ArticlePDF Available

Estimates of the Economic Effects of Sea Level Rise

Authors:

Abstract

Regional estimates of direct cost (DC) are commonly used to measure the economic damages of sea level rise. Such estimates suffer from three limitations:(i) values of threatened endowments are not well known, (ii) loss of endowments does not affect consumer prices, and (iii) international trade is disregarded. Results in this paper indicate that these limitations can significantly affect economic assessments of sea level rise. Current uncertainty regarding endowment values (as reflected in two alternative data sets), for example, leads to a 17 percent difference in coastal protection, a 36 percent difference in the amount of land protected, and a 36 percent difference in DC globally. Also, global losses in equivalent variation (EV), a welfare measure that accounts for price changes, are 13 percent higher than DC estimates. Regional EV losses may be up to 10 percent lower than regional DC, however, because international trade tends to redistribute losses from regions with relatively high damages to regions with relatively low damages. Copyright Kluwer Academic Publishers 2001
Environmental and Resource Economics 19: 113–129, 2001.
© 2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 113
Estimates of the Economic Effects of Sea
Level Rise
ROY F. DARWIN1and RICHARD S. J. TOL2
1Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Washington DC, USA; 2Centre for
Marine and Climate Research, Hamburg University, Hamburg, Germany; Institute for
Environmental Studies, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam, The Netherlands and Center for Integrated
Studies of the Human Dimensions of Global Change, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA,
USA
Accepted 28 November 1999
Abstract. Regional estimates of direct cost (DC) are commonly used to measure the economic
damages of sea level rise. Such estimates suffer from three limitations: (i) values of threatened
endowments are not well known, (ii) loss of endowments does not affect consumer prices, and (iii)
international trade is disregarded. Results in this paper indicate that these limitations can significantly
affect economic assessments of sea level rise. Current uncertainty regarding endowment values (as
reflected in two alternative data sets), for example, leads to a 17 percent difference in coastal protec-
tion, a 36 percent difference in the amount of land protected, and a 36 percent difference in DC
globally. Also, global losses in equivalent variation (EV), a welfare measure that accounts for price
changes, are 13 percent higher than DC estimates. Regional EV losses may be up to 10 percent lower
than regional DC, however, because international trade tends to redistribute losses from regions with
relatively high damages to regions with relatively low damages.
Key words: direct cost, economic impacts, equivalent variation, sea level rise
JEL classification: D58, Q00, Q24
1. Introduction
Sea level rise is among the most profound impacts of climate change. Thermal
expansion of ocean waters and melting of land-ice due to higher ambient tempera-
tures would lead to a rise in the average sea level by about 50 cm by the end
of the next century (Warrick et al. 1996). Human activities cluster near low-lying
coasts because of the fertility of land in deltas, proximity of sea food, and transport
opportunities. The coastal zone is also one of the most productive and diverse
natural areas (Vellinga and Leatherman 1989). Even a relatively modest sea level
rise would thus have a substantial effect on human society, unless, perhaps costly,
protective measures are undertaken (Bijlsma et al. 1996). A number of studies have
tried to quantify the impacts of sea level rise (Fankhauser 1994; Hoozemans et al.
1993; Leatherman and Nicholls 1995a, b; Nicholls 1995; Nicholls and Hoozemans
114 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
1996; Nicholls and Mimura 1998; Nicholls et al. 1995; Yohe et al. 1995, 1996;
Yohe and Schlesinger 1998). These studies are far from perfect: data bases are
rough and incomplete, and methods used are crude (Bijlsma et al. 1996). The
studies are also less than satisfactory from an economic point of view. Human
adaptation, for example, is either absent or unrealistically sophisticated (West et al.
1998).
Another shortcoming is that welfare estimates are often confined to direct cost
(DC) the value of land and/or capital lost plus investments is coastal protection.
Such estimates suffer from three limitations. First, the value of land and capital
located in coastal areas threatened by sea level rise is not well known. Because
of their influence on the optimal level of coastal protection, different assumptions
about land and capital values have an indirect as well as an immediate effect on
DC estimates. Second, DC is only a first order approximation of welfare losses. By
assuming constant prices, it neglects second order effects. Third, DC is generally
estimated for specific regions in isolation. Because of international trade, however,
the economic impacts of sea level rise are likely to spill across regional and national
boundaries and affect areas with little or no immediate damages. The purpose of
this paper is to illustrate and evaluate the extent to which these limitations may
distort estimates of the economic losses that might be generated by sea level rise.
2. Procedures
We illustrate the limitations of the DC method with two models the Climate
Framework for Uncertainly, Negotiation and Distribution (FUND; cf. Tol 1997,
1999a–e) and the Future Agricultural Resources Model (FARM; cf. Darwin 1999;
Darwin et al. 1995, 1996). By combining values of land and capital with per-unit
costs of coastal quantities and costs of dryland and wetland lost to sea level rise.
We use FUND to estimate and compare the effects of different assumptions about
land and capital values on these optimal levels. FARM contains a twelve-region
geographical information system (GIS) that estimates the type of land lost to sea
level rise and an eight-region computable general equilibrium (CGE) economic
model that estimates DC and equivalent variation (EV), a welfare measure that
also accounts for second order economic effects. Because FARMs CGE economic
model is global, it also simulates international trade. Hence, we use FARM to
estimate and compare DC with EV and to evaluate cross-boundary spillovers due
to international trade.
2.1. POTENTIAL GEOPHYSICAL IMPACTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE
The impacts of a 0.5-m rise in sea level are evaluated in the twelve regions defined
in FARMs GIS (see Table I). For each region, Table II presents estimates of the
length of coast at risk, the potential dryland loss without protection, the potential
wetland loss without protection, and the additional potential wetland loss if full
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 115
Table I. Description of the regions.
Acronym Name Description
USA United States of America United States of America
CAN Canada Canada
EC European Community 12 members countries of EC in 1990
JPN Japan Japan
ANZ Australia and New Zealand Australia and New Zealand
OEA other East Asia South Korea, China, Hong Kong, Taiwan
SEA South East Asia Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand
LAaLatin America Latin America
OEaother Europe European countries not in EC and
former Soviet Union
fSUMaformer Soviet Union and Mongolia former Soviet Union and Monoglia
OAOaother Asia and Oceania Middle East, South Asia, and Oceania
AFRaAfrica Africa
aFARM’s Computable General Equilibrium economic model groups these regions into one “Rest
of the World” region. FARM’s Geographical Information System, however, does track some
information about these regions so as to conduct partial equilibrium analyses.
protection for dryland were implemented. The coast length of all countries in the
world was taken from the Global Vulnerability Assessment (GVA) by Hoozemans
et al. (1993), an update of work earlier done for the Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change (IPCC CZMS, 1990, 1991). Other sources, such as the proceed-
ings of the 1993 World Coast Conference (Bijlsma et al. 1994), Nicholls and
Leatherman (1995a, b) and Fankhauser (1994) use (occasionally widely) different
estimates of the length of the coast of particular countries. However, the length of
a coast depends on the measurement procedure. The GVA is based on an internally
consistent, globally comprehensive data set and therefore used here. Threatened
coastlines are small portions of the total coastlines of the various regions (cf. Figure
3.1 of Hoozemans et al. 1993). The land area threatened ranges from 0.01 percent
in Canada to 1.03 percent in Southeast Asia for an overall average of 0.25 percent.
Wetland losses for a 0.5-m sea level rise were taken from the GVA and, where
available, replaced with results from country studies as reported by Bijlsma et al.
(1996) and some additional studies reported by Nicholls and Leatherman (1995a,
b) and Beniston et al. (1998). The reasons are this: (i) the GVA is a desk study
which occasionally shows signs of the great haste of its preparation; (ii) the country
studies use local data; and (iii) land lost because of sea level rise is more obviously
estimable than coast length. Bijlsma et al. (1996), however, only report wetland
losses in the absence of coastal protection. The GVA reports wetland losses both
with and without coastal protection for all countries. The country-specific ratio
between the two was used to derive wetland losses with protection according to
Bijlsma et al. (1996).
116 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
Table II. Coastline, dryland and wetland threatened by a 0.5 metre sea level rise.
Region Coastline Dryland Wetland Wetlanda
(km) (km2)(km
2)(km
2)
USA 28,716 10,000 5,700 395
CAN 4,554 485 0 0
ECb32,788 1,962 1,605 451
JPN 4,463 1,150 287 4
ANZ 18,415 1,568 128 92
OEA 27,768 17,694 2,940 890
SEA 29,808 22,907 7,341 2
LA 39,233 28,515 22,892 2,578
OE 28,850 1,089 19 1
fSUM 22,097 7,569 0 0
OAO 77,018 90,129 24,130 0
AFR 34,665 67,477 15,248 173
aAdditional wetland threatened by full protection.
Dryland losses are not reported in the GVA, but they are by Bijlsma et al. (1996).
The GVA reports people-at-risk, which is the number of people living in the one-
in 1000-year flood plain, weighted by the chance of inundation. Combining this
with the GVA’s coastal population densities, area-at-risk results. The relationship
between area-at-risk and land loss for the 18 countries in Bijlsma et al. (1996)
was used to derive land losses from the GVA’s area-at-risk for the other countries.
We used the geometric mean of the ratio between Bijlsma’s area-at-risk and land
loss as a correction factor. This procedure introduces additional uncertainty. The
review of the SCOR Working Group 89 (1991) shows that land loss estimates due
to climate change are not very accurate.
2.2. VALUES OF LAND,CAPITAL,AND COASTAL PROTECTION
Following Fankhauser (1994), the OECD average of dryland value in FUND was
set at 2 million U.S. dollars per km2. Regional values follow from correcting for
GDP per km2(based on population density in the coastal zone, as reported by
the GVA, and income per capita). The OECD average of wetland value was set at
5 million dollars per km2, again following Fankhauser (1994). Regional wetland
values follow from scaling with:
GDP/Capita
20,000
1+GDP/Capita
20,000 (1)
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 117
Table III. Assumed values of drylands, wetlands, and protection costs.
Region FUND FARM
ProtectionaDrylandbWetlandbDrylandbWetlandbCapitalb
(106$/km) (106$/km2)(10
6$/km2)(10
6$/km2)(10
6$/km2)(10
6$/km2)
USA 3.3 1.56 5.90 0.53 0.013 0.84
CAN 2.8 0.16 5.92 0.02 0.002 0.01
EC 3.4 19.89 5.21 2.91 0.038 10.34
JPN 6.6 21.87 6.22 16.99 0.089 26.33
ANZ 2.0 0.12 5.29 0.08 0.002 0.07
OEA 5.9 0.74 0.34 0.66 0.001 0.49
SEA 1.6 0.31 0.49 0.14 0.012 0.09
LAc4.3 0.26 0.78 0.06 0.009 0.03
OEc1.6 1.49 1.75 0.38 0.005 0.20
FSUMc2.4 0.19 3.10 0.05 0.006 0.03
OAOc4.1 0.43 0.26 0.11 0.001 0.06
AFRc3.0 0.31 0.30 0.08 0.001 0.04
aTotal, undiscounted costs of protection against a 1 metre sea level rise in 100 years, as reported by
Hoozemans et al. (1993).
bNet present value, based on an effective discount rate of 1% and an infinite time horizon; see text
for derivation.
cFARM’s CGE model groups these regions into one ‘rest of the world’. Aggregate net present values
are 0.26, 0.003 and 0.14 million $/km2for dryland, wetland, and capital, respectively. Regional
values are interpolated proportionally to the dryland values of FUND.
which is scaled to unity for the OECD in 1990. The costs of coastal protection
follow from the GVA, again where possible replaced by country study results. Table
III shows the values.
In FARM, land in each region is assigned to up to six climate-defined classes.
Land in each land class is further divided into five major uses and/or covers
cropland, grazing land, forest land, land used in producing other economic goods
and services (e.g., urban, suburban, and industrial land), and “other” land (i.e.,
deserts, barren wilderness, and wetlands). Total annual regional returns to land
services for cropland and grazing land are derived from cost data in the Global
Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database (Hertel 1993). These total returns are
distributed to the land classes based on each land class’s respective contributions
to crop and livestock production. Average rents for these two uses by land class are
obtained by dividing returns per use per land class by the number of hectares per
use per land class.
Returns to forest land in FARM are approximately one third the returns to
pasture. Rental values forurban, suburban, and industrial landin the currentversion
of FARM are approximately equal to cropland rents. This assumption is based n the
opportunity cost principle, e.g., that the cost of land used for urban and industrial
118 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
purposes is the value that land would have if it were used for other purposes, in this
case, growing crops. Using cropland rents for opportunity costs isolates the biolo-
gically based productive capacity of urban land from its productive capacity due to
the proximity of large capital aggregates. Returns to “other” land are assumed to be
one-tenth the returns to forest land and are added to returns to land in the services
sector. The end result is that each region’s land is treated as a heterogeneous good
and each land-use-land-class combination has its own price.
Each land-use-land-class combination also is associated with an unknown
quantity of homogeneous capital, which also generates an annual return. Total
annual regional returns to capital for 13 commodities are derived from cost data
in the GTAP database (Hertel 1993). Returns by commodity are distributed to the
land classes based on each land class’s share of commodity production. Crop-
land produces three commodities: 1) wheat, 2) other grains, and 3) non-grains.
Pasture and forestland produce livestock and forest products, respectively. Urban,
suburban, and industrial land produces eight commodities: 1) coal, oil, gas, 2)
other minerals, 3) fish, meat, milk, 4) other processed foods, 5) textiles, clothing,
and footwear, 6) other nonmetallic manufactures, 7) other manufactures, and 8)
services. Average per-hectare capital returns by use and land class are obtained by
dividing returns per use per land class by the number of hectares per use per land
class. Because it supports relatively large aggregates of capital, urban, suburban,
and industrial land is associated with greater returns to capital per hectare than
land used for other purposes. Returns to capital on desert, barren wilderness, and
wetlands are zero because capital is assumed to be absent on such land.
The distribution of land at risk due to sea level rise by region, class, and use is
derived with FARM’s GIS by combining 10-minute resolution altitude data (U.S.
Navy, Fleet Navigational Operations Center 1992) with land-use and land-cover
data (Olson 1992) and FARMs land-class data. We use the land-class-land-use
shares for dryland and wetlands implicit in this data to distribute FUND’s dryland
and wetland losses across FARM’s land uses and land classes. Regional estimates of
wetlands FARM’s coastal land are obtained with FUND’s ratios of wetland to total
land at risk in each region. Wetlands are distributed according to the land-class
shares of “other” land. All other FARM land types are dryland.
FARM’s wetland values in Table III are average values of all wetlands in the
land classes at risk to sea level rise in a given region. They do not reflect the value
of any environmental services that wetlands might provide. Hence they capture
only a small portion (less than 1 percent) of the wetland values considered by
FUND, which do include recreation and nature values. Dryland values are average
values of all land not wetland in the land classes at risk. They reflect only 13
percent to 89 percent of the dryland values assumed by FUND. This is due in part
because FARM’s rental values for urban, suburban, and industrial land only reflect
its biologically-based productive capacity.
FARM’s capital values in Table III are average values of returns to fixed capital
per km2in the land-use-land-class combinations at risk. “Fixed” capital is capital
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 119
that could not be economically moved as sea leave rises. It consists primarily of
buildings, roads, piers, and similar items found near the seashore. Returns to fixed
capital are assumed to be equal to 0.5 total capital returns. The quantity per unit
area (and hence its value per unit area) is assumed to increase at the same rate
as land values in this analysis. Combining FARM’s capital and dryland values
together yields values that reflect 19 percent to 198 percent of FUND’s dryland
values. The relatively large differences between these values and the wetland
values clearly indicates that there is considerable uncertainly about the values of
endowments threatened by sea level rise.
2.3. ESTIMATING THE LEVEL OF COASTAL PROTECTION
Given values of land and protection, FUND calculates optimal levels and costs of
coastal protection as well as optimal quantities and costs of dryland and wetland
lost to sea level rise. The fraction of land protected against sea level rise follows:
L=max 0,11
2PC +WL
DL  (2)
Lis the fraction of the coastline to be protected. WL is the net present value of
wetland lost due to full coastal protection. DL is the net present value of dryland
lost to sea level rise. PC is the net present value of the protection if the whole
coast is protected. See Fankhauser (1994) for the derivation of (2). He uses a very
simple, large linear model so as to be able to express the optimal level of protection
in closed-form. Below, we use simple expressions for the growth of dryland losses,
wetland losses and protection costs so that their net present values can be expressed
in closed form too.
The GVA reports average protection costs per year over the next century (see
Table III). PC is calculated assuming annual costs to be constant. This is based on
the following. First, the coastal protection decision makers anticipate a linear see
level rise. Second, coastal protection entails large infrastructural works which last
for decades. Third, the considered costs are direct investments only, and techno-
logies for coastal protection are mature, that is, technologies and prices will not
change substantially in the future.
WL is the net present value of the wetlands lost due to full coastal protection.
Wetland values are assumed constant relative to income, reflecting how much
current decision makers care about the non-marketed services and goods that get
lost. The amount of wetland lost is assumed to increase linearly over time. DL
denotes the net present value of the dryland lost if no protection takes place.
Dryland values are assumed to rise at the same pace as the economy grows. The
amount of dryland lost is assumed to increase linearly over time.
120 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
Throughout the analysis, a pure rate of time preference, ρ, of 1.0 percent per
year is used. The actual discount rate lies thus 1.0 percent above the growth rate of
the economy, g. The net present costs of protection PC are thus equal to:
PC =
X
t=11
1+ρ+gt
PCa=1+ρ+g
ρ+gPCa(3)
where PCais the average annual costs of protection.
The net present costs of wetland loss WL follow from:
WL =
X
t=1
t1
1+ρ+gt
WL
0=1+ρ+g
+g)2WL
0(4)
where WL0denotes the value of wetland loss in the first year.
The net present costs of dryland loss DL are:
DL =
X
t=0
t1+g
1+ρ+gt
DL0=(1+g)(1+ρ+g)
ρ2DL0(5)
where DL0is the value of dryland loss in the first year.
2.4. ESTIMATING THE COSTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE
As land and fixed capital are lost to sea level rise or as resources are diverted from
other pursuits to coastal protection, the supply of consumer goods and services
in a region declines relative to a no-sea-level-rise scenario. This results in lower
production levels and higher prices. Direct cost is the value of land and/or capital
lost plus investments in coastal protection. Direct cost is also equal to the value of
consumer goods and service foregone (assuming constant prices) and so it provides
an estimate of welfare change. This and the fact that it is relatively easy to calculate
ensures its popularity in the literature (Cline 1992; Fankhauser 1994; Jansen et al.
1991; Nicholls and Leatherman 1995a, b; Nordhaus 1991; 1994; Rijsberman 1991;
Titus 1992; Titus et al. 1991; Tol 1995, 1996; Yohe 1990, 1995, 1996).
In FUND, DC is calculated as the amount of wetland and dryland land lost
times their respective values plus the length of coast protected times the costs of
protection per km. FUND’s DC estimates are annuitised. Direct cost in FARM is
calculated as the amount of wetland per land class lost times its value per land
class, plus the amount of dryland per use per land class lost times its value per
use per land class, plus the amount of dryland per use per land class lost times the
amount of fixed capital returns lost per unit area per use per land class, plus the cost
of coastal protection. The amount of wetland and dryland lost as well as the costs
of coastal protection used in FARMs calculations come from FUND. FARM’s DC
estimates (including the cost of coastal protection from FUND) are annual.
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 121
Direct cost does not reflect the total value of consumer goods and service fore-
gone as a result of sea level rise, however, because it does not take account of the
higher prices that would be generated by the relatively large loss of land andcapital
resources. Higher prices mean that consumers will not only have fewer goods and
services available to them, but also that each dollar spent on goods and services
will buy less. The effects of changing prices is captured with equivalent variation
(EV), another standard measure of welfare change. EV is the difference, in terms of
money expenditure in this case at pre-sea-level-rise prices between the level of
consumer satisfaction under sea level rise and the level of satisfaction under no sea
level rise. Estimates of EV are provided by FARMs CGE model for eight regions.
Direct cost also does not accurately capture the geographical distribution of
welfare losses that sea level rise would generate. Lower production levels and the
higher prices induced in one region will spill over into other regions through inter-
national trade. Because it simulates international trade in, as well as production of,
13 commodities, FARM’s regional estimates of EV reflect the geographical distri-
bution of damages more accurately than do its regional estimates of DC. Hence a
comparison of FARM’s DC and EV estimates provides information about the extent
to which ignoring price changes and international spillovers generates affects the
measurement of the potential damages of sea level rise.
FARM simulates sea level rise by reducing land and capital quantities by
appropriate amounts. The total amount (km2) of wetland and dryland lost are
derived from FUND.TheFARM’s GIS derives the amount of land lost by use
and class and creates exogenous shocks (in percent change format) for FARM’s
CGE model that are consistent with land’s heterogeneity. FARM’s GIS also esti-
mates the total annual returns to fixed capital lost by region. These lost capital
returns are combined with FUND’s annual costs of coastal protection under the
following assumptions: (i) capital is treated as a homogeneous factor in FARM,
(ii) expenditures on structures that provide coastal protection are primarily returns
to capital because their construction is capital intensive, and (iii) the construc-
tion and/or maintenance of these capital structures preclude the purchase of other
capital structures. Regional percent changes of the combined total of lost returns
from this homogeneous capital are equivalent to regional percent changes in lost
capital itself, and, therefore, are utilized as the exogenous shocks to capital by
FARM’s CGE model. The losses are imposed on 1990 conditions in a comparative
static analysis. FARM’s CGE model is implemented and solved using GEMPACK
(Harrison and Pearson 1996).
3. Results
We first present FUND’s estimates of the level of coastal protection and the corre-
sponding land losses caused by a 0.5-m rise in sea level under two different
assumptions regarding the values of land and capital endowments. We then present
two sets of estimates of the economic costs of sea level rise. The first set contains
122 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
Table IV. Level of coastal protection, dryland losses, and wetland losses in response to
a sea level rise of 0.5 m by source of endowment values and regiona.
Region FUND’s land values FARM’s land and capital values
CoastlinebDryland Wetland Coastline Dryland Wetland
(%) (km2)(km
2) (percent) (km2)(km
2)
USA 82 1,800 6,023 72 2,808 5,984
CAN 0 485 0 0 484 0
EC 92 163 2,019 80 386 1,967
JPN 97 38 290 98 27 290
ANZ 0 1,568 128 0 1,568 128
OEA 91 1.572 2,940 93 1,276 3,765
SEA 95 1,079 7,343 92 1,783 7,343
LA 83 4,755 25,040 49 14,535 24,156
OE 20 867 19 0 1,089 19
fSUM 0 7,569 0 0 7,569 0
OAO 90 5,144 24,130 82 16,073 24,130
AFR 86 9,442 15,396 56 29,475 15,345
aEstimated with FUND using results from equations (2), (4), and (5).
bCoastline threatened by sea level rise.
FUND’s estimates of annuitised DC based on the assumptions used for the coastal
protection estimates. The second set contains of DC and EV based on FARM’s
endowment values. A short discussion of the results ends this section.
3.1. LEVELS OF COASTAL PROTECTION
FUND’s estimates of the percent of threatened coastline protected as well as the
dryland and wetland lost to a 0.5 rise in sea level are presented in Table IV. Two
sets of estimates are presented. The first set is based on FUND’s land values while
the second set is based on FARM’s land and fixed capital values. Both sets rely on
FUND’s protection costs. As the level of protection depends on the ratio of protec-
tion costs and the value of the threatened endowments (see Equation (2)) and as
protection costs are the same in both the FUND-based and FARM-based estimates,
the regional pattern of protection levels follows directly from the regional pattern
of land values displayed in Table III.
For example, FUND-based levels of coastal protection are zero in three regions
Canada, Australia/New Zealand, and the former Soviet Union (plus Mongolia).
FARM-based protection levels are zero in the same three regions plus other Europe.
The latter is due to FARMs relatively low initial values of dryland plus fixed capital
in other Europe (Table III). FARM’s values of dryland plus fixed capital are lower
than FUND’sdryland values in the six other regions where FUND-based protection
levels are higher than FARM-based levels. Differences in coastline protection for
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 123
these six regions range from 3 to 69 percent. In the two regions where FARM-based
protection levels are higher than the FUND-based levels, FARM’s values of dryland
plus fixed capital are larger than FUND’s dryland values. Differences in coastline
protection in these regions are 1 and 2 percent. Overall, the amount of threatened
coastline protected in the FARM-based scenario is 17 percent lower on average than
that in the FUND-based scenario. As a result, the amount of total land lost in the
FARM-based scenario is 36 percent higher than that in the FUND-based scenario.
A comparison of land lost in Table IV with land threatened in Table II indi-
cates that coastal protection reduces the total amount of land lost to sea level rise.
Reductions in losses are limited, however, to dryland. Wetland losses are greater if
coastal protection is employed, especially in the US, EC, Other East Asia, and Latin
America. Equation (2) indicates that coastal protection decrease as wetland values
increase. We evaluate the magnitude of this phenomenon by estimating coastal
protection levels using FARM’s values for dryland and fixed capital but FUND’s
values for wetlands. Protection levels decline slightly relative to the case where
all values are from FARM (not shown). The regions most affected by the higher
wetland values were the United States and Latin America where protection of
the threatened coastline dropped to 71 percent and 48 percent respectively. Higher
wetland values did not affect the first two significant figures of coastal protection
in the other regions. The change is small because the amount of wetland lost to
coastal protection is relatively small (Table II).
3.2. ECONOMIC COST
Table V presents annuitised DC for a 0.5-m rise in sea level (with and without
coastal protection) based on both FUND and FARM’s endowment values. As
expected, annuitised costs with optimal protection are lower than net present costs
without optimal protection, about 65 percent for FARM’s endowment values and
about 75 percent for FUND’s endowment values. FARM-based DC is lower than
FUND-based DC in all regions except Japan and Other East Asia, where FARM-
based protection levels are higher than FUND-based protection levels. Without
coastal protection, FUND-based DC is 77 percent higher than FARM-based DC.
With coastal protection, FUND-based DC is 36 percent higher.
Table VI presents annual DC and lost EV based on FARM’s endowment values.
Direct cost is composed of the cost of protection, fixed capital lost, and land lost.
Annual protection costs are calculated withFUND and, given the linearity assump-
tions in this analysis, they would equal actual annual protection cost around 2050
when sea level rise is projected to rise 0.25 m. Values of fixed capital and land are
from FARM. FARMs per-km2values of these endowments (Table III), however,
pertain to economic conditions in 1990. Because these values are expected to be
higher in 2050, total DC based on an area inundated by a 0.25-m sea level rise
would underestimate the 2050 damages. To compensate somewhat we assume that
the area inundated conforms to a 0.5-m rise in sea level in 2100. These costs are
124 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
Table V. Annuitised direct cost (million dollars per year) for a 0.5 m rise in sea level rise by source
of endowment values, level of coastal protection, and regiona.
FUND’s land values FARM’s land and capital values
No protectionbProtectioncWetlandsdNo protectionbProtectioncWetlandsd
USA 2,772 1,317 653 1,697 1,162 1
CAN14140220
EC 6,954 1,638 163 2,826 1,448 1
JPN 4,483 433 35 6,181 435 1
ANZ 34 34 13 31 31 0
OEA 9,289 2,329 19 11,400 2,348 0
SEA 5,061 693 68 3,062 678 2
LA 5,210 2,316 336 1,667 1,683 0
OE 290 324 1 93 93 0
fSUM 251 251 0 80 80 0
OAO 27,809 4,597 119 8,932 4,210 0
AFR 3,700 1,408 88 1,184 1,100 0
Total 42,923 10,533 2,958 24,990 8,941 5
aEstimated with FUND using equations (2)–(5).
bValue of dryland lost to sea level rise.
cValue of dryland lost to sea level rise, coastal protection, and wetland lost to coastal protection.
dValue of wetland lost to sea level rise, excluding wetland lost to coastal protection.
relatively small, especially in developed regions, when compared to total regional
economic activity (e.g., total expenditures) in 1990. Direct cost for the first five
regions listed in Table VI ranges from almost nothing to 0.009 percent of total
expenditures in 1990. Direct cost for Other East Asia, South East Asia, and the
rest-of-world is, respectively, 0.105, 0.077, and 0.049 percent of total expenditures
in 1990.
Equivalent variation is estimated by FARM. World EV lost is $4,956 million,
approximately 13 percent higher than world DC, which is equal to $4,395 million.
The additional losses are not equally distributed across the regions. In developed
regions, differences between EV losses and DC range from $11 million to $290
million (from 43 percent to 8,213 percent). In developing and rest-of-world
regions, differences between EV losses and DC range from $227 million to $28
million (from 10 percent to +4 percent).
3.3. DISCUSSION
TableIII indicates that there is considerable uncertainty in the value of endowments
threatened by sea level rise. Results in Tables IV and V indicate that these differ-
ences can have significant effects on the level of coastal protection, the amount of
land inundated, and overall costs that a given region might have to bear. This uncer-
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 125
Table VI. Annual direct cost and equivalent variation lost (million dollars per year)
for a 0.5 m rise in sea level with coastal protection by region.
Region Direct costs Equivalent
ProtectionaFixed CapitalbLandcTotal Variationd
USA 343 50 17 410 585
CAN 0 0 0 0 11
EC 446 90 13 549 839
JPN 144 11 5 160 421
ANZ 0 1 1 3 18
OEA 763 8 9 781 809
SEA 220 3 4 226 233
ROW 2,017 117 133 2,267 2,040
LA 417 27 32 475
OE 0 2 2 3
fSUM 0 4 4 8
OAO 1,309 51 58 1,419
AFR 291 33 37 361
Total 3,933 280 182 4,395 4,956
aEstimated with FUND using equation (2) and FARM’s values for land and fixed
capital.
bCombines land quantities estimated by FUND with FARM’s per-hectare fixed
capital values.
cCombines land quantities estimated by FUND with FARM’s land values.
dEstimated with FARM.
tainty may also pertain to those regions for which both FUND and FARM assume
that the value of threatened endowments is small. A more accurate assessment, for
example, might find that the value of Canadian endowments threatened by sea level
rise would be high enough to trigger a positive level of coastal protection.
Results in Table VI indicate that the DC approach provides inaccurate global
and regional estimates of the economic impacts of sea level rise. Globally, DC is
lower than EV because the former does not account for the higher prices that would
be generated by the loss of endowments that sea level rise would induce around the
world. Regionally, DC differs from EV not only because of rising prices but also
because of spillovers generated by international trade. In general, trade between
regions tends to redistribute losses from regions with relatively high damages to
regions with relatively low damages. This principle may also apply to FARM’s
ROW region, that is, EV losses would probably be smaller than DC in other Asia
(plus Oceania) but larger than DC in other Europe and the former Soviet Union
(plus Mongolia). It also means that regions without coastlines are likely to sustain
some economic hardships from sea level rise.
126 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
Region-specific impacts on EV depend on the relative importance of land,
labour, and capital as sources of income, the composition of exports and imports,
and trade policies. This implies that the DC-EV comparison is subject to a few
limitations. One limitation pertains to the uncertainty surrounding the value of
endowments. Different regional estimates of DC, either in total or among endow-
ments, would have led to different estimates of EV. Another limitation is that
FARM imposes impacts of sea level rise projected for 2050 on 1990 conditions.
Differences in regional growth rates, however, mean that the 2050 pattern of trade
spillovers is likely to vary from the one depicted here.
4. Summary and Conclusions
Direct-cost estimates are commonly used to measure the economic damages of
sea level rise. Such estimates suffer from three limitations: (i) values of threatened
endowments are not well-known, (ii) loss of endowments does not affect consumer
prices, and (iii) international trade is overlooked. We have shown that, because of
these limitations, DC estimates may significantly misrepresent the economic losses
that might be generated by sea level rise, globally and even more so regionally.
For many parts of the world there is considerable uncertainty about the value
of land and capital endowments threatened by sea level rise. This is turn generates
uncertainty about the level of coastal protection, the amount of land inundated,
and overall DC that a given region might have to bear. In the example presented
in this paper, differences in endowment values lead to a 17 percent difference in
coastal protection, a 36 percent difference in the amount of land protected, and
a 36 percent difference in DC when coastal protection was implemented. When
coastal protection was not implemented, the difference in DC is 77 percent. One
way to reduce this uncertainty is to obtain more accurate data on the value of land
and capital in general. Ideally, values for both dryland and wetland would include
market and non-market components. A related activity would be to obtain data on
the value of water and labour (both market and household) endowments threatened
by sea level rise.
As a worldwide phenomenon, climate-induced sea level rise is likely to cause
significant losses in land and capital endowments in many regions simultaneously.
The size and scope of these losses will induce a general increase in consumer prices
that will generate economic costs above those considered by DC. In our example
global EV-based damages are 13 percent higher than DC-based damages. At the
same time, the response of international traders to differential changes in regional
prices will tend to redistribute losses from regions with relatively high damages
to regions with relatively low damages. This means that sea level rise is likely to
reduce economic welfare even in land-locked regions. The only way to overcome
these limitations is to substitute partial equilibrium analyses of isolated regions
with general equilibrium analyses of the world as a whole.
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 127
Finally, because the experiments conducted for this analysis do not accurately
depict reality in all respects, we recognize that our estimates of the potential
economic damages of sea level rise may be seriously flawed. This possibility,
however, should not detract one from the insights that the analysis in the paper
provides. The objective of this research was to determine the extent to which
limited knowledge of the value of endowments and inadequate modeling capa-
bilities may affect economic assessments of sea level rise. Our results indicate that
significant gains in accuracy are likely to be obtained with greater knowledge and
improved modeling capabilities.
Acknowledgments
This paper originates in the authors’ participation in the climate change impacts
workshop of the Energy Modeling Forum. We appreciate comments by two
anonymous reviewers. Any errors, of course, are ours. The views expressed herein
do not necessarily reflect those of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.
References
Beniston,M.,R.S.J.Tol,R.Delecolle,G.Hoermann,A.Iglesias,J.Innes,A.J.McMicheal,W.J.
M. Martens, I. Nemesova, R. J. Nicholls and F. L. Toth (1998), ‘Europe’, in R. T. Watson, M.
C. Zinyowera and R. H. Moss, eds., The Regional Impacts of Climate Change An Assessment
of Vulnerability, ASpecial Report of IPCC Working Group II. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, pp. 149–185.
Bijlsma, L. (eds.) (1993), World Coast Conference 1993 Proceedings. The Hague: Coastal Zone
Management Centre, National Institute for Coastal and Marine Management.
Bijlsma, L., C. N. Ehler, R. J. T. Klein, S. M. Kulshrestha, R. F. McLean, N. Mimura, R. J. Nicholls,
L. A. Nurse, H. Perez Nieto, E. Z. Stakhiv, R. K. Turner and R. A. Warrick (1996), ‘Coastal Zones
and Small Islands’, in R. T. Watson, M. C. Zinyowera and R. H. Moss, eds., Climate Change
1995: Impacts, Adaptations and Mitigation of Climate Change: Scientific-Technical Analyses
Contribution of Working Group II to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 289–324.
Broadus, J. M. (1996), ‘Economizing Human Responses to Subsidence and Rising Sea Level’, in J.
D. Milliman and B. U. Haq, eds., Sea Level Rise and Coastal Subsidence. Dordrecht: Kluwer
Academic Publishers, pp. 313–325.
Cline, W. R. (1992), The Economics of Global Warming. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International
Economics.
Darwin, R. F. (1999), A FARMer’s View of the Ricardian Approach to Measuring Effects of Climatic
Change on Agriculture’, Climatic Change 41(3–4), 371–411.
Darwin, R. F., M. Tsigas, J. Lewandrowski and A. Raneses (1996), ‘Land Use and Cover in
Ecological Economics’, Ecological Economics 17(3), 157–181.
Darwin, R. F., M. Tsigas, J. Lewandrowski and A. Raneses (1995), World Agriculture and Climate
Change: Economic Adaptations (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,
Agricultural Economic Report Number 703). Washington, D.C.
Fankhauser, S. (1994), ‘Protection vs. Retreat The Economic Costs of Sea Level Rise’, Environment
and Planning A 27, 299–319.
Harrison, W. J. and K. R. Pearson (1996), ‘Computing Solutions for Large General Equilibrium
Models Using GEMPACK’, Computational Economics 9(1), 83–127.
128 ROY F. DARWIN AND RICHARD S. J. TOL
Hoozemans, F. M. J., M. Marchand and H. A. Pennekamp (1993), A Global Vulnerability Analysis:
Vulnerability Assessment for Population, Coastal Wetlands and Rice Production and a Global
Scale (second, revised edition). Delft: Delft Hydraulics.
Houghton, J. T., L. G. Meiro Filho, B. A. Callander, N. Harris, A. Kattenberg and K. Maskell
(eds.) (1996), Climate Change 1995: The Science of Climate Change Contribution of Working
Group I to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change CZMS (Misdorp, R., J. Dronkers and J.R. Spradley,
eds.) (1990), Strategies for Adaption to Sea Level Rise. The Hague: Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change/Ministry to Transport and Public Works.
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change CZMS (1991), Common Methodology for Assessing
Vulnerability to Sea-Level Rise. The Hague: Ministry of Transport, Public Works and Water
Management.
Jansen, H. M. A., O. J. Kuik and C. K. Spiegel (1991), ‘Impacts of Sea Level Rise: an Economic
Approach’, in Anonymous, Climate Change Evaluating the Socio-Economic Impacts.Paris:
OECD.
Leatherman, S. P. and R. J. Nicholls (1995), ‘Accelerated Sea-Level Rise and Developing Countries:
An Overview’, Journal of Coastal Research 14, 1–14.
Nicholls, R. J., S. P. Leatherman, K. C. Dennis and C. R. Volonte (1995), ‘Impacts and Responses
to Sea-Level Rise: Qualitative and Quantitative Assessments’, Journal of Coastal Research 14,
26–43.
Nicholls, R. J. and S. P. Leatherman (1995), ‘Global Sea-level Rise’, in K. M. Strzepek and J. B.
Smith, eds., When Climate Changes: Potential Impact and Implications. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Nicholls, R. J. and F. M. J. Hoozemans (1996), ‘The Mediterranean: Vulnerability to Coastal
Implications of Climate Change’, Ocean & Coastal Management 31(2–3), 105–132.
Nordhaus, W. D. (1991), ‘To Slow or Not to Slow: The Economics of the Greenhouse Effect’,
Economic Journal 101, 920–937.
Nordhaus, W. D. (1994), Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change.
Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Olson, J. S. (1992), World Ecosystems (WE1.3). Digital Raster Data on a 30-minute Geographic
(lat/log) 360 ×720 grid. In: Global Ecosystems Database Version 1.0: Disc A. Boulder, CO:
National Geophysical Data Center.
Rijsberman, F. R. (1991). ‘Potential Costs of Adapting to Sea Level Rise in OECD Countries’, in
Anonymous, Responding to Climate Change: Selected Economic Issues. Paris: OECD, pp. 11–
50.
SCOR Working Group 89 (1991), ‘The Response of Beaches to Sea Level Changes: A Review of
Predictive Models’, Journal of Coastal Research 7(3), 895–921.
Titus, J. G. (1992), ‘The Costs of Climate Change to the United States’, in S. K. Majumdar, L.
S. Kalkstein, B. M. Yarnal, E. W. Miller and L. M. Rosenfeld, eds., Global Climate Change:
Implications, Challenges and Mitigation Measures. Easton: Pennsylvania Academy of Science,
pp. 384–409.
Tol, R. S. J. (1995), ‘The Damage Costs of Climate Change Towards More Comprehensive
Calculations’, Environmental and Resource Economics 5, 353–374.
Tol, R. S. J. (1996), ‘The Damage Costs of Climate Change: Towards a Dynamic Representation’,
Ecological Economics 19, 67–90.
Tol, R. S. J. (1997), ‘On the Optimal Control of Carbon Dioxide Emissions An Application of
FUND’, Environmental Modelling and Assessment 2, 151–163.
Tol, R. S. J. (1999a), ‘The Marginal Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions’, The Energy Journal 20(1),
61–81.
ESTIMATES OF THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SEA LEVEL RISE 129
Tol, R. S. J. (1999b), ‘Time Discounting and Optimal Control of Climate Change: An Application of
FUND’, Climatic Change 41(3–4), 351–362.
Tol, R. S. J. (1999c), ‘Kyoto, Efficiency, and Cost-Effectiveness: Applications of FUND’, Energy
Journal Special Issue on the Costs of the Kyoto Protocol: A Multi-Model Evaluation, 130–156.
Tol, R. S. J. (1999d), ‘Spatial and Temporal Efficiency in Climate Policy: Applications of FUND’,
Environmental and Resource Economics 14(1), 33–49.
Tol, R. S. J. (1999e), ‘Safe Policies in an Uncertain Climate: An Application of FUND’, Global
Environmental Change 9, 221–232.
Tol, R. S. J. (1999f), New Estimates of the Damage Costs of Climate Change, Part I: Benchmark
Estimates, Institute for Environmental Studies D99/1. Amsterdam: Vrije Universiteit.
Tol, R. S. J. (1999g), New Estimates of the Damage Costs of Climate Change, Part II: Dynamic
Estimates, Institute for Environmental Studies D99/2. Amsterdam: Vrije Universiteit.
Turner, R. K., W. N. Adger and P. Doktor (1995), ‘Assessing the Economic Costs of Sea Level Rise’,
Environment and Planning A 27, 1777–1796.
U.S. Navy. Fleet Navigational Operations Center. 1992. FNOC/NCAR Global Elevation, Terrain, and
Surface Characteristics. Digital Raster Data on a 10-minute Geographic (lat/long) 1080 ×2160
grid. In: Global Ecosystems Database Version 1.0: Disc A. Boulder, CO: National Geophysical
Data Center.
Vellinga, P. and S. P. Leatherman (1989), ‘Sea Level Rise, Consequences and Policies’, Climatic
Change 15, 175–189.
Warrick, R. A., C. Le Provost, M. F. Meier, J. Oerlemans and P. L. Woodworth (1996), ‘Changes
in Sea Level’, in J. T. Houghton, L. G. Meiro Filho, B. A. Callander, N. Harris, A. Kattenberg
and K. Maskell, eds., Climate Change 1995: The Science of Climate Change Contribution of
Working Group I to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 359–405.
Yohe, G. W. (1990), ‘The Cost of Not Holding Back the Sea: Toward a National Sample of Economic
Vulnerability’, Coastal Management 18, 403–431.
Yohe, G. W., J. Neumann and H. Ameden (1995), ‘Assessing the Economic Cost of Greenhouse-
Induced Sea Level Rise: Methods and Applications in Support of a National Survey’, Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 29, S-78–S-97.
Yohe, G. W., J. Neumann, P. Marshall and H. Ameden (1996), The Economics Costs of Sea Level
Rise on US Coastal Properties’, Climate Change 32, 387–410.
Yohe, G. W. and M. E. Schlesinger (1998), ‘Sea-Level Change: The Expected Economic Cost of
Protection or Abandonment in the United States’, Climatic Change 38, 447–472.
... The spatially specific nature of SLR consequences is an established fact 3, 14 . While regional estimates of direct damages and national assessments of indirect damages of SLR are well-studied 3,7,8,11,30 , the detailed regional assessment of total economic damages of SLR remains a challenge. Our study addresses this gap, quantifying regional and sectoral specificities of macroeconomic consequences of SLR in Europe. ...
... In contrast to the traditional approach of disaggregating coarse top-down assessments, our approach reveals distributional impacts quantified bottom-up based on specific sectoral compositions of all 271 European regions, explicitly taking into account SLR vulnerabilities of different sectors in different locations and the economic ripple effects via trade flows, relative price signals and factor substitution to other economies. Previous assessments of SLR along the European coast provided valuable starting bases, whether they assessed total economic impacts at the national level 3,7,8,11 , direct impacts at the regional level and the benefits of coastal protection 14 , or even total impacts at the regional level in the medium term 30 . However, to our knowledge, regionally-differentiated impacts at the sectoral level, relevant to develop targeted adaptation strategies to specific types of economic activity, have not been assessed before. ...
Article
Full-text available
Economic costs of climate change are conventionally assessed at the aggregated global and national levels, while adaptation is local. When present, regionalised assessments are confined to direct damages, hindered by both data and models’ limitations. This article goes beyond the aggregated analysis to explore direct and indirect economic consequences of sea level rise (SLR) at regional and sectoral levels in Europe. Using a dynamic computable general equilibrium model and novel datasets, we estimate the distribution of losses and gains across regions and sectors. A comparison of a high-end scenario against a no-climate-impact baseline suggests a GDP loss of 1.26% (€871.8 billion) for the whole EU&UK. Conversely our refined assessments show that some coastal regions lose 9.56–20.84% of GDP, revealing striking regional disparities. Inland regions grow due to the displaced demand from coastal areas, but the GDP gains are small (0–1.13%). While recovery benefits the construction sector, public services and industry face significant downturns. We show that prioritising recovery of critical sectors locally reduces massive regional GDP losses, at negligible costs to the overall European economy. Our analysis traces regional economic restructuring triggered by SLR, underscoring the necessity of region-specific adaptation policies that embrace uneven geographic impacts and unique sectoral profiles to inform resilient strategy design.
... cũng đặt ra mối đe dọa lớn khi mực nước biển tăng cao xâm nhập vào các nguồn nước ngọt, đe dọa cung cấp nước sạch và tổ chức cấu trúc sinh thái. Làm thay đổi môi trường ven biển, bao gồm các đầm lầy, rừng ngập mặn và rạn san hô, đe dọa đa dạng sinh học biển và các hệ sinh thái quan trọng … [2]. Bên cạnh ý nghĩa trong nghiên cứu tai biến thiên tai, xác định được giá trị tăng lên của mực nước biển cũng góp phần cập nhật các bề mặt động lực đặc trưng trên biển. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study applied the GRU (Gated Recurrent Unit) model, a type of Recurrent Neural Network (RNN), to analyze tidal data collected at the Vung Tau tide gauge station from January 1, 1999, to December 31, 2022. Experimental results show that the statistical performance of the model is very promising: RMSE = 2.2 mm; MAE = 0.5 mm; Kappa = 0.98, and F-Score = 0.96. Additionally, to verify the effectiveness of the model, the dataset was divided into training, testing, and prediction datasets. Statistical results indicate that the GRU model can reliably predict tidal values using statistical features of the prediction dataset, such as RMSE = 0.06mm, MAE = 0.05 mm. The study also highlights the necessity of implementing outlier detection and elimination for the input dataset to achieve high prediction accuracy.
... Climate change and global warming has created a detrimental threat throughout the world, resulting in melting of glacier and rising the sea level. Rising sea level affects coastline areas by entering into the crop field, not only affecting the crop yields, making the soil unproductive, destroying the habitat, and affecting the trade market (Darwin and Tol 2001). Southeast Asia, East Asia, South Asia, and the Southeast US are more liable to be affected by rising sea level (Dasgupta et al. 2009). ...
Chapter
Climate change predictions may benefit from an awareness of how current changes have impacted food availability. Many agricultural activities throughout the globe have seen fast climate change over the last few decades, and greenhouse gas (GHG) levels in the atmosphere have also surged. Because of the near inevitability that climate and CO2 trends will continue in the future, several concerns about food security remain unanswered, one of which is whether or not global agriculture’s overall productivity will be influenced. It was also observed that climate change might have a significant impact on global food security in the next decades. Global anthropogenic trends, such as expanding populations, the diversion of grains to biofuels, increased protein consumption, and weather extremes, are imposing increasing pressure on agricultural productivity. In order to lower global CO2 levels and store atmospheric CO2, sustainable farming systems and management practises should be adopted. For resource-strapped farmers vis-à-vis policymakers, in this chapter, we documented a comprehensive list of possible implications of climate change on key worldwide field crop yield, mitigation techniques, and long-term prospects.
... However, this approach fails to capture induced price changes through market demand and supply available to CGEs (Sugiyama et al., 2008). Darwin and Tol (2001) discovered that CGE modelling of global welfare under SLR was 13% higher than the Direct Cost Method. CGE modelling reports more accurate results by integrating financial transfers. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This paper assesses the regional economic implications from local-scale coastal hazards under a changing climate. It explores possible financial pathways for vulnerable communities that create resilient adaptations via a managed retreat from the coast. A new Integrated Assessment Modelling approach (C-ADAPT) is created using Systems Dynamics. The tool incorporates Scenario Planning modules into an economic impact model called MERIT (Modelling the Economic Resilience of Infrastructure Tool). C-ADAPT explores the baseline impacts of coastal storms and sea-level rise on households, industries and government over 30-year simulations for the region of Hawke's Bay, New Zealand, for comparison against mitigation and adaptation scenarios. Compared to baseline scenarios, the managed retreat scenarios of central government climate bonds and local government property rating taxes reduce risk by 25% to 42% by 2050. Similarly, capital losses, inoperability, and infrastructure disruption are reduced, enabling community resiliency. The rates scenarios excelled in producing much better outcomes for regional Total Value Added (TVA), where it was 2.9% above the mid-range (RCP4.5) baseline climate scenario and 8.3% above the worst-case (RCP8.5) baseline climate scenario. However, local government consumption increased by 36.2% in 2043 (worst-case) and 31.4% in 2049 (mid-range) over the baseline. Alternatively, at the peak of managed retreat funding by the central government, the bonds scenario is 6.3% in 2039 (worst-case) and 4.5% in 2050 (mid-range), greater than the baseline government consumption. Although TVA only increases by 0.22% (mid-range) and 4.31% (worst-case) above the baseline for the bonds scenarios. Nonetheless, the bonds scenario was more effective at increasing regional household consumption (0.5% and 0.3% greater than the mid-range and worst-case rates scenarios, respectively) and unemployment (1.8% and 0.9% lower than the mid-range rates and worst-case scenarios). Construction and manufacturing are buoyed by managed retreat, whereas primary production is at a loss as secondary and tertiary industries offer better returns when land supply is scarce. A 'slow and steady' managed retreat achieved through property rating tax scenarios was economically more beneficial than 'quick fix' climate bonds scenarios. This is because the bonds scenarios lock up investment capital with the central government for a longer duration when compared to the shorter time over which local government holds rates before it is necessary to act. Simulation results also show that defence structures mitigate damages, loss of operability and infrastructure disruption by 2030 (worst-case) and 2040 (mid-range). Although coastal defence only increased economic output (TVA) by 0.3 to 1.2% by 2050. Thus, one could state that managed retreat stimulates the economy more than installing coastal defences or doing nothing.
... Second, the present study evaluates economic damages based on the "Manual for economic evaluation of flood control investment (draft)" (hereafter, "flood control manual") (MLIT, 2020), while the authors' previous study (Oba et al., 2021) used the econometric relationship between past hydrological disasters, similar to Tamura et al. (2019) on the global scale. Other efforts to estimate the global economic damage of SLR have also appeared, including Fankhauser (1995), the FUND model (Darwin & Tol, 2001), and the DIVA model (e.g., Hinkel et al., 2014), which used wet and dry land losses associated with the per capita income and population density of the affected areas. One of the unique contributions of this study is its use of the most current Japanese SSP population and land use projections, which were released in 2021 (NIES, 2021a(NIES, , 2021bYoshikawa et al., 2022) and make it possible to evaluate the socioeconomic impacts in detail. ...
Article
Full-text available
Sea level rise (SLR) due to climate change poses a serious threat to human populations in coastal areas. As a result, assessing the impacts of SLR and evaluating potential adaptations is essential. This study assesses the impacts of SLR and ocean tides on coastal Japanese prefectures by estimating the extent of potentially inundated areas, affected populations, and economic damages. The latest climate scenarios, tidal data, and shared socioeconomic pathways (SSPs) are used to estimate the SLR and its inundation effects at a resolution of 1 km. Economic damages are estimated following the methods outlined in the “Manual for economic evaluation of flood control investment (draft).” It was found that all impacts (inundated areas, affected populations, and economic damages) under RCP2.6-SSP1 are significantly smaller than those under RCP8.5-SSP5, suggesting the importance of mitigation efforts. In addition, the study evaluates the cost and effectiveness of protection and relocation adaptations using data on the cost of constructing dikes and the cost of relocating houses and infrastructure. While relocations due to SLR have not yet been undertaken in Japan, the relocation costs could be estimated based on the conventional scheme of community relocation for natural disasters such as life-threatening floods and tsunamis caused by major earthquakes. It was found that the costs of relocation can exceed those of protection under the current framework of Japanese relocation policies.
... Because our economic model is for beach going to beaches in Los Angeles and Orange counties, we limited our initial investigation to this part of the coast. Like other studies that have attempted to link climate change with beach recreation, we focus specifically on the effect on day use beach visitors (see for instance Bin et al. 2007;Deke et al. 2001;Darwin and Tol 2001;Bosello, Roson, and Tol 2007;Loomis and Crespi 1999). We focus on two potential scenarios of beach change. ...
Article
The purpose of this study was to estimate the economic damage from land loss caused by potential inundation due to sea level rise by 2100 in the coastal areas of Japan, and to compare this estimate with those calculated by conventional estimation methods. We used the posted land prices for residential land and the prices of rice paddies, crop fields, and timber forests to estimate the economic damage from land loss. Average land prices were calculated and interpolated for each municipality. Inundated area and economic damage were calculated under three scenarios: SSP1-2.6, SSP2-4.5, and SSP5-8.5. The potential inundated area nationwide in 2100 was estimated as 2,542-2,707 km² (SSP1-2.6 to SSP5-8.5). The economic damage varied from 158 to 200 trillion yen (SSP1-2.6 to SSP5-8.5) in 2050 and from 185 to 428 trillion yen (SSP1-2.6 to SSP5-8.5) in 2100.
Chapter
In drylands, the agriculture sector’s capacity to respond to climatic hazards is minimal. Crop modeling and determining the economic consequences of the impact of climate change are noticeably insufficient. To create respectable livelihoods in rural regions based on agriculture and sustainable dryland systems, the youth require education in this field. Improving yield and climate monitoring are key challenges for the successful adaptation of agriculture in drylands. To improve the ability to predict how environmental change will affect the agricultural sector in drylands, researchers need adequate research tools, accurate data, and models. The concept of integrated assessment modeling (IAM) is used to group several modeling techniques for evaluating the effects of climate change. Multidisciplinary assessment involves the development of methodologies for integrating knowledge across disciplines, especially between socio-economic and biophysical systems, to look into and comprehend their causal links. An interdisciplinary approach should integrate different models.
Article
This study assesses the commonly adopted adaptation planning strategies of infrastructures in Northwest Florida (USA) based on economic analysis under different objective years. Specifically, the economic analysis considers both direct and indirect impacts of sea level rise by deploying the interdependence of infrastructures. We demonstrate the difference and significance of considering indirect economic impacts in the process of cost-benefit analysis under sea level rise. Based on the results, we recommend that the most effective strategy is partial protection of land use plus inundated transportation network upgrade, even though the total shoreline protection can make more benefits. Furthermore, we compare the performance of objective planning year from two criteria: total benefits and cost-effectiveness. The result indicates that the year 2080 could be the most economical if it is set as the objective year for the long-term infrastructure planning. The result also highlights that the economic analysis of infrastructure should be conducted over time since the total costs are distributed over many years. It is not to say that the farther the year is, the more effectiveness the strategy would be, although the total benefits would be greater.
Article
Full-text available
The current global mean sea level was reached about 4,000 years ago after deglaciation following an ice age. It has been relatively stable ever since. But if the projections of such scientific bodies as the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) hold, global mean surface temperature could increase by 1.5°- 4.5° C, and the annual rate of sea level rise could increase from the current (approximately) 2 millimeters to as much as 6 millimeters over the coming decades. This means the sea level could rise by as much as 0.66 meters (about 2 feet) by the end of the 21st century, even if existing trends do not worsen. This could imperil small island nations and coastal areas, especially river deltas and coastal urban areas where subsidence has accelerated. The sea level fluctuations caused by natural variations in the Earth’s atmosphere, ocean and lithosphere can range from tens to hundreds of meters and usually change over relatively long time scales of several hundreds to thousands of years. Recent increase in greenhouse gases caused by human activities, however, threaten to induce shorter-term instabilities that may accelerate global warming and sea-level rise. Although there are many uncertainties in predictive models of sea level change, there seems to be an unmistakable trend toward an increase in atmospheric greenhouse gases and a rise in the sea level (largely because of thermal expansion of the ocean water). This global component of sea level rise has to be combined with the local component of coastal subsidence to arrive at an effective relative rate of sea-level rise, which will vary with locality. Human activities in many coastal zones of the world have increased natural subsidence rates, especially in river deltas and coastal urban centers due to excessive withdrawals of the aquifer water or hydrocarbons. Case studies from three delta regions with large populations (Bengal, Nile, and Niger deltas) illustrate the problems associated with development activities, both upstream and within the delta, many of which inevitably led to increased subsidence and threat from advancing seas. The large coastal cities of Bangkok, Shanghai and Tianjin are typical of many coastal urban areas in the developing world where population pressures and demand for increased freshwater has led to rapid depletion of local aquifers, increases in subsidence by as much as tenfold, saltwater intrusion, and significant environmental degradation. In view of these problems, projected sea-level rise in the next century augurs ill for these areas. The global sea level rise component may be of more immediate concern to small island nations such as the Maldives in the Indian Ocean and the Marshall Islands in South Pacific. These coral islands and atolls are barely above the sea level as it is, and a sea level rise like that predicted could mean a considerable loss of dry land. The coral reefs that are already in ill health because of population pressures and the attendant adverse environmental effects may not be able to keep pace with such a sea-level rise. Mitigation strategies to combat advancing seas are different for each type of area discussed in this paper but are generally a combination of protective and retreat adaptations. The paper also emphasizes the urgency of building protective structures around economically vital areas and planning the relocation of populations from the flood-prone areas that are likely to experience greater impact from the advancing seas and cyclones likely to be spawned by an increase in sea surface temperature.
Chapter
Potential economic impact and required human adjustments due to land subsidence and rising sea level in low-lying coastal areas are explained in order to help guide public response, and to anticipate the ways in which people will affect and be affected by these problems. A form of benefit-cost analysis to estimate the expected cost of an event in the absence of mitigation is an economic impact assessment. For example, rough estimates of the scale of potential impact of land subsidence and sea-level rise in Bangladesh and Egypt are reported on the basis of inundation scenarios up to the year 2050. Using strong assumptions about economic growth rates, land rent as a segment of the national product, intertemporal discount rate, and rate of inundation, a method is formulated for extending this characterization to an even cruder estimate of potential economic loss. This is a certainty-equivalent value confined to land inundation. Aside from obvious sources of imprecision, it underestimates several important phenomena: lost capital structures, increased exposure to storm damage and interior flooding, and such secondary effects as saline intrusion, crowding and factor reallocation costs. Even so, it is probably an overestimate because it is not based on probability, assumes a linear rate of land loss, and, most importantly, ignores cost reductions arising from human responses. Five economic topics involved in such responses receive special attention. These are: (1) the advantages of incremental responses to gradual change; (2) principles for managing uncertainty; (3) the ‘retrofit’ problem and capital durability; (4) economic discounting of future values; and (5) the nature and implications of common property, spillover, transboundary and informational effects.
Article
Any accelerated rise in sea level could have a major impact on the countries considered in this issue; the resulting problems will vary from country to country and depend on coastal geomorphology and present and future human activities in the coastal zone. Based on their highly-populated deltaic areas, China, Bangladesh, and Egypt are highly susceptible to sea-level rise. Sea-level rise could also cause significant problems in Senegal, and particularly Uruguay; this being largely related to tourist-based developments and to the high cost of beach nourishment. Considering the 10 countries contained in this issue, Bangladesh, Senegal, Nigeria, and Egypt appear most vulnerable — that is have the least ability to cope with sea-level rise based on their existing physical and human susceptibility, large and rapidly expanding coastal populations, and limited experience of likely adaptation techniques. Coastal wetlands are expected to experience losses at a global scale given accelerated sea-level rise, exacerbating existing rates of loss due to natural and human-induced factors, such as direct reclamation. The above conclusions are largely based upon the present pattern and distribution of coastal development in these countries. Their rapidly expanding coastal populations make continuing rapid and major coastal development almost certain; without careful planning, this will increase the vulnerability already described. Protection is technically feasible and likely in developed areas; although, increasingly large populations would be dependent on coastal defenses and would face catastrophic consequences in the event of failure. In some deltaic and wetland settings, comprehensive natural system engineering approaches such as controlled flooding and sediment management may be useful. However, there are limits to the ability of humans to counter all the projected losses of coastal wetlands. The uncertainty associated with future sea-level rise demands flexible policies in the coastal zone which can adapt to changing conditions. Sea-level rise exacerbates existing problems, rather than creating fundamentally new problems; thus, these approaches are best integrated with solutions to existing coastal problems. Thus, the coastal implications of climate change are one possible trigger for integrated coastal zone management. This will provide a strategic perspective of the coastal zone and contribute towards its more effective long-term management.
Article
Three distinct models from earlier work are combined to: (1) produce probabilistically weighted scenarios of greenhouse-gas-induced sea-level rise; (2) support estimates of the expected discounted value of the cost of sea-level rise to the developed coastline of the United States, and (3) develop reduced-form estimates of the functional relationship between those costs to anticipated sea-level rise, the cost of protection, and the anticipated rate of property-value appreciation. Four alternative representations of future sulfate emissions, each tied consistently to the forces that drive the initial trajectories of the greenhouse gases, are considered. Sea-level rise has a nonlinear effect on expected cost in all cases, but the estimated sensitivity falls short of being quadratic. The mean estimate for the expected discounted cost across the United States is approximately $2 billion (with a 3% real discount rate), but the range of uncertainty around that estimate is enormous; indeed, the 10th and 90th percentile estimates run from less than $0.2 billion up to more than $4.6 billion. In addition, the mean estimate is very sensitive to associated sulfate emissions; it is, specifically, diminished by nearly 25% when base-case sulfate emission trajectories are considered and by more than 55% when high-sulfate trajectories are allowed.