ArticlePDF Available

Mix-Up: Models of Governance and Framing Opportunities in U.S. and EU Consumer Policy

Authors:

Abstract

Students of comparative politics have highlighted different styles of regulation in the U.S. and Europe. These differences also apply to consumer policy and its different models of governance. The paper holds that governance is a key variable but adds aspects of issue framing. Two examples of consumer policy are analysed: regulation of genetically modified organisms and tobacco control. The case studies show that features of governance such as adversarial legalism or the precautionary principle are not necessarily linked to distinctive styles of regulation. Instead they vary across policy fields. Only a mix of governance elements and framing opportunities for interest groups can explain output and new directions of consumer policy. Dilemmas of collective action appear to be shrinking for consumers because framing trumps mobilization of members. Copyright Springer 2005
Provided for non-commercial research and educational use only.
Not for reproduction, distribution or commercial use.
This article was originally published in the International Encyclopedia of the Social
& Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, published by Elsevier, and the attached copy
is provided by Elsevier for the author’s benefit and for the benefit of the
author’s institution, for non-commercial research and educational use including
without limitation use in instruction at your institution, sending it to specific
colleagues who you know, and providing a copy to your institution’s administrator.
All other uses, reproduction and distribution, including
without limitation commercial reprints, selling or
licensing copies or access, or posting on open
internet sites, your personal or institution’s website or
repository, are prohibited. For exceptions, permission
may be sought for such use through Elsevier’s
permissions site at:
http://www.elsevier.com/locate/permissionusematerial
From Strünck, C., 2015. Consumer Policy. In: James D. Wright (editor-in-chief),
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Vol
4. Oxford: Elsevier. pp. 733–737.
ISBN: 9780080970868
Copyright © 2015 Elsevier Ltd. unless otherwise stated. All rights reserved.
Elsevier
Author's personal copy
Consumer Policy
Christoph Stru
¨nck, School of Arts and Humanities, University of Siegen, Siegen, Germany
Ó2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Abstract
Consumer policy aims at protecting and empowering consumers. Consumers are a very large group but they suffer problems
of collective actions. This is why governments, consumer organizations, and companies apply tools such as bans, regulations,
advice, litigation, or self-regulatory standards. Relations between companies and consumers are asymmetrical, with
consumers lacking vital information. Additionally, behavioral economics reveal striking biases: habits, norms, and irrational
attitudes shape everyday consumption. Governance of consumer policy is different, however, resting on different ideas and
ideologies, as comparative politics shows. Complex digital markets, the service industry, and the quest for sustainable
consumption are core challenges to consumer policy.
Introduction
Companies need consumers to sell. Consumers need compa-
nies to deliver. The relation between companies and consumers
is not as adversarial as between employers and employees.
Neoclassic economics holds that markets will provide whatever
individual consumers long for: good quality, low prices, and
choice at every level. Why consumer policy, then?
Consumers stand on the weak side of an asymmetric rela-
tionship. Struggling with information overload and short on
time, comparing products is messy. Lots of information biases
as well as behavioral biases shape consumption. This is why
collective action of consumers is necessary to maintain effective
markets. Supposing, mass of consumers buy products with
minor aws. No single consumer will take up efforts to
complain or even to sue. This collective behavior leads to
economic inefciency. More fundamentally, people expect
governments to safeguard against dangerous products and
hazards. Last but not least, consumers also bear political
responsibility because buying comes with price tags for others.
This is why collective action is necessary.
Consumers are among the largest social groups in society,
spanning all categories of social status, gender, age, and cultural
attitudes. Consumption is both the basic need and symbol of
expression. To consume is not only to buy a good, but also the
way consumers use and recycle those goods is at least as
important as purchase. Consumption is both individual choice
and social behavior, it is deeply rooted in group thinking,
norms, and tradition, and it is mostly embedded in house-
holds. Yet, consumers are not as well organized as employees,
professions, or business groups. Their collective action prob-
lems exceed those of most other groups.
Consumers are a large and heterogeneous group that suffers
a fundamental dilemma of free riding. Consumers neatly tin
what Mancur Olson called diffuse and weak interests(Olson,
2003): nobody is willing to join collective action because
everyone will benet from it. This is why governments often
support and subsidize consumer organizations, especially in
Europe. In the United States, foundations and public interest
law rms act as political entrepreneurs.
Additionally, governments act on behalf of consumers:
they ban dangerous products, they enact safety and quality
standards, and they regulate markets to protect consumers.
Consumer policy cuts across different realms. As for the United
States, agencies such as the Federal Trade Commission, the
Environmental Protection Agency, or the Food and Drug
Administration are in charge.
Consumer policy is not just government action and
collective action of consumer groups. Companies pursue
consumer policy, too. A classic example is self-regulation. In
most advanced economies, there are self-regulatory bodies of
industry. They monitor markets and blame competitors for
wrongful practices.
Summed up, consumer policy aims at protecting consumers
and empowering them to make informed choices. Govern-
ments, associations, and companies carry out consumer policy.
Policy tools include bans, standards, obligations, education,
information, and litigation. Consumer policy is mainly regu-
latory policy; it is less distributive or redistributive. Thus, costs
and benets are usually spread quite evenly. You might expect
consumer policy to be a cherished subject for politicians, then.
However, consumer policy has to cope with a classic
dilemma of cross-cutting policies (Stone, 2012). Most policies
have clear boundaries in which government, business, and
interest groups are separated from other constituencies. This is
the case with social policy, environmental policy, or agricul-
tural policy. With consumer policy, things are different.
Consumer issues cut across a whole range of policies. On the
one hand, regulatory capture is less likely because there is no
iron triangleof vested interests. On the other hand, compre-
hensive policies are less likely, too. Additionally, when costs are
spread evenly it might provoke resistance from all sectors of
business. Thus, similar to redistributive policies, consumer
policy is shaped by conicts and ideologies.
Are Consumers Rational: Ideas and Ideologies
in Consumer Policy
Every policy faces cleavages that affect collective interests. As for
consumer policy, it comes with a price tag for companies. They
might have to disclose information on products and yield
certain rights to consumers. Lawmakers argue that rules apply
to everybody in order to maintain fair competition. Business
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Volume 4 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.75057-4 733
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, Second Edition, 2015, 733–737
Author's personal copy
groups argue that consumers are sovereign to decide on their
own. However, business groups are split over goals and
instruments of consumer policy. Companies with high quality
standards even support stronger rules to single out lemons.
Yet, the core conict is about rational consumption. Do
consumers act rationally; do they bear full responsibility for
what they are doing? The paradigm of rational consumers is
rooted in neoclassic economics. Equivalent to perfect markets,
consumers are well informed and sovereign. However, insti-
tutional economics has hinted that transaction costs for
consumers can be high. Additionally, institutional economics
highlight asymmetrical relations between companies and
consumers, as the famous market for lemonsby Akerlof has
shown (Akerlof, 1970): buyers of used cars cannot correctly
asses the quality of what they are buying. This problem
systematically undermines effectiveness of markets. Only
institutional rules can guarantee that consumers benet from
markets whose products they cannot compare as easily as
textbook wisdom suggests.
Institutional economics paved the way for the information
approach: consumer policy has to provide special information
to make up for disadvantages of consumers. More recently,
behavioral economics has cast doubt on the information
approach.Experiments show that framing, anchor effects, and
habits shape consumption predominantly. Most consumers
lack time and knowledge to compare, being stuck in routines
and habits. Rational choiceis rare; often it is impossible
(Albanese, 2006;Hantula, 2012). There are even effects of
information overload that confuse consumers.
Additionally, there is no such thing as the average
consumer. Social science has detected different types: condent
consumers, responsible consumers, and vulnerable consumers
(Gronow and Warde, 2001). Instruments and strategies of
consumer policy need to be tailored to the needs of different
forms of behavior.
These ndings undermine conventional arguments on
consumption. They also fuel ideological struggles in consumer
policy. Should consumer policy just provide information or
should it guide consumers? Does soft paternalism clash with
individual choice and free markets? Should consumer policy
focus on individual consumers or should it support group
action? Is the general notion of consumersin line with
complex and heterogeneous societies?
Conicts about ideas and ideologies have unfolded in
different countries, embedding different approaches toward
consumer policy. Ideas and ideologies not only include
assumptions about consumers but also stretch to regulatory
devices like the much debated precautionary principle.
Convergence or Divergence: Governance of Consumer
Policy in Advanced Economies
For a long time, policies in the United States seemed to be more
risk averse when it came to protecting consumers. Research
reveals that the tide turned in 1990: since then it was rather the
European Union and its member states that invented strict
regulatory standards (Vogel, 2012). When it came to pharma-
ceuticals, chemicals, or food safety, US standards were strictest
before 1990. Business groups complained about drug lagsand
red tape. Deregulation and Reaganomics in the United States
boosted costbenet analysis as a tool for risk regulation
during the 1980s. Lobbying by business groups scaled back the
precautionary principle further.
In the European Union, the common market brought
about change. Following the Single European Act of 1986,
regulatory competition unfolded in Europe. It often came with
aCalifornia effect(Vogel, 1997): inuential countries with
high standards of consumer protection served as blueprints.
Subsequently, a race to the top went off. It also gave legitimacy
to policies of deregulation. The European Commission
championed these rules worldwide in order to achieve
comparative advantages.
Theoretically and empirically, the precautionary principle is
ambiguous. The rule of thumb better safe than sorrycan avert
risks yet it can also deprive consumers of innovation (Sunstein,
2008). Anyway, the precautionary principle is not just meant to
spare consumers risks. It might also serve as an equivalent for
old school protectionism.
The history of the precautionary principle proves that
motives and hidden agendas of consumer policy are manifold.
Consumer policy can also boost the market position of
national business. Yet governance is never rationally con-
structed. It results from a mix of culture, political institutions,
lobbyism, and economic structure.
Existing modes of governance treat consumers as citizens, as
buyers, or as social groups (Trumbull, 2006). Citizens with
their rights shape the protection model,whereas buyers are
linked to the information model.Consumers as social and
political group nourish the negotiation model.The United
States came close to the protection model,Germany largely
represents the information model,and most Scandinavian
countries have enshrined the negotiation model.
Historically, governance of consumer policy has been
shaped by regulatory tradition, legal systems, and other
institutional factors. The protection model in the United
States emerged because regulatory agencies, common law,
and judicial activism paved the way for mobilizing consumers
(Vogel, 2012). Vice versa, public interest groups achieved new
rights that could be enforced through litigation.
In Germany, ordoliberal tradition of economic policy
considered competition to be the key for consumer policy
(Kelemen, 2011). Government created a unique endowment,
the Stiftung Warentest (product testing). It is supposed to
provide neutral testing and information that serves all
consumers.
In contrast, Scandinavian countries like Sweden have
invented institutions like the ombudsman that consumer
groups and business groups can turn to. This model does not
treat consumers as anonymous buyers but as an organized
group that can deal with conicts. However, the relation is not
considered adversarial as in the case of the United States.
Instead, procedures are supposed to mitigate cooperative
relations.
In the meantime, there are signs of convergence. Sweden has
invented class action for consumer issues, adding some
elements of the protection model.Regulatory agencies in
Germany will get a mandate of consumer protection, resem-
bling patterns in the United States and the United Kingdom.
In addition, the European Union is still planning to bolster
734 Consumer Policy
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, Second Edition, 2015, 733–737
Author's personal copy
public interest litigation. Consumer rights seem to be a tool of
creeping convergence in consumer policy.
Fighting for Rights: Public Interest Litigation and
Consumer Policy
Litigation has shaped consumer policy for a long time. Insti-
tutional differences between Europe and the United States are
still striking. Class action is widely unknown in Europe.
Instead, government agencies or associations take the lead in
public interest litigation. Contingency fees and tort damages
are still much more a feature of US adversarial legalism
(Strünck, 2008).
As for the United States, consumer policy got a boost by
judicial activism in the wake of the civil rights movement (Epp,
1998). Ralph Nader gured prominently as an early consumer
advocate, running Public Citizenas a powerful public interest
group (Eisner, 2000). He picked General Motors as his rst
prominent adversary: his paper Unsafe at Any Speeddepicted
the popular car Corvette as a most dangerous vehicle.
Public interest litigation helped to raise safety standards, to
ban hazardous products, and to protect vulnerable groups
against risks such as smoking. On the other hand, public
interest litigation in the United States averted more compre-
hensive legislation (Kagan, 2007). There are signs that the
European Union ofcials jump on the bandwagon of class
action (Kelemen, 2011). However, national legal systems still
restrict the scope of public interest litigation in Europe.
Currently, there is no clear picture in European class actions
on the opt-in and opt-out arrangements. Sweden has famously
switched to an opt-in system, whereas countries as diverse as
Portugal, Spain, Denmark, Norway, the United Kingdom, and
Germany have introduced opt-out clauses, at least in consumer
protection law (Cafaggi and Micklitz, 2009). Traditionally,
European countries pursue opt-in strategies due to their legal
tradition of individually authorized lawyers.
The US tradition of opt-out not only raises questions of
accountability but also increases the pressure to settle cases
prematurely. Contingency fees show the same effect. Interest-
ingly enough, opt-in clauses have the effect of producing lead
plaintiffs who are committed and credible toward their
members. Most public interest groups can handle opt-in cases
better than private attorneys.
Another institutional device that affects the activities of
public interest groups is the role of government agencies
(Strünck, 2008). In Sweden, for instance, government agencies
lead public interest litigation despite its corporatist tradition. In
Austria, the federal consumer organization dominates public
interest litigation. The role of government touches on the issue
of funding of the public interest litigation, as well. Third-party
nancing is an underestimated factor whenever the scope of
representation is at stake. Above all, loser paysrule is
predominant in Europe and for public interest groups, it means
that cases they are likely to win will not pose any nancial
burden to them (Hodges et al., 2009).
The loser paysrule also results in high predictability,
compared to punitive damages in the United States. It renders
legal expenses insurance a predictable business, too. Thus,
conditions for external funding are good. This does not
necessarily mean that public interest groups can rely on
funding from third parties. Some European governments
delegate litigation to public interest groups and provide suf-
cient funding, as well. In Austria, the Ministry of Consumer
Protection regularly assigns litigation to the federal consumer
organization to carry out (Micklitz and Stadler, 2006).
In other countries like France, membership fees are a vital
source of funding of litigation. This, however, creates negative
incentives to sue. The same is true for the German Act Against
Unfair Practices. It allows for skimming of the prots if
corporate misconduct can be proven. Consumer organizations
are entitled to act on behalf of consumers before courts.
Injunctions are almost a standard routine operation for
consumer organizations and self-regulatory bodies of business
in Germany. The business-based center for competition issues
7000 injunctions every year.
To consumer groups litigation is an ambiguous tool.
Depending on funding, they face a time-consuming and very
sophisticated legal process. Whether litigation brings in new
opportunities to frame public discourses depends on subjects
and claimants that are affected. Some types of public interest
groups are small, understaffed organizations that run
campaigns. They are just not experienced enough to undertake
ambitious legal efforts. In addition, campaigning gets quicker
media attention for less effort. Thus, it is a strategic choice for
public interest groups whether to embark on legal venues at
large scale.
Certainly, outcomes for diffuse and weak interests are
different when private parties or lawyers act instead of public
interest groups. In the European setting, effects are mostly
restricted to parties involved in the litigation. It might lead to
policy changes if the case is highly salient and expensive and
the fear of future litigation may deter the market participants
from certain behavior. However, even smaller damages to
consumers might harm public interests. In this case, third-party
funding and standing rights are crucial factors in whether
public interest groups pick up litigation as a strategy.
Litigation aims at enforcing law. Additionally, law rms and
consumer groups can call attention to loopholes in legislation,
mobilizing political clout to change the law. Historically,
litigation has brought about social change, especially in the
United States. Attitudes have changed (smoking), and power
relations have been affected (abortion). Social change is the
main topic of activists who champion political consumerism.
This trend revives concepts of collective action in consumer
policy.
Fighting for a Better World: New Patterns of Political
Consumerism
Empowering consumers is a crucial goal of consumer policy.
However, some consumer groups need not to be empowered;
they would rather empower other people and the public.
Political consumerism is on the rise, not only in the industri-
alized world. The range of ideas is broad. There are movements
that are fundamentally critical on mass consumption and the
business of branding (Galvagno, 2011). Others target compa-
nies and monitor their activities. They claim that companies are
not just businesses but bear political responsibility. Boycotts
Consumer Policy 735
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, Second Edition, 2015, 733–737
Author's personal copy
and buycotts are launched to change corporate behavior. At the
same time, activists want consumers to see the broad picture. In
their perspective, consumption is not just to buy and use
something; consumption affects life of people everywhere.
Some of those activities have resulted in policy change:
governments enacted new standards, a whole range of labels
have emerged, and some companies have revamped their codes
of conduct (Stolle and Micheletti, 2013). Does this trend
increase political participation; does it bring consumers to act
as political group?
New forms of political consumerism are individualized
forms of collective action(Holzer, 2006). Consumers do not
engage as group but act individually. This kind of market-based
activity makes up for problems of free riding. If consumers are
difcult to organize it is another option to nudge them indi-
vidually. This is why political consumerism is often equated
with voting. In globalized economies with trust in traditional
politics waning, political shoppingmight be an alternative
tool of participation.
The gures are striking: people in Sweden and Switzerland
seem to be extraordinarily sensitive toward consumption,
whereas people in South European and East European coun-
tries seem to care least about political consumption. In Sweden
and Switzerland, 50% and more people asked had used posi-
tive buying in the last 12 months, and more than 30% had
boycotted products. In Greece, Portugal, and Hungary gures
did not exceed 10% (Koos, 2012).
It is not just postmaterialist attitudes that drive political
consumerism. Political and economic variables matter, too,
which is why countries show different forms of activism.
Several variables account for these differences: The more
afuent a society, the more likely are people to use consump-
tion to express political values. Highly concentrated markets in
retail services seem to trigger backlashes, too. Additionally,
more decentralized political institutions ease political
consumption. However, nongovernmental organizations and
social movements do not signicantly increase the level of
political consumption. Apparently, their campaigns still much
more focus on other issues that do not translate into critical
consumption.
Technology has fundamentally changed opportunity struc-
tures. Social media make companies vulnerable to attacks on
their reputation. Codes of Corporate Social Responsibility
(CSR) are an answer to new waves of political consumerism
(Stolle and Micheletti, 2013). Consumer policy indirectly
contributes too. The more labeling, the better the opportunity
structures (Koos, 2011). Vice versa, labeling results from
campaigning.
Social scientists fret over whether critical consumption
really resembles political participation. Some stress that people
act as consumer citizens,using economic tools for political
reasons. Others decry the volatile behavior of consumers.
Whatever the motivation for political consumption, environ-
mental risks and labor standards in the developing world are
often targets. Thus, consumer policy in advanced economies
might help to improve those conditions. Thus, critical
consumers primarily care about employees in developing
countries.
Political consumerism calls attention to side effects of
global production. This also sheds light on risks that consumers
in developing countries are facing. Small producers might be
exploited to serve the needs of Western consumers. On the
other hand, consumers in those countries are exposed to
fundamental risks of products, too.
In most developing countries, consumer policy is still in the
wake. However, it has to tackle most elementary health risks to
consumers, mainly connected with food and pollution. Aside
from pollution, it is food safety that is most critical to Chinas
ruling communist party (Jiang and Zhu, 2013).
Consumer policy gures prominently in advanced econo-
mies whose markets are regulated. Consumer organizations,
the media, and lawyers push governments to act on behalf of
consumers. It is not like that in developing countries.
Consumer policy in the less developed world is just in the
making. This leaves ample room for governments to imitate
policies or to invent new forms of governance. Quite generally,
changes in society and markets challenge consumer policy.
Challenges to Consumer Policy
Traditionally, safety of products has been one of the core
issues of consumer policy. The rise of the service sector has
highlighted the issue of quality control. More recently, the
nancial crisis has shown that even the ercest competition
does not keep consumer from being ripped off. Financial
services, old-age provision, and other services are hard to assess
for individual consumers. At the same time, those investments
are supposed to last for a long time. Often, vulnerable
consumers fall victim to services with long-term impact. Thus,
creating transparency and setting enforceable quality standards
are the main tasks of consumer policy in the future.
Additionally, digital markets pose new challenges. Do users
of social media need to be protected against data transfer? In
a strict sense, people are usersnot consumers,of social
media. Does traditional consumer policy apply? Transnational
shopping through the internet provides lots of advantages and
also problems to consumers. Can they enforce their rights if the
provider runs its business in a remote place? Can consumers
trust providers that run consumer advice online? Regulating
digital markets will remain a huge challenge to consumer
policy.
Another aspect is sustainable consumption. Here the debate
on soft paternalism pops in. Is it OK to nudge consumers in
order to ponder sustainable choices? What to do about waste
and reuse of products? Do companies primarily bear respon-
sibility or is it consumers, too, who have to act?
A contentious issue in international politics is free trade
agreements. The pending Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership between the United States and the European Union
is a test case. Consumer advocates stir up fears of genetically
modied organism entering European markets against the will
of consumers. Which level of regulation is up for negotiations?
As for governance, the role of government is likely to
change. Consumer policy has mostly been protection by law.
However, are governments capable of enforcing the law in ever
more complex markets? Alternatively, will litigation and tort
damages step in as the more effective precautionary principle?
In fragmented political systems like the United States or
the European Union, third sector organizations increasingly
736 Consumer Policy
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, Second Edition, 2015, 733–737
Author's personal copy
implement policies. Will consumer groups and campaigns take
on more responsibility? Will companies engage more in
cooperative relations with consumer groups to bolster CSR
policies?
The situation in developing countries is different. Grass-
roots protests against contaminated food or polluted drinking
water urge governments to act. Yet, civil society might still be
too weak to craft and implement policies themselves. Given the
imminent threat of food safety issues and other risks, civil
society organizations might pick up consumer policy as
a crucial issue. Handling basic risks for consumers is a litmus
test for governmentslegitimacy; this is even truer in countries
where everyday life comes with lots of risks.
Consumer policy has often been scandal driven. Nondem-
ocratic governments might just ride out things. In democratic
societies, scandals often punctuate a long time policy equilib-
rium, opening up space for outsiders to lobby (Baumgartner
and Jones, 2002). Future politics and research will show who
is able to shape and deliver consumer policy, for which groups,
for which goals, and for how long.
See also: Antitrust Policy: Lessons from the US; Behavioral
Economics; Ethical Codes, Professional: Business Codes;
Governance; International Trade: Commercial Policy and Trade
Negotiations; Internet and Privacy; Issue Networks: Iron
Triangles, Subgovernments, Policy Communities, Policy
Networks; Law and Economics; Public Choice Economics;
Public Policy; Regulation, Empirical Analysis of; Regulation,
Political Economy of; Regulatory Agencies.
Bibliography
Akerlof, George A., 1970. The market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market
mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (3), 488500.
Albanese, Paul, 2006. Inside economic man: behavioral economics and consumer
behavior. In: Handbook of Contemporary Behavioral Economics : Foundations and
Developments. Sharpe, Armonk, NY [u.a.], pp. 323.
Baumgartner, Frank R., Jones, Bryan D., 2002. Policy Dynamics. University of Chicago
Press, Chicago.
Cafaggi, Fabrizio, Micklitz, Hans-W., 2009. New Frontiers of Consumer Protection: The
Interplay between Private and Public Enforcement. Intersentia, Antwerp; and
Portland, OR.
Eisner, Marc A., 2000. Regulatory Politics in Transition, second ed. Johns Hopkins
University Press, Baltimore.
Epp, Charles R., 1998. The Rights Revolution: Lawyers, Activists, and Supreme Courts
in Comparative Perspective. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Galvagno, Marco, 2011. The intellectual structure of the anti-consumption and
consumer resistance eld. European Journal of Marketing (1112), 16881701.
Gronow, Jukka, Warde, Alan, 2001. Ordinary Consumption. Routledge, London.
Hantula, Donald A., 2012. Consumers are foragers, not rational actors: towards
a behavioral ecology of consumer choice. In: Handbook of Developments in
Consumer Behaviour. E. Elgar, Cheltenham [u.a.], pp. 549577.
Hodges, Christopher, Vogenauer, Stefan, Tulibacka, Magdalena, 2009. Costs and
funding of civil litigation: a comparative study. Legal Research Paper Series 2009,
1118.
Holzer, Boris, 2006. Political consumerism between individual choice and collective
action: social movements, role mobilization and signalling. International Journal of
Consumer Studies 30 (5), 405415.
Jiang, Qijun, Zhu, Ying, 2013. Confronting the crisis of food safety and revitalizing
companiessocial responsibility in the Peoples Republic of China. Asia Pacic
Business Review 19 (4), 600616.
Kagan, Robert A., 2007. Globalization and legal change: the Americanizationof
European law? Regulation & Governance 1 (2), 99120.
Kelemen, R. Daniel, 2011. Eurolegalism: The Transformation of Law and Regulation in
the European Union. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Koos, Sebastian, 2012. What drives political consumption in Europe? A multi-level
analysis on individual characteristics, opportunity structures and globalization.
Acta Sociologica 55 (1), 3757.
Koos, Sebastian, 2011. Varieties of environmental labelling, market structures, and
sustainable consumption across Europe: a comparative analysis of organizational
and market supply determinants of environmental-labelled goods. Journal of
Consumer Policy: Consumer Issues in Law, Economics and Behavioural Sciences
34 (1), 127151.
Micklitz, H.-W., Stadler, A., 2006. The Development of collective legal actions in
Europe, especially in German civil procedure. European Business Law Review
[online], 17 (5), 14731503.
Olson, Mancur, 2003. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of
Groups, 21. Printing. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Stolle, Dietlind, Micheletti, Michele, 2013. Political Consumerism: Responsible Action
in the Global Age. Cambridge University Press, New York.
Stone, Deborah, 2012. Policy Paradox: The Art of Political Decision Making. W.W.
Norton & Co., New York, 3. Au.
Strünck, Christoph, 2008. Claiming consumersrights.: patterns and limits of adver-
sarial legalism in European consumer protection. German Policy Studies 2008,
167192.
Sunstein, Cass R., 2008. Laws of Fear: Beyond the Precautionary Principle, 4. Printing.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Trumbull, Gunnar, 2006. Consumer Capitalism: Politics, Product Markets, and Firm
Strategy in France and Germany. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.
Vogel, David, 1997. Trading Up: Consumer and Environmental Regulation in a Global
Economy. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Vogel, David, 2012. The Politics of Precaution: Regulating Health, Safety, and Envi-
ronmental Risks in Europe and the United States. University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Consumer Policy 737
International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, Second Edition, 2015, 733–737
Author's personal copy
... his well-acknowledged consumer capitalism approach (Trumbull 2006a, b). This approach is also an example of a political science perspective on consumer policy (Strünck 2005;Vogel 2012;see Nessel 2016asee Nessel , 2017). Trumbull's main argument is that different consumer policy organizations are closely intertwined with specific ideas about consumers and markets (e.g., Trumbull 2006a, pp. ...
... On the other hand, it obliges sellers to adhere to a set of rules in market transactions (see below). Consequently, consumer law and consumer rights are a main element of consumer policy acknowledged by legal scholars (see Micklitz and Saumier 2018b for a recent overview) as well as by political scientists (Strünck 2005;Trumbull 2006a, b;Vogel 2012). Moreover, since the Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union, which was adopted in 2000, the provision of "fundamental [consumer] rights are having an increasing impact on consumer protection, playing a growing role in EU and Member States' law" (Benöhr 2013, p. 46). ...
... Collective consumer interests are usually represented by consumer associations. Consumer associations have been identified as important for the democratic representation of consumers in policy-making (Strünck 2005;Trumbull 2006a, b;Vogel 2012), in the legal arena (Cafaggi and Micklitz 2009;Micklitz and Saumier 2018b), and for the sound functioning of markets (Nessel 2016a(Nessel , pp. 76-96, 2017. The right of consumers to be politically, legally, and economically represented by consumer associations is hence another important element of modern consumer policy. ...
Article
Full-text available
This article examines consumer policy in 28 EU Member States. It introduces a new methodological framework and several indicators to analyse legal, social, enforcement, and associational dimensions of consumer policy. Drawing on the most recent data, the empirical results provide a detailed picture of consumer policy across Europe displayed in several indices. The results furthermore allow for statistically testing consumer policy regimes, as suggested by previous research. These indices reveal great differences between individual countries but only few instances of statistically significant differences between consumer policy regimes. Considering legal and political accounts as well as sociological explanations that have not yet been applied, possible explanations for these findings are discussed. It is concluded that comparative consumer policy analysis should further analyse differences between individual European countries in several dimensions and should not only account for consumer policy regimes from a legal or a political science perspective. The methodological framework and the theoretical explanations outlined in this article may help to accomplish this goal.
... Furthermore, although the scopes of the Directives generally have been enhanced, the harmonization level for certain issues in two originally fully harmonized directives, the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive (2005/29/EC) and the Consumer Rights Directive (2011/83/EC), were reduced in the recently adopted Modernisation Directive (Directive (EU) Given that the consumer policy regimes incorporate key variables often found to determine countries' preferences in international negotiations, and the claimed continuity of regimes, it can be hypothesized that it is possible to identify differences between the consumer policy regimes when it comes to preferences in EU consumer policy. However, recent research argues that, perhaps due to the efforts by the European Commission to harmonize EU consumer policy, the regime approach is of little value for understanding differences in European consumer policy today (Nessel 2019;Strünck 2005). ...
Article
Full-text available
EU consumer policy is a policy area that is receiving increased attention and is considered important for the proper functioning of the internal market. Yet, as with many other supranational policy areas, conflicting positions of the Member States have led to many compromises and rejections of EU-initiated proposals. By building on regime theory and previous research identifying consumer policy regimes, the aim with this article is to investigate potential patterns in countries' preferences in EU consumer policy. With this, the article seeks both to contribute to the theoretical understanding of factors influencing Member States' positions to EU consumer policy and to the debate on how future EU consumer policies should be designed and put into power. Differences in country and regime preferences are analysed using data collected through an open public consultation as part of the European Commission's Fitness Check of European consumer and marketing law in 2016 and through interviews with key stakeholders in 2018. The results show that there are substantial differences between the regimes and that the level of harmonization of consumer and marketing law seems to be the most contested issue. Furthermore, the article points to several potential reasons for these differences between countries and regimes and recommends that future studies should be undertaken to generate deeper knowledge about the effects of these explanatory factors.
... Governance also connotes policy processes evolving within those structures as stakeholders mobilize to address specific issues (e.g. Dekker et al. 2015;Goodwin 2015;Scholten 2016;Strünck 2005). This article focuses on the second aspect and conceptualizes the policy process as composed of one discursive and one applied, practical element (e.g. ...
Article
Full-text available
The article provides an analysis of policy responses to mobile EU citizens without legal residence in the Netherlands, Austria and Sweden. A comparative case study design uses qualitative survey and interview data to identify national and local policy responses to the implications of EU citizens from Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) living without legal residence in the aforementioned countries. The theoretical framework specifies how the institutional logic of welfare regimes is likely to generate policy responses that address need, sanction informality or do both. The choice indicates the priority given to redistributive outcomes, administrative procedures, or both. The results reveal similar responses to those implications relating to the labour market, but slightly different approaches to the implications in the social domain. Policy responses to labour market implications have predominantly focused on sanctioning informality. Swedish and Austrian policy responses in the social domain have focused on addressing need. Dutch policy responses to social issues instead focused on sanctioning informality, prioritizing procedure. The results indicate that local and national policy responses to implications of informal intra-EU migration may be fruitfully understood through the prism of welfare regimes and related approaches to need and informality.
Chapter
Verbraucherverbände sollen die allgemeinen Interessen von Verbraucherinnen und Verbrauchern vertreten. Konsumenten schließen sich allerdings selten zu einer größeren Gruppe zusammen. Daher agieren Verbraucherverbände in der Regel stellvertretend, im Sinne von „Verbraucherfremdorganisationen“. Als solche nutzen sie alle etablierten Instrumente des Lobbyismus, können aber auch noch auf spezielle rechtliche Möglichkeiten zurückgreifen. Die Funktionen solcher Lobby-Instrumente werden in diesem Beitrag ebenso erörtert wie die Herausforderungen für Verbraucherverbände durch politischen, wirtschaftlichen, sozialen und medialen Wandel.
Chapter
Die Politikwissenschaft beschäftigt sich mit Verbraucherinteressen, wie sie organisiert und wie sie repräsentiert werden. Außerdem untersucht sie, wie Entscheidungsprozesse in der Verbraucherpolitik ablaufen und welche Netzwerke dafür relevant sind. Theoretisch ist davon auszugehen, dass die kollektiven Interessen von Verbraucherinnen und Verbrauchern so allgemein sind, dass ein klassisches Trittbrettfahrer-Problem entsteht: Kaum jemand tritt einer Verbraucherorganisation bei, weil er damit rechnet, dass verbraucherpolitische Maßnahmen ohnehin allen zugutekommen. Die starke Individualisierung des Konsums trägt ebenfalls dazu bei, dass die Organisationsfähigkeit, aber auch die Konfliktfähigkeit von Verbraucherinnen und Verbrauchern begrenzt ist. Wer nimmt dann Einfluss auf verbraucherpolitische Entscheidungsprozesse? Die Politikfeldanalyse als Subdisziplin kümmert sich darum, Netzwerke zu analysieren, die Lobbying-Strategien organisierter Interessen zu rekonstruieren und die steuernde Rolle des Staates zu reflektieren. Die wichtigsten empirischen Ergebnisse: Kampagnenfähigkeit und kollektive Rechtsdurchsetzung spielen eine immer größere Rolle, die Digitalisierung schafft neue Möglichkeiten, Verbraucherinnen und Verbraucher zu informieren, zu organisieren und zu mobilisieren. Die Grundlagen der Verbraucherpolitik verändern sich und damit auch die Machtverhältnisse und Entscheidungsprozesse.
Article
Consumer policy is already being shaped by a combination of governance models. This position paper argues that complexity-oriented convergence models are a timely addition. Modern day consumer policy is characterized as interactive and integrative, replete with shifting boundaries and coalitions and evolving roles for each of state, market and society. This paper focused on governance in the consumer policy arena, arguing that this process needs to acknowledge and reconcile complexity. After describing the basic tenets of complexity theory, two characteristics of contemporary tri-sector interaction (i.e., sector blurring and sector distortion) were discussed. These boundary characteristics necessitate the need for approaches that can accommodate complexity during consumer policy governance. Three examples of the latter were profiled: sector convergence, network governance and cross-sector governance. These conceptualizations accommodate the dynamics, complexity and emergence of contemporary consumer policy governance.
Chapter
Die Politikwissenschaft beschäftigt sich mit Verbraucherinteressen, wie sie organisiert und wie sie repräsentiert werden. Außerdem untersucht sie, wie Entscheidungsprozesse in der Verbraucherpolitik ablaufen und welche Netzwerke dafür relevant sind. Theoretisch ist davon auszugehen, dass die kollektiven Interessen von Verbraucherinnen und Verbrauchern so allgemein sind, dass ein klassisches Trittbrettfahrer-Problem entsteht: Kaum jemand tritt einer Verbraucherorganisation bei, weil er damit rechnet, dass verbraucherpolitische Maßnahmen ohnehin allen zugutekommen. Die starke Individualisierung des Konsums trägt ebenfalls dazu bei, dass die Organisationsfähigkeit, aber auch die Konfliktfähigkeit von Verbraucherinnen und Verbrauchern begrenzt ist. Wer nimmt dann Einfluss auf verbraucherpolitische Entscheidungsprozesse? Die Politikfeldanalyse als Subdisziplin kümmert sich darum, Netzwerke zu analysieren, die Lobbying-Strategien organisierter Interessen zu rekonstruieren und die steuernde Rolle des Staates zu reflektieren. Die wichtigsten empirischen Ergebnisse: Kampagnenfähigkeit und kollektive Rechtsdurchsetzung spielen eine immer größere Rolle, die Digitalisierung schafft neue Möglichkeiten, Verbraucherinnen und Verbraucher zu informieren, zu organisieren und zu mobilisieren. Die Grundlagen der Verbraucherpolitik verändern sich und damit auch die Machtverhältnisse und Entscheidungsprozesse.
Chapter
In a quiet way, tobacco tort litigation emerged as a challenge to the tobacco industry in the mid-1950s at the height of the popularity of smoking—long before a more pervasive regulatory attack on the industry was envisioned by even the most ardent of antitobacco activists. At the time, roughly half the adult population in the United States smoked. There were no limitations on advertising; indeed, tobacco was among the leading industry advertisers on television and radio and in the print media. Similarly, there were no limitations on where smoking might take place, no enforcement of bans on sales to minors, minimal excise taxes, and no public health reports on the risks of smoking. Against this backdrop the initial cancer scare based on scientific data triggered the first wave of lawsuits against tobacco manufacturers (Rabin 1993). By now, the consequent total lack of success in the courthouse over the course of almost forty years, involving two waves of litigation, is a familiar story.
Chapter
During the 1940s and 1950s, cigarette smoking rivaled baseball as America’s national pastime. On motion picture screens, cigarettes were depicted as wholly desirable, smoked by the glamorous and sophisticated, by gritty Gis winning World War II, and tilting up at a jaunty angle from President Franklin Roosevelt’s profile. In 1965, 52% of American adult men were cigarette smokers. Now, however, cigarettes are widely castigated as the nation’s number one public health problem. Cigarette manufacturers have been besieged by multimillion and even multibillion dollar lawsuits; their shares trade at a record low price-earnings ratio (Norris 2000). In many cities, office workers who want a cigarette break are forced to huddle outside the building’s doorway. In 1995, only 25% of American adults were smokers, and in many social circles, smoking is regarded as pathological. This remarkable transformation is far from complete. Millions of Americans have not quit smoking, hundreds of thousands continue to die from lung cancer and other diseases each year, and teenagers still join the army of the addicted in disturbingly large numbers. Nevertheless, it seems clear that tobacco, once unchallenged, is now on the defensive, and few would bet that in 25 years the proportion of Americans who smoke cigarettes as we know them will be as high as it is today.