ArticlePDF Available

The Rise and Fall of Subprime Mortgages

Authors:

Abstract

After booming the first half of this decade, U.S. housing activity has retrenched sharply. Single-family building permits have plunged 52 percent and existing-home sales have declined 30 percent since their September 2005 peaks. ; A rise in mortgage interest rates that began in the summer of 2005 contributed to the housing market's initial weakness. By late 2006, though, some signs pointed to renewed stability. They proved short-lived as loan-quality problems sparked a tightening of credit standards on mortgages, particularly for newer and riskier products. As lenders cut back, housing activity began to falter again in spring 2007, accompanied by additional rises in delinquencies and foreclosures. Late-summer financial-market turmoil prompted further toughening of mortgage credit standards. ; The recent boom-to-bust housing cycle raises important questions. Why did it occur, and what role did subprime lending play? How is the retrenchment in lending activity affecting housing markets, and will it end soon? Is the housing slowdown spilling over into the broader economy?
The Rise and Fall of Subprime Mortgages
by Danielle DiMartino and John V. Duca
After booming the first half of this decade, U.S. housing activity has retrenched
sharply. Single-family building permits have plunged 52 percent and existing-home sales
have declined 30 percent since their September 2005 peaks (Chart 1).
A rise in mortgage interest rates that began in the summer of 2005 contributed
to the housing market’s initial weakness. By late 2006, though, some signs pointed to
renewed stability. They proved short-lived as loan-quality problems sparked a tightening
of credit standards on mortgages, particularly for newer and riskier products. As lenders
cut back, housing activity began to falter again in spring 2007, accompanied by addi-
tional rises in delinquencies and foreclosures. Late-summer financial-market turmoil
prompted further toughening of mortgage credit standards.
The recent boom-to-bust housing cycle raises important questions. Why did
it occur, and what role did subprime lending play? How is the retrenchment in lending
Insights from the
F E D E R A L R E S E RV E B A N K O F D A L L A S
EconomicLetter
VOL. 2, NO. 11
NOVEMBER 2007
Past behavior suggests
that housing markets’
adjustment to more
realistic lending
standards is likely
to be prolonged.
EconomicLetter FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS
2
FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS EconomicLetter
activity affecting housing markets, and
will it end soon? Is the housing slow-
down spilling over into the broader
economy?
Rise of Nontraditional Mortgages
Monitoring housing today entails
tracking an array of mortgage prod-
ucts. In the past few years, a fast-
growing market seized upon such
arrangements as “option ARMs,” “no-
doc interest-onlys” and “zero-downs
with a piggyback.” For our purposes,
it’s sufficient to distinguish among
prime, jumbo, subprime and near-
prime mortgages.
Prime mortgages are the tradi-
tionaland still most prevalent type
of loan. These go to borrowers with
good credit, who make traditional
down payments and fully document
their income. Jumbo loans are gener-
ally of prime quality, but they exceed
the $417,000 ceiling for mortgages
that can be bought and guaranteed by
government-sponsored enterprises.
Subprime mortgages are extended
to applicants deemed the least credit-
worthy because of low credit scores
or uncertain income prospects, both of
skip payments by reducing equity or,
in some cases, obtain a mortgage that
exceeded the home’s value.
These new practices opened
the housing market to millions of
Americans, pushing the homeowner-
ship rate from 63.8 percent in 1994
to a record 69.2 percent in 2004.
Although low interest rates bolstered
homebuying early in the decade, the
expansion of nonprime mortgages
clearly played a role in the surge of
homeownership.
Two crucial developments
spurred nonprime mortgages’ rapid
growth. First, mortgage lenders adopt-
ed the credit-scoring techniques first
used in making subprime auto loans.
With these tools, lenders could better
sort applicants by creditworthiness and
offer them appropriately risk-based
loan rates.
By itself, credit scoring couldn’t
have fostered the rapid growth of
nonprime lending. Banks lack the
equity capital needed to hold large
volumes of these risky loans in their
portfolios. And lenders of all types
couldn’t originate and then sell these
loans to investors in the form of resi-
dential mortgage-backed securities,
or RMBS —at least not without added
protection against defaults.
The spread of new products offer-
ing default protection was the second
crucial development that fostered sub-
prime lending growth. Traditionally,
banks made prime mortgages funded
with deposits from savers. By the
1980s and 1990s, the need for deposits
had eased as mortgage lenders created
a new way for funds to flow from sav-
ers and investors to prime borrowers
through government-sponsored enter-
prises (GSEs) (Chart 2, upper panel).
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are
the largest GSEs, with Ginnie Mae
being smaller. These enterprises guar-
antee the loans and pool large groups
of them into RMBS. They’re then sold
to investors, who receive a share of
the payments on the underlying mort-
gages. Because the GSEs are feder-
ally chartered, investors perceive an
which reflect the highest default risk
and warrant the highest interest rates.
Near-prime mortgages, which are
smaller than jumbos, are made to bor-
rowers who qualify for credit a notch
above subprime but may not be able
to fully document their income or pro-
vide traditional down payments. Most
mortgages in the near-prime category
are securitized in so-called Alternative-
A, or Alt-A, pools.
Some 80 percent of outstanding
U.S. mortgages are prime, while 14
percent are subprime and 6 percent
fall into the near-prime category.
These numbers, however, mask the
explosive growth of nonprime mort-
gages. Subprime and near-prime loans
shot up from 9 percent of newly origi-
nated securitized mortgages in 2001 to
40 percent in 2006.
1
The nonprime boom introduced
practices that made it easier to obtain
loans. Some mortgages required
little or no proof of income; others
needed little or no down payment.
Homebuyers could take out a simulta-
neous second, or piggyback, mortgage
at the time of purchase, make inter-
est-only payments for up to 15 years,
Chart 1
Housing Activity Drops Off
Millions of units Millions of units
.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
2
’07’06’05’04’03’02’01’00
4
5
6
7
8
Total existing-home sales
Single-family
building permits
Subprime
woes hit
Mortgage
rates start rising
SOURCES: National Association of Realtors; Census Bureau; authors’ calculations.
EconomicLetter FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS
FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS EconomicLetter
3
implicit government guarantee of them.
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, however,
haven’t packaged many nonprime
mortgages into RMBS.
Lacking the same perceived status,
nonagency RMBS—those not issued by
Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and Ginnie
Mae—faced the hurdle of paying
investors extremely large premiums to
compensate them for high default risk.
These high costs would have pushed
nonprime interest rates to levels out-
side the reach of targeted borrowers.
This is where financial innova-
tions came into play. Some like col-
lateralized debt obligations (CDOs),
a common RMBS derivative were
designed to protect investors in
nonagency securities against default
losses. Such CDOs divide the streams
of income that flow from the under-
lying mortgages into tranches that
absorb default losses according to a
preset priority.
The lowest-rated tranche absorbs
the first defaults on the pool of
underlying mortgages, with succes-
sively higher ranked and rated tranches
absorbing any additional defaults. If
defaults turn out to be low, there may
be no losses for higher-ranked tranches
to absorb. But if defaults are much
greater than expected, even higher-
rated tranches may face losses.
Having confidence in the ability
of quantitative models to accurately
measure nonprime default risk, a brisk
market emerged for securities backed
by nonprime loans. The combination of
new credit-scoring techniques and new
nonagency RMBS products enabled
nonprime-rated applicants to qualify
for mortgages, opening a new chan-
nel for funds to flow from savers to a
new class of borrowers in this decade
(Chart 2, lower panel).
Nonprime Boom Unravels
As problems began to emerge in
late 2006, investors realized they had
purchased nonprime RMBS with overly
optimistic expectations of loan quality.
2
Much of their misjudgment plausibly
stemmed from the difficulty of forecast-
Chart 2
Mortgage Financial Flows
Prime
mortgage
borrowers
Savers
and
investors
Nonprime
mortgage
borrowers
2000–06
B
uy
nonagency
RMB
S
Mortgage
originators
Banks
1980s–90s
Prim
e
mortga
ge
s
Buy
G
S
E
RMB
S
Subprime/
near
-pri
m
e
mortgages
Prim
e
mort
gages
Depo
sits
Prime
mortgage
borrowers
Savers
and
investors
Mortgage
originators
Banks
Prim
e
mortga
ge
s
Buy
G
S
E
RMB
S
Prim
e
mort
gages
Depo
sits
.
EconomicLetter FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS
4
FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS EconomicLetter
ing default losses based on the short
history of nonprime loans.
Subprime loan problems had
surfaced just before and at the start
of the 2001 recession but then rapidly
retreated from 2002 to 2005 as the
economy recovered (Chart 3). This
pre-2006 pattern suggested that as
long as unemployment remained low,
so, too, would default and delinquen-
cy rates.
This interpretation ignored two
other factors that had helped alleviate
subprime loan problems earlier in the
decade. First, this was a period of rap-
idly escalating home prices. Subprime
borrowers who encountered financial
problems could either borrow against
their equity to make house payments
or sell their homes to settle their
debts. Second, interest rates declined
significantly in the early 2000s. This
helped lower the base rate to which
adjustable mortgage rates were
indexed, thereby limiting the increase
when initial, teaser rates ended.
Favorable home-price and interest
rate developments likely led models
that were overly focused on unem-
ployment as a driver of problem loans
to underestimate the risk of nonprime
mortgages. Indeed, swings in home-
price appreciation and interest rates
may also explain why prime and
subprime loan quality have trended
together in the 2000s. This can be
seen once we account for the fact
that past-due rates—the percentage
of mortgages delinquent or in some
stage of foreclosure—typically run five
times higher on subprime loans (Chart
3). When the favorable home-price
and interest rate factors reversed, the
past-due rate rose markedly, despite
continued low unemployment.
Failure to appreciate the risks
of nonprime loans prompted lenders
to overly ease credit standards.
3
The
result was a huge jump in origination
shares for subprime and near-prime
mortgages.
Compared with conventional
prime loans in 2006, average down
payments were lower, at 6 percent for
subprime mortgages and 12 percent
for near-prime loans.
4
The relatively
small down payments often entailed
borrowers’ taking out piggyback loans
to pay the portion of their home
prices above the 80 percent covered
by first-lien mortgages.
Another form of easing facilitated
the rapid rise of mortgages that didn’t
require borrowers to fully document
their incomes. In 2006, these low- or
no-doc loans comprised 81 percent of
near-prime, 55 percent of jumbo, 50
percent of subprime and 36 percent of
prime securitized mortgages.
The easier lending standards
coincided with a sizeable rise in
adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs). Of
the mortgages originated in 2006 that
were later securitized, 92 percent of
subprime, 68 percent of near-prime,
43 percent of jumbo and 23 percent
of prime mortgages had adjustable
rates. Now, with rates on one-year
adjustable and 30-year fixed mort-
gages close, ARMsmarket share has
dwindled to 15 percent, less than
half its recent peak of 35 percent in
2004.
Chart 3
Quality of Prime and Subprime Mortgages Deteriorates
Percent Percent
Share of conventional subprime
mortgages past due
2
2.2
2.4
2.6
2.8
3
’07’06’05’04’03’02’01’00’99’98
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
Share of conventional prime
mortgages past due
NOTES: Conventional mortgages are those not insured by the Federal Housing Administration or guaranteed by the
U.S. Department of Veterans Affairs. Data are seasonally adjusted. Shaded area indicates recession.
SOURCE: Mortgage Bankers Association.
Failure to appreciate the
risks of nonprime loans
prompted lenders to overly
ease credit standards.
The result was a huge
jump in origination
shares for subprime and
near-prime mortgages.
EconomicLetter FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS
FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS EconomicLetter
5
In early 2007, investors and lend-
ers began to realize the ramifications
of credit-standard easing. Delinquency
rates for 6-month-old subprime and
near-prime loans underwritten in 2006
were far higher than those of the same
age originated in 2004.
Other signs of deterioration also
surfaced. The past-due rate for out-
standing subprime mortgages rose
sharply and neared the peak reached
in 2002, with the deterioration much
worse for adjustable- than fixed-rate
mortgages. In first quarter 2007, the
rate at which residential mortgages
entered foreclosure rose to its fast-
est pace since tracking of these data
began in 1970.
Lenders reacted to these signs
by initially tightening credit standards
more on riskier mortgages. In the
Federal Reserve’s April 2007 survey
of senior loan officers, 15 percent of
banks indicated they had raised stan-
dards for mortgages to prime borrow-
ers in the prior three months, but a
much higher 56 percent had done so
for subprime mortgages. Responses to
the July 2007 survey were similar.
However, in the October 2007
survey the share of banks tightening
standards on prime mortgages jumped
to 41 percent, while 56 percent did
so for subprime loans. Many nonbank
lenders have also imposed tougher
standards or simply exited the busi-
ness altogether. This likely reflects
lenders’ response to the financial dis-
ruptions seen since last summer.
The stricter standards meant fewer
buyers could bid on homes, affecting
prices for prime and subprime bor-
rowers alike. Foreclosures added to
downward pressures on home prices
by raising the supply of houses on
the market. And after peaking in
September 2005, single-family home
sales fell in September 2007 to their
lowest level since January 1998.
The number of unsold homes
on the market has risen, sharply
pushing up the inventory-to-sales
ratio for existing single-family
homes from their low in January
2005 to their highest level since the
start of this series in 1989 (Chart
4). Condominium supply, which is
reflected in the all-home numbers, has
experienced an even sharper increase
since early 2005.
These high inventories will likely
weigh on construction and home prices
for months to come. After peaking in
early 2005, the Standard & Poor’s/Case-
Shiller index of year-over-year home-
price appreciation in 10 large U.S. cities
was down 5 percent in August—its big-
gest drop since 1991. While a Freddie
Mac gauge of home prices posted a
small year-over-year gain in the second
quarter, the pace was dramatically off
its highest rate, reported in third quar-
ter 2005 (Chart 5).
In the absence of home-price
appreciation, many households are
finding it difficult to refinance their
way out of adjustable-rate mortgages
obtained at the height of the hous-
ing boom. Larger mortgage payments
could exacerbate delinquencies and
foreclosures, especially with interest
rate resets expected to remain high for
the next year (Chart 6). This suggests
mortgage quality will likely continue
to fall off for some time.
Financial Turmoil
By August 2007, the housing
market’s weaknesses were apparent:
loan-quality problems, uncertainty
about inventories, interest rate resets
and spillovers from weaker home pric-
es. These, coupled with ratings agen-
cies’ downgrading of many subprime
RMBS, led to a dramatic thinning in
trading for subprime credit instru-
ments, many of which carried synthet-
Chart 4
Existing-Home Inventories Rise from Late-2004 Lows
Months supply of unsold homes
Single-family homes
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
’07’06’05’04’03’02’01’00’99’98’97’96’95’94’93’92’91’90’89
All homes
NOTE: The all-homes category covers single-family homes, condominiums and nonrental apartments. Shaded areas
indicate recession.
SOURCE: National Association of Realtors.
In the absence of home-
price appreciation, many
households are finding it
difficult to refinance their
way out of adjustable-rate
mortgages.
EconomicLetter FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS
6
FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS EconomicLetter
ic, rather than market, values based
on models because of the instruments’
illiquidity.
On Aug. 14, the paralysis in the
capital markets led three investment
funds to halt redemptions because
they couldn’t reasonably calculate the
prices at which their shares could be
valued. This event triggered wide-
spread concern about the pricing of
many new instruments, calling into
question many financial firms’ mar-
ket values and disrupting the normal
workings of the financial markets.
Investors sought liquidity, putting
upward pressure on overnight inter-
est rates and sparking a sharp upward
repricing of risk premiums on assets,
particularly those linked to nonprime
mortgages. One outcome was an
interest rate spike for both mortgage-
backed commercial paper and jumbo
mortgages, which heightened financial
market uncertainty. In this environ-
ment, nonagency RMBS were viewed
as posing more liquidity and default
risk than those packaged by Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac.
Facing greater perceived default
risk, investors began demanding much
higher risk premiums on jumbo mort-
gage securities, pushing up the cost
of funding such loans via securitiza-
tion and encouraging lenders to incur
the extra cost of holding more of
these loans in their portfolios. This
contributed to a 1 percentage point
jump in jumbo interest rates between
June and late August, an especially
important increase given that jumbos
accounted for about 12 percent of
mortgage originations last year.
Although spreads between jumbo
and conforming loan rates have fallen
off their late-summer highs, they’re
still elevated. The higher rates have
dampened the demand for more
expensive homes, just as tighter credit
standards reduced the number of buy-
ers for lower-end homes.
Macroeconomic Effects
A housing slowdown mainly affects
gross domestic product by curtailing
Chart 6
Scheduled Resets on Adjustable-Rate Mortgages
Remain High
Billions of dollars in loans
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
Nov.JulyMarchNov.July
2007 2008
Subprime
Jumbo
Near prime
GSE
SOURCE: Bank of America estimates based on LoanPerformance data.
Chart 5
Home-Price Appreciation Plunges
into Negative Territory
Percent (year-over-year)
S&P/Case-Shiller
U.S. index
Freddie Mac
repeat-sales index
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
’07’06’05’04’03’02’01’00’99’98’97’96’95’94’93’92’91’90’89’88’87
NOTE: Shaded areas indicate recession.
SOURCES: Freddie Mac; Standard & Poor’s/Case-Shiller.
EconomicLetter FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS
FEDE R AL R ESERVE B ANK O F DAL L AS EconomicLetter
7
housing construction and home-related
spending. It also reins in spending
by consumers who have less housing
wealth against which to borrow.
5
Residential construction likely
exerted its largest negative effect in
third quarter 2006, when it subtracted
1.3 percentage points from the annual
pace of real GDP growth. Last year,
many forecasts predicted home con-
struction would stop restraining GDP
growth by the end of 2007 and the
industry would start recovering in
2008. These predictions were made
before the tightening of nonprime
credit standards began in late 2006.
The change in standards will likely
prolong the housing downturn and
delay the recovery, although it’s hard
to tell precisely for how long. Since
single-family permits have already
fallen 52 percent from their September
2005 peak, however, the worst of the
homebuilding drag may be behind us.
The same may not be true for
housing’s indirect effect on consump-
tion. Since the late 1990s, many
homeowners have borrowed against
housing wealth, using home equity
lines of credit or cash-out refinancing
or not fully rolling over capital gains
on one house into a down payment or
improvements on the next one. These
mortgage equity withdrawals gave
people access to lower cost, collateral-
ized loans, which bolstered spending
on consumer goods. By one measure,
these withdrawals were as large as
6 to 7 percent of labor and transfer
income in the early to mid-2000s.
The magnitude and timing of
these withdrawals may have changed
in hard-to-gauge ways. New research
suggests housing wealth’s impact on
consumer spending grew as recent
financial innovations expanded the
ability to tap housing equity.
6
This
is consistent with prior research on
housing’s connection to U.S. consumer
spending.
7
Aside from the interest-
rate-related refinancing surge of 2002
and 2003, mortgage equity-withdrawal
movements have become increasingly
sensitive to swings in home-price
appreciation since a 1986 law granted
a federal income tax deduction for
home equity loans (Chart 7).
Compounding the uncertain out-
look for consumption is the likely
reversal of the early 2000s’ mort-
gage credit liberalization.
8
This will
put further downward pressure on
home prices and housing wealth and
may curtail home equity loans and
cash-out refinancings. Finally, the
homebuying enabled by the easing of
credit standards in recent years may
have been at the expense of later
sales, further dampening the market
going forward.
The timing of housing wealth’s
impact on consumption may have
also changed. For example, before
the advent of equity lines and cash-
out refinancings, housing wealth
increases may have affected U.S. con-
sumption mainly by reducing home-
owners’ need to save for retirement.
Since then, such financial innovations
have enabled households to spend
their equity gains before retirement.
It’s unclear how much this may be
reversed by the 2007 retrenchment in
mortgage availability.
Looking Ahead
The rise and fall of nonprime
mortgages has taken us into largely
uncharted territory. Past behavior,
however, suggests that housing mar-
kets’ adjustment to more realistic
lending standards is likely to be pro-
longed.
9
One manifestation of the slow
downward adjustment of home prices
and construction activity is the mount-
ing level of unsold homes. The muted
outlook for home-price appreciation,
coupled with the resetting of many
nonprime interest rates, suggests fore-
closures will increase for some time.
The sharp reversal of trends in
home-price appreciation will also
dampen consumer spending growth, an
effect that may worsen if the pullback
in mortgage availability limits people’s
ability to borrow against their homes.
Although recent financial market
turmoil will likely add to the housing
slowdown, there are mitigating factors.
Chart 7
Mortgage Equity Withdrawals Increasingly Move
with Housing Inflation and Mortgage Refinancings
Percent (2-quarter moving average) Percent (year-over-year)
Housing inflation
Mortgage equity withdrawal
labor + transfer income
’07’05’03’01’99’97’95’93’91’89’87’85’83’81’79’77
–4
0
4
8
12
16
20
Interest-rate-driven
surge in cash-out and
other mortgage refinancing
{
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
NOTE: Shaded areas indicate recession.
SOURCES: Freddie Mac; Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve, flow of funds data; authors’ calculations.
EconomicLetter is published monthly
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the authors and should not be
attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge
by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX
75265-5906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone
at 214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed web site, www.dallasfed.org.
Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer
Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research
W. Michael Cox
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
Robert D. Hankins
Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision
Executive Editor
W. Michael Cox
Editor
Richard Alm
Associate Editor
Monica Reeves
Graphic Designer
Ellah Piña
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS
2200 N. PEARL ST.
DALLAS, TX 75201
First, the effect of slower home-
price gains on consumer spending is
likely to be drawn out, giving mon-
etary policy time to adjust if necessary.
Second, the Federal Reserve has
been successful in slowing core inflation
while maintaining economic growth.
This gives policymakers inflation-fight-
ing credibility, which enables them to
coax down market interest rates should
the economy need stimulus.
Third, even if the tightening of
mortgage credit standards undesirably
slows aggregate demand, monetary
policy could still, if need be, help offset
the overall effect by stimulating the
economy via lower interest rates. This
would bolster net exports and business
investment and help cushion the impact
of higher risk premiums on the costs of
financing for firms and households.
10
DiMartino is an economics writer and Duca a
vice president and senior policy advisor in the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Notes
The authors thank Jessica Renier for research
assistance.
1
See “The Subprime Slump and the Housing
Market,” by Andrew Tilton, US Economics
Analyst, Goldman Sachs, Feb. 23, 2007, pp.
4 6. Securitized mortgages account for roughly
70 to 75 percent of outstanding, first-lien U.S.
residential mortgages, according to estimates in
“Mortgage Liquidity du Jour: Underestimated No
More,” Credit Suisse, March 13, 2007, p. 28.
2
See, for example, Federal Reserve Chairman
Ben Bernanke’s remarks, “Housing, Housing
Finance, and Monetary Policy,” at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s Economic
Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyo., Aug. 31, 2007.
3
Part of the reason lenders eased credit stan-
dards was that they planned to sell, rather
than hold, the mortgages. The earlier easing of
standards may have partly owed to the potential
moral hazard entailed when nonconforming loans
are originated with the intent to fully sell them to
investors. Bernanke discusses this in his remarks
at the 2007 Jackson Hole symposium (note 2).
4
The figures are for securitized mortgages. See
“Mortgage Liquidity du Jour” (note 1).
5
“Making Sense of the U.S. Housing Slowdown,
by John Duca, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Economic Letter, November 2006.
6
See “How Large Is the Housing Wealth Effect?
A New Approach,” by Christopher D. Carroll,
Misuzu Otsuka and Jirka Slacalek, National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
no. 12746, December 2006; and “Housing,
Credit and Consumer Expenditure,” by John
Muellbauer, paper presented at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s Economic
Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyo., Aug. 31–Sept.
1, 2007. Also see “Booms and Busts in the
UK Housing Market,” by John Muellbauer and
Anthony Murphy, Economic Journal, vol. 107,
November 1997, pp. 170127; and “House
Prices, Consumption, and Monetary Policy: A
Financial Accelerator Approach,” by Kosuke Aoki,
James Proudman and Gertjan Vlieghe, Journal of
Financial Intermediation, vol. 13, October 2004,
pp. 41435.
7
“Estimates of Home Mortgage Originations,
Repayments, and Debt on One-to-Four-Family
Residences,” by Alan Greenspan and James
Kennedy, Finance and Economics Discussion
Series Working Paper no. 2005-41, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
September 2005; and “Mutual Funds and the
Evolving Long-Run Effects of Stock Wealth on
U.S. Consumption,” by John V. Duca, Journal
of Economics and Business, vol. 58, May/June
2006, pp. 20221.
8
This is a possibility to which Muellbauer (2007,
note 6) alludes.
9
See Duca (note 5).
10
For a discussion of the channels of monetary
policy, see “Aggregate Disturbances, Monetary
Policy, and the Macroeconomy: The FRB/US
Perspective,” by David Reifschneider, Robert
Tetlow and John Williams, Federal Reserve
Bulletin, January 1999, pp. 119.
Next EconomicLetter
Related Article: From Complacency to Crisis: The Rise
and Fall of Risk Taking in the Early 21st Century
... The time range of the data is from January 2005 to December 2020. This long time interval covers several well-known market events, such as the crash of 2008-2009 caused by the subprime mortgage crisis [42] and the 'meltdown' in 2020 caused by COVID-19 [43], which diversifies the market states and enables our trading agent to learn from real-world data fluctuations. Each collected stock contains nine different features ranging from the fundamental indexes like OPEN, CLOSE, LOW, HIGH to the technical indexes like BOLL and MACD. ...
Article
Full-text available
As a fundamental problem in algorithmic trading, portfolio optimization aims to maximize the cumulative return by continuously investing in various financial derivatives within a given time period. Recent years have witnessed the transformation from traditional machine learning trading algorithms to reinforcement learning algorithms due to their superior nature of sequential decision making. However, the exponential growth of the imperfect and noisy financial data that is supposedly leveraged by the deterministic strategy in reinforcement learning, makes it increasingly challenging for one to continuously obtain a profitable portfolio. Thus, in this work, we first reconstruct several deterministic and stochastic reinforcement algorithms as benchmarks. On this basis, we introduce a risk-aware reward function to balance the risk and return. Importantly, we propose a novel interpretable stochastic reinforcement learning framework which tailors a stochastic policy parameterized by Gaussian Mixtures and a distributional critic realized by quantiles for the problem of portfolio optimization. In our experiment, the proposed algorithm demonstrates its superior performance on U.S. market stocks with a 63.1% annual rate of return while at the same time reducing the market value max drawdown by 10% when back-testing during the stock market crash around March 2020.
... The economy is constantly changing, as DiMartino and Duca (2007) proved by examining how the stock market and economy in the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan, France, and Germany altered through time. Prior to that, Ibrahim (1999) examined dynamic interactions between stock prices and macroeconomic variables using bivariate and multivariate cointegration, concluding that the stock market was inefficient regarding information. ...
... Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002) examined the hypothesis that equity returns are significantly affected by the macroeconomic conditions. DiMartino and Duca (2007) interested in understanding the long-term relationship between the stock market and the economy in the US, the UK, Japan, France and Germany. To do so, they employed the Granger causality test to investigate the causality direction between GDP and the stock market. ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose Several theoretical and empirical studies have shown the significant effects of economic and environmental factors on a large number of financial indicators. In this paper the authors are going to study whether the main stock market index, is impacted by the variations of the exchange rate and the interest rates. Design/methodology/approach This paper studies the response of the index market return to fluctuations in the interest rate and the exchange rate in five countries from the MENA region (Tunisia, Morocco, Egypt, Turkey and Jordan). To investigate whether this impact exists, the authors used the non-linear autoregressive distributed lag (NARDL) model with daily data from June 1998 to June 2018. Findings The application of the non-linear ARDL model confirms the presence of cointegration between return index, interest rate and exchange rate. The results show that the asymmetry hypothesis is only valid for the short run which suggests that the market index is sensitive to the variation in the interest rate and exchange rate. This means that these macroeconomic factors play an important role in the MENA region stock markets. Originality/value The findings confirm that the index returns in the MENA region stock markets are related to macroeconomic fundamentals such as the exchange rate and the real interest rate. The reaction of some indices is sensitive to whether the shocks are positive or negative. This finding may help investors to choose their strategies starting from these changes. Accordingly, policy makers must pay attention to the development progress of stock market.
... In the absence of home-price appreciation, many households are finding it difficult to refinance their way out of adjustable-rate mortgages obtained at the height of the housing boom. Larger mortgage payments could exacerbate delinquencies and foreclosures, especially with interest rate resets expected to remain high for the next year (DiMartino & Duca, 2007). ...
Article
Full-text available
Un sistema financiero bien informado y cauteloso puede mejorar el bienestar de una economía al canalizar los excedentes de los ahorradores a los prestatarios. Sin embargo, en una situación de crisis, el menor precio de bienes hipotecables limita la capacidad de crédito de la economía, generando la posibilidad de una reducción en el crédito inclusive en un escenario de bajas tasas de interés. Este documento ilustra el punto anteriormente mencionado através de un modelo de equilibrio general en el que el uso de activos como colateral determina que tan riesgoso es el comportamiento del sistema financiero. Esta y varias otras condiciones amplifican la magnitud de un choque de productividad negativo
Article
Full-text available
Recorrendo a um trabalho de revisão bibliográfica e de análise de dados financeiros, no presente estudo abordamos a temática da globalização dos mercados financeiros e das suas causas, são analisadas as especificidades dos principais crashes bolsistas históricos: o de 1929, o de 1987, o das empresas tecnológicas e o da atual crise financeira global. De seguida, é estudada a temática do contágio ou propagação de crises entre mercados bolsistas, começando por analisar o seu conceito, para depois serem abordados os três principais canais de transmissão de crises, designadamente o comercial, o financeiro e o puro. O fenómeno da globalização financeira ajudou à aproximação dos mercados financeiros, mas igualmente à criação de condições propicias à ocorrência de situações de contágio à escala global, penalizadoras da estabilidade económico financeira global, o que abre espaço à necessidade de repensar a arquitetura do sistema financeiro internacional.
Chapter
This chapter outlines the evolution of the European integration process, giving an overview of the most important regulatory steps related to the banking and financial system culminated in the creation of the Banking Union. A focus is also given to the international financial crisis; its origins and impacts from the perspective of the European banking system and to the role played by supervision aimed at ensuring the financial stability.KeywordsEuropean UnionInternational financial crisisEuropean banking systemBanking UnionFinancial integrationBanking supervisionCapital adequacy
Chapter
The basic and common features of bubbles are revealed by historical reviews and comparisons of important episodes. Assumptions about the effectiveness of monetary policy initiatives and approaches are questioned along with the assumption that GDP growth and market returns are related.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any references for this publication.