ArticlePDF Available

Knowledge and Organization in the Theory of the Multinational Corporation: Some Foundational Issues

Authors:

Abstract

This paper addresses the interaction of knowledge and organization in IB research, particularly research on the MNC. The argument is advanced that although the MNC literature is quite advanced with respect to its treatment of firm-level knowledge, several closely connected problems remain. In particular, there has been an over-emphasis on knowledge flows and an under-emphasis on knowledge stocks; the micro-foundations of MNC knowledge are unclear; and there is a no clear understanding of the causal relations between knowledge stocks and flows and organizational control. A control theory approach that may resolve some of these problems is then sketched. Copyright Springer 2006
December 2003
Knowledge and Organization in the
Theory of the Multinational
Corporation: Some Foundational Issues
Nicolai J Foss
CKG WP 1/2004
CKG Working Paper No. 1/2004
December 2003
ISBN: 87-91506-16-6
Department of Management, Politics and Philosophy
Copenhagen Business School
The Center for Knowledge Governance
Blaagaardsgade 23 B
DK-2200 Copenhagen N
Denmark
Phone +45 3815 3630
Fax +45 3815 3635
E-mail: ckg.lpf@cbs.dk
www.cbs.dk/ckg
Knowledge and Organization in
the Theory of the Multinational Corporation:
Some Foundational Issues
Nicolai J Foss
Department of Management, Politics, and Philosophy
Copenhagen Business School
Blaagaardsgade 23B; 2200 Copenhagen N; Denmark
njf.lpf@cbs.dk
Keynote Speech to the European International Business Academy
Copenhagen, 10-12 December 2003
15 December 2003
Abstract
This talk addresses the interaction of knowledge and organization in IB research,
particularly research on the MNC. The argument is made that although the MNC
literature is quite advanced with respect to its treatment of firm-level knowledge,
several connected problems remain. In particular, there has been an over-emphasis
on knowledge flows and an under-emphasis on knowledge stocks; the
microfoundations of MNC knowledge are unclear; and there is a no clear
understanding of the causal relations between knowledge stocks and flows and
organizational control. A control theory approach that may resolve some of these
problems is then sketched.
Keywords
The MNC, knowledge, organizational control, control theory.
Acknowledgments
I am grateful to Gabriel Benito, Thorbjørn Knudsen, Torben Pedersen and Udo
Zander for discussion of the issues treated herein. The usual disclaimer applies.
1
Introduction
I don’t consider myself an international business scholar, so my perspective in this talk will
be that of an outsider to the field. Bringing outsiders in is sometimes warranted, because it
may provide a useful fresh look. Of course, there is also the possibility of utter confusion
and misunderstanding. What alternative has materialized is something I shall leave to your
judgment at the end, and take consolation in the fact that keynote speeches are
acknowledged vehicles for airing crazy ideas.
I shall do two things: First, I shall critically discuss the current treatment of knowledge
and organization in the theory of the MNC. I wish to argue that in spite of the present
popularity of “knowledge-based” approaches in the international business literature, the
field is still far from a coherent knowledge-based understanding of the MNC. There is no
elaborate and coherent conceptualization of what it means to say that the MNC is a
“knowledge-based entity.” There is (still) little understanding of how organizational control
impacts processes of knowledge sharing (transfer), integration, and creation. Conversely,
understanding of how existing stocks of knowledge (“capabilities”?) constrain the
application of mechanisms of organizational control is lacking. Thus, causality is unclear,
in the sense that extant research is not really clear about under which conditions knowledge
characteristics are best seen antecedents to the choice of mechanisms of organizational
control, and, conversely, under which conditions mechanisms of organizational control can
be chosen so as to influence the characteristics and flows of knowledge. Thus, the causal-
temporal structure of managerial choices relating to knowledge and organization in the
MNC is not clear.
Part of the problem is that we don’t have much of a useful apparatus to help us frame
these issues. I don’t necessarily call for finely honed, formal models. That may be an
ultimate ambition. However, what I believe is badly needed in the theory of the MNC, and
perhaps the international business field at large, are apparatuses that are in between the
loose, verbal account and the full-blown formal model. We may call such apparatuses
“heuristic frames” (Winter 1987), because they identify the variables that we are talking
about, and lay out their temporal-causal relations in a “heuristic” and not fully formal
manner. This leads into the second point of this talk: The issues may very usefully be
framed by means of using control theory as a relevant heuristic frame. The remainder of the
talk is organized around these two points.
Knowledge Gaps in the MNC Literature
Knowledge and Economic Organization in the IB Literature
It is to the lasting credit of the theory of the MNC that it took knowledge seriously as
a key factor in understanding economic organization long before the mainstream economics
of organization did this. As late as 1998 Bengt Holmström and John Roberts (1998: 90),
two of the leaders of formal organizational economics, observed that
Information and knowledge are at the heart of organizational design, because
they result in contractual and incentive problems that challenge both markets
and firms … In light of this, it surprising that leading economic theories … have
paid almost no attention to the role of organizational knowledge.
2
Observe that at the time that this statement was made, organizational knowledge had already
been a favorite construct in the international business field for more than a decade,
challenging, or at least complementing, the “leading economic theories” in that field. And
the idea that economic organization – specifically, the comparative contracting issue of
whether to export, license, establish foreign operations, etc. – may be influenced by the
characteristics of firm-specific assets other than that of asset specificity had been around
much longer.
In general, it seems that the MNC, or more generally, IB field has considerable lead-
time with respect to understanding how knowledge and economic organization connects.
In particular, the recent emphasis in the so-called “differentiated MNC literature” on
orchestrating knowledge flows between MNC units has brought some mainly empirically
based insight into the organizational requirements of knowledge transfer, and the
literature as a whole identifies key tradeoffs in organizational design, such as those between
keeping knowledge local or sharing it. These are tradeoffs that may apply to any firm, but
they are perhaps best and most vividly understood in the context of the MNC. In fact, the
argument may be made that the international business field would seem to be a preeminent
testing ground of knowledge-based theories, particularly as these pertain to economic
organization, because the knowledge issues that may drive economic organization (e.g.
costs of communicating across a market interface) are simply more likely to be pronounced
in an international than a national context.
Three Related Problems
Enough of praise. There are a number of (related) problems with extant work on
knowledge and organization in MNCs.
1
These are 1) an absence of methodological
individualist (or micro-) foundations, 2) lack of understanding of the MNC knowledge
structure, and 3) unclear causality. In my view, these three problems together provide the
main reason for our lack of understanding of how knowledge and organization interact in
the MNC. Consider them seriatim.
Absence of methodological individualist (micro) foundations. Like the knowledge-
based literature in general, notions of firm- or unit-specific “capabilities,” “competencies,”
“knowledge assets,” etc. abound. These are aggregate concepts. Such concepts are, of
course, not illegitimate per se, provided their foundation in individual behavior is
understood. However, this is hardly case for a notion such as firm-level “competence.”
Definitions of these terms, to the extent that they are given at all, tend to “define” these ill-
defined concepts in terms of other ill-defined concepts, such as defining competence in
terms of “capabilities” and “routines”). If pressed on the issue, proponents of notions of
competence etc. tend to invoke a number of conceptually different entities, such as
heuristics and strategies, organizational processes and arrangements, cognitive issues (e.g.,
“organizational memories”), and incentives (“truces”) many of which are equally in need
of clear definition and conceptualisation
2
and whose interrelations are entirely unclear.
Even more problematically, there is no real theory of choice behavior in recent
“knowledge-based” work. This may be seen from the way in which writers treat economic
organization in a methodological collectivist way, namely in terms of postulating crude
1
In actuality these are largely problems that plague the whole “knowledge movement”.
2
For a fuller discussion and critique, see Foss (2003).
3
causal relations between capabilities and economic organization, little attention being paid
to the micro-analytic issues involved. Not surprisingly, these stories are vulnerable to basic
critiques from the perspective of comparative contracting (Foss 1996; Williamson 1999).
Do these points matter for international business research, or are they merely
methodological niceties?
I think they do matter, both for theory building and for managerial implications. For
example, in much of the capabilities view, there is an unstated assumption that knowledge
inside firms is assumed be relatively homogenous, and therefore not very costly to
communicate, while knowledge between firms (“differential capabilities”) is taken to be
(very) heterogeneous (and therefore costly to communicate). Of course, recent work on the
“differentiated MNC” goes beyond this because of its heavy focus on cognitive and
motivational impediments to knowledge transfer between MNC units; thus, “differential
capabilities” within the firm (i.e., the MNC) are certainly recognized in this literature. Still,
because there is little explicit attention to individual rational choice in this approach,
arguments pertaining to intra-MNC knowledge transfer acquires an ad hoc character, and,
indeed, the literature seems to be very much empirically driven. The managerial implication
of the lack of proper methodological individualist foundations is that it is unclear how
knowledge processes may be influenced by mechanisms of organizational control, since
there is no specification of how these controls influences individual behavior with respect to
accumulating, building, sharing, integrating, etc. knowledge.
Lack of understanding of the MNC knowledge structure. This is a theme that I have
pursued recently with my colleague Torben Pedersen (Foss and Pedersen 2003). It is related
to the previous point. Although work on the MNC, and particularly recent work on the
differentiated MNC, certainly does not assume that all intra-MNC knowledge is essentially
homogenous, it remains true that comparatively little research has been devoted to
understanding the ways in which knowledge may be stratified, distributed, partly
overlapping, complementary or, in another word, structured inside MNCs (see Lyles and
Schwenk 1992). In fact, in general much more attention has been devoted to understanding
knowledge flows between MNC subsidiaries than to understanding the stratification of
knowledge stocks across the MNC. This is not satisfactory, for flows emerge from stocks,
as it were, and they change other stocks.
Unclear causality. The interaction between knowledge and organization is less clearly
conceptualized and framed in the IB literature than one could wish for. The key problem in
thinking about the interaction of knowledge and organization in the MNC has to do with
causality and temporality. Does knowledge constrain organization, or is it rather somehow
the way around, or is there some degree of simultaneity in their determination, or is it the
case that different kinds of organizational control influence knowledge flows whereas
knowledge stocks function as constraints on the feasible values of organizational
instruments, etc., etc.? These are important scientific questions, and there are obvious
managerial implications of getting the causality right. However, the IB literature does not
offer much of a theoretical framework to handle this kind of questions.
Research Opportunities: Knowledge and Organization
Whereas the MNC literature is much more advanced than the economics literature on
organization with respect to its treatment of knowledge, the latter is considerably more
advanced with respect to its treatment of incentives and property rights and how allocations
of these influence value-creation through the impact on various externality problems. There
4
is a lot to be said for bringing these two bodies of thought even more closely together. I
also think there is something to be said in favor of the notion of letting an economics-based
“rational action approach” take the lead in such an endeavour (see further Buckley and
Casson 2001).
Early economics-based contributions to the emerging MNC literature highlighted the
“internal market” aspects of the MNC (Buckley and Casson 1976). This remains a good
starting point for analysis. Specifically, we may look at “internal market failures” related to
the internal supply of various kinds of public goods and open access resources, and how
firms may deal with such failures (Vining 2003). Knowledge resources at various levels of
the MNC may be analysed in pretty much the standard terms of the theory of public goods
(i.e., degrees of excludability, rivalry in use, strategic behavior in connection with eliciting
information, bargaining problems, etc.).
This may help us understand better the peculiar management problems associated with
building, transferring and integrating knowledge in the MNC. Thus, we will become
knowledgeable about how reward systems, monitoring, and the allocation of decision and
ownership rights in MNCs influence these knowledge processes. However, an important
extra benefit is that we will better understand the MNC as a knowledge structure. This is
hardly a conventional argument, so I elaborate a bit here.
One may think of the overall MNC knowledge structure as a set of nodes connected by
arrows. The individual nodes refer to knowledge elements, such as, for example, a
marketing capability in a subsidiary in a certain country, or a patent held by the corporate
center. Nodes may be identical, as when two subsidiaries exploit the same patent. Notions
of organizational knowledge structures (as in Lyles and Schwenk 1992) and perhaps “core
competences” and the like can be represented as the set of identical nodes over subsidiaries
and MNC headquarters. Nodes may represent tacit or explicit knowledge, or knowledge
with or without public good character. Unidirectional arrows represent one-way spillovers;
arrows that go in both ways represent complementarities between knowledge elements.
How does organization, and organizational economics ideas, relate to such a
knowledge-based conceptualization? A useful first beginning may be to conceptualise
knowledge resources in the terms alluded to above, as being different in terms of their
degree of excludability. To some extent this is already done in the MNC literature; thus, the
familiar tacit-explicit knowledge distinction is (also) about the extent to which knowledge is
excludable from other potential users.
However, a key insight in the relevant economics literature, which I see only partly
reflected in the MNC literature, is that excludability is endogenous to managerial action.
Thus, depending on the relevant costs and benefits, knowledge can be made available to
multiple agents. Much more is involved in this than the transfers of knowledge between
MNC units that are so intensively discussed in recent literature. Also involved is the fact
that agents or MNC units may choose to make the knowledge they control excludable in
various ways, for example, because this gives them bargaining power in dealings with other
MNC units. A further dimension is that excludability has to do with knowledge
characteristics, as already indicated. However, knowledge characteristics are not
exogenously given; they are endogenous to instruments of organizational control (among
other things). Thus, incentives may be provided for revealing knowledge, organizational
knowledge management initiatives may be started, and expatriation initiatives clearly
influence the dissemination of knowledge within the MNC, all of which makes knowledge
5
less excluded and excludable. Alternatively, knowledge may deliberate be kept local and
tacit.
This line of reasoning suggests that what I earlier called the “MNC knowledge
structure” is to some extent endogenous to organizational arrangements and managerial
actions. In other words, fully understanding the way in which knowledge inside the MNC
is shared, dispersed, transferred, integrated, etc. requires that attention be paid to the latter
“control variables,” to use a terminology that I shall explain in the following.
Knowledge and Organization in the MNC:
A (Sketch of a) Control Theory Heuristic Frame
To briefly take stock, I have made the argument that there is an ill-understood intersection
between MNC knowledge, individual behaviour and organizational control. One of the
reasons why it is ill understood is that it is hard to see which models can assist
understanding here. Thus, the issues seem so complex and intricate that modelling them in
the rigorous fashion of the formal economist perhaps is and must remain a hopeless
ambition. On the other hand, current thinking on issues in the intersection between MNC
knowledge, individual behaviour and organizational control is too unsystematic and unclear,
as argued earlier. I agree wholeheartedly with Peter Buckley’s observation that what is
required in the core theory of international business research is “… careful redefinition of
the relationship between key explanatory variables so that new developments grow
organically from the theory rather than being added in a piecemeal and arbitrary fashion”
(Buckley 1990: 663). Issued 13 years ago, this statement still holds true.
What we certainly can and should strive for are frameworks that “ … identify the
relevant variables and the questions that the user must answer in order to develop
conclusions tailored to a particular industry and company” (Porter 1994: 428). And we can
do more than that, for we can also strive towards identifying and agreeing on which
variables we wish to think of as relatively fixed, at least in the short run, and which
variables we may think of a given to short-run managerial manipulation, and, finally, how
these variables relate over time. In other words, we can and should think systematically
about how we conceive of the time structure of managerial choice related to the interaction
between knowledge and organization variables (Postrel 2003). As I see it, the constraints on
this “modeling problem” is that we wish
… to make room for conscious managerial choice, but, given the complexity of the
choice problem(s) facing MNC management, we may not wish to portray decision-
makers as cognitive gods, that is, some notion of bounded rationality may be
appropriate;
… utilize some of the “stylized facts” relating to the time structure of managerial
choice, for example, that firm-level routines and capabilities may only change
slowly, while some kinds (certainly not all) of organizational control (e.g., relating
to delegation and the provision of incentives) can be changed in the short(er) run;
… to embed the interaction of MNC knowledge and organization in a strategic
context where the “MNC knowledge structure” is to some extent endogenous to
organizational arrangements and managerial actions.
6
Following the leads of Paul Rubin (1973), Sidney Winter (1987) and Steven Postrel (2003),
I argue that ideas from control theory may be particularly helpful for framing the issues.
3
Admittedly, this is not the only possible heuristic frame, but is arguably the one that best
meets the above restrictions on the relevant modeling problem.
Control Theory
The fundamental idea in control theory is summed up in the Alcoholics Anonymous
serenity prayer:
“God grant me the serenity to accept the things that I cannot change, courage to
change the things I can, and wisdom to know the difference” (cited in Winter
1987: 162).
Generalizing and adding a bit to the “wisdom” part, very little can be changed in the very
short run, some things can be changed in the longer run, and almost everything can be
changed in the very long run. (Economists will recognize this from Marshallian price
theory). The “courage” to change things is strategic decision making within such a temporal
framework.
More formally, control theory makes a distinction between three types of variables,
namely “control variables,” “state variables,” and “environmental variables.” Control
variables are those variables that can be set instantaneously at the various values within their
feasible ranges (i.e., control variables may be constrained). State variables are those that
change under the influence of the control variables. State variables may be constrained by
boundary conditions that determine starting values. Environmental variables are
parameters. Transition equations describe how changes in state variables are related to the
levels of state variables, and the values of control and environmental variables. An
objective function describes how the overall objective relates to state, control and
environmental variables.
The relevance of these distinctions for the problems that were considered earlier is that
they indicate one way to structure and make sense of the causal-temporal structure of
managerial choices relating to organization and knowledge. In the context of the arguments
I have sketched in the earlier sections, MNC knowledge stocks may be thought of as state
variables, and various kinds of organizational control (monitoring, incentives, order-giving)
may be thought of as control variables. Note also that control variables – those that most
directly reflect managerial choice – may be constrained within certain intervals. This
directs our attention to the foundations of managerial choice behaviour. Thus, Winter
(1987: 162) suggests that managerial attention is the ultimate constraint on managerial
choice, and Postrel (2003: 4) notes that for this reason, “… the allocation of attention is the
ultimate control variable at the disposal of the firm” (an idea that goes back at least to Edith
Penrose 1959). This provides at least the beginnings of a theory of individual behaviour, for
economizing with bounded rationality may in this manner be placed center stage in our
thinking about how knowledge and organization connects.
3
The classical mathematics reference is Pontryagin et al. (1962). The use of control theory to address
knowledge issues was first suggested by Rubin (1973) (modelling Penrose 1959) and was taken further by
Winter (1987). Postrel (2003) applies control theory to the resource-based view of the firm.
7
A Model Sketch
4
So, here is one way in which thinking about the causal-temporal structure of
managerial choices relating to knowledge and organization in an MNC setting may be
represented. To repeat, the purpose of the following is simply to suggest that thinking may
be somewhat advanced by laying out explicitly what one considers to be the relevant
variables and how they connect, what Winter (1987) calls a “heuristic frame.” For this
reason, the following is grossly simplified, makes several affronts to realism, and involves
highly questionable assumptions (e.g., that “knowledge characteristics” may be represented
as “a state variable” and that the external environment can be “freezed”). So be it.
I take the objective of the MNC to maximize profits over some time horizon (there are
t time periods) by means of building knowledge assets, and deploying them through the use
of organizational control to their best uses, for example, by means of intra-MNC knowledge
transfer. Ultimately, building knowledge assets is attractive because it may result in new
product characteristics and/or lower costs of production. However, there are various
(investment and organizational) costs of building, sharing, integrating, etc. such assets.
Moreover, managerial attention is limited, so it has to be economized with.
Control variables. The “building” aspect of earning profits from knowledge assets
suggests the importance of managerial choice. The relevant managerial control variables
are, first, a vector of instruments of organizational control, O
t
. These may include designing
incentives for knowledge building and ways of transferring best practices, monitoring these
activities, etc..
5
A second important control variable is investments in knowledge building,
I
t
, in the form of investments in organizational control designed to foster knowledge
building, purchasing knowledge on the relevant markets, hiring new knowledge workers,
acquiring knowledge-intensive new firms and integrating them into the MNC network, etc.
The Penrose-Winter-Postrel argument concerning scarce attention in organizations suggests
the importance of devoting attention to organizational control, a
t
, as a control variable.
State variables. The state variables are, first, the aggregate MNC knowledge stock, S
t
;
second, attention capacity, A
t
; third, knowledge characteristics, H
t
.
6
Of course, treating such
a thing as “knowledge characteristics” as a variable is a very crude simplification. If it
assists intuition, think of it as some measure of, say, the tacitness of the MNC knowledge
stock. The important thing is that knowledge characteristics may change under the impact
of the application of organizational instruments. For example, knowledge sharing programs
may be coupled with explicit monetary rewards to assist in making knowledge more explicit
and easier to share.
Environmental variables. The environmental variables include wages, w; and a
stochastic knowledge shock process that represents innovations outside the firm,
t
}.
4
The following is a modification of Postrel (2003).
5
Although these variables are, of course, discrete, they may be modelled as being continuous within their
feasible ranges; for example, incentive intensity lies in the interval [0,1] (the β of agency theory).
6
Any organization theorist will also tell us that important aspects of organization belongs to the class of state
variables, notably organizational beliefs and culture. Indeed, some may argue that there is no clear line of
demarcation between these aspects of organization and such knowledge assets as “organizational
competence.” All this may be granted; however, for the sake of simplicity, we neglect all this.
8
Objective function. We fix prices, p; production capacity, K; capital costs, r, and
abstract from the actions of rivals. Given this, the instantaneous profits for the firm can be
written as
7
:
(1) π
t
= pq
t
Kr – C
t
- I
t
- wA
t
, where
(2) q
t
= min [D
t
, K].
(3) D
t
= D (V
t
p).
(4) V
t
= V (O
t
, H
t,
A
t
).
(5) H
t
= H (O
t
, I
t
)
(6) C
t
= C (q
t
, K, O
t
, A
t
, S
t
, H
t
,
t
}).
Here, D is demand and V is the willingness to pay. Willingness to pay depends on
product characteristics that in turn can be influenced by means of organizational control.
The idea is that instruments of organizational control can be adopted to initiate and
accomplish, for example, the transfer of knowledge of how to provide certain product
certain characteristics from one MNC unit to another one. Knowledge characteristics
influence the costs and benefits of such transfer processes. Attention also influences
willingness to pay, because attention may be allocated to innovating new product
characteristics.
Organizational control also enters into the determination of production costs, together
with output, capacity, the aggregate MNC knowledge stock, S
t
and stochastic shocks to
technology. The idea here is the same as above: Instruments of organizational instruments
may be chosen to influence the transfer of knowledge about production processes; to the
extent that best practice is successfully transferred, production costs are lowered. Moreover,
such instruments may be chosen to influence process innovation; for example, rewards may
be tied to the discovery of incremental improvements of processes. Finally, knowledge
characteristics also determine overall MNC costs of production. This is because knowledge
characteristics co-determine the transfer of best-practice technology. Thus, MNCs that can
easily transfer best-practice technology likely have lower overall costs of production than
those MNCs where transfer is more difficult. The allocation of attention influences costs of
production; for example, managerial attention may be allocated to breaking bottlenecks in
the production process, reducing cost of production.
Transition equations. The three state variables are updated in the following way:
(7) S
t
= S
t-1
+ s (I
t
, O
t,
).
(8) A
t
= A
t-1
+ a (I
t,
O
t
).
(9) H
t
= H
t -1
+ h (I
t
,O
t
,).
Thus, the MNC knowledge stock evolves under the application of organizational control
instruments and investments in knowledge building; attention capacity may be expanded
through such investments as purchasing knowledge on the relevant markets, hiring new
knowledge workers, and acquiring knowledge-intensive new firms; and the characteristics
of the MNC knowledge structure evolves under the application of instruments of
7
The actual objective function is of course the expected presented discounted value of (1).
9
organizational control applied to manipulating this structure as well as investments in
knowledge building.
Feasible sets and initial conditions. In any period control variables are set within their
relevant feasible sets. Investments in knowledge acquisition, I
t
,
are obviously constrained
upwards by the size of internal cash flows and the character of capital markets. I
t
may be
negative, as when knowledge erodes (“organizational forgetting”?). It is constrained in the
downward direction by the complete erosion of the MNC knowledge stock. Given the
primitive way that organizational control, O
t
, have been characterized, it is perhaps
premature to go into detail about how it is constrained. However, such elements of of the O
t
vector as incentive pay is constrained, for the individual agent, by how much of the total
wage that can be paid as variable pay (namely (close to) 100 %).
Implications
One could try to solve the dynamic programming problem implied by (1) – (8), a
pretty complex affair given the size of the problem. However, the main point of the
exercise is to exemplify by means of sketching a heuristic frame how thinking about key
relations between important variables may be furthered. Thus, although the above heuristic
frame is entirely (hopelessly?) simplistic, it nevertheless helps us to focus attention on some
key points:
As stated, it lays bare the temporal-causal structure between key variables related
to the building and transfer of knowledge in the MNC and the role played by
organizational control in this process.
In particular, the argument has been made that some variables are more
constraining than others. Thus, “capabilities” is a shorthand for the constraints
represented by the existing MNC knowledge stock, the existing amount of
available attention, and the characteristics of knowledge. These state variables
both constrain and enable the MNC’s shorter-run actions. The control theory
heuristic frame therefore clarifies which are the “stock-like” variables and which
are the “flow-like” variables and how the relate.
The key to understanding how capabilities develop in the MNC lies in
understanding the functional forms s (), a (), and h () in the transition equations
((6) – (8)).
The development of capabilities may be understood in terms of, relatively
operational, control variables, notably organizational control and investments in
building knowledge.
The functional forms in the transition equations suggests that the relevant control
variables, that is, organizational control and investments in building knowledge,
may be either substitutes or complements with respect to their impact on the
relevant state variables. This suggests an empirical research agenda of
considerable managerial relevance.
MNCs may differ because the functional forms of their transition equations, that is,
s (), a (), and h (), differ. Thus, not all firms are equally capable in building and
transferring knowledge inside the MNC, augmenting the MNC knowledge stock
10
from outside sources, and influence the characteristics of knowledge so as to
facilitate knowledge transfer.
Over time the allocation of attention means that the MNC cannot be the best at all
activities. The reason is that allocation constraints means that firms cannot devote
optimum attention to all activities (Postrel 2003: 10). In terms of the model,
attention influences both process innovation and the introduction of new product
characteristics and these activities compete for scarce attention. Increasing returns
to allocating attention to one activity causes knowledge specialization. The
ultimate constraint on the building of capabilities may be the available attention.
The heuristic frame not only implies more precision about the relations between
the key variables, it also suggests a sort of micro-foundation for thinking about
knowledge in the MNC. The emphasis on the allocation attention and on
managers as being forward looking but bounded rational is one component of such
a foundation.
Conclusions
This talk has roamed widely, as, I suppose, befits a keynote speech. Whether it has roamed
too widely is up to you to decide. To briefly take stock, among the points I have made are
these:
Although it is to the lasting credit of the MNC literature that it at very early treated
knowledge issues in the context of organization, much of the thinking about these
issues suffer from two problems:
o 1. A lack of clarity with respect to the temporal-causal relations between key
organizational and knowledge-related variables.
o 2. An absence of a clear rational action foundation for thinking about how
knowledge and organization connects.
Control theory provides a convenient heuristic frame for thinking about these issues,
that is, identifying which are the relevant variables and how they connect.
A number of conclusions follow immediately from such an approach. In particular,
we are led to think in a more disciplined manner about the nature, characteristics,
and development of MNC knowledge, about what are the constraints on the
development of such capabilities, and how knowledge stocks and knowledge flows
interact in the process under the impact of mechanisms of organizational control.
11
References
Buckley, Peter J. 1990. “Problems and Developments in the Core Theory of International
Business, “Journal of International Business Studies 657- 665.
Buckley, Peter J and Mark Casson. 1976. The Future of the Multinational Enterprise.
London:
Buckley, Peter J and Mark Casson. 2001. “Strategic Complexity in International Business,”
in Alan M Rugman and Thomas L Brewer, eds. 2001. The Oxford Handbook of
International Business. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Foss, Nicolai J. 1996. “Knowledge-Based Approaches to the Theory of the Firm: Some
Critical Comments,” Organization Science 7: 470-476.
Foss, Nicolai J. 2003. “Bounded Rationality and Tacit Knowledge in the Organizational
Capabilities Approach: an Evaluation and a Stocktaking,” Industrial and Corporate
Change 12: 185-201.
Foss, Nicolai and Torben Pedersen. “The MNC as a Knowledge Structure: The Roles of
Knowledge Sources and Organizational Instruments in MNC Knowledge
Management,” Working Paper 2003-, Center for Knowledge Governance,
Copenhagen Business School, http://www.cbs.dk/ckg/
Gupta, Anil K. and Vijay Govindarajan. 2000. “Knowledge Flows Within Multinational
Corporations,” Strategic Management Journal 21: 473-496.
Holmström, Bengt and John Roberts. 1998. “The Boundaries of the Firm Revisited,”
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12: 73-94.
Lyles, Marjorie A. and Charles R. Schwenk. 1992. “Top Management, Strategy, and
Organizational Knowledge Structures,” Journal of Management Studies 29: 155-174.
Penrose, Edith T. 1959. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Pontryagin, L.S., V.G. Boltyanskii, R.V. Gamkrelidze, and E.F. Mischenko. 1962. The
Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes. New York: Interscience.
Porter, Michael E. 1994. „Toward a Dynamic Theory of Strategy,“ in Richard Rumelt, Dan
Schendel and David Teece, eds. 1994. Fundamental Issues in Strategy: a Research
Agenda. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Postrel, Steven. 2003. “Resources and Capabilities as Constraint,” paper for the Academy of
Management Meetings, Seattle, 1-8 August, 2003.
Rubin, Paul. 1973. “The Expansion of Firms,” Journal of Political Economy 81: 936-949.
Vining, Aidan. 2003. “Internal Market Failure: A Framework for Diagnosing Firm
Inefficiency,” Journal of Management Studies 40: 431-457.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1999. ”Strategy Research: Governance and Competence
Perspectives,” Strategic Management Journal 20: 1087-1108.
Winter, Sidney G. 1987. “Knowledge and Competence as Strategic Assets,” in David J.
Teece, ed. The Competitive Challenge. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publ. Co.
CKG – Working Papers
www.cbs.dk/ckg
2003
2003-1:
Nicolai J. Foss, Kenneth Husted, Snejina Michailova, and Torben Pedersen:
Governing Knowledge Processes: Theoretical Foundations and Research
Opportunities.
2003-2:
Yves Doz, Nicolai J. Foss, Stefanie Lenway, Marjorie Lyles, Silvia Massini,
Thomas P. Murtha and Torben Pedersen: Future Frontiers in International
Management Research: Innovation, Knowledge Creation, and Change in
Multinational Companies.
2003-3:
Snejina Michailova and Kate Hutchings: The Impact of In-Groups and Out-
Groups on Knowledge Sharing in Russia and China CKG Working Paper.
2003-4:
Nicolai J. Foss and Torben Pedersen : The MNC as a Knowledge Structure: The
Roles of Knowledge Sources and Organizational Instruments in MNC Knowledge
Management CKG Working Paper.
2003-5:
Kirsten Foss, Nicolai J. Foss and Xosé H. Vázquez-Vicente: “Tying the Manager’s
Hands”: How Firms Can Make Credible Commitments That Make Opportunistic
Managerial Intervention Less Likely CKG Working Paper.
2003-6:
Marjorie Lyles, Torben Pedersen and Bent Petersen: Knowledge Gaps: The Case
of Knowledge about Foreign Entry.
2003-7:
Kirsten Foss and Nicolai J. Foss: The Limits to Designed Orders: Authority under
“Distributed Knowledge” CKG Working Paper.
2003-8:
Jens Gammelgaard and Torben Pedersen: Internal versus External Knowledge
Sourcing of Subsidiaries - An Organizational Trade-Off.
2003-9:
Kate Hutchings and Snejina Michailova: Facilitating Knowledge Sharing in
Russian and Chinese Subsidiaries: The Importance of Groups and Personal
Networks Accepted for publication in Journal of Knowledge Management.
2003-10:
Volker Mahnke, Torben Pedersen and Markus Verzin: The impact of knowledge
management on MNC subsidiary performance: the role of absorptive capacity
CKG Working Paper.
2003-11:
Tomas Hellström and Kenneth Husted: Mapping Knowledge and Intellectual
Capital in Academic Environments: A Focus Group Study Accepted for
publication in Journal of Intellectual Capital CKG Working Paper.
2003-12:
Nicolai J Foss: Cognition and Motivation in the Theory of the Firm: Interaction or
“Never the Twain Shall Meet”? Accepted for publication in Journal des Economistes
et des Etudes Humaines CKG Working Paper.
2003-13:
Dana Minbaeva and Snejina Michailova: Knowledge transfer and expatriation
practices in MNCs: The role of disseminative capacity.
2003-14:
Christian Vintergaard and Kenneth Husted: Enhancing selective capacity through
venture bases.
2004
2004-1:
Nicolai J. Foss: Knowledge and Organization in the Theory of the Multinational
Corporation: Some Foundational Issues
2004-2:
Dana B. Minbaeva: HRM practices and MNC knowledge transfer
2004-3:
Bo Bernhard Nielsen and Snejina Michailova: Toward a phase-model of global
knowledge management systems in multinational corporations
2004-4:
Kirsten Foss & Nicolai J Foss: The Next Step in the Evolution of the RBV:
Integration with Transaction Cost Economics
2004-5:
Teppo Felin & Nicolai J. Foss: Methodological Individualism and the
Organizational Capabilities Approach
2004-6:
Jens Gammelgaard, Kenneth Husted, Snejina Michailova: Knowledge-sharing
Behavior and Post-acquisition Integration Failure
... Given that, knowledge generation is contingent upon the interdependency between a static knowledge stock and a dynamic knowledge flow (Wu & Shanley, 2009), the internal knowledge structure does not only provide the base to acquire new knowledge, but also shapes the scope and direction of future knowledge exploration (Wu & Shanley, 2009). For instance, knowledge stock has been suggested to be related to the recognition, assimilation and utilization (i.e., exploitation) of new knowledge (Foss, 2006), which are crucial for inbound OI practices. Importantly, knowledge structure seems to not be one monolithic whole, but rather has been studied, albeit scantily, along three different dimensions, namely, the 1) breadth and depth of knowledge, 2) short-term versus long-term knowledge and 3) the retrieval of knowledge (Volberda, Foss & Lyles, 2010). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
The successful integration of internal and external knowledge is crucial for the success of inbound open innovation processes. Yet, to date, our understanding of how different kinds of knowledge characteristics affect the knowledge absorption process in inbound open innovation is still rather fragmented. In this chapter, the authors provide an overview of how different aspects of knowledge (i.e., internal and external knowledge antecedents: prior knowledge, internal and external knowledge structure, knowledge source, types of knowledge, and knowledge environment) related to knowledge absorption in the inbound open innovation process. In the discussion, the authors highlight how far different knowledge characteristics either help or hinder knowledge absorption and, thereby, the potential success of inbound open innovation practices. Moreover, they point towards areas that promise to be fruitful for future research exploring the link between aspects of knowledge and absorptive capacity in the context of inbound open innovation.
... Its primary focus is on the capacity of subsidiaries and it is largely an organizational, 'depersonalized' view of the multinational. More recent contributions have begun to explore the micro-foundations of knowledge creation and transfer in MNCs, indicating a trend towards recognizing the role of individual actors in this line of research (Foss, 2006;Johnson and Duxbury, 2010). This literature addresses an area-knowledge transfer-that globalizing actors might be involved in, but work remains to be done on individuals whose roles are transnational in nature as well as the nature of the transnational work. ...
Chapter
MNCs are important players in the diffusion of management ideas, knowledge and norms across borders because of pressures to standardize practices as much as possible, while adapting to local differences as much as necessary. The international management literature increasingly highlights the important role of individuals within those MNCs in cross-border norm diffusion, but we still lack an integrated approach to these ‘globalizing actors’ and their activities. We discuss international management research related to knowledge transfer in MNCs, international assignments and global elites and consider its contributions and limitations in terms of aiding our understanding of globalizing actors in relation to management ideas. Arguing that this work holds important insights, but says little about how actors mobilize their skills and resources to navigate complex environments, we draw on a more diverse range of research to bring context and person back into focus.
... This article also addresses the important question, discussed by Foss and Pedersen (2004), of how MNE managers at both the subsidiary and headquarters level can orchestrate knowledge transfer activities in the MNE network and how this affects knowledge transfer effectiveness. The link between organizational processes and knowledge transfer is still under-researched (Foss, 2006). This article connects actions taken by headquarters with more micro-features associated with subsidiaries engaged in knowledge transfer, that is, the social structures of inter-subsidiary relationships (Szulanski, Cappetta, and Jensen, 2004) that can help explain knowledge transfer effectiveness. ...
Chapter
This article examines the utilization of knowledge transferred between sending and receiving subsidiaries within multinational enterprises. A model was developed and tested on 169 specific knowledge transfer projects. The model explains the utilization of knowledge subject to transfer in terms of hierarchical governance tool efficacy and lateral relationships within the multinational enterprise. The results show that headquarters' involvement during knowledge development does not have any significant impact on subsequent knowledge utilization in the receiving units and, in fact, hierarchical governance forms have a negative impact on knowl- edge utilization. However, lateral relationships are positive stimuli to building subsidiary capabilities in the knowledge transfer process that enhance receiving unit knowledge utilization.
Article
In this paper, our goal is twofold: First, we investigate how the headquarters (HQ) choice of knowledge transfer mechanisms is linked to (1) different types of organizational knowledge and (2) structural conditions. Second, we apply a meta-synthesis approach to cumulate empirical findings of a set of qualitative case studies which, due to the difficulty of the interpretation and generalization of results, generally tend to remain isolated, and their potential to advance knowledge in the field is largely ignored. By synthesizing primary case study evidence across a set of nine qualitative case studies, we show that HQ used a large set of measures to indirectly influence knowledge transfer in more decentralized companies. Put differently, by making conscious choices of how to transfer knowledge, MNEs can overcome structural impediments to its transfer. The technique used in this paper can be a source of inspiration for other researchers in this and related fields. JEL Codes: F23
Book
Full-text available
Innovation contributes to corporate competitiveness, economic performance, and environmental sustainability. In the Internet era, innovation intelligence is transferred across borders and languages at an unprecedented rate, yet the ability to benefit from it seems to become more divergent among different corporations and countries. How much an organization can benefit from innovation largely depends on how well innovation is managed in it. Thus, there is a discernible increase in interest in the study of innovation management. This handbook provides a comprehensive guide to this subject. The handbook introduces the basic framework of innovation and innovation management. It also presents innovation management from the perspectives of strategy, organization, resource, as well as institution and culture. The book's comprehensive coverage on all areas of innovation management makes this a very useful reference for anyone interested in the subject.
Article
Given the project-based organization’s (PBO) strong focus on autonomy and temporary decentralisation, it faces unique challenges with regard to long-term organisational learning and capability development. To address how PBOs cope with these challenges, we address the role of knowledge governance (KG) mechanisms to foster capability development. The present paper reports on a multiple case study comprising 23 PBOs and demonstrates the importance of ‘configurations of KG mechanisms’ for facilitating learning and capability development. This paper develops four distinct configurations (balanced, formalistic, interactive, and fragile) that promote three principal organisational-level learning processes: shifting, leveraging and adapting. This research underscores the close relationship between knowledge governance mechanisms and capability development and the importance of designing the appropriate configuration of KG mechanisms to foster capability development.
Article
Full-text available
Reflections on the early days of computing, the importance of standards, and The Old Man.
Article
Pursuing a nodal (i.e., subsidiary) level of analysis, this paper advances and tests an overarching theoretical framework pertaining to intracorporate knowledge transfers within multinational corporations (MNCs). We predicted that (i) knowledge outflows from a subsidiary would be positively associated with value of the subsidiary’s knowledge stock, its motivational disposition to share knowledge, and the richness of transmission channels; and (ii) knowledge inflows into a subsidiary would be positively associated with richness of transmission channels, motivational disposition to acquire knowledge, and the capacity to absorb the incoming knowledge. These predictions were tested empirically with data from 374 subsidiaries within 75 MNCs headquartered in the U.S., Europe, and Japan. Except for our predictions regarding the impact of source unit's motivational disposition on knowledge outflows, the data provide either full or partial support to all of the other elements of our theoretical framework. Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Book
Introduction to the Second Edition - Preface - The Multinational Enterprise in the World Economy - A Long-run Theory of the Multinational Enterprise - Alternative Theories of the Multinational Enterprise - The World's Largest Firms - Predictions and Policy Implications - Index
Chapter
This chapter outlines a progressive research agenda for the field of international business studies. In retrospect there have been significant theoretical achievements in international business (IB) over the past 40 years, but there has also been a loss of focus.
Article
Participants in research and development alliances face a difficult challenge: how to maintain sufficiently open knowledge exchange to achieve alliance objectives while controlling knowledge flows to avoid unintended leakage of valuable technology. Prior research suggests that choosing an appropriate organizational form or governance structure is an important mechanism in achieving a balance between these potentially competing concerns. This does not exhaust the set of possible mechanisms available to alliance partners, however. h? this paper we explore an alternative response to hazards of R&D cooperation: reduction of the 'scope' of the alliance. We argue that when partner firms are direct competitors in end product or strategic resource markets even 'protective' governance structures such as equity joint ventures may provide insufficient protection to induce extensive knowledge sharing among alliance participants. Rather than abandoning potential gains from cooperation altogether in these circumstances, partners choose to limit the scope of alliance activities to those that can be successfully completed with limited (and carefully regulated) knowledge sharing. Our arguments are supported by empirical analysis of a sample of international R&D alliances involving electronics and telecommunications equipment companies. Copyright (C) 2004 John Wiley Sons, Ltd.
Article
Pursuing a nodal (i.e., subsidiary) level of analysis, this paper advances and tests art overarching theoretical framework pertaining to intracorporate knowledge transfers within multinational corporations (MNCs). We predicted that (i) knowledge outflows from a subsidiary would be positively associated with value of the subsidiary's knowledge stock, its motivational disposition to share knowledge, and the richness of transmission channels; and (ii) knowledge inflows into a subsidiary would be positively associated with richness of transmission channels, motivational disposition to acquire knowledge, and the capacity to absorb the incoming knowledge. These predictions were tested empirically with data from 374 subsidiaries within 75 MNCs headquartered in the U.S., Europe, and Japan. Except for our predictions regarding the impact of source unit's motivational disposition on knowledge outflows, the data provide either full or partial support to an of the other elements of our theoretical framework. Copyright (C) 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Article
Business strategy is a complex subject and is usefully examined from several perspectives. This paper applies the lenses of governance and competence to the study of strategy. Both the governance and the competence perspectives have had the benefit of distinguished antecedents. They have also had to deal with tautological reputations. I begin with the governance perspective, with emphasis on the six key moves through which it has been operationalized. I then examine the competence perspective in these same six respects. Governance challenges the competence perspective to apply itself more assiduously to operationalization, including the need to choose and give definition to one or more units of analysis (of which the 'routine' is a promising candidate). The research challenges posed by competence to which governance can and should respond include dynamic transaction costs, learning, and the need to push beyond generic governance to address strategy issues faced by particular firms (with their distinctive strengths and disabilities). A lively research future for these two perspectives, individually and in combination, is projected.