones. But are these
c h anges quan titatively importan t?
Figure 1 displays the benc hm ark vs. coun terfactual distributions of ination and
output. A ll the distributions are tilted in the expected directions, but the magnitudes of
the shifts are dierent from eac h other. In particular, plan ting a good m on etary policy
in the ’60s and ’70s does exert a re m ar kable im pa ct on the distribu tion of ination
in terms of median and standard deviation (both signicantly lower); by contrast, the
distribution of output is basically unaected by su ch a regim e shift.
16
This result nds
its conrmation in the somewhat ’symm etr ic’ scenario, when the bad policy is im posed
in the second subsample. In fact, according to our sim ula tion s under a passive mon etary
policy we would have observ ed a w orse outcome in terms of ination volatility in the
second subsample (though the impact of the ’bad policy’ on the v olatilit y of ination
seems to be lower than the one of the ’good policy’ in abso lute terms), but not so m u ch
in terms of output v olatility. Th is is conrmed by the gures collected in Table 3 , that
sho w how and ho w m uc h the distributions vary when dierent systema tic monetary
policies are imp lem ented.
Dierently, the role of (either good or bad) luck seems to be relevant for both volat il-
ities. In fact, a ccordin g to our simulations milder shocks in the ’6 0s and ’70s would hav e
implied a m uch calmer beha v ior of the U.S. economy, both in terms of ination and
16
Notice that, according to the Kolmogorov-Smirnov 2-sided test, all the ’counterfactual’ distribu-
tions plotted in Figure 1 are statistically dierent (at the 10% signicance level) with respect to the
’factual’ ones. However, in this paper we are concerned with the economic relevance of the ’policy’ vs
’luck’ drivers.
8
in term s of output. ’Simmetric ally’, big macroeconom ic shoc ks in the las t two decades
would have triggered a large ma croeconomic instabilit y also under good m oneta ry pol-
icy.
Table 5 oers a synthetic sum mary o f our resu lts. First, systematic monetary policy
does inuence the volatility of inatio n. Suc h volatility w ould hav e been about 32%
smaller (or 30% bigger) if monetary policy had been tighter (or less agg ressive). These
gu res support the role played by the Fed in the ’80s and ’90s in stabilizing the v o latility
of the ination rate, as also found b y Cogley an d Sargent (2005) and Mumtaz and
Surico (2006). Hence, indeterminacy triggered by a ’passiv e’ monetary policy is likely
to ha ve played an important role in forming the macroeconomic scenario of the pre-
Volc ker era, as previously poin ted out b y Clarid a, Galí, and Gertler (2000) and Lubik
and Sc horfheide (2004). Neverth eless, monetary policy has har d time in expla ining the
low e r o utp ut volatility of the ’80s and ’90s. Indeed, the historic ally re levan t policy
switch does not trigger much of a reaction in the business cycle. Th is nding supports
the resu lts com ing from Stock and Watson (2003)’s coun terfactual simulations. Third,
the role played b y good luck seems to be relativ e ly more important than the one of good
policy in both subsam ples. In this sense, our results corroborate those by Canova and
Gambetti (2005), Canova, Gam betti, and Pappa (2006), Primiceri (2005), Sims and
Zha (2006), Arias, Hansen, and Ohanian (2006), and Justiniano and Primiceri (2006).
[Table 4, Figure 1, Table 5 about here]
4 Robustness c heck
We perform a robustness ch eck along three dimensions: Th e magnitude of the supply
shocks, that of the in tertemporal elasticit y of substitution τ in the IS curv e, and that
of the slope parameter κ in th e Phillips cu rve.
Magnitude of the Supply Shocks
So far the analysis has m ainly relied upon Lubik and Sc horfheide (2004)’s estimates
of the vo la tilitie s of ination, output, and the structural shocks. As a check, we estimate
an alternative model - i.e. th e Rudebusch and Svensson (1999) model - and concentrate
on the estim ated stand ard deviatio ns of the errors. We nd cσ
ε
π
=1.18, cσ
ε
x
=0.89 for
the rst sample, and cσ
ε
π
=0.71, cσ
ε
x
=0.43 for the second one.
17
Theremarkabledrop
in the supply shoc k - estimated b y Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) - seems to be conrm ed,
but the relativ e magnitude of the demand shoc k with respect to the supply shock is
much higher. By con ditionin g on these new values of the volatilities of the d em and and
supply shocks, and ke eping the vector of policy pa ram eters θ
pol
and t he volat ility of th e
monetary policy shock σ
ε
MP
and that of the sunspot shoc ks σ
ζ
unchanged, w e recalibrate
the vector
©
τ,κ,ρ
z
g
ª
in order to matc h the medians of the actual v olatilities.
17
Newey-West correction for the VCV matrix (3 lags). A check with the CBO potential output (as
to substitute the HP measure for the output trend) delivered very similar estimates. The whole set of
estimates of the Rudebusch and Svensson (1999)’s model is available u pon request.
9
The results of our calibration, reported in Table 6, poin t to wards ’estimates’ that are
fairly similar to those previously obtaine d, with a sligh tly higher in terte m poral elasticity
of sustitution and a slighly lower slope of the Phillips curve. As previously done, we
emp loy the same set of calibrated parameter values for both the subsa m ples: O ur new
calibration is a vailable in Table 7.
18
[Tables 6 and 7 about here ]
The factual simulations conrm that the model is able to t the data with a fair
precision (see Table 8 ). We then run new coun ter factual sim ulations. As far as the
conclusions about the role of systematic monetary policy vs. structural shoc ks is con-
cerned, also these sim ulation s lead us to remark the relevance of systematic mon etary
policy on ination volatility, and that of the dieren t magnitude of the supply and
demand shoc ks on both the volatilities under in vestigation. Figure 2 and Tables 8 and
9 give support to this statem ent.
[Table 8, Figure 2, Table 9 about here]
Higher Intertem poral Elasticity of Substitution τ
Our benchmark calibration delivers a value of τ of about 0.06, fairly in line with
recen t estimates of the IS curv e for the U.S. by Fuhrer and Rud ebu sch (2004). How ever,
alternative, higher estimates may be found in the literature. To assess the ro bu sness of
our n din gs, we perform our simulations by raising its value up to 0.09, as in Rudebusc h
(2002). All the other parameters are calibrated as in Table 3.
Factual simulations rev eal that this parameterization delivers (median) v o latilities
that lay within the (or close to the) 90% bootstrapped condence intervals. As far as
our qualitative results are concerned, Tables 10 and 11, as well as Figure 3, testify that
this para m eter perturbation does not aect our qualitativ e conclusions.
[Table 10, Figure 3, Table 11 about here]
Lower Slope of the Phillips curve κ
Given the importance of the parameter κ in the Phillips curve, we perturb it in order
to perform a further robustness c h eck. We assign to κ a new value, i.e. 0.58,avalue
in line with the posterior mean obtained by Lubik and Schorfheide (2004). We notice
that the factual simulations deliv e r median values for inatio n that are m uch smaller
than the actual ones. How ever, when running ou r simulations with such a small value
for the parameter κ (the other parameter estimates are as those reported in Table 3),
our q ua litative results turn out to be conrmed (see Tables 12 and 13 and Figure 4).
[Table 12, Figure 4, Table 13 about here]
18
As before, we employ the battery of the point-estimates obtained for t he second subsample. The
alternative choice implies very similar results.
10
5Conclusions
In this paper w e calibrated a new-Keynesian model to perform factual and coun t erfac-
tual sim ulations relative to the U.S. macroeconomic behavior in order to understand
the relative merits of the ’Good (M on etary) Policy’ vs. ’Good Luck’ h ypotheses for
explaining the Great Moderation. Importantly, in performing our simulations under
the bad’ policy scenario, we allowed for sunspot shocks and distortions in the trans-
mission mechanism from the structural shocks to the endogenous variables to aect the
equilibrium values o f the variables of in terest.
Our results show that both an aggressive policy against ination uctuations and
benign macroeconomic shoc ks are likely to haveplayedabigroleinshapingthepath
of ination and output. In particular, systematic moneta ry policy mov es turn out to
hav e been important in stabilizing the ination rate, but have not been as eectiv e in
stabilizing the business c ycle. By co ntrast, less volatile ma croeconom ic shoc k s are q u ite
importan t for explaining the behavior of both variables.
All in all, while supporting the role of system atic monetary policy in inuencing
ination uctuations, this paper supports the importance of the relative role pla y ed
by structura l shoc ks in the determ inatio n of the U.S. m acr oeconomic volatilities. This
nd ing corroborates some recent con tribu tions by Stock and Watson (2003), Arias,
Hansen, and Ohanian (2006), and Justiniano and Primiceri (2006), who argue that
variations regarding - respectively - pure supply shocks, total factor productivity, and
inv estm e nt-specic technological shock s migh t be the cau ses of the red u ced vo latility of
the business cycle. R egard ing the uctuations of the ination rate, ou r results seem to
oer some support to Mankiw (2006, p. 184) who recently wrote: "I wonder whether
weexaggeratetheroleofpolicydecisionsandunderstatetheroleofluck. Onereasonis
that the ba d ination performance of the 1970s and the good ination performan ce of
the 1990 s were not limited to the Un ited States. If there was policy failure in the 1970s
and success in the 1990s, the blame and credit go to the world community of central
bankers, not to the single person leading the Federal Reserv e. I suspect, ho wev er, that
the dierenc e cannot be fu lly explained by policy at all. [...] The favora ble supply-sid e
dev elopments of the 1990s w ere not caused by monetary policy, but they did make the
job of policymak e rs a lot easier. Luc k pla ys a large role in how history judges central
bankers."
Howev er, it m ust be recognized that a more cautious measurement of such ’exoge-
nous’ shocks is w arranted. In fact, what w e label as ’exogenous migh t be (at least
in part) the product of economic policies. Citing Krueger (2003, p. 64), "The [shock]
that leap s to mind imm ediately is the oil price increase in 1973 -74, whic h I think of as
ha ving come at the end of a commodity price boom - itself a result of the dollar ination
and, for that matter, labor union strik es and things like this, which I think w ere partly
because of uncertain ty about relative prices. If so, trea ting those a s macroeconomic
shocks that are quite exogenous ma y understate quite signicantly the ro le o f im p roved
monetary policy".
To take Krueger’s consideration up, one should work with more sophisticated models
11
able to take into accoun t e xchange rate uctuations, imperfections in the labor market,
price heterogeneity, and so on, features that are just lack ing in the simplied view of
the w orld that the simple 3 equation new-Keynesian monetary policy model oers us.
We plan to pursue further research along this a ven ue in the future.
References
Arias, A ., G.D. Han sen, and L.E. Ohanian, 2006, Why Ha ve Business Cycle Fluctua -
tions Become Less Volatile?, NBER Working P aper No. 12079, March.
Benati, L ., and P. Surico, 2006, The Great Moderation and the ’Bernank e Conjecture’,
mimeo.
Beyer,A.,andR.E.A.Farmer,2005,TestingforIndeterminacy: AnApplica-
tion to U.S. Monetary P olicy: Comm ent on paper by Thomas Lubik and Frank
Sc horfheide, The American Economic Review,forthcoming.
Blanchard, O., and J. Simon, 2001, The Long and Large Decline in U.S. Output
Volatility, Brookings Pa pers on Economic Activity, 1, 135-174.
Bernank e, B., 2004, The Great Moderation, Remarks at the meetings of the Eastern
Econo m ic Association, Washington, DC, February 20.
Boivin, J., and M. Giannoni, 2005, Has Mone tary Policy Become More Eective?, The
Review of Ec onomics and Statistics,forthcoming.
Canova, F., 1994, Statistical Inference in Calibrated Models, Journal of Applie d Econo-
metrics, 9, S123-S144, December.
Canova, F., and L. Gambetti, 2005 , Structural changes in the US econ omy: Bad Luc k
or Bad Policy?, mim eo.
Canova, F., L. Gambetti, and E. Pappa, 2006, The Structural Dynamics of the U.S.
Output and Ination: What Explains the Changes?, Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking,forthcoming.
Castelnuo vo and Surico, 2006, The Price Puzzle: Fact or Artefact? Bank of England
Working P apers Series, No. 288.
Clarida, R., J. Galí, and M. Gertler, 1999, The Science of Monetary Policy: A New
Keynesian P erspective, Jo u rn a l of Economic Literature, XXXVII, 1661-1707, De-
cember.
Clarida, R., J. Galí, and M. Gertler, 2000, Monetary P olicy Ru les and Macroeco-
nom ic Stabilit y: Evidence and Some Theo ry, The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
115(1), 147-180
Cogley, T., and T . J. Sa rge nt, 2005, Drift an d Volatilities: M on etary Policies a n d
Outcom es in the Post WW II US, Review of Ec onom ic Dynamics, forthcoming.
12
Da vidson, R., and J.G. MacKinnon, 2006, Bootstrap Methods in Econometrics, in
T.C. Mills and K . Patterson (eds.): P algr av e Handbook of Econometrics, Volume
1: Ec onometric Th eory, Palgrav e MacM illan.
Fuhrer, J.C., and G.D. Rudebusc h, 2004, Estimating the Euler Equation for Output,
Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6), 1133-1153, September.
Gord on, R.J., 2005, Wha t Caused the De cline in U.S. Bu sines s Cycle Volatilit y ?,
NBE R Working Paper No. 1 1777, Novem ber.
Hanson , M.S., 2005, Varying Monetary P olicy Regim es: A Vector Autoregressive In-
vestigation, mimeo.
Kim, C., and C. Nelson, 1999, Has the U.S. Econom y Become More Stable? A Bay esian
Appr oa ch Based on a Marko v-S w itching Model o f the Business Cycle, The R eview
of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 608-616.
Kim, C., C. N elson , and J. P iger, 2 004, The Less Volatile U.S. Economy: A Bayesian
In vestigation of Timing, Breadth, and Potential Explanations, Journal of Business
and Economic Statistic s,22(1),80-93.
Krueg er, A., 200 3, General Discussion: Has the Business Cycle Chang ed? Evidence
and E xplan ations, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas Cit y, Proceedings of the S ym-
posium on "Monetary Policy a nd Uncertaint y", Jac kson Hole, Wyoming, A u gust
28-30, 2003.
Lubik, T.A., and F. Schorfheide, 2003, Computing Sunspot Equilibria in Linear Ra-
tional Expectations Models, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Contr ol,28(2),
273-285.
Lubik, T.A., and F. Schorfheide, 2004, Testing for Indeterminacy: An Application to
US Monetary P olicy, The A m erican Economic Review,94(1),190-217.
Lubik, T.A., and F. Sc horfheide, 2006, Testing for Indeterminacy: A Reply to Com-
ments by A. Bey er and R. Farmer, The American Economic Review,forthcoming.
Mank iw , N.G ., 2006, A letter to Ben Bernanke, TheAmericanEconomicReview,
96(2), 182-184, May.
McC onn ell, M., an d G. Per ez-Q u iros, 2000, Ou tpu t uctuation s in the United States:
Wh at has changed since the early 1980’s?, The A meric an Ec onomic R eview,90(5),
1464-1476.
Mumtaz, H., and P. Surico, 2006, Evolving Internation al Ination Dynamics: World
and Country Specic Factors, mimeo.
Primiceri, G., 2005, Tim e Varying Structural Vector Autoregression s and Moneta ry
Policy , The Review of Econom ic Studies, 72, 821-852, July.
Rudebusch, G.D ., 2002, Assessing Nominal Income Rules for Monetary P olicy with
Model and Data Un cer tainty, TheEconomicJournal, 112, 402-432, April.
13
Smets, F., and R. Wouters, 2003, A n Estim ated Stoc hastic Dynam ic General Equi-
librium Model of the Euro A rea, Journal of the Europ ean Economic Association,
1(5), 1128-1175.
Sims, C.A., and T. Zha, 2 005, Were there regime switches in US monetary policy?,
The Americ an Ec onomic R eview,forthcoming.
Stock, J.H., and M .W. Watson, 2003, Has the Business Cycle Changed? Evidence
and E xplan ations, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas Cit y, Proceedings of the S ym-
posium on "Monetary Policy a nd Uncertaint y", Jac kson Hole, Wyoming, A u gust
28-30, 2003.
Woodford, M., 200 3, Interest and Prices: Foundation of a Theory of M onetary P olicy,
Princeto n University Press.
14
1960Q1-1979Q3 19 84Q1-1999Q4
Outp u t trend σ
π
σ
x
σ
π
σ
x
HP
2.48
[1.68 ; 3.84 ]
1.69
[1.24; 2.2 5 ]
0.95
[0.77 ; 1.23 ]
0.92
[0.65; 1.33]
CBO
2.48
[1.68; 3.84 ]
2.33
[1.62; 3 .28]
0.95
[0.77; 1.23 ]
1.40
[.95; 2.20 ]
Table 1: INFLATION AND OUTPUT, BOOTSTRAPPED VO LATILITES. The Ta-
ble displa ys the 50th [5h; 95th] percen tiles of simulated distributions computed with
a semiparam etric bootstrap procedure. First, w e estimated su b-sam p le specicAR(3)
processes for the series under investigation. Next, the bootsrapped distributions w ere
comp uted b y simulating 10,000 pseudo-series with the estimated AR models, keeping
xed the estimated autoregressiv e parameters. The errors w ere sampled with replace-
ment from the urns of the estim a ted residuals. Follow ing Davidson and MacK inno n
(2006, eq. 23 .11 page 82 1) the latter were rescaled to make the variance of the sampled
errors equal to the autogressive processes’s estimated one. In itial conditions for the AR
processes: Hystorical values. ARCH -La grang e Multiplier test (3 lags) supported the
assump tion of hom oschedasticity of the estim ated errors. First observation for the HP
trend comp utatio n: 1955Q1; last observation: 2005Q3. CBO : Output trend computed
b y the Congression al B udget Oce.
P rio r’ distr ib u tio ns Calibrated values
Parameters Type Mean Std 90%-interv al 1st su bsample 2nd s ubsample
τ
1
Gam ma 19.94 14.07 [3.56; 47.02] 0.0551 (τ) 0.0594 (τ)
κ Gamma 0.75 0.31 [0.33; 1.3 1] 1.3581 1.3641
ρ
g
Beta 0.95 0.05 [0.85; 0.99] 0.9438 0.9407
ρ
z
Beta 0.50 0.09 [0.35; 0.65] 0.4655 0.4603
Table 2: CA L IB R ATED PARAMET E R VAL U E S. Calibration of the no n-policy pa ra-
meter s performed by minimizin g a distance function that tak e s into account the gaps
bet ween the model consistent vs. a ctual standa rd deviatio ns (m edians) of the variables
in the model. The momen ts are w eigh ted via the variance of the standard deviations
of the actual data. The ’poin t estimates’ of the non-policy parameters are a weigh ted
a verage of the elemen ts of the best 5 percent tuples. 1st subsam ple: 1960Q1-19 79Q 3,
2nd subsam ple: 1984Q 1-1999Q 4.
15
Par ameters 1st subsample 2nd subsample
ρ
π
0.83 2.15
ρ
x
0.27 0.93
ρ 0.68 0.79
σ
ε
z
1.13 0.64
σ
ε
g
0.27 0.18
σ
ε
MP
0.23 0.18
σ
ζ
0.20
τ 0.0594
κ 1.3641
ρ
g
0.9407
ρ
z
0.4603
Table 3: CALIBRATION OF THE DGP NEW-KEYNESIAN MODEL. Parameter
values borrow e d from the literature (see main text) / calibrated via a minimim distance
estimation. 1st subsample: 1960Q1-1979Q3, 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4.
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q4
σ
π
σ
x
σ
π
σ
x
Actual
(bootstr.)
2.48
[1.68; 3.84 ]
1.69
[1.24; 2.25]
0.95
[0.77; 1.23 ]
0.92
[0.65; 1.33]
Factual
(simulat.)
1.92
[1.66 ; 2.24 ]
2.15
[1.84; 2.52]
0.79
[0.67 ; 0.93 ]
1.14
[0.95; 1.3 6 ]
Good Policy
(simulat.)
1.40
[1.21; 1.62 ]
2.02
[1.72; 2.36]
Factual Factual
Good Luck
(simulat.)
1.14
[0.97; 1.34 ]
1.23
[1.05; 1.45]
Factual Factual
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
1.06
[0.89; 1.25 ]
1.21
[1.00; 1.45]
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
1.40
[1.19; 1.63 ]
2.03
[1.70; 2.38]
Table 4: V OLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FA CTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TUAL SIMULATIONS, BENCHMARK CALIBRATION. The Table displays the 50th
[5th; 95th] percen tiles of the simulated distributions based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st
subsample: 1960Q1-1979Q3; 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4.
16
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std output
Figure 1: FACTUAL VS. COUNTERFA CTUAL SIMULATIONS. Solid line: Factual
distributions; ’S quared ’ line: Coun terfa ctu al distributions. Calibra tion of the model:
Benchmark (see the explanation in the text). N u mber of repetitions: 10,000.
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q4
σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var
Good Policy
(simulat.)
-31.70% -6.48% --
’Good Lu ck’
(simulat.)
-52.02% -56.37% --
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
--29.53% 6.14%
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
--57.23% 57.51%
Table 5: STANDARD DEVIATION, PER CENTAGE VARIATION. The percentage
variations w ere compu ted on the medians of the simulated vola tilities with respect to
the benchm a rk factual scenario based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st subsample: 1960Q1-
1979Q3; 2n d subsample: 1984Q 1-1999Q4 .
17
P rio r’ distr ib u tio ns Calibrated values
Parameters Type Mean Std 90%-interv al 1st su bsample 2nd s ubsample
τ
1
Gam ma 19.94 14.07 [3.56; 47.02] 0.0627 (τ) 0.0771 (τ)
κ Gamma 0.75 0.31 [0.33; 1.3 1] 1.2946 1.2841
ρ
g
Beta 0.95 0.05 [0.85; 0.99] 0.9435 0.9436
ρ
z
Beta 0.50 0.09 [0.35; 0.65] 0.4486 0.4516
Table 6: CALIBRATED PARAMETER VALUES, R UDEBUSCH AND SVENSSON
(1999)’S DEM A N D A N D S U PP LY SHOC K S. Calibration of the ’non-policy’ parame-
ters performed by minimizin g a distance fun ction that take s into accoun t the gaps
bet ween the model consistent vs. a ctual standa rd deviatio ns (m edians) of the variables
in the model. The momen ts are w eigh ted via the variance of the standard deviations
of the actual data. The ’poin t estimates’ of the non-policy parameters are a weigh ted
a verage of the elemen ts of the best 5 percent tuples. 1st subsam ple: 1960Q1-19 79Q 3,
2nd subsam ple: 1984Q 1-1999Q 4.
Par ameters 1st subsample 2nd subsample
ρ
π
0.83 2.15
ρ
x
0.27 0.93
ρ 0.68 0.79
σ
ε
z
1.13 0.64
σ
ε
g
0.27 0.18
σ
ε
MP
0.23 0.18
σ
ζ
0.20
τ 0.0771
κ 1.2841
ρ
g
0.9436
ρ
z
0.4516
Table 7: CALIBRATION OF THE DGP NEW-KEYNESIAN MODEL, R UDEBUSCH
AND SVENSSON (1999)’S DEMAND AND SUPPLY SHOCKS. Rest of the calibration:
See the main text. 1st subsample: 1960Q1-1979Q3, 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4.
18
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q4
σ
π
σ
x
σ
π
σ
x
Actual
(bootstr.)
2.48
[1.68; 3.84 ]
1.69
[1.24; 2.25]
0.95
[0.77; 1.23 ]
0.92
[.065; 1.33]
Factual
(simulat.)
1.73
[1.46 ; 1.97 ]
2.20
[1.85; 2.54]
0.74
[0.64 ; 0.86 ]
1.22
[1.04; 1.4 5 ]
Good Policy
(simulat.)
1.22
[1.05; 1.42]
2.04
[1.74; 2.39]
Factual Factual
Good Luck
(simulat.)
1.09
[0.92; 1.28]
1.32
[1.11; 1.55]
Factual Factual
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
1.01
[0.85; 1.18]
1.31
[1.09; 1.55]
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
1.22
[1.03; 1.43]
2.03
[1.70; 2.44]
Table 8: V OLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FA CTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TUAL SIMULATIONS, DEMAND AND SUPPLY SHOCKS A LA R UDEBUSCH
AND SVENSSON (1999). The Table displa ys the 50th [5th; 95th] percentiles of the
sim ulated distributions based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st subsample: 1960Q1-1979Q3;
2nd subsam ple: 1984Q 1-1999Q 4.
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q4
σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var
Good Policy
(simulat.)
-34.32% -7.28% --
’Good Lu ck’
(simulat.)
-45.76% -51.21% --
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
--30.97% 7.27%
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
--50.33% 50.96%
Table 9: V OLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FA CTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TUAL SIMULATIONS. SHOCKS A LA RUDEBUSCH AND SVENSSON (1999). The
percentage variations were compu ted o n th e m ed ia ns of the simulated volatilities with
respect to the benchm a rk factu al scenario based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st subsample:
1960Q1-1979Q3; 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4.
19
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std output
Figure 2: FACTUAL VS. COUNTERFACTUAL SIMULATIONS, SHOCKS A LA
RUDE B U SC H AND SVENSSON (1999). Calibration of th e model d riven by the shoc ks
estimated with the Rudebusch and S vensson (19 99)’s model. Solid line: Factual distri-
butions; ’Squared’ line: Coun terfac tual distributions. Number of repetitions: 10,000.
20
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q 4
σ
π
σ
x
σ
π
σ
x
Actual
(bootstr.)
2.48
[1.66; 3.83]
1.68
[1.24; 2.24]
0.97
[0.78; 1.29 ]
1.23
[1.08; 1.43 ]
Factual
(simulat.)
1.74
[1.48 ; 2.02 ]
2.11
[1.79 ; 2.46]
0.70
[0.59 ; 0.81 ]
1.10
[0.93 ; 1.30 ]
’Good Policy’
(simulat.)
1.21
[1.05; 1.38]
1.95
[1.67; 2.27]
Factual Factual
Good Luck
(simulat.)
1.04
[0.89; 1.23]
1.21
[1.02; 1.40]
Factual Factual
’Bad Policy’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
0.96
[0.81; 1.13]
1.19
[0.99; 1.41]
’Bad L uck’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
1.22
[1.03; 1.43]
1.96
[1.64; 2.31]
Table 10: VOLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FACTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TUAL SIMULATIONS, H IGH IES. The Table displays the 50th [2.5th; 97.5th] per-
centiles of the sim ula ted distributions based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st sub sam ple:
1960Q1-1979Q3; 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4.
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q4
σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var
Good Policy
(simulat.)
-36.07% -7.89% --
’Good Lu ck’
(simulat.)
-51.27% -55.89% --
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
--32.32% 7.19%
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
--55.62% 57.29%
Table 11: VOLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FACTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TU A L SIMULATION S , HIGH IES. The percentage variations w ere computed on the
medians of the simulated volatilities with respect to the bench m ark factual scenario
based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st subsample: 1960Q1-1979Q3; 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-
1999Q4.
21
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std output
Figure 3: FA CTUAL VS. COUNTERFA CTUAL SIMULATIONS, HIGH IES τ.High
in ter temporal elasticity of substitution, benc hm ark calibration for the rest of the model.
Solid line: Factual distributions; Squared’ line: Counterfactual distributions. Num ber
of repetitions: 10,000.
22
’60Q1-’79Q3 84Q1-’99Q4
σ
π
σ
x
σ
π
σ
x
Actual
(bootstr.)
2.48
[1.66; 3.83 ]
1.68
[1.24; 2.24]
0.97
[0.78; 1.29 ]
1.23
[1.08; 1.43]
Factual
(sim u la t.)
1.02
[0.85 ; 1.24 ]
2.23
[1.86; 2.61]
0.40
[0.34 ; 0.48 ]
1.19
[0.99; 1.4 3 ]
Good Policy
(simulat.)
0.71
[0.61; 0.81]
2.10
[1.80; 2.47]
Factual Factual
Good Luck
(simulat.)
0.69
[0.54; 0.95]
1.26
[1.05; 1.48]
Factual Factual
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
0.52
[0.43; 0.61]
1.25
[1.04; 1.48]
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
Factual Factual
0.71
[0.59; 0.82]
2.10
[1.75; 2.49]
Table 12: VOLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FACTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TUAL SIMULATIONS, LOW SLOPE k. The Table displays the 50th [5th; 95th]
percentiles of the sim ulated distributions based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st subsam ple:
1960Q1-1979Q3; 2nd subsample: 1984Q1-1999Q4.
’60Q1-’79Q3 82Q4-’98Q4
σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var σ
π
,%var σ
x
,%var
Good Policy
(simulat.)
-36.82% -5.93% --
’Good Lu ck’
(simulat.)
-39.29% -57.31% --
’Bad P olicy ’
(simulat.)
--25.40% 4.64%
’Bad Luc k ’
(simulat.)
--55.99% 56.71%
Table 13: VOLATILITIES COMPUTED WITH FACTUAL AND COUNTERFAC-
TUA L SIMUL ATIONS , L OW SL O PE k. The percentage variations were compu ted
on the m edian s of the simulated volatilities w ith respect to the benc hm a rk factual sce-
nario based on 10,000 repetitions. 1st subsample: 1960Q1-1979Q3; 2nd subsample:
1984Q1-1999Q4.
23
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev inflation
Probability
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std inflation
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. good luck
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad policy
stdev output
0 2 4
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
factual vs. bad luck
std output
Figure 4: FA C T UA L V S. COU N TE R FACTUAL SIMULATIONS, LOW SLOPE κ.
Lo w slope coec ient in the P hillips curv e, benc hm ar k calibration for the rest of the
model. Solid line: Factual distributio ns; ’Squared’ line: Co unterfactual distributions.
Number of repetitions: 10,000.
24
Tec hnical Appendix: Solution of the LRE Model
Let’s consider a linear rational expectations model as the follow ing one:
π
t
= β[φ
π
E
t
π
t+1
+(1 φ
π
)π
t1
]+κ(x
t
z
t
)
x
t
= φ
x
E
t
x
t+1
+(1 φ
x
)x
t1
τ(R
t
E
t
π
t+1
)+g
t
R
t
=(1 ρ)[ρ
π
π
t
+ ρ
x
(x
t
z
t
)] + ρR
t1
+ ε
MP
t
z
t
= ρ
z
z
t1
+ ε
z
t
,g
t
= ρ
g
g
t1
+ ε
g
t
This model can be cast in the follo w in g canonical form :
Γ
0
(θ)s
t
= Γ
1
(θ)s
t1
+ Ψ(θ)ε
t
+ Π(θ)η
t
(A1)
where the vector s
t
=[x
t
t
,R
t
,E
t
x
t+1
,E
t
π
t+1
,g
t
,z
t
]
0
collects the n variables of the
system, ε
t
=[ε
MP
t
π
t
x
t
] is the vecto r of l fundamen tal shoc ks, η
t
=[(x
t
E
t1
x
t
), (π
t
E
t1
π
t
)]
0
collects the k rational expectations forecast errors, and θ is the v ector of the
param eters of the model outlined in th e previous section. The matrices of th e canonical
form are presen ted belo w:
Γ
0
=
100 0 0 0 0
010 0 0 0 0
001 0 0 0(1 ρ)ρ
x
00τ φ
x
τ 01
000 0 βφ
π
0 κ
000 0 0 1 0
000 0 0 0 1
Γ
1
=
0001000
0000100
00ρ (1 ρ)ρ
x
(1 ρ)ρ
π
00
(1 φ
x
)001000
0 β(1 φ
π
)0 κ 100
00000ρ
g
0
000000ρ
z
1
Ψ =
000
000
100
000
000
010
001
, Π =
10
01
(1 ρ)ρ
x
(1 ρ)ρ
π
10
κ 1
00
00
In th e exercises proposed in the paper, w e set φ
x
= φ
π
=1.
In order to transform the canonical form and solve the model, we follow Sims (2001)
and exploit the generalized complex Sc hur decom position (QZ) of the m atrices Γ
0
and
Γ
1
. This corresponds to computing the matrices Q, Z, Λ and such that QQ
0
= ZZ
0
=
I
n
, Λ and are upper triangular, Γ
0
= Q
0
ΛZ and Γ
1
= Q
0
Z.Dening w
t
= Z
0
s
t
and
pre-multiplying (A1) by Q, we obtain:
·
Λ
11
Λ
12
0 Λ
22
¸·
w
1,t
w
2,t
¸
=
·
11
12
0
22
¸·
w
1,t1
w
2,t1
¸
+
·
Q
1.
Q
2.
¸
(Ψε
t
+ Πη
t
) (A2)
where, without loss of generalit y, the vector of generalized eigenvalues λ,whichisthe
vector of the ratios between the diagonal elemen ts of and Λ, has been partitioned
such th at the lower block collects all the explosive eigenvalues. The matrices , Λ and
Q hav e been partitioned accordingly, and therefore Q
j.
collects the bloc ks of rows that
correspond to the stable (j =1)and unstable (j =2)eigenvalues respectiv ely.
The explosive block of (A2) can be rewritten as:
1
w
2,t
= Λ
1
22
22
w
2,t1
+ Λ
1
22
Q
2.
(Ψε
t
+ Πη
t
) (A3)
Given the set of m equations (A3), a non-explosive solution of the linear rational ex-
pectations model (A1) for s
t
requires w
2,t
=0t 0. This can be obtained by settin g
w
2,0
=0and choosing for ev ery vector ε
t
the endogenous forecast error η
t
that satises
the following condition
Q
2.
(Ψε
t
+ Πη
t
)=0 (A4)
A general stable solution for the endogenous forecast error can be comp uted through
a singu lar value decomposition of Q
2.
Π
|
{z}
mxk
= U
|{z}
mxm
D
|{z}
mxk
V
0
|{z}
kxk
= U
.1
|{z}
mxr
D
11
|{z}
rxr
V
0
.1
|{z}
rxk
,whereD
11
is
a diagonal matrix and D and U are orthonorm al matrices. Using this decomposition,
1
It is possible to have some zero-elements on the main diagonal of Λ
22
. In this case, the latter matrix
is not inv ertible. The ’solving-forward’ solution proposed by Sims (2001) and extended by Lubik and
Schorfheide (2003) overcomes this problem. A Technical Appendix with a more detailed discussion of
the s olution strategy is available from the authors upon request.
2
Lubik and Schorfheide (2003) show that in equilibrium the vector of endogenous forecast
errors reads as follows:
η
t
=(V
0
.1
D
1
11
U
.1
Q
2.
Ψ + V
.2
f
M)ε
t
+ V
.2
ζ
t
(A5)
where
f
M is the (k r)xl matrix governin g the inuence of the sunspot shock on the
model dynamics.
Assum ing that Γ
1
0
exists, th e solution (A5) can be combined w ith (A1) to yield the
follo w ing law of motion for the state vector:
s
t
= Γ
1
s
t1
+
h
Ψ
Π
V
.1
D
1
11
U
0
.1
Q
2.
Ψ + Π
V
.2
f
M
i
ε
t
+ Π
V
.2
ζ
t
(A6)
where a generic X
= Γ
1
0
X.
In general, w e can be confronted with three cases. If the num ber o f endogenous
forecast errors k is equal to the number of non zero singular values r, the system is
determ ined and the stabilit y condition (A4) uniquely determines η
t
. Insuchacase,
V
.2
=0, then the last t wo addends of (A6) drop out. This implies that the dynamics of
s
t
is purely a function of the structural p arameters θ.
If the number of endogenous forecast errors k exceeds the number of nonzero singular
values r, the system is indeterminate and sunspot uctuations can a rise. Lubik and
Sc horfheide (2003) sho w that this can inuence the solution along two dimensions. First,
sunspot uctuations ζ
t
can aect the equilibrium dynamics. Second, the transmissio n
of fundamen tal shoc ks ε
t
is no longe r un ique ly ident ied as the elements of
f
M are not
pinned dow n by the structure of the linear ra tional expectations model.
Alternativ ely, the number of endogenous forecast errors k can be smaller than the
number of nonzero singular values r, and then the system has no solutions. These
three conditions generalize the procedure in B lan chard and Kahn (1980) of counting
the n umber of unstable roots and predetermined variables.
2
In order to compu te
f
M and then the solutions of the model under indeterminacy,
it is necessary to im pose some additional restrictions on the endogenous forecast er-
rors. Follo wing Lubik and Schorfheide (2004), we c hoose
f
M such that the impulse
responses
∂s
t
∂ε
0
t
associated with the system (A6) are con tin uous at the boundary between
the determin acy and the indeterm ina cy region. This solution is labelled ’con t inuity ’.
In particular, let Θ
I
and Θ
D
be the sets of all possible vectors of parameters θ
0
s in the
indeterm inacy and d eterm ina cy region r espectiv ely. For every vector θ Θ
I
we identify
2
The solution method proposed by Sims (2001) has the advantage that it does not require the
separation of predetermined variables from ’jump’ variables. Rather, it recognizes that in equilibrium
models expectational residuals are attached to equations and that the structure of the coecient
matrices in the canonical form implicitly selects the linear combination of variables that needs to be
predetermined for a s olution to exist.
3
a corresponding vector
θ Θ
D
that lies on the boundary of the two regions and c hoose
f
M suc h that the response of s
t
to ε
t
conditiona l on θ mimics the response conditional
on
θ. This c orresponds to requiring that the condition
∂s
t
∂ε
0
t
(θ)=B
1
(θ)+B
2
(θ)=Ψ
Π
V
.1
D
1
11
U
0
.1
Q
2.
Ψ + Π
V
.2
f
M (A7)
beascloseaspossibletothecondition
∂s
t
∂ε
0
t
(
e
θ)=B
1
(
e
θ) (A8)
Applyin g a least-square criterion, we can then com pu te
f
M =[B
0
2
(θ)B
2
(θ)]
1
B
0
2
(θ)
h
B
1
(
e
θ) B
1
(θ)
i
(A9)
and use (A9) to calculate the so lution of the m odel in (A5) and (A 6).
The new vector
θ is obtained from θ by replacing ρ
π
with the co ndition that marks
the boundary between th e determinacy and indeterminacy region. Woodford (200 3)
shows that this condition corresponds to the follo w ing interest rate reaction to ination
eρ
π
=1
(1 β)
κ
ρ
x
(A10)
As an alternative to the ’con tinuit y’ solution, we also compute the solution of the
model under indeterminacy by imposing
f
M =0
(kr)xl
,i.e. theeects of the sunspot
shocks are orthogonal to the eects of the structural shocks. This solution is dubbed
’orthogona lity’.
Contributions cited in this Tec hn ical Appendix
Lubik, T.A., and F. Schorfheide, 2003, Computing Sunspot Equilibria in Linear Ra-
tional Expectations Models, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Contr ol,28(2),
273-285.
Lubik, T.A., and F. Schorfheide, 2004, Testing for Indeterminacy: An Application to
US Monetary P olicy, The A m erican Economic Review,94(1),190-217.
Sims, C.A., 2001, Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models, Computational Ec o-
nomics, 20, 1-20.
4
... See discussion in the next sub-Section. 31 Castelnuovo (2006) shows that these results, obtained under 'continuity', are robust to a variety of di¤erent model calibrations. 32 These results have been obtained by allowing for 'indeterminacy'in our simulations. ...
Article
Full-text available
Good policy'and 'good luck'have been identi…ed as two of the possible drivers of the 'Great Moderation', but their relative importance is still widely debated. This paper investigates the role played by equilibrium selection under indeter-minacy in the assessment of their relative merits. We contrast the outcomes of counterfactual simulations conditional on the 'continuity' selection strategy -largely exploited by the literature -with those obtained with a novel 'sign re-striction' based strategy. Our results suggest that conclusions achieved under 'continuity'are not necessarily robust to the selection of di¤erent -still economi-cally sensible -equilibria. According to our simulations, the switch to a hawkish systematic monetary policy may very well induce an increase in output volatil-ity. Hence, our sign restriction-selection strategy 'resurrects'the ination-output policy trade-o¤. JEL classi…cation: E30, E52. seminar participants at the Society for Computational Economics (Limassol), the Far Eastern Meeting of the Econometric Society (Beijing), the First Piero Moncasca Money-Macro Workshop (Pavia), and the second ICE 3 (Rimini) for helpful suggestions on earlier drafts of the paper. All remaining errors are ours. Financial support by the Italian Ministry of University and Research is gratefully acknowledged (PRIN 2005-N. 2005132539). All remaining errors are mine. The opinions expressed in this contributions are not necessarily those of the Bank of Finland. Address for correspon-dence: Efrem Castelnuovo, Department of Economics, University of Padua, Via del Santo 33, I-35123 Padova (PD).
Article
“Good policy” and “good luck” have been identified as two of the possible drivers of the “Great Moderation,” but their relative importance is still widely debated. This paper investigates the role played by equilibrium selection under indeterminacy in the assessment of their relative merits. We contrast the outcomes of counterfactual simulations conditional on the “continuity” selection strategy–largely exploited by the literature–with those obtained with a novel “sign restriction” based strategy. Our results suggest that conclusions achieved under “continuity” are not necessarily robust to the selection of different–still economically sensible–equilibria. According to our simulations, the switch to a hawkish systematic monetary policy may very well induce an increase in output volatility. Hence, our sign restriction–selection strategy “resurrects” the inflation–output policy tradeoff.
Article
Sargent and Ljungqvist (1998, 2005, 2006a, 2006b) impute the persis- tence of long term unemployment in Europe since 80s to the welfare state's inability to cope with more turbulent times. They claim that global eco- nomic conditions have been more turbulent in 80s and 90s, comparing to earlier decades, and construct a model based on search with a turbulence at micro level to reproduce the evolution of unemployment in laissez-faire and welfare economies. Plethora of research, among others Stock and Watson (2002, 2003, 2005), document on the other hand a fall in aggregate volatility of macro series in the US and G7 countries since 80s. We attempt to reconcile these two findings. Can the model of Sargent and Ljungqvist (1998) based on micro turbulence be consistent with macro data? We look at macro series of productivity and real wages (plus GDP and employment) for a number of countries and find a decline in aggregate volatility since 80s. We then generate macro series based on Sargent and Ljungqvist (1998) search model and establish what sort of aggregate volatility it predicts for welfare and laissez-faire economies under different degrees of turbulence, and find that it is potentially consistent with macro data.
Article
This paper shows that the explanation of the decline in the volatility of GDP growth since the mid 1980s is not the decline in the volatility of exogenous shocks but rather a change in their propagation mechanism. (JEL: E32, E37, C32, C53) (c) 2008 by the European Economic Association.
Article
Full-text available
We investigate the sources of the important shifts in the volatility of US macroeconomic variables in the postwar period. To this end, we propose the estimation of DSGE models allowing for time variation in the volatility of the structural innovations. We apply our estimation strategy to a large-scale model of the business cycle and find that shocks specific to the equilibrium condition of investment account for most of the sharp decline in volatility of the last two decades.
Article
Using Bayesian tests for a structural break at an unknown break date, we search for a volatility reduction within the post-war sample for the growth rates of U.S. aggregate and disaggregate real GDP. We find that the growth rate of aggregate real GDP has been less volatile since the early 1980's, and that this volatility reduction is concentrated in the cyclical component of real GDP. The growth rates of many of the broad production sectors of real GDP display similar reductions in volatility, suggesting the aggregate volatility reduction does not have a narrow source. We also find a large volatility reduction in aggregate final sales mirroring that in aggregate real GDP. We contrast this evidence to an existing literature documenting an aggregate volatility reduction that is shared by only one narrow sub-component, the production of durable goods, and is not present in final sales. In addition to the volatility reduction in real GDP, we document structural breaks in the volatility and persistence of inflation and interest rates occurring over a similar time frame as the volatility reduction in real GDP.
Article
Monetary policy and the private sector behaviour of the U.S. economy are modelled as a time varying structural vector autoregression, where the sources of time variation are both the coefficients and the variance covariance matrix of the innovations. The paper develops a new, simple modelling strategy for the law of motion of the variance covariance matrix and proposes an efficient Markov chain Monte Carlo algorithm for the model likelihood/posterior numerical evaluation. The main empirical conclusions are: (1) both systematic and non-systematic monetary policy have changed during the last 40 years - in particular, systematic responses of the interest rate to inflation and unemployment exhibit a trend toward a more aggressive behaviour, despite remarkable oscillations; (2) this has had a negligible effect on the rest of the economy. The role played by exogenous non-policy shocks seems more important than interest rate policy in explaining the high inflation and unemployment episodes in recent U.S. economic history.
Article
The decline in the level and persistence of inflation over the 1980s is a common feature of the most industrialized economies in the world. The rise in inflation volatility of the late 1970s and the subsequent fall of the 1980s is country specific for the UK, Canada, and, to a lesser extent, the United States, Italy, and Japan. Since the late 1980s, inflation predictability has declined significantly across the industrialized world. We link the empirical results to recent theories of international inflation.
Article
*Prepared for the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium, "Monetary Policy and Uncertainty," Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 28-30, 2003.The authors thank Dick van Dijk, Brian Doyle, Graham Elliott, Charles Evans, Jon Faust, John Fernald, Andrew Harvey, Siem Jan Koopman, Denise Osborn, Lucrezia Reichlin, Ken Rogoff, and Glenn Rudebusch for helpful comments and discussions; Jorgen Elmeskov for providing some of the data; and Jean Bovin, Marc Giannoni, Frank Smets, Raf Wouters, and Glenn Rudebusch for extensive help and comments on the model-based calculations. This research was supported in part by NSF grant SBR-0214131.
Article
Monetary policy and the private sector behaviour of the U.S. economy are modelled as a time varying structural vector autoregression, where the sources of time variation are both the coefficients and the variance covariance matrix of the innovations. The paper develops a new, simple modelling strategy for the law of motion of the variance covariance matrix and proposes an efficient Markov chain Monte Carlo algorithm for the model likelihood/posterior numerical evaluation. The main empirical conclusions are: (1) both systematic and non-systematic monetary policy have changed during the last 40 years—in particular, systematic responses of the interest rate to inflation and unemployment exhibit a trend toward a more aggressive behaviour, despite remarkable oscillations; (2) this has had a negligible effect on the rest of the economy. The role played by exogenous non-policy shocks seems more important than interest rate policy in explaining the high inflation and unemployment episodes in recent U.S. economic history.
Article
Recently, two stylized facts about the behavior of the U.S. economy have emerged: first, macroeconomic aggregates appear to be less volatile post-1984 than in the preceding 2 decades; second, monetary policy appears more responsive to inflationary pressures – and thereby more “stabilizing” – during the Volcker/Greenspan chairmanships relative to earlier regimes. Does a causal relationship exist between these two observations? In particular, has “better” policy by the Federal Reserve Board contributed significantly to the lessened volatility of the U.S. economy? This paper uses a structural vector autoregressive (VAR) specification to address these questions, examining the advantages and limitations of such an approach. In contrast with much of the existing research on these topics, I find that most of the quantitatively significant changes in volatility are attributed to breaks in the non-policy portion of the structural VAR, and not to the identified policy equation.
Article
We provide a computationally simple method of analyzing the effects of fundamental and sunspot shocks in linear rational expectations models when the equilibrium is indeterminate. Under indeterminacy sunspots can affect model dynamics through endogenous forecast errors. Moreover, the effect of fundamental shocks on forecast errors is not uniquely determined. The solution method is illustrated with a New Keynesian dynamic stochastic equilibrium model that can be solved analytically. Under a passive interest-rate rule, the response of inflation to an unanticipated interest rate cut is ambiguous: there are some equilibria in which inflation increases and others in which prices fall.
Article
New Keynesian macroeconomic models have generally emphasized that expectations of future output are a key factor in determining current output. The theoretical motivation for such forward-looking behavior relies on a straightforward generalization of the well-known Euler equation for consumption. In this paper, we use maximum likelihood and generalized method of moments (GMM) methods to explore the empirical importance of output expectations. We find little evidence that rational expectations of future output help determine current output, especially after taking into account the small-sample bias in GMM.
Article
Was the Great Moderation in the United States due to good policy or good luck? Taking, as data generation process, a New Keynesian sticky-price model in which the only source of change is the move from a passive to an active monetary rule, we show how standard econometric methods, both reducedform and structural, often misinterpret good policy for good luck. Specifically, we show how such a move is perfectly compatible with: (a) little change in the estimated impulse-response functions to a monetary policy shock, as in Stock and Watson (2002), Primiceri (2005), Canova and Gambetti (2005), and Gambetti, Pappa, and Canova (2006). (b) Significant changes in the estimated volatilities of both reduced-form and structural shocks–as in (e.g.) Ahmed, Levin, and Wilson (2004) and Stock and Watson (2002)–even in the absence, by construction, of any change in the volatilities of structural innovations. (c) Little change in the integrated normalised spectra of inflation and GDP growth at the business-cycle frequencies, as in Ahmed, Levin, and Wilson (2004). In line with Bernanke’s (2004) conjecture, the explanation is that conventional econometric methods are intrinsically incapable of capturing the role played by the systematic component of monetary policy in (de)stabilising in- flation expectations, and are therefore inevitably bound to confuse shifts in expected inflation with true structural innovations, thus giving the illusion of good luck even when good policy is, by construction, the authentic explanation