ArticlePDF Available

Warlord Competition

Authors:

Abstract

Warlords compete for turf that provides them with rents and 'taxable' resources, but they can also offer a semblance of security within their respective territories. This article first examines two economic models of warlord competition. Because such competition takes place through the use of force or the threat of the use of force, more competition typically leads to lower material welfare as resources are wasted on unproductive arming and fighting. This is in contrast to ordinary economic models, in which typically greater competition leads to higher material welfare. Furthermore, rents from oil, diamonds, and even foreign aid crowd out production. In extreme cases, this crowding out of ordinary production can be complete, whereby all economic resources can be devoted to the unproductive competition for rents. The article then reviews factors that lead either to actual war or to peace in the shadow of war. Because war is destructive, human beings are typically risk averse, and there exist numerous complementarities in production and consumption, we can expect peace in the shadow of war to be most often preferable by all parties. Actual war can take place because of incomplete information about the preferences and capabilities of the adversaries but also, somewhat surprisingly, when the shadow of the future is sufficiently long.
Copyright ã UNU/WIDER 2001
* Department of Economics, University of California, Irvine.
This study has been prepared within the UNU/WIDER project on Why Some Countries Avoid Conflict
While Others Fail, which is co-directed by Dr Tony Addison and Dr Mansoob Murshed.
Discussion Paper No. 2001/54
Warlord Competition
Stergios Skaperdas*
August 2001
Abstract
Warlords compete for turf that provides them with rents and ‘taxable’ resources but they
can also offer a semblance of security within their respective territories. This article first
examines two economic models of warlord competition. Because such competition
takes place through the use of force or the threat of the use of force, more competition
typically leads to lower material welfare as resources are wasted on unproductive
arming and fighting. This is in contrast to ordinary economic models, in which typically
greater competition leads to higher material welfare. Furthermore, rents from oil,
diamonds, and even foreign aid crowd out production. In extreme cases this crowding
out of ordinary production can be complete, whereby all economic resources can be
devoted to the unproductive competition for rents. The article then reviews factors that
lead either to actual war or to peace in the shadow of war. Because war is destrucrive,
human beings are typically risk averse, and there exist numerous complementarities in
production and consumption, we can expect peace in the shadow of war to be most
often preferable by all parties. Actual war can take place because of incomplete
information about the preferences and capabilities of the adversaries but also, somewhat
surprisingly, when the shadow of the future is long.
Keywords: warlord competition, conflict, cooperative and non-cooperative behaviour
JEL classification: C71, C72, O17
UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER)
was established by the United Nations University as its first research and
training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland in 1985. The purpose of
the Institute is to undertake applied research and policy analysis on structural
changes affecting the developing and transitional economies, to provide a
forum for the advocacy of policies leading to robust, equitable and
environmentally sustainable growth, and to promote capacity strengthening
and training in the field of economic and social policy making. Its work is
carried out by staff researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and through
networks of collaborating scholars and institutions around the world.
UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU/WIDER)
Katajanokanlaituri 6 B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland
Camera-ready typescript prepared by the author and Anna Kervinen at UNU/WIDER
Printed at UNU/WIDER, Helsinki
The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s). Publication does not imply
endorsement by the Institute or the United Nations University, nor by the programme/project sponsors, of
any of the views expressed.
ISSN 1609-5774
ISBN 952-455-232-9 (printed publication)
ISBN 952-455-233-7 (internet publication)
Warlord Competition*
STERGIOS SKAPERDAS
Department of Economics, University of California, Irvine
Abstract: Warlords compete for turf that provides them with rents and
taxable resources but they can also o¤er a semblance of security within
their respective territories. This article rst examines two economic models
of warlord competition. Because such competition takes place through the
use of force or the threat of the use of force, more competition typically leads
to lower material welfare as resources are wastedon unproductive arming and
ghting. This is in contrast to ordinary economic models, in which typically
greater competition leads to higher material welfare. Furthermore, rents
from oil, diamonds, and even foreign aid crowd out production. In extreme
cases this crowding out of ordinary production can be complete, whereby all
economic resources can be devoted tothe unproductive competition for rents.
The article then reviews factors that lead either to actual war or to peace in
the shadow of war. Because war is destrucrive, human beings are typically
risk averse, and there exist numerous complementarities in production and
consumption, we can expect peace in the shadow of war to be most often
preferable by all parties. Actual war can take place because of incomplete
information about the preferences andcapabilities of the adversaries but also,
somewhat surprisingly, when the shadow of the future is long.
*Presented at the workshop on why some countries avoid con‡ict while
others fail;held at, and sponsored by, the World Institute for Development
Economics Research (WIDER), United Nations University, Helsinki, 20-21
October, 2000. I would like to thank Halvor Mehlum, Mansoob Murshed,
other workshop participants, and three referees for their helpful comments.
1
1 Introduction
From the earliest recorded wars in history to the present, con‡ict has been
taking place between hierarchically organized groups with emperors, kings,
lords or generals at the top and common foot soldiers at the bottom. Nowa-
days, in many countries from Colombia, to Somalia, to the northern parts
of Afghanistan broad swaths of territory are outside the e¤ective control of
central governments - if those exist at all - and contested by rival groups, typ-
ically headed by what we could fairly characterize as warlords. By linguistic
convention, such conict constitutes competition, and that competition has
at least some economic objectives. Evaluating conict as competition from
an economic perspective is not a simple matter, however, for we cannot
blindly apply the received economic models without running into problems.
Is a greater number of competitors, for example, a good thing when there
is con‡ict as it is taken to be in the case of ordinary competing business
rms? With more competitors we would expect more ghting and resource
waste, less predictability, and greater di¢culties in communication, negoti-
ation, and settlement. Therefore, intuitively at least, it appears that the
answer to the question just posed above cannot be ’yes more competition
can be expected to lead to a worse outcome.
To make sense of this and other related peculiarities of what we call
in this paper warlord competition, we need a model di¤erent from the
model of ordinary rms competing on priceandpossibly onother dimensions.
Warlords instead compete over rents - oil, diamonds, drugs, foreign aid - as
well as over taxationof their subjects by being su¢ciently strong to deter
and, if necessarily, ght their competitors. We rst examine two types of
competition, one which is localized and another which is more generalized.
Wendthatrents, byincreasingtheintensityofcompetitionamong warlords,
crowd out some of the production under both types of competition. The
crowding-out e¤ect though is higher under generalized competition and in
some circumstances it can be nearly complete. There are even cases under
which all the productive resources and population are diverted toward the
unproductive competition for rents.
We then examine the incentives warlords face for going to war compared
to those for engaging in armed peace’, whereby they negotiate and settle
under the threat of going to war. Factors that favor armed peace include the
degree to which war is destructive, the risk aversion of the warlords, and how
complementaryorinterdependentisthe contestedsurplus withothergoodsor
2
services. War can be induced by thefactors thathave beenwidelynoted - like
misperceptions, misunderstandings, absence of communication channels - as
well as by characteristic that is normally considered to promote cooperation,
not conict: a long value attached to the future by the adversaries.
2 Two Kinds of Competition
Consider an area - district, country, or even more than one country - in
which the state is weak or non-existent. In the face of rampant insecurity,
individual producers areprotected by warlords. Inreturn, warlords receive a
xed share ® 2 (0;1) of each producers output, which for simplicity we take
to be equal to unity. For brevity and analytical convenience we do not model
explicitly here how warlords protect producers from individuals robbers or
bandits. The interested reader is instead referred to Konrad and Skaperdas
(1999) or Skaperdas (2001) in which a is derived from the maximizing choices
of producers and warlords briey, producers take costly actions to reduce
the size of that share, whereas warlords also devote resources to increase the
same share. We denote the number of producers by P. Therefore, the total
output received by warlords from producers is aP:
In addition to producers, the area under consideration has additional
rents that can have di¤erent sources: natural resources like oil, gas, timber,
or diamonds as well as cash, loans, and in-kind contributions from foreign
governments, international organizations, NGOs, or foreign diasporas.
1
Let
the net size of these rents available to warlords be T.
The L warlords compete for these rents and the surplus extracted from
producers through force or the threat of the use of force. Force is determined
by the number of warriors hired by each warlord at a resource cost ¯ 2 (0;1).
Competition is modeled as a contest (e.g., Tullock, 1980; Dixit, 1987) as it
also has been done in models of conict (e.g., Hirshleifer; 1988; Grossman,
1991; Skaperdas, 1992). With more than two warlords, though, there is
not a single way of modeling competition between them. We shall therefore
examine two di¤erent types of competition: one that is more localized and
the other one being closer to free-for-all.
1
These outside forces could also directly subsidize the cost of ghting and therefore
in‡uence warlord competition in other ways. The role of diasporas has been emphasized
by Collier & Hoe-er (2001).
3
2.1 Localized Competition
Because of geography, transportation di¢culties, and communication costs,
warlords possibly could extend their range and pose challenges to those in
their immediate vicinity only. To capture that characteristic of limited range,
suppose the warlords are equally spaced around a circle. The neighbors of
warlord l = 2;:::;L ¡ 1 are warlords l ¡ 1 and l + 1; warlords 1 and L have
one another as neighbors as well as, respectively, 2 and L ¡ 1.
The rents and other output are evenly distributed around the circle and
there is thus a surplus of size
T+®P
L
available for distribution among any
particular pair of warlords. Each warlord can contest the surplus to either of
his sides and can hire warriors who are dedicated to guarding either the left
or right border. That is, warlord l can hire w
l
l¡1
warriors to contest the
surplus on the side of warlord l ¡1 and w
l
l+1
warriors on the side of warlord
l + 1. The share of the surplus goes to warlord l when challenging warlord
l ¡ 1 is determined by a contest success function that equals:
2
w
l
l¡1
w
l
l¡1
+ w
l¡1
l
(1)
All warlords are risk neutral and theirpayo¤ functions canthus be dened
as follows:
V
l
¸
=
w
l
l¡1
w
l
l¡1
+ w
l¡1
l
T + ®P
L
¡¯w
l
l¡1
+
w
l
l+1
w
l
l+1
+ w
l+1
l
T + ®P
L
¡¯w
l
l+1
= (
w
l
l¡1
w
l
l¡1
+ w
l¡1
l
+
w
l
l+1
w
l
l+1
+ w
l+1
l
)
T + ®P
L
¡ ¯(w
l
l¡1
+ w
l
l+1
) (2)
Because of risk neutrality and the absence of other complications, there
is no di¤erence between assuming that
w
l
l¡1
w
l
l¡1
+w
l¡1
l
represents the share of the
local surplus received by warlord l in competition with warlord l ¡ 1 or the
probability of winning the same surplus. Later we shall discuss instances in
which settling under the threat of going to war leads to di¤erent outcomes
2
This is the functional form employed by Tullock (1980) for rent-seeking contests.
Hirshleifer (1989) hasdiscussed itsproperties andSkaperdas(1996)has providedaxiomatic
derivation of this and other functional forms.
4
than the one in which actual war takes place and, importantly, why actual
war or settlement under its threat would take place.
All warlords choose the number of warriors they allocate to each of their
two borders non-cooperatively, so that these choices form a Nash equilib-
rium. It can be shown that a symmetric equilibrium exists, whereby every
warlord chooses to deploy the following number of warriors against each of
his neighbors:
w
¸
=
T + ®P
4¯L
(3)
Consistently with intuition, the number of warriors deployed is positively
actually, linearly related to the surplus available between neighboring
warlords,
T+®P
L
; and negatively related to the cost of hiring warriors (¯). By
substituting w
¸
into the warlords payo¤ function, we obtain the equilibrium
prot of a warlord:
V
¸
=
T + ®P
2L
(4)
Even though this prot decreases as the number of warlords increases,
the total prot by summing up over all warlords equals LV
¸
=
T+®P
2
and is
therefore independent of the number of warlords. Given, then, the functional
forms we have assumed, half of the total surplus is taken as prot by warlords
whereas the remainder becomes dissipated in the hiring of warriors.
3
The warriors and warlords do not add anything to production - they both
play a parasitic role in the economy by competing for the appropriation of
the surplus. Whereas in the short-run production is given, in the long-run
we could expect it to respond to the level of appropriation. A major way in
which production is determined in our context is simply by the number of
individuals who decide to become producers. The other option is to become
a warrior. (For simplicity, we ignore the possibility of warlords coming from
the same population). Let N denote the total number of individuals in the
3
Of course, there is no signicance to having the surplus exactly split between warlords
and warriors. This property is a consequence of our specic assumption on the contest
success function, and other functional forms would yield di¤erent splits, which would have
a similar qualitatitive interpretation.
5
area under consideration and W the total number of warriors. The producers
and warriors exhaust the population so that:
N = P + W (5)
For individuals who reside in the area to choose to become warriors, they
wouldlike to have anincomeat least ashigh as thatof producers, whichas we
have seen equals 1 ¡®. Therefore, the cost of hiring warriors from the area,
¯, must equal or be higher than 1 ¡®. By (3), the total number of warriors
under localized competition is W
¸
= 2Lw
¸
=
T+®P
2¯
. By substituting this
quantity in (5), we can nd the induced number of producers under localized
competition:
P
¸
=
2¯
2¯ + ®
N ¡
1
2¯ + ®
T (6)
Total production, by the choice of units we have made, also equals P
¸
:
Note how the presence of higher rents, T, induces lower production. This oc-
curs because higher rents induce a greater level of appropriative competition
which in turn induces the hiring of a greater number of warriors that have
to come from the ranks of producers.
The total ’income of the area, however, should include the rents and
would equal:
T + P
¸
=
2¯
2¯ + ®
N +
2¯ + ® ¡1
2¯ + ®
T (7)
Income increases as rents increase, but less than the increase in rents
because of the reduction in production induced by the higher rents.
2.2 Generalized Competition
The model we have just examined has many idealized properties. Rents and
production are not typically uniformly distributed across areas. Mineral
wealth is often concentrated in one area and much economic activity is to be
found agglomerated in geographically small areas. This characteristic and
the ease of communication and movement make plausible that those who, in
6
the absence of su¢cient restraints, contest the rents and output of a given
area do so as a whole, and not just some small subset of it that is determined
by the accidents of geography. We will therefore examine now a model in
which all warlords compete for all the surplus that is available in a free-for-
all’. Whereas this type of competition is in some ways the other extreme of
the localized competition we have already analyzed, and is thus inevitably
unrealistic, our objective is to determine how our …ndings change with the
di¤erent assumptions. We can then be more con…dent for the results that
do not change and we will have good reason to attribute the results that do
change to the type of competition that takes place.
Each warlord, l; now chooses a number of warriors, w
l
, that is not aimed
against his neighbors but against all other lords. The share of the surplus
received by that warlord is determined by the higher dimensional analogue
to (1):
w
l
§
L
j=1
w
j
where L > 1 (8)
The payo¤ function of warlord l under generalized competition then be-
comes the following:
V
l
g
=
w
l
§
L
j=1
w
j
(T + ®P) ¡¯w
l
(9)
Again, as withthe case of localized competition, because of riskneutrality
and other assumptions,
w
l
§
L
j=1
w
j
can be interpreted as a share or as probability
of winning the total surplus. The Nash equilibrium choices of warriors and
the induced equilibrium payo¤ of a warlord are:
w
g
=
(L ¡1)(T + ®P)
¯L
2
(10)
V
g
=
T + ®P
L
2
(11)
Each warlord hires more warriors now, provided that L > 2: Note how
the payo¤ of a warlord is inversely related to the square of the number of
7
warlords. Thus, contrary to the case of localized competition, the total
prots of warlords, LV
g
=
T+®P
L
, vary inversely with their number - the more
warlords there are, the more intense the competition among them becomes
and the lower the total prots are.
To determine the number of producers we follow the same method we
employed in the case localized competition. The total number of warriors
under generalized competition is W
g
= Lw
g
=
(L¡1)(T+®P)
¯L
, and the substitu-
tion of this number in (5) and rearrangement yields the number of producers
(as well as of total output):
P
g
=
¯L
(® + ¯)L ¡®
N ¡
L¡1
(® + ¯)L ¡®
T (12)
In the absence of any rents (T = 0) and with more than two warlords,
it can be shown that the number of producers in (12) is lower than those
under localized competition in (6). As with localized competition, output is
decreasing in the size of the rents
_
T. However, contrary to that other case,
production depends on the number of warlords. For a large enough number
of lords (and, for example, when ¯ = 1 ¡ ®), the reduction in output as a
result of a given increase in rents is almost the same as the increase in rents
itself! Competition is more intense here and any increase in the rents induces
a considerably greater demand for warriors who have to come out of the ranks
of potential producers. Total ’income can be similarly calculated by adding
the value of the rents to the output in (12). The addition of even large rents
can have a negligible e¤ect on income by the aforementioned reduction in
output that they can induce.
4
Equation (12) has been derived on the assumption that the number of
producers is positive. In fact, when the rents are high enough it is possible
to have the whole population turn into warriors with no one becoming a
producer. When ¯ = 1 ¡ ®; that occurs when N <
L¡1
(1¡a)L
T: Hence, when
rents are high enough relative to the population, there may be no production.
Finally, it should be noted that the number of warlords should be en-
dogenous in the long-run. Whereas under localized competition that number
does not a¤ect production, under generalizedcompetition by (12) production
4
Parenthetically, the property we have just noted could provide the basis of an alterna-
tive explanation of the Dutch disease’, the commonly noted tendency of some countries
becoming poorer following the exploitation of a newly discovered resource like oil.
8
depends on the number of warlords.
5
Overall, there are several di¤erences between the types of warlord com-
petition: First, generalized competition is more intense, as measured by the
resources devoted to capturing the surplus. Second, production is lower un-
der generalized competition. Third, the presence of rents under localized
competition discourages production less than it does under generalized com-
petition; that is, crowding out of ordinary production by rents take place
in under both kinds of competition but it is higher under generalized com-
petition.
2.3 External Intervention
We shall now briey interject a note on the e¤ects of external intervention,
the participation of players in con‡ict who would be considered outsiders
by the other parties in the con‡ict. In the current turmoil in the Congo,
for example, almost every country from Uganda in the north to Zimbambwe
in the south appears to be involved to a lesser or greater extent either in
support of Kabilas government or with the forces opposing him. Similarly,
in Afghanistan all the neighboring countries, as well as more distant ones,
have at one time or another participated on the side of some of the evolving
parties to the long civil war there. These are by no means the only examples
of con‡ict that have drawn some form of external intervention; it is the rule
rather than the exception.
Within the framework we have just examined the generalized kind of
competition wouldperhaps be more appropriate. Onee¤ectof outsideparties
wouldworkthrough thesubsidizationofsomeof the contestants, or simply by
becoming one of the contestants themselves. In either case the e¤ect would
be to increase the resources devoted to capturing the surplus and therefore
to increase the intensity of con‡ict
There is, however, another type of external intervention, by those who, by
circumstance, interest, or even altruism, contribute to the increase in rents
in the a¤ected area. Foreign investments in natural resource extraction and
various forms of foreign aid, including possibly humanitarian, contribute to
5
We could determine that number by equating the warlords equilibrium payo¤ in (11)
to a xedcost of entry intothe business of war; the resultant equationalong withequation
(12) would determine the number of warlords and the number of producers as functions
of
9
the rents contested by the di¤erent warlords and therefore increase the inten-
sity of con‡ict. Moreover, such externally generated rents crowd out some
domestic production, and especially in the case of generalized competition
crowding out can be nearly complete.
External forces can of course play another, more positive, role by facili-
tating conict management and cooperation, an issue to which we now turn.
3 Why not Cooperate?
In both models we have examined, there is no e¤ective distinction between,
on the one hand, actual, overt con‡ict according to which one side emerges
as winner and the others are defeated and, on the other hand, the condition
of armed peace or armed cooperation’, whereby the warlords divide up the
rents under the threat of overt conict.
6
In general, we can expect, overt
conict and armed peace to have di¤erent welfare consequences. We will now
rst examine the forces that generate a di¤erence between overt con‡ict and
armed peace and then discuss why, despite the seeming superiority of armed
peace over overt conict, we observe so much overt conict. At the end of
the section, we will briey discuss how institutions of conict management
and peace could emerge to mediate disputes between warlords.
3.1 Overt Con‡ict versus Armed Peace
Forsimplicityof presentation,suppose therearejusttwowarlords. Then, the
two types of competition lead to the same payo¤ functions and equilibrium.
In addition, suppose the two warlords choose rst their respective number
of warriors and then they have the option of either inducing overt conict
or negotiating and settling under the threat of conict. If both were to
choose negotiation, then they would settle in an armed peace; otherwise,
overt conict would occur. We are interested in what occurs in this second
phase - whether and under what circumstances, once they have chosen their
warriors, the two sides would negotiate and settle. As we shall next see there
are several seemingly compelling reasons for not engaging in overt conict.
The question that might be raised, however, is: If the warlords can ne-
gotiate and make binding agreements on other things, why cant they make
6
I would like to thank Jack Hirshleifer for having suggested in conversation the term
armed peace’.
10
binding agreements on the number of warriors and thus disarm? The prob-
lem with making a contract on the number of warriors is that such a contract
would need warriors to be enforceable there is no higher authority over the
warlords and, therefore, would not be binding. With warriors at hand,
though, each side would have the force, the threat’, to make a contract en-
forceable on other things, including the division of the surplus. That is, there
is incomplete contracting on arming but not on other types of contracts that
can be enforced through reversion to ghting.
7
3.1.1 Destruction
Overt conict rarely takes places without destroying people and material
goods. Suppose then that if con‡ictwere to occura constant proportion1¡µ
of the surplus would be destroyed, thus leaving a net surplus of µ(T + ®P)
to be contested between the two adversaries (0 < µ < 1). In the event of
overt con‡ict, the winner would receive this surplus whereas the loser would
receive nothing. The payo¤ of warlord l = 1;2 under conict would then be:
V
l
c
=
w
l
w
1
+ w
2
µ(T +®P) ¡ ¯w
l
(13)
Without conict, the surplus remains intact. Therefore, if warlord l were
to receive a share
w
l
w
1
+w
2
of total surplus his payo¤ would be
w
l
w
1
+w
2
(T +®P)¡
¯w
l
>
w
l
w
1
+w
2
µ(T +®P)¡¯w
l
= V
l
c
. Consequently, each warlord would prefer
to settle rather than engage in overt con‡ict regardless of the number of war-
riors he or his opponent possesses. The division of the surplus in accordance
with
w
l
w
1
+w
2
is not however the only possible division that Pareto-dominates
conict. In fact, there is a continuum of such possible divisions yielding a
typical bargaining problem to be dealt with by the two warlords. As is well
known, there is not a single plausible bargaining rule (or, bargaining solu-
tion) that can be universally considered superior, but the Nash Bargaining
solution enjoys much support in the economic theory literature. (For an
overview of bargaining solutions, Roth, 1979; for a noncooperative justica-
tion of the Nash solution, see Binmore, Rubinstein, & Wolinsky, 1986.) In
7
There is a whole literature in economics that allows for such incomplete contracting
and bargaining that is mostly associated with the theory of the rm. Grossman and Hart
(1986) is a rst paper in a long line in which incomplete contracting in on the level of
relationship-specic investments that parties make, although a contract can be signed on
the division of the surplus once these investments have been made.
11
cases of risk neutrality, as it is in our model here, the Nash solution also
coincides with other symmetric solutions. Without going into the details, if
the adversaries were to follow such a symmetric solution at the negotiation
and settlement stage, the payo¤ function of warlord l would be the following:
V
l
p
= (
w
l
w
1
+ w
2
µ +
1 ¡µ
2
)(T + ®P) ¡¯w
l
(14)
Note that the division rule is
w
l
w
1
+w
2
µ +
1¡µ
2
and how the e¤ect of de-
struction enters into the determination of this payo¤ under armed peace.
The more destructive conict is (that is, the lower is the value of µ), the less
important are the warriors in determining the division of the surplus. The
equilibrium choice of warriors for both warlords turns out to be:
w
p
=
µ(T + ®P)
4¯
(15)
Again, note how the greater the possibility of destruction is, the lower
is the equilibrium choice of warriors. It turns out that this is also the equi-
librium number of warriors if the two sides expected overt conict to take
place under the payo¤s in (12). Perhaps the more basic point,then, is that
peace and the degree of cooperation involved under such conditions simply
require arming that does not have to be lower than the arming that would be
undertaken by the adversaries if they were expecting over con‡ict. Moreover,
in more complex environments than the one just examined, di¤erent sharing
norms,’ di¤erent bargaining solutions, can have very di¤erent e¤ects on arm-
ing and the welfare of the adversaries (see, Anbarci, Skaperdas & Syropoulos,
forthcoming).
3.1.2 Risk Aversion
Another feature of con‡ict situations that is important for whether adver-
saries engage in overt conict is their attitudes towards risk. Since there are
winners and losers in wars, conict is risky even if no destruction were to
take place. But risk is disliked by most people, even those like generals and
warlords who might be preparing their whole lives for it. For some risks inlife
there is insurance available but there is not any insurance available against
losing a war. What can be done instead is for the adversaries to choose not
12
to go to war, negotiate and settle their di¤erences in a fashion similar to the
way we have just seen in the case of destructive con‡ict.
To be more precise, suppose conict is not destructive but both warlords
are risk averse and both have a von Neuman-Morgenstern utility function
U(¢): Then the payo¤ of warlord 1 under overt conict would equal (the
payo¤ of warlord 2 is similarly dened):
V
1
c;risk
=
w
1
w
1
+ w
2
U[µ(T + ®P) ¡¯w
1
] +
w
2
w
1
+ w
2
U[¡¯w
1
] (16)
Again, following the logic in the case of destructive conict, suppose the
two adversaries were to divide the surplus in accordance with their winning
probabilities. That is, suppose warlord 1 receives
w
1
w
1
+w
2
(T +®P) as his share
of the total surplus, thus ensuring a sure payo¤ of U[
w
1
w
1
+w
2
(T +®P)¡¯w
1
] =
U[
w
1
w
1
+w
2
((T +®P)¡¯w
1
)+
w
2
w
1
+w
2
(0¡¯w
1
)], which by the concavity of U(¢)
implies that this sure payo¤ is strictly higher than the expected utility payo¤
under conict in (16).
8
Given that there is always an incentive to negotiate under risk aversion,
the question is how many warriors and resources are the warlords going to
expend in jockeying for a better negotiating position. As with the case of
destructive conict, much depends on the rule of division the adversaries
expect to use at the negotiating phase of their interaction.
3.1.3 Complementarities in Production and Consumption
The contestable rents andproductioncould be complementary to othergoods
that are deemed useful by producers and warlords alike but which are not
contestable. The leisure or even labor of producers, for example, cannot be
appropriated by the warlords but it is usually complementary in utility (for
the case of leisure) or in production (for the case of labor). If one were
to lose the complementary contestable surplus in conict, however, these
other goods would typically be a worth a lot less. The winner, on the
other hand, might have too much of the contestable surplus and too little of
the other non-contestable goods. Without going into the technical details,
9
8
With risk-seeking warlords, of course, the opposite would be true and overt con‡ict
would be preferable. U(¢) in such a case would be convex and therefore the payo¤ under
overt conict in (16) would be higher.
9
See Anbarci, Skaperdas & Syropoulos (forthcoming) for a formal specication and
derivation of the incentives to negotiate under such complementarities.
13
conict distributes resources ine¢ciently and therefore the adversaries could
instead negotiate fora peaceful, andmore e¢cient, divisionof the contestable
resources.
As we have just seen, then, there are plenty of reasons for settling in the
shadow of conict in a balance of power state in which the adversaries arm
in order to maintain their negotiating position. The level of arming itself,
however, depends on the norm or rule of division the adversaries expect
to adopt, with some rules being more sensitive to arming than others. A
limiting case of a rule is the one that is completely insensitive to arming and
according to which the two sides maintain a xed portion of the surplus.
That is the case that the adversaries completely trust one another, property
rights are completely specied and enforceable, as they are supposed to be in
ordinary economic environments. However, despite the variety of incentives
that may exist for armed peace, we still observe not just arming but overt
conict as well. We then next discuss some of the reasons that may induce
overt conict.
3.2 Why Overt Conict Occurs
Against the incentives to negotiate there are others that could actually pre-
cipitate con‡ict. One clear incentive would be that of risk-loving (or, risk-
seeking) preferences by warlords. In such a case, if destruction were not too
high, the adversaries would prefer to take the risk of war over the sure bet
of dividing up the surplus. While this can be a factor in inducing conict
under some circumstances, it is a cheap way of trying to understand why
overt conict occurs; attributing a phenomenon to a preferential parameter
should probably be a last resort. For the case of conict we can …nd alter-
native, plausible sets of explanation, one more well-known within economics
and another less so.
3.2.1 Incomplete Information
In the models we have examined, the adversaries know the exact size of the
rents and the level of production; the number of their adversaries and their
preferences; the exact nature of the contest success function that determines
the disposition of the surplus; and in the case of negotiation and settlement
they are supposed to share a norm about how to divide up the surplus. In
14
short, they face what economists and game theorists refer to as complete
information about all aspects of the game.
In reality of course adversaries face incomplete information in at least
one of the above dimensions. They might have only a general estimate of
the size of the surplus, the strengths and preferences of their adversaries, the
nature of the contest, and they might have no shared norms, or at least they
are not sure about them, in the event of negotiations. If the beliefs of the
adversaries about any of these dimensions deviate signicantly from one an-
other, then it would be perfectly possible to have equilibria (in appropriately
de…ned games) in which overt conict is the outcome despite the presence of
incentives to negotiate and settle. Bester and Warneryd (2000) examine such
an environment where there is war because at least one side underestimates
the strength of the other. There is much other research that shows how
suboptimal outcomes occur under incomplete information in many di¤erent
contexts, but Brito and Intriligator (1985) is another paper that specically
considers the possibility of war.
Many wars can at least partly be attributed to the presence of incomplete
information. World War I, for example, has been described to have occurred
after a series of misunderstandings, miscalculations, and even inattention to
details by some leaders at a time that trade and other interdependencies
among the future combatants made war unthinkable in the minds of opin-
ionmakers on both sides (see Joll, 1992, pp.10-41 ). If war could occur, then,
between the great powers of Europe that had established channels of commu-
nication, regular diplomatic exchanges, and norms of conduct that had been
evolving for centuries, it would be far easier to take place between warlords
who face a far less predictable environment, possibly without regular chan-
nels of communication and without established norms of conduct to guide
many of their critical moves.
3.2.2 How a Long Shadow of the Future Can Induce Con‡ict in-
stead of Cooperation
It has become a rather common belief in economics and political science that
conict typically yields to cooperation as adversaries value the future more
highly, or, as the shadow of the future becomes longer (Axelrod, 1984). This
belief is based on folk-theorem type of arguments in conditions of repeated
interaction. A long shadow of the future encourages long-term relationships
and the development of a live-and-let-live attitude between the adversaries.
15
However, there is a di¤erent e¤ect a long shadow of the future can have.
A warlord by pursuing war now could weaken his adversaries permanently or
even possibly eliminate them and become king well into the future. There-
fore, a warlord who values the future highly could indeed take the chance of
war instead of pursuing negotiation, despite the short-term benets of ne-
gotiation, because the expected long-run prots could be higher in case the
opponents become permanently weakened or eliminated. In environments
in which those who win gain an advantage well into the future, both the
intensity of conict, as measured by the amount of resources devoted to it,
increases (Skaperdas and Syropoulos, 1996) and the choice of overt con‡ict
over negotiation becomes more common (Garnkel and Skaperdas, 2000) as
the future becomes more important.
The argument of many parties that initiate wars is that they are forced
to do so because otherwise they would lose any advantage they might have
and thus have a lower probability of winning as a result. Again, during the
fateful summer of 1914, Germany felt that, to have any chance of swiftly
defeating France before Russia fully mobilized, it would have to call for gen-
eral mobilization as early as possible and before the intentions of the Entente
powers became fully known. But the call for mobilization by Germany would
certainly hasten war as it actually did. Thus, both the various forms that
incomplete information takes and the attempts by adversaries to gain a per-
manent strategic advantage over their opponents by initiating war are factors
that induce conict, despite the presence of incentives in the short-run to ne-
gotiate.
3.3 Conict Management in the Long-Run
The visitor to the Northern Italian city of Bologna today cannot miss the
tall, skinny towers that de…ne its skyline. They were built during the twelfth
and thirteen centuries when the city was wracked by clan warfare. The fact
that about 60 of the original 200 towers still stand is testament to how en-
during con‡ict can be. Other Italian cities had similar experiences to those
of Bologna at about the same time. To the people living then, that was the
only possible state of the world they could imagine. It was a state of what
we have called armed peace, punctuated by outright warfare when conditions
changed and one or more sides thought it could gain an advantage over the
others. Some periods were a lot more peaceful than others and the sides to
the conict could relax and go about their business without feeling threat-
16
ened. Informal and formal understandings would develop until some internal
or external force would change the apparently fragile equilibrium. This con-
dition did not end with the end of the thirteenth century. It continued in
di¤erent forms. The fteenth to the sixteenth centuries, for example, was
the world in which Machiavelli lived and the Tuscan countryside was guest
to French and German troops, Swiss papal guards, and the multitude of con-
dottieri - the various warlords o¤ering their services to cities who at the end
of their designated service would more often than not sack the homes of their
former employers. Italy did not unify until the second half of the nineteenth
century, and of course since then the country has not been completely free
of foreign troops or domestic contention.
Compared to other places, Italy has not been especially con‡ictual. Af-
ter all, this is the country in which the Renaissance and the commercial
revolution occurred. In closing with the example of Italy, we would like to
underscore the tremendous di¢culties in building the trust, the commitment,
and the institutions that will allow for disarmament and the elimination of
overt con‡ict. The transition from settling scores in the battleeld to settling
them in courts and parliaments is a process that has only began to be in-
vestigated by economists. It takes a very long time to build institutions and
not much to destroy them. Only recently have economists come to recognize
the central importance of institutions of conict management for economic
development. (Recent prominent examples of this recognition are Rodrik,
1999, and Oslon, 2000.) Though we cannot expect to …nd a recipe for end-
ing the many civil wars that are still taking place and those that are sure
to erupt in other countries, economists could complement the long-standing
e¤orts of other social scientists in identifying more direct paths than those
known to building institutions of con‡ict management.
References
[1] Anbarci, Nejat, Stergios Skaperdas & Constantinos Syropoulos, forth-
coming. Comparing Bargaining Solutions in the Shadow of Conict:
How Norms Against Threats can Have real E¤ects’, Journal of Eco-
nomic Theory.
[2] Axelrod, Robert, 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic
Books.
17
[3] Bester, Helmut & Karl Warneryd, 2000. ’Con‡ict Resolution, working
paper, Stockholm School of Economics.
[4] Binmore, Kenneth, Ariel Rubinstein, & Asher Wolinsky, 1986. The
Nash Bargaining Solution in Economic Modeling’, Rand Journal of Eco-
nomics, 16, 176-188.
[5] Brito, Dagobert L. & Michael D. Intriligator, 1985. ’Conict, War, and
Redistribution, American Political Science Review, 79(4), 943-957.
[6] James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison & Gordon Tullock, eds, 1980.
Toward a Theory of the Rent Seeking Society. CollegeStation, TX:Texas
A&M University Press.
[7] Collier, Paul & Anke Hoe-er, 2001. Greed and Grievance in Civil War’,
manuscript, Washington , DC: World Bank.
[8] Dixit, Avinash, 1987. Strategic Behavior in Contests’, American Eco-
nomic Review, 77, 891-898.
[9] Garnkel, Michelle & Stergios Skaperdas, 2000. ’Conict Without Mis-
perceptions or Incomplete Information; How the Future Matters’, Jour-
nal of Conict Resolution, 44 (6), 792-806.
[10] Grossman, Herschel I., 1991. A General Equilibrium Model of Insurrec-
tions, American Economic Review, 81(3), 912-921.
[11] Grossman, Sanford & Oliver Hart, 1986. The Costs and Benets of
Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, Journal of
Political Economy, 84, 691-719.
[12] Hirshleifer, Jack, 1988. The Analytics of Continuing Conict, Synthese,
76, 201-233.
[13] Hirshleifer, Jack, 1989. Con‡ict and Rent-seeking Success Functions’,
Public Choice, 63, 101-112.
[14] Joll, James, 1992. The Origins of the First World War. 2ns edn. New
York: Longman.
18
[15] Konrad, Kai & Stergios Skaperdas, 1999. The Market for Protection
and the Origin of the State, working paper, University of California,
Irvine and London, UK: CEPR.
[16] Olson, Mancur, 2000. Power and Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.
[17] Rodrik, Dani, 1999. The New Global Economy and Developing Coun-
tries: Making Openness Work. Policy Essay No. 24, Washngton, D.C.:
Overseas Development Council.
[18] Roth, Alvin, 1979. Axiomatic Models of Bargaining. New York: Springer
Verlag.
[19] Skaperdas, Stergios, 1992. Cooperation, Conict, and Power in the Ab-
sence of Property Rights’, American Economic Review, 82(4), 720-739.
[20] Skaperdas, Stergios, 1996. ’Contest Success Functions, Economic The-
ory, 7(1), 283-290.
[21] Skaperdas, Stergios, 2001. The Political Economy of Organized Crime:
Providing Protection When the State Does Not’, Economics of Gover-
nance, forthcoming.
[22] Skaperdas, Stergios & Constantinos Syropoulos, 1996. Can the Shadow
of the Future Harm Cooperation?’, Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 29(3), 355-372.
[23] Tullock, Gordon, 1980. E¢cient Rent Seeking’, in J.M. Buchanan, R.D.
Tollison, & G. Tullock.
STERGIOS SKAPERDAS, b. 1959, PhD in Economics (Johns Hopkins,
1989). Associate Professor, University of California, Irvine (1996-); area
of research: political economy. Co-editor of The Political Economy of
Conict and Appropriation (Cambirdge University Press, 1996).
19
... Such economistic explanations of the warlord often look to demand-side factors to explain the role of the warlord. It is argued that globalization coupled with a weak state creates the "pull" for individuals to engage in the exploitation of economic resources through the use or threat of use of force (Reno 2004;Skaperdas 2002). However, such an approach may underestimate the impact of "push" factors, particularly the inability of weakened or failed states to fulfill its necessary functions. ...
... Such economistic explanations of the warlord often look to demand-side factors to explain the role of the warlord. It is argued that globalization coupled with a weak state creates the "pull" for individuals to engage in the exploitation of economic resources through the use or threat of use of force (Reno 2004;Skaperdas 2002). However, such an approach may underestimate the impact of "push" factors, particularly the inability of weakened or failed states to fulfill its necessary functions. ...
... Specifically, comparative researchers believe that NRR may produce a variety of social problems, including violence (Collier and Hoeffler, 2002). This more recent strand of research is similar to what is being proposed by community-level scholars -that the resource curse may create conflict and violence (Collier and Hoeffler, 2005;De Soysa and Neumayer, 2007;Ross, 2003;Skaperdas, 2002). Violence related to natural resources that occurs globally has garnered significant attention in the press, especially when related to conflicts over resources such as oil and minerals. ...
Article
Full-text available
Countries that rely on natural resource rents (that is, the revenue generated from the sale of natural resources) may suffer from a variety of social problems. This exploratory study reviews the natural resource extraction literature to derive a 'natural resource rents–homicide' hypothesis. Data for 173 countries for the years 2000 to 2012 are examined to determine if there is a correlation between natural resource rents and homicide rates. Multilevel growth models suggest that natural resource rents are positively correlated with homicide rates within countries (level 1) but not between them (level 2). Importantly, the correlation between natural resource rents and homicide is strongest when natural resource rents are lagged. We conclude by suggesting that increasing natural resource rents may be counterproductive over the long run and sow the seeds for a future increase in homicide.
Article
Full-text available
En este artículo se analiza el uso de la violencia y la corrupción como factores de maximización del beneficio de los traficantes en el mercado de los cultivos de coca. Se propone que la condición de ilegalidad de este mercado da lugar al establecimiento de sistemas de seguridad privada y corrupción que operan como estrategias de maximización de los beneficios de los traficantes, y se propone la existencia de un umbral de acción de la justicia que hace inviable la actividad ilegal.
Article
Full-text available
This article, first, examines the association between resource rents, institutions and economic growth in Africa, as well as the performance of resource-rich and non-resource-rich countries on institutional quality and political governance. The findings suggest that resource rents failed to contribute to long-term growth on the continent. Additionally, higher resource rents are associated with relatively weak institutions. Second, using historical data, the study tests the validity of the resource-curse hypothesis in two resource-rich countries, namely, Nigeria and Botswana. Although both countries have derived substantial revenues from their natural resource sectors, the distributed-lag results show that Nigeria may have experienced a natural resource curse, while Botswana has not. These findings are presumed, based on the extant literature, to be explained by differences in the level of institutional quality.
Article
Previous studies have cited inequality as a major factor relating to conflicts in Indonesia, while consideration of polarization and fractionalization as drivers of conflict is limited. The current paper examined the roles of three indices (polarization, inequality and fractionalization) in explaining the incidence of conflicts in Indonesian provinces over 2002–2012. This study used income (proxied by expenditure) differences to measure polarization and inequality, with subnational data as the unit of analysis. In addition, to complete the analysis, the present study used a variety of socioeconomic indicators as additional control variables. This paper verified that the high degrees of income polarization, ethnic fractionalization and income inequality are associated with the high probability of conflicts in Indonesian provinces. It also found that socioeconomic factors such as poverty, unemployment, population and natural resources, as well as some types of local government spending are significantly associated with conflicts.
Preprint
Full-text available
Sumario La crisis económica en Venezuela exige un cambio radical de políticas, entre las cuales destaca, por su relevancia y carácter controversial, la política cambiaria. En este documento se caracteriza la política cambiaria en Venezuela, identificando las razones que explican la naturaleza del régimen cambiario dominante y evaluando su desempeño a la luz de la literatura especializada y la experiencia reciente. Se analizan las principales ventajas y desventajas de los regímenes cambiarios susceptibles de ser adoptados, tomando en consideración la influencia de algunos aspectos específicos o idiosincráticos de la economía venezolana. Se focaliza el interés en el tema de la flexibilidad del tipo de cambio, que se entiende como un proceso donde deben superarse ciertas etapas y conjugarse ciertos requerimientos en el marco de un programa integral de estabilización y reformas estructurales que busque reducir la inflación y salir de la profunda recesión en que se encuentra la economía. Las debilidades institucionales sugieren la adopción de una estrategia gradualista, lo cual exige diferenciar con precisión las diferentes fases que la componen: la salida ordenada, la estabilización y el crecimiento sostenido. La política cambiaria debe cumplir diferentes funciones en cada una de esas fases; para desempeñarlas adecuadamente se requiere, a su vez, el cumplimiento de un conjunto de condiciones institucionales, financieras, políticas y sociales. Especial atención exige el análisis de la probable situación inicial de la economía para el momento en que se debe producir la unificación del tipo de cambio, ya que ésta determina la ruta general de acciones de política durante esta etapa crítica de ajustes y reformas. Asimismo, se consideran diferentes estrategias en el periodo transitorio que pudieran conducir a un régimen de flotación administrada del tipo de cambio nominal. Por último, se analizan las características básicas del manejo de la política cambiaria bajo un régimen de flexibilidad, que debe ser acompañado de una política monetaria centrada en la consecución de objetivos inflacionarios. A lo largo del trabajo se enfatiza la necesidad de comprender el manejo del régimen cambiario como un proceso de aprendizaje que se desarrolla dentro de un marco institucional, evitando así caer en el error de considerar a la política cambiaria como una respuesta estática e incontrovertible. Palabras clave: Venezuela, régimen cambiario, estabilización JEL: E52, E58, E61, F31, F32
Article
Full-text available
Violence is key to understanding human interaction and societal development. The natural state of societal organization is that a subset of the population, capable of mustering organized large-scale violence, forms an elite coalition that restrains both violence and coercive appropriation. We highlight key mechanisms underlying such natural states using insights from the economic literature on conflict and appropriation. Our results show large variations in elite size, appropriation, production levels, and welfare across natural states due to only minor variations in exogenous model parameters. Specifically, unproductive societies tend to have a large elite coalition and a high tax rate. Only when the elite coalition is small (which occurs in societies with high productivity) but still able to control a sizeable share of production, can societies prosper in a natural state.
Article
'This masterly book succinctly surveys contemporary literature on the sources of conflict in developing countries as well as policies to secure a stable peace, including many insightful contributions by the author. The treatment of this important but controversial field is both informative and well balanced. It should be essential reading for all students and policy makers who believe that policy should be evidence-based.'
Article
Full-text available
Our theory of costly contracts emphasizes that contractual rights can be of two types: specific rights and residual rights. When it is costly to list all specific rights over assets in the contract, it may be optimal to let one party purchase all residual rights. Ownership is the purchase of these residual rights. When residual rights are purchased by one party, they are lost by a second party, and this inevitably creates distortions. Firm 1 purchases firm 2 when firm 1's control increases the productivity of its management more than the loss of control decreases the productivity of firm 2's management.
Book
The process of global economic integration has sharply altered the context in which most governments are thinking about policies for economic development. The world economy and the 'dictates' of international economic integration loom much larger than ever before. Indeed, in many 'emerging' economies traditional developmental concerns relating to industrialization and poverty have been crowded out by the pursuit of 'international competitiveness'. Openness to the world economy can be a source of many economic benefits. The importantion of investment and intermediate goods that may not be available domestically at comparable cost, the transfer of ideas and technology from more developed nations, and access to foreign savings can help poor nations circumvent some of the traditional obstacles to rapid growth. But these are only potential benefits, to be realized in full only when the complementary policies and institutions are in place domestically. The claims made by the boosters of international economic integration are frequently inflated or downright false. Countries that have done well in the postwar period are those that have been able to formulate a domestic investment strategy to kick-start growth and those that have had the appropriate institutions to handle adverse external shocks, not those that have relied on reduced barriers to trade and capital flows. The evidence from the experience of the last two decades is quite clear: the countries that have grown most rapidly since the mid-1970s are those that have invested a high share of GDP and maintained macroeconomic stability. The relationship between growth rates and indicators of openness - levels of tariff and non-tariff barriers or controls on capital flows - is weak at best. Policymakers therefore have to focus on the fundamentals of economic growth - investment, macroeconomic stability, human resources, and good governance - and not let international economic integration dominate their thinking on development.
Article
The rent-seeking competitions studied by economists fall within a much broader category of conflict interactions that also includes military combats, election campaigns, industrial disputes, lawsuits, and sibling rivalries. In the rent-seeking literature, each party's success pi (which can be interpreted either as the probability of victory or as the proportion of the prize won) has usually been taken to be a function of the ratio of the respective resource commitments. Alternatively, however, pi may instead be a function of the difference between the parties' commitments to the contest. The Contest Success Function (CSF) for the difference from is a logistic curve in which, as is consistent with military experience, increasing returns apply up to an inflection point at equal resource commitments. A crucial flaw of the traditional ratio model is that neither onesided submission nor two-sided peace between the parties can ever occur as a Cournot equilibrium. In contrast, both of these outcomes are entirely consistent with a model in which success is a function of the difference between the parties' resource commitments.
Article
It is generally thought that in long-term relationships high valuations of the future are conducive to cooperation. In an intertemporal model of conflict, however, we demonstrate the possibility of the opposite effect: a longer shadow of the future may harm cooperation. In particular, we show that the degree of inefficiency is positively related to: (i) the agents' valuation of the future, (ii) potential growth rates in resources, (iii) the size of initial resource endowments, and (iv) the effectiveness of conflict.