ArticlePDF Available

Overhauling multinationals for the Anthropocene: How a rogue subsidiary offers a blueprint for sustainable development

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This research addresses the question of how multinational enterprises (MNEs) can be overhauled to reckon with the finite ecosystem services that characterize the Anthropocene epoch. A comparative mechanism-based methodology is employed to seek an answer in the class of entities that MNEs are benchmarked against the unorthodox organization of a recently dubbed Unilever’s “rogue subsidiary,” i.e., Ben & Jerry’s, which could evolve into a turning point in sustainable development if replicated on a sufficient scale. The findings are that this subsidiary has put exceptional mechanisms to work, turning around functions that typically bolster the capabilities of MNEs to cash in on natural resources and other non-equity stakeholders. In a nutshell, these mechanisms 1) reduce the cost that stakeholders bear when engaging with MNEs across the value chain; 2) put the wardens of the company mission in charge of the organizational drivers of environmental and social commitments; 3) prevent the conflict of interests inherent in making wardens accountable to shareholders; 4) appoint key MNE executives in good faith consultation with wardens; and 5) secure wardens’ recourse to the courts in the case of a breach of contract.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
Available online 13 May 2024
0921-8009/© 2024 The Authors. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-
nc-nd/4.0/).
Overhauling multinationals for the Anthropocene: How a rogue subsidiary
offers a blueprint for sustainable development
Alejandro Agafonow
a
,
*
, Marybel Perez
b
a
ESSCA School of Management, 55 quai Alphonse Le Gallo, 92513 Boulogne-Billancourt, Paris, France
b
ESSCA School of Management, 1 rue Joseph Lakanal - BP 40348, Angers 49003, France
ARTICLE INFO
Keywords:
Anthropocene
Ben & Jerrys
Climate Change
Multinational Enterprise
Rent Appropriation
Theory of the Firm
ABSTRACT
This research addresses the question of how multinational enterprises (MNEs) can be overhauled to reckon with
the nite ecosystem services that characterize the Anthropocene epoch. A comparative mechanism-based
methodology is employed to seek an answer in the class of entities that MNEs are benchmarked against the
unorthodox organization of a recently dubbed Unilevers rogue subsidiary, i.e., Ben & Jerrys, which could
evolve into a turning point in sustainable development if replicated on a sufcient scale. The ndings are that
this subsidiary has put exceptional mechanisms to work, turning around functions that typically bolster the
capabilities of MNEs to cash in on natural resources and other non-equity stakeholders. In a nutshell, these
mechanisms 1) reduce the cost that stakeholders bear when engaging with MNEs across the value chain; 2) put
the wardens of the company mission in charge of the organizational drivers of environmental and social com-
mitments; 3) prevent the conict of interests inherent in making wardens accountable to shareholders; 4) appoint
key MNE executives in good faith consultation with wardens; and 5) secure wardensrecourse to the courts in the
case of a breach of contract.
The transnational corporations are ambivalent [] Their positive
contribution to development cannot be disregarded. But their
ambivalence gives grounds for serious and lasting concern. For
everywhere, and especially in the centres, they carry a considerable
share of the responsibility for the deterioration of the environment
and the destruction of non-renewal natural resources. And where the
periphery is concerned, their immediate interests and the collective
interests are not necessarily the same. (Prebisch, 1977, p. 280).
1. Introduction
Policymakersxation with economic growth as measured by GDP
may not have been as menacing for humanity in the Holocene epoch,
before anthropogenic emissions became the driving force of climate
change. However, such a xation, which biases wealth for produced and
human capital and against natural capital (Arrow et al., 1995; Daly,
1990; Dasgupta, 2021a), may prove to be fatal in the Anthropocene
epoch, i.e., the unofcial designation of the most recent geological time
when the role of humans in the depletion of ecosystems has become
patent (Waters et al., 2016).
Because the Anthropocene has made plain that ecosystem services
are not limitless (Engel et al., 2008; Wunder, 2015) and because markets
are known for failing to put a price tag on ecosystem services to curb
their consumption accordingly (Dasgupta, 2021a; Hardin, 1968), it is
high time to enter natural capital into the equation of wealth. One
possible way to do so is to take on the feedback loops between in-
stitutions and natural capital (Dasgupta, 2008; Ostrom, 2009), over-
hauling institutions to deal with the market failures that have led to the
depletion of ecosystems.
Thus, if institutions are taken to be “…social infrastructure (e.g.,
laws, property rights, beliefs, and the extent of trust among people) for
guiding the allocation of resources, including the capital assets them-
selves (Dasgupta, 2008, p. 5), a logical candidate to overhaul is the
bundle of property rights that a multinational enterprise (MNE here-
after) is (Coase, 1937, 1988). This is because the MNE, despite being but
one legal template bundling property rights, is noteworthy for its impact
on the depletion of ecosystems owing to its geographical outreach linked
to international trade (Lenzen et al., 2012) and its distinct capability to
deprive non-equity stakeholders, Nature included, of value to be
* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: alejandro.agafonow@essca.fr (A. Agafonow), marybel.perez@essca.fr (M. Perez).
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Ecological Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2024.108232
Received 29 November 2023; Received in revised form 1 April 2024; Accepted 4 May 2024
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
2
appropriated by shareholders in the form of prots.
This view of the impact of MNEs on ecosystems contrasts with a
sanguine account that deems MNEs to be the amiable agent of sustain-
able development, which emerging evidence on the negative environ-
mental impact of the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs hereafter)
(Zeng et al., 2020) helps to further call into question. The sanguine ac-
count overlooks what the dawn of MNEs at the turn of the 20th century
meant to achieve (Chandler, 1999), which economics and organization
scholarship seized to shed light on the distinguishing attributes of these
kinds of rms leading to a rude awakening to their true role. This is in
agreement with the observations of policymakers in developing coun-
tries, as evidenced by this articles opening quotation from Raúl Pre-
bisch (1977), former executive director of the United Nations Economic
Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC).
As it will be expounded, just as MNEs have outstripped other kinds of
rms in preventing managers from indulging in self-serving behavior
and employees from shirking, they have arguably excelled at cashing in
on natural resources and other non-equity stakeholders too. This is
because MNEs divisionalized structure is the most sophisticated orga-
nizational undertaking to replicate the high-powered incentives of
markets inside the organization, enabling MNEs to haggle and bargain
more aggressively over apportioning out razor-thin rents among stake-
holders (Baumol, 1967; Brickley et al., 2016; Chandler Jr., 1999; Jensen
and Meckling, 1998; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992; Mintzberg, 1979;
Roberts, 2004; Williamson, 1981, 1985). This situation is aggravated in
the case of Nature because it is a mobile, invisible, or silentstake-
holder (Dasgupta, 2021b, p. 18) which, by denition, lacks the negoti-
ation skills and the capability of unied action commonly attributed to
human stakeholders (Barney, 2018; Coff, 1999).
This bleak picture of MNEs painted, we insist, by mainstream econ-
omists and organization scholars, does not have to be met with shrugged
shoulders. Instead, the present article takes a proactive step in
answering the question: how can MNEs be overhauled to reckon with the
nite ecosystem services that mark the Anthropocene epoch? Sustain-
able development is taken herein to be the qualitative capacity to
convert that constant level of physical resource use (throughput) into
improved services for satisfying human wants(Daly, 1990, p. 33), and
property rights are regarded as a meansperhaps a kind of social
technologyto affect resource throughput in agreement with equality
(Agafonow and Perez, 2024a).
Thus, a possible answer is sought in the subsidiary of an MNE whose
unconventional organization has for the most part dropped beneath the
radarexcept for Agafonow and Perez (2017). This is because reliable
sources of data about the instance-level parts that make up the inner
workings of rms can be difcult to come by (Coase, 1991), especially
when rms are not bound by disclosure standards.
The MNE in question is Unilever, which in 2000 added to its more
than four hundred fully owned subsidiaries the ice-cream maker Ben &
Jerrys (B&J hereafter). Despite the little academic interest aroused by
the unorthodox organization of this subsidiary, certain oddities have
topped out as the tip of an iceberg hiding exceptional mechanisms that,
if replicated by other MNEs, could become a turning point in the role
played by these kinds of rms in sustainable development.
These oddities comprise, most notably, a complaint to the London
Stock Exchange motivated by what the petitioner claimed to be a rouge
subsidiarythat evade[s] normal corporate governance practices(UK
Lawyers for Israel, 2021, p. online); a mission statement in the sub-
sidiarys articles of incorporation where equity holders are missing with
potentially far-reaching legal implications, which reads: We have a
progressive, nonpartisan, social mission that seeks to meet human needs
and eliminate injustices in our local, national and international com-
munities by integrating these concerns into our business activities. Our
focus is on children and families, and the environment(SEC, 2000, p.
92); as well as discrepant decisions about where to do business coming
from two different Unilevers ice-cream makers, i.e., whereas B&J
refused to do business in the Israeli settlements in Palestinian territory
(Kingsley, 2022), Walls has defended its decision to keep its Cornetto
ice-cream in war-ridden Russia (Thomas, 2023).
Anticipating what will be expounded in the methodology section,
this research extrapolates based on extant knowledge on the cogs a
wheels that are characteristic of MNEs as a class of entities, which a
comparative mechanism-based methodology makes possible (Craver
and Darden, 2013; Steel, 2008). It does not employ a case-study meth-
odology because: [c]ase study is not a methodological choice but a
choice of what is to be studied. By whatever methods, we choose to
study the case (Stake, 2003, p. 134), and a case alone has limited
extrapolation capabilities.
Thus, this research has found, in a nutshell, that B&J shows a plau-
sible way along which MNEs could be overhauled to reckon with the
Anthropocene consisting of:
1) The reduction of the marginal cost of engaging with one more
MNE borne by stakeholders across the value chain through the
appointment of dedicated wardens of the environmental and social
mission of a company (the wardens of the mission, for short), which B&J
achieved by appointing stakeholder representatives.
2) Dodging the conict of interests involved in making the wardens
of the mission accountable to shareholders, which B&J accomplished by
shielding wardens with a self-perpetuating status, i.e., stakeholder rep-
resentatives designate like-minded individuals to ll the vacant posi-
tions of representation.
3) Putting the wardens of the mission in charge of the organizational
drivers of the companys environmental and social commitments, as
well as granting them the capacity to prevent MNE executives from
acting on these drivers, which B&J attained by granting wardens power
over product introduction, the changing of product standards and
specications,and "the licensing or other use of the trademark" (SEC,
2000, p. 81), through which they can credibly have an impact on
stakeholders across the value chain.
4) Involving the wardens of the mission with the appointment of key
MNE executives, which B&J realized instituting that the CEO be
appointed in good faith consultation with wardens.
5) Last but not least, safeguarding all of the above by giving the
wardens of the mission recourse to the courts, which B&J implemented
with an injunction that can redress breach of contract.
Most recently, Unilever has announced that it is studying ways to
part with the portfolio of divisions where B&J is situated (Speed et al.,
2024). It is difcult to assert whether this has been motivated by the
disagreement about doing business in Israeli settlements (Kingsley,
2022). But the fact is that the drivers with the power to alter the envi-
ronmental and social commitments of B&J are off-limits to Unilever
whichas it will be expounded hereinreduces the MNEs capability to
exact value from B&Js stakeholders, making it a candidate for a
divestment that would upend a twenty-four-year-old groundbreaking
acquisition.
2. What MNEs Were Created For
Todays existential battle for intellectual property and industrial
espionage (Editorial board., 2022) speaks of a reality marked by the
adversarial nature of markets, where the appropriation of rents pivots on
the control of coveted resources. This is in stark contrast with the view of
the free private enterprise as the amiable agent of sustainable develop-
ment, popularly known as trickle-down economics, or as posited by a
champion of unregulated markets: Even the poorest today owe their
relative material well-being to the results of past inequality (Hayek,
2011, p. 98).
The weakness of this sanguine view of the role of the private enter-
prise, and MNEs in particular, in sustainable development is that, on the
one hand, it overlooks the threat that the kinds of oligarchic capitalism
(Baumol et al., 2007) or crony capitalism (Haber, 2002) in many devel-
oping countries pose to their own population, whose wellbeing is
jeopardized by institutions stacked against inclusive economies
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
3
(Agafonow and Donaldson, 2015). On the other hand, this view ignores
what MNEs were created for in the rst place, and what their role in a
real-world adversarial market economy is.
The making of MNEs is far from aiming at deepening sustainable
development, although there are positive side effects to be sure. Eco-
nomics and organization scholarship are clear about the reasons for the
replacement of functional organizational units with the divisional units
that gave rise to MNEs, namely, it is a way to offset the shift of rents
away from net prots toward self-serving subgoals which, however
disallowed by top management, were pursued by the heads of outsized
functional departments (Baumol, 1967; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992;
Roberts, 2004; Williamson, 1981, 1985).
MNEs owe their inception to the increasingly complex choices of
capital expenditures that top management faced at the turn of the 20th
century, when functionally departmentalized rms had vertically inte-
grated, growing too large whenever the nature of production allowed
standardization without giving up on quality, e.g., the production of
cigarettes as opposed to cigars where avors and aromas matched the
complexity of wines (Chandler Jr., 1999).
The appropriation of rents by equity holders, who were self-made
tycoons (Chandler Jr., 1999), lessened when capital expenditures were
not justied by their added value to the bottom line, which the top
management was unable to assess in the absence of markets inside these
kinds of rms (Williamson, 1981, 1985). Thus, the dawn of modern
MNEs hinged on methods to overcome both the difculties top man-
agement faced when judging the opportunity costs of the demands of
capital expenditures made by the heads of outsized functional de-
partments, and the cognitive overload of top managers who were
increasingly overwhelmed by the mix of strategic and operating
decision-making in these large organizations (Chandler Jr., 1999; Wil-
liamson, 1981, 1985).
The inception of MNEs hinged on the formation of divisional units,
which lies in moving production into subsidiaries that will now operate
as quasi-autonomous entities, relinquishing the kinds of administrative
coordination with top management that functional units require. The
autonomy side of the equation means that subsidiaries are entrusted with
authority over the quantity of output to be produced, the product mix (e.
g., low- vs. high-end products) to be emphasized, and marketing activ-
ities, thus competing on their own in the market (Brickley et al., 2016;
Jensen and Meckling, 1998; Mintzberg, 1979). The quasi side of the
equation means that subsidiaries fall short of the autonomy that an in-
dependent rm enjoys because prots are transferred to headquarters
which, in turn, will authorize or refuse capital expenditures based on
how protable subsidiaries are instead of poking around in the dark
without market signals, as it is the case with large functionally organized
rms (Milgrom and Roberts, 1992; Mintzberg, 1979; Williamson, 1985).
This has given way to a body of knowledge, too large to acknowledge
here, on how to make these markets internal to MNEs better emulate real
markets in the allocation of resources according to opportunity costs,
known as transfer prices. Another way paved by this research on MNEs is
how to raise the power of incentives to heighten prot making. Just as
powerful heads of outsized functional departments can erode prot
margins by self-serving decisions that claim a larger part of the rent
cake, so to speak, staff can do the same when their compensation is not
contingent on measurable tasks or outputs (Lazear, 1986). Thus, this
strand of the literature has sought to craft organizational structures
inlaid with high-powered incentives over and above divisional bound-
aries (Baker, 2000; Brown, 1990; Hoskisson et al., 2018; Lazear, 2018;
Pencavel, 2012; Zenger and Hesterly, 1997).
2.1. MNE rent appropriation: critical interfaces in the nexus of contracts
To put in a stylized digest what has just been expounded, what makes
MNEs an efcacious tool in appropriating rent hinges on two critical
interfaces linking the nodes of the board of directors up in the head-
quarters, with the subsidiaries and their internal executive authority
down the organizational hierarchy.
The rst interface of interest corresponds to β* (see Fig. 1 and
Table 1), through which the board of directors discharges its function of
rating the performance of subsidiaries, which is illustrated with the
known icon of the divisionalized organizational form proposed by Min-
tzberg (1979, 1981). One thing that should strike the reader is the row of
white inverted Ts representing subsidiaries which in todays Unilever,
for instance, are more than four hundred. To rate performance means to
evaluate after the fact, in specic quantitative terms, in the case of
business corporations by measures of prot, sales growth, and return on
investment(Mintzberg, 1979, p. 383) thus making capital expenditures
based on objective basis instead of on the clout of subsidiary executives.
The second interface corresponds to
η
* (see Fig. 1 and Table 1), via
which the board of directors discharges its function of designating
compliant subsidiary executives, illustrated with the icon of a CEOs
ofce door. This grip on subsidiary executives should not come as a
surprise for it is a standard practice in the corporate world, as well as a
trump card commonly played by public authorities in the name of na-
tional interest like, for instance, the recent power to appoint Pirellis
CEO that the Italian government has accorded a trusted minority
shareholder to countervail the higher stake held by the Chinese com-
pany Sinochem (Kazmin and Sciorilli Borrelli, 2023).
Thus, rating and designation are key functions that parsimoniously
illustrate the key parts of the mechanisms that MNEs employ to offset the
shift of rents away from net prots to enhance the capture of value by
shareholders, more about which will be said under the ndings heading.
If there is any hope to rethink MNEs for the ongoing Anthropocene
epoch, when ecological thresholds are being overstretched by human
activities (Muradian, 2001; Uehara, 2013), the strain that MNEs place
on stakeholders and their ecosystems can only be tackled by overhauling
this mechanism, which today gives shareholders the means to hold ex-
ecutives accountable as per the market value of equity (Milgrom and
Roberts, 1992; Williamson, 1993), and at the expense of the integrity of
ecosystems and the claims of non-equity stakeholders (Agafonow and
Perez, 2024a).
2.2. The trickle-down bias of International Business scholarship: A
critique
One could hardly be blamed for believing that International Business
(IB hereafter) is a eld called to seize the true role of MNEs in sustainable
development. Yet, according to recent accounts of its exponents, IB
scholarship has built a rm-centered lens that has crowded out societal
concerns (Buckley et al., 2017; Rygh, 2019; Van Assche, 2018). This
makes it particularly vulnerable to the lapses of the trickle-down
interpretation of sustainable development.
This rm-centered lens has made at least a part of IB scholarship
aloof from the environmental issues that stem from heightening prot-
making by apportioning out razor-thin rents among non-equity stake-
holders which, as mainstream economists and organization scholars
have remarked, is what MNEs are intended for. Thus, when environ-
mental and social issues have been considered, a part of the IB schol-
arship appears to have been led astray by the trickle-down bias that
overlooks the adversarial nature of markets.
By way of example, Oetzel and Doh (2009) posit that greater
collaboration between MNEs and NGOs can harness rm-specic ad-
vantages on the grounds that:
MNEs are under pressure to continuously increase shareholder return
[] As large MNEs saturate their home markets and those of the
other developed countries, developing countries are necessary for
continued growth. To succeed in these markets, however, rms must
understand how to compete, particularly in the face of institutional
and economic underdevelopment. MNE-NGO collaborations may
provide market access to geographic and demographic groups that
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
4
would otherwise be out of their reach. (Oetzel and Doh, 2009, p.
115).
It is public knowledge, however, that owing to the conguration of
MNEsbundle of property rights the balance between value capturein
the form of protsand value creationin the form of a positive
environmental impactis likely to be tilted in favor of shareholders.
This is also sidelined by Kolk and Pinkse (2008) when positing that
MNEs green rm-specic advantages can help tackle climate change,
which in hindsight is unwarranted in the light of new evidence on how
SDGs disguise environmental destruction (Zeng et al., 2020).
A cross-sectional and self-administered survey conducted by van
Zanten and van Tulder (2018), tapped executives with responsibilities
for the sustainability policies of 350 MNEs headquartered in Europe and
North America. It found that these “…MNEs have adopted an important
but fairly narrow/passive role in contributing to SDGs(van Zanten and
van Tulder, 2018, p. unpaginated). On the contrary, given the conr-
mation bias that is expected to surface when the opinions of interested
parties are tapped, these ndings speak volumes for the plausible lack of
compliance with SDGs.
A different self-administered surveythis time longitudinal and in a
single countryseems to show that environmental innovation at foreign
subsidiaries is higher when both MNEs are headquartered in countries
with strong pro-environmental institutions and the subsidiaries in
question are the product of greeneld investments (i.e., subsidiaries
created from scratch instead of acquired). Thus, to benet from envi-
ronmental innovation Konara et al. (2021) recommend that host coun-
tries channel foreign investment to greeneld subsidiaries instead of the
acquisition of domestic ones. They, however, overlook the negative
societal impact of turning capital away from indigenous subsidiaries, as
well as the mixed evidence about positive spillover effects from foreign
investments (Gorg and Greenaway, 2004).
Acknowledging that their research does not shed light on the
mechanisms of environmental innovation, Konara et al. (2021) submit
that: [f]uture research could examine these mechanisms at a more
micro level, probably through a qualitative approach or a questionnaire
survey(p. 12). The mechanisms of MNEs are at the very heart of the
present article and, as will be expounded next, researching mechanisms
is indeed a qualitative endeavor, except that it goes beyond what
questionnaires can achieve.
IBs reliance on rm heterogeneity to conjecture differences in rm
performance (Van Assche, 2018) has brought one rm too many for the
proper treatment of mechanisms. This is because studying the
Fig. 1. The mechanism of the archetypical multinational enterprise: 1) Shareholders >
α
* >board of directors; 2) Board of directors >β* >subsidiaries; 3) Board of
directors >
η
* >CEOs of subsidiaries; 4) CEOs of subsidiaries >κ* >subsidiariesnancial performance; 5) Shareholders >λ* >stock exchange; 6) Shareholders >
μ
* >law court; 7) Rule or legal doctrine >
ν
* >law court; 8) Law court >ξ* >duciary duty; 9) Fiduciary duty >ο* >board of directors (Adapted from Agafonow
and Perez, 2024a and based on Brickley et al., 2016; Chandler, 1999; Easterbrook and Fischel, 1996; Jensen and Meckling, 1998; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992;
Mintzberg, 1979; Roberts, 2004; Schanzenbach and Sitkoff, 2020; Williamson, 1981, 1985 and Creative Commons icons. By Alena, Alessandro Suraci, Alzam,
barurezeki, Adrien Coquet, Gregor Cresnar, DC Icons, Eliricon, b farias, Endang rmansyah, Hironicons, Gan Khoon Lay, Magicon, Murat Mustafa, RROOK, Sri,
Creative, Stall, Amethyst Studio, and Viktorijareut, licensed under CC-BY-3.0.).
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
5
microanalytic features of rms involves a breadth (more observations)
for depth (greater detail) tradeoff (Williamson, 1985, p. 105). Thus,
IBs reliance on large micro-datasets in place of instance-level parts
pieced together in the workable whole that an MNC is, has exposed it to
the limits of the statistical t between prediction and response variables.
These limits stem from the many functions that can account for the
relationship between variables, saying nothing about real mechanisms
at work, or as posited by Murphy (1978): using some function for no
better reason than that it gives an optimal t, may tell us nothing at all
scientically [] It is obvious, then, that in practice, excellence of t of
some function does not guarantee insight(p. 08).
More colorful but also telling is the argument of Ioannidis (2003),
who reminds us that recording 100 astrological parameters for 1000
subjects with diabetes mellitus and 1000 control-group subjects (i.e.,
without diabetes), ve astrological parameters will be found to be
signicantly correlated with diabetes. Needless to say, no self-respecting
physician would credit diabetes to the inuence of astrology, despite
such parameters being able to account for heterogeneity and the cor-
relation being signicant.
Instead, studying the inner workings of MNEs entails something that
the exponents of IB have just begun to recognize, namely, that there are
several levels of analysis involved and that inner workings are located at
the level of the rm (Andersson et al., 2014; Buckley et al., 2017). Still,
this is something that the goodness of t of a statistical model has limits
to cope with (Ioannidis, 2003; Murphy, 1978) and which the exponents
of IB have not acknowledged yet. Only when this is brought home it is
possible to leverage thick nomological descriptions to spell out the
details of how things work (Cartwright, 2004, p. 815), which is at the
heart of the comparative mechanism-based methodology employed
herein.
It will take, however, a paradigm shift in IB scholarship to move in
the right direction which, notwithstanding the intention of fostering
research with societal impact (Doh et al., 2023), is likely to be slowed
down by the view of academic publishing as a means to boost the
monetary reward of IB academics (e.g., Li et al., 2023). Because the
wrong incentives make the whitewashing of research take precedence
over genuine knowledge breakthroughs (Agafonow and Perez, 2023a,
2024b), it is reasonable to expect IB journals positioned in the highest
tiers of rankings to be ooded with counterfeit social-impact research.
We will thus be forgiven for being skeptical about the renaissanceof IB
scholarship (cf. Buckley et al., 2017).
3. Comparative mechanism-based methodology
That short-term value maximization destroys value has acquired the
status of an axiom, yet it is lacking in how-tos. This is because the
changes in the inner workings of rms that would arguably lead them
away from short-term value maximization have rarely been ascertained
in terms of mechanisms, which otherwise could harness the design un-
dertaking that overhauling MNEs for the Anthropocene demands.
Thus, employing a benchmark-comparison method (Hsiung and
Gunning, 2002) this research builds on contrastive explanation (Lipton,
2004) to set off by contrast what the differences between the mecha-
nisms of a point of reference, i.e., an archetypical MNE, and its foil, i.e.,
Unilevers B&J, are. It is thus possible to weigh the implications of the
differences between B&J and the archetypical MNE on how rents are
apportioned out among stakeholders, including Nature.
Benchmarking Unilevers B&J against an archetypical MNE would
be insufcient for a design undertaking without a mechanism-based
system, which lays down how the inner workings in question are
congured. Thus, starting from the denition of mechanisms as “…en-
tities and activities organized to produce a phenomenon(Darden et al.,
2018, p. 2), this research sets forth how entities display functions to
discharge powers or capacities that bring about changes in other entities
(Chibucos et al., 2014; Smith et al., 2005; Steel, 2008).
Mechanisms are in a stronger position to make extrapolations than
the correlation of cross-sectional data, which is arguably the dominant
methodology in empirical social sciences. While the latter aims to
extrapolate based on reducing sampling errors to increase the proba-
bility that a phenomenon is recurrent in large samples (Altman and
Krzywinski, 2017; Babbie, 2021), mechanisms extrapolate based on the
cogs a wheels that have been determined to be characteristic of entire
classes of entities (Craver and Darden, 2013; Steel, 2008)like the
MNEs studied herein. Thus, mechanisms are on rmer grounds to
generalize ndings for they can sort the causal from the random,
whereas purely random patterns that exhibit statistical correlations at
signicant levels are obstacles for extrapolating with correlations
(Popper, 1971; Schick Jr. and Vaughn, 2014).
Mechanisms would be of little help, however, should a common
framework to deal with the units of observation be absent (Ostrom,
2009). Such a framework is thus mobilized through two complementary
steps. On the one hand, the units of observation employed in this
research count on a high degree of reliability by coming from lawful
agreements and stock exchange lings, whose breach opens the door to
costly litigation. This counteracts the adaptive goal-oriented behavior of
agents (Simon, 1996) turning the words therein into deeds, which lends
data a higher degree of reliability compared to subjective eld research
where it is difcult to tell reliable data apart from impressionistic data
(Blaikie, 2010), and where the events observed may be lost in a distant
past without the possibility to revisit them in the hope of replication.
On the other hand, the Basic Formal Ontology described in Arp et al.
(2015)which also counts on the ISO/IEC 218381 standardis
employed to classify the units of observation. Data coding is thus man-
ifest, instead of latent (Babbie, 2021), laying bare the instance-level parts
Table 1
Description of the causal parts of the nexus of contracts of the archetypical MNE.
(Authorsown based on Brickley et al., 2016; Chandler Jr., 1999; Easterbrook
and Fischel, 1996; Jensen and Meckling, 1998; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992;
Mintzberg, 1979; Roberts, 2004; Schanzenbach and Sitkoff, 2020; Williamson,
1981, 1985)
Link Pair of nodes Causal-role
Function
Comments
α
*
(Alpha)
Shareholders and
board of directors
Vote Shareholders hold in check
the board of directors of the
MNE through voting
β*
(Beta)
Board of directors
and subsidiaries
Rate The board of directors rate
the performance of the
MNEs subsidiaries through
protability measures
η
*
(Theta)
Board of directors
and the CEOs of
subsidiaries
Designate The board of directors
designates the CEOs of
subsidiaries
κ*
(Lambda)
CEOs and
subsidiaries
nancial
performance
Oversee CEOs oversee the nancial
performance of subsidiaries
λ*
(Nu)
Shareholders and
stock exchange
Exit Stock exchanges offer a
low-cost exit option for
shareholders
μ
*
(Xi)
Shareholders and
law court
Appeal Shareholders have legal
standing to appeal to a law
court to redress the breach
of duciary duty
ν
*
(Omicron)
Rule or legal
doctrine and law
court
Guide The adjudication by law
courts is guided by the best
interest legal doctrine
ξ*
(Rho)
Law court and
duciary duty
Adjudicate In the event of a lawsuit, the
law court adjudicates on
the conict based on the
duciary duty owed to
shareholders
ο*
(Sigma)
Fiduciary duty and
board of directors
Deterrence The decision-making of the
board of directors is
constrained by deterrence
inherent to penalties for the
breach of duciary duty
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
6
or individual denizens of reality (Arp et al., 2015) which, for illustration
purposes, are gathered in the Porphyrian Tree of Fig. 2 and Tables 1 and
2.
This formal ontology is a stepping stone to building a much-needed
common framework (Ostrom, 2009) because it paves the way for the
interoperability of data across studies (Arp et al., 2015), as it has been
successfully shown in biomedicine (Arp et al., 2015; Smith, 2008), as
well as making plain the building blocks of the mechanisms expounded
herein. It only remains to bring the instance-level parts of this Por-
phyrian Tree together in an intelligible schema, showing how entities
react as a result of the capacities discharged through relevant functions,
which is the object of what remains of this article.
4. Findings
The London Stock Exchange received in 2021 a complaint that reads:
“…it appears that Unilever has a rouge division in the United States
known as Ben & Jerrys Homemade (‘Ben & Jerrys) which has been
structured so as to evade normal corporate governance practices (UK
Lawyers for Israel, 2021, p. online). The complaint sought to downgrade
Unilevers premium listing, pointing out that the relationship between
Unilever and B&J is dysfunctional because:
[] what is taking place is a failure of corporate governance which is
inherent in the structure of Unilever. As noted above, it appears that
Unilever has delegated important high risk decisions to an unelected
board which is accountable to nobody. (UK Lawyers for Israel, 2021,
p. online).
In effect, and as posited by Coff (1999): Shareholdersbargaining
power is only as strong as their ability to monitor or provide incenti-
vesin other words governance structures (p. 126). Thus, for share-
holders to successfully claim as much net prots as possible, suitable
organizational arrangements must be in place. Key functions to see to it
that only enough rent is apportioned out among stakeholdersso that,
as seen earlier, subsidiary executives do not indulge in self-serving
behavior and employees do not shirkare rating and designation illus-
trated with the interfaces β* and
η
* respectively (see Fig. 1 and Table 1).
Unilevers structure falters precisely in these key functions with ripple
effects across the nexus of contracts that favor non-equity stakeholders.
To mention a few of these effects, some of which were ahead of their
time, B&Js non-equity stakeholders are upheld when: A) a substantial
part of the incentive-based compensation of board members is calcu-
lated taking into consideration social performance (SEC, 2000); B) full-
and part-time employees in the companys manufacturing plants and
scoop shops are paid an annually adjustable livable wage (Agafonow
and Perez, 2017; Ben and Jerrys Homemade Inc, 2015); C) the company
strikes long term agreements with family farms to employ best practices
in the production of organic dairy (Agafonow and Perez, 2017; Ben and
Jerrys Homemade Inc, 2015); D) it sources key ingredients from fair-
trade producers and invests in helping these producers increase pro-
duction capacity (Agafonow and Perez, 2017; Ben and Jerrys Home-
made Inc, 2015); E) it partners with non-prots to help people that face
employment barriers acquire skills (Agafonow and Perez, 2017; Ben and
Jerrys Homemade Inc, 2015); F) it commits 7.5% of the companys
annual pre-tax prots to be spent in community projects and to support
progressive public campaigns, like opposing the administration of Re-
combinant Bovine Growth Hormone to dairy cows, promoting childrens
basic needs in the US national agenda (Ben and Jerrys Homemade Inc.,
n.d.); G) as well as withdrawing the sales of ice-creams in support of
human rights (Kingsley, 2022).
Importantly, these are not simply the product of the goodwill of
managers, whose behavior, however commendable, may fall prey to the
agency and adaptive goal-oriented behavior motivated by pressing cir-
cumstances (Agafonow and Perez, 2023b, 2024a; Simon, 1996). On the
contrary, they are the product of a nexus of contracts whose nodes hold
by-relations that make the goal of apportioning out rent among non-
equity stakeholders operational ex ante (March and Simon, 1993),
which was engineered during the negotiations that paved the way to the
acquisition of B&J by Unilever (SEC, 2000).
It is the unconventional ex-ante conguration of this nexus of con-
tractshinted at in the complaint to the London Stock Exchange-
which arguably prevents Unilever from turning the screw on B&J to the
point where its non-equity stakeholders would get just enough rent to
keep them in place or prevent them from leaving (Coff, 1999; Peteraf,
1993) thus amassing substantial rent surplus to be appropriated by
shareholders, as it is only to be expected in the archetypical MNE.
Fig. 2. Porphyrian Tree of Ben & Jerrys and the archetypical MNE in keeping with a Basic Formal Ontology (Authors own based on Arp et al., 2015 and Creative
Commons icons. By Alena, Alessandro Suraci, Alzam, barurezeki, Adrien Coquet, Gregor Cresnar, DC Icons, Eliricon, b farias, Endang rmansyah, Didzis Gruznovs,
Dan Hetteix, Hironicons, David Khai, Gan Khoon Lay, Tommy Lau, Magicon, Murat Mustafa, RROOK, Fery Saputra, Sri, Creative, Stall, Amethyst Studio, Marc
Torrada, Numeralia Vita Zein, and Viktorijareut, licensed under CC-BY-3.0.).
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
7
4.1. The mechanism of Ben & Jerrys
Unlike the appointment of the archetypical subsidiarys CEO, B&Js
CEO is not unilaterally designated by the corporate board of Unilever,
which is tributary to the large shareholder base that holds Unilever
accountable through majority vote via the link
α
(see Fig. 3 and Table 2).
On the contrary, B&Js CEO is designated via the link
ι
(see Fig. 3 and
Table 2) by an appointment committee consisting of the Class U direc-
torwhich is the representative of Unileveras well as two Class I
directorswhich are part of the wardens of the companys environ-
mental and social missionwith whom Unilever is expected to consult
in good faith (SEC, 2000, p. 81).
Interestingly enough, Class I directors were initially seven members
from among B&Js earlier boardreferred to as the surviving corporation
board, including the very founders of the company Ben Cohen and Jerry
Greeneldwhose appointment falls outside Unilevers remit as illus-
trated in the link γ where the function of designation is circle-backslash.
As expressed in the merger agreement:
Directors shall be elected for one year terms (subject to earlier
removal, death or resignation), and a majority of directors then in
ofce in each Class shall designate the candidates for election to the
Company Board in such Class each year, and Conopco shall cause the
election of such candidates [] Vacancies on the Company Board
shall be lled in a like manner. Conopco, as sole shareholder of the
Surviving Corporation, shall remove any director of any Class at the
written request of at least a majority of the directors of such Class
then in ofce and shall not otherwise remove any member of the
Company Board after the Effective Time, other than a Class U Di-
rector or the CEO following termination of his or her employment.
(SEC, 2000, p. 39).
It is noteworthy that Class I directors are, as expressed in the
complaint to the London Stock Exchange, unelectedand accountable
to nobody(UK Lawyers for Israel, 2021, p. online). These kinds of di-
rectors are called self-perpetuating and they are typical of non-prot or-
ganizations (Hansmann, 2000), where there are no shareholders
because residual rent surplus is not meant to be distributed as dividends
but to be reinvested into the organization for the sake of beneciaries,
perhaps better summed up by the notion of value devolution (Agafonow,
2015; Agafonow and Donaldson, 2015).
As Unilevers fully owned subsidiary, however, B&J is meant to
transfer prots up to headquarters, only that such prots are a discounted
surplus after rent has been apportioned out over and above what it would
take to keep non-equity stakeholders in place (Coff, 1999; Peteraf,
1993). This is because key drivers with the power to alter the environ-
mental and social commitments of B&J are off-limits to Unilever,
allowing Class I directors to keep in check how the business is conducted
via the link
ε
(see Fig. 3 and Table 2), thus having the capacity to prevent
the CEO from acting in several areas. More specically, and as expressed
Table 2
Description of the causal parts of the nexus of contracts of Unilevers Ben &
Jerrys.
(Authors own based on Agafonow and Perez, 2017; Brickley et al., 2016;
Chandler Jr., 1999; Easterbrook and Fischel, 1996; Jensen and Meckling, 1998;
Milgrom and Roberts, 1992; Mintzberg, 1979; Roberts, 2004; Schanzenbach and
Sitkoff, 2020; SEC, 2000; Williamson, 1981, 1985)
Link Pair of nodes Causal-role
Function
Comments
α
(Alpha)
Unilevers shareholders
and board of directors
Vote Unilevers shareholders
hold in check the board
of directors through
voting
β
(Beta)
Unilevers board of
directors and
subsidiaries
Rate Unilevers board of
directors rate the
performance of the
MNEs subsidiaries
through protability
measures
γ
(Gamma)
Unilevers board of
directors and B&Js
Class I directors
Does not
designate
Unilevers board of
directors does not
designate B&Js Class I
directors
δ
(Delta)
Self-perpetuation and
B&Js Class I directors
Designate B&Js Class I directors
designate themselves in
a self-perpetuating
fashion
ε
(Epsilon)
B&Js Class I directors
and the companys
environmental and
social performance
Oversee The Class I directors of
B&J oversee the
environmental and
social performance of
the company
ζ
(Zeta)
B&Js Class I directors
and appointment
committee
Partake B&Js Class I directors
partake in the
appointment committee
charged with appointing
B&Js CEO
η
(Eta)
Unilevers board of
directors and B&Js
Class U director
Designate Unilevers board of
directors designates
B&Js Class U director
θ
(Theta)
B&Js Class U director
and appointment
committee
Partake B&Js Class U director
partakes in the
appointment committee
charged with appointing
B&Js CEO
ι
(Iota)
Appointment
committee and B&Js
CEO
Designate B&Js appointment
committee, composed of
Class U and Class I
directors, appoints
B&Js CEO
κ
(Kappa)
B&Js CEO and the
companys nancial
performance
Oversee The CEO of B&J
oversees the nancial
performance of the
company
λ
(Lambda)
Unilevers shareholders
and stock exchange
Exit Stock exchanges offer a
low-cost exit option for
Unilevers shareholders
μ
(Mu)
Unilevers shareholders
and law court
Appeal Unilevers shareholders
have legal standing to
appeal to a law court to
redress the breach of
duciary duty
ν
(Nu)
Rule or legal doctrine
and law court
Guide The adjudication by law
courts is guided by the
best interest legal
doctrine
ξ
(Xi)
Law court and duciary
duty
Adjudicate In the event of a lawsuit,
the law court
adjudicates on the
conict based on the
duciary duty owed to
Unilevers shareholders
(subject to the merger
agreement in force)
ο
(Omicron)
Fiduciary duty and
Unilevers board of
directors
Deterrence The decision-making of
Unilevers board of
directors is constrained
Table 2 (continued )
Link Pair of nodes Causal-role
Function
Comments
by deterrence inherent
to penalties for the
breach of duciary duty
π
(pi)
Injunction and law
court
Guide An injunction guides the
adjudication by law
courts subject to the
merger agreement in
force
ρ
(Rho)
B&Js Class I directors
and injunction
Appeal B&Js Class I directors
have recourse to an
injunction meant to
force Unilever to comply
with the merger
agreement in force
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
8
in the merger agreement:
The Company Board shall be the custodians of the Ben & Jerrys
brand image and shall have primary responsibility for safeguarding
the integrity of the essential elements of the Ben & Jerrys brand-
name (the ESSENTIAL INTEGRITY OF THE BRAND). The Com-
pany Board shall work together with the CEO to provide that the
business of the Surviving Corporation is conducted in a manner that
preserves and enhances the Essential Integrity of the Brand. As part
of this responsibility, the Company Board may prevent any action by
the CEO in the areas of new product introduction, the changing of
product standards and specications, the approval of the content of
marketing materials and the licensing or other use of the Ben &
Jerrys trademark that, in each case, a majority of the Company
Board reasonably determines to be inconsistent with the Essential
Integrity of the Brand. (SEC, 2000, p. 81).
Note that Class I directors hold sway over B&Js commitments via the
root cause of such commitments, notably product introductionand
the changing of product standards and specications,thanks to which
the company can credibly claim to link prosperity for all its stakeholders
from seed to freezer(Ben and Jerrys Homemade Inc, 2018, p. Online).
For instance, they were able to challenge the decision of former CEO
Walt Freese to debase B&Js iconic ice-cream Cherry Garcia adding new
kinds of cherries into it that were smaller and tasted like rubber
(Edmondson, 2014, p. 203). This is far from being a trivial decision for it
is by altering product standards and specications, e.g., removing
organic milk or fair-trade nuts and berries from the ice-cream mix, that
the company could relinquish its environmental and social impact across
the value chain. Likewise, the inuence of Class I directors on the
licensing or other use of the trademark,has allowed them to stand for
human rights by refusing to license the commercialization of its ice-
creams in certain regions (Kingsley, 2022).
Thus, to prevent Unilever from interfering with Class I directors
sway over the companys environmental and social commitments, the
mechanism under consideration has been reinforced with an injunction,
i.e., recourse to a judicial order meant to force Unilever to comply with
Fig. 3. The mechanism of Unilevers Ben & Jerrys: 1) Unilevers shareholders >
α
>Unilevers board of directors; 2) Unilevers board of directors >β >sub-
sidiaries; 3) Unilevers board of directors >γ >B&Js Class I directors; 4) Self-perpetuation >δ >B&Js Class I directors; 5) B&Js Class I directors >
ε
>envi-
ronmental and social performance; 6) B&Js Class I directors >ζ >appointment committee; 7) Unilevers board of directors >
η
>B&Js Class U director; 8) B&Js
Class U director >θ >appointment committee; 9) Appointment committee >
ι
>B&Js CEO; 10) B&Js CEO >κ >nancial performance; 11) Unilevers share-
holders >λ >stock exchange; 12) Unilevers shareholders >
μ
>law court; 13) Rule or legal doctrine >
ν
>law court; 14) Law court >ξ >duciary duty; 15)
Fiduciary duty >ο >Unilevers board of directors; 16) Injunction >
π
>law court; 17) B&Js Class I directors >
ρ
>injunction (Authorsown based on Agafonow
and Perez, 2017; Brickley et al., 2016; Chandler, 1999; Easterbrook and Fischel, 1996; Jensen and Meckling, 1998; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992; Mintzberg, 1979;
Roberts, 2004; Schanzenbach and Sitkoff, 2020; SEC, 2000; Williamson, 1981, 1985 and Creative Commons icons. By Alena, Alessandro Suraci, Alzam, barurezeki,
Adrien Coquet, Gregor Cresnar, DC Icons, Eliricon, b farias, Endang rmansyah, Didzis Gruznovs, Dan Hetteix, Hironicons, David Khai, Gan Khoon Lay, Tommy Lau,
Magicon, Murat Mustafa, RROOK, Fery Saputra, Sri, Creative, Stall, Amethyst Studio, Marc Torrada, Numeralia Vita Zein, and Viktorijareut, licensed under CC-
BY-3.0.).
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
9
the terms of the agreement, illustrated in Fig. 3 with an umbrella. Acting
via the links
ρ
and
π
, Class I directors can request court adjudication to
force Unilever to comply with the mechanism explained heretofore.
Without this injunction, Unilever could plausibly break with the terms of
the merger agreement to get back to business as usual in the manage-
ment of B&J. This is because the best interest doctrinewhich in the case
of the US where B&J is incorporated guides court adjudication via the
links
ν
and ξ—gives priority to shareholders when there are conicts of
interest (Schanzenbach and Sitkoff, 2020), which is illustrated with a
shackle representing the duciary duty that ties the board of directors in
with shareholders subject to the so-called business judgment rule
(Easterbrook and Fischel, 1996).
The injunction was put to a test rst in the 2000s when, under the
leadership of CEOs Yves Couette and Walt Freese, Unilever tried to back
down from B&Js commitments and interfered with the job of Class I
directors (Agafonow and Perez, 2017), as well as in 2021 when the
company announced that the licensing agreement with an Israeli com-
pany would be stopped in support of human rights in the Israeli settle-
ments in Palestinian territory (Kingsley, 2022). This latter chapter
opened a conict with Unilever headquarters that despite its bitter-
nesswith retaliations from Israeli interest groups, divesting actions
from US public pension funds, and activism by Unilever minority in-
vestors (Evans, 2022b)has settled for the middle ground of selling the
Israeli business to its licensee who will now use a different branding for
its ice-creams (Kingsley, 2022).
5. Discussion: Overhauling MNEs for the Anthropocene
Overhauling MNEs for the Anthropocene entails diminishing these
rms capabilities to capture the rents that non-equity stakeholders
would receive if a short-term, prot-maximizing strategy were aban-
doned. Key to it is the control of the organizational drivers of the
companys environmental and social commitments, on account of which
MNEs successfully prevent the displacement of a prot-maximizing goal
(Mintzberg, 1983) which is instrumental in serving shareholders.
The green dashed ovals in Fig. 4 seek to highlight what makes B&J
distinct from an archetypical MNE, setting off by contrast (Hsiung and
Gunning, 2002) what the mechanisms to apportion out rents among
stakeholders consist of, either genuinely fostering an environmental and
social mission like in B&J, or expropriating value from non-equity
stakeholders like in a MNE. Thus, subsidiaries in the archetypical MNE
are organized to put key internal organizational drivers off limits for
non-equity stakeholders, instead placing these drivers under the tight
control of the nexus node of subsidiary executives or, for illustration
purposes, a CEOs ofce door inside the green dashed oval on the right
side of Fig. 4.
Putting non-equity stakeholders behind the wheel, so to speak, is
confronted, however, with the challenge that stakeholders across the
value chain are contingent or tangential (Rounds & Rounds, 2020), i.e.,
there are too many different beneciaries. Therefore, the non-equity
stakes held by these many beneciaries are dispersed enough to make
the marginal cost of engaging with one more MNE, i.e., to press it to
uphold environmental and social commitments, high enough to invite
inaction. It is thus possible to concentrate such stakes by appointing
Fig. 4. The mechanisms of Unilevers Ben & Jerrys and the archetypical multinational enterprise compared (Authorsown based on Agafonow and Perez, 2017;
Brickley et al., 2016; Chandler, 1999; Easterbrook and Fischel, 1996; Jensen and Meckling, 1998; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992; Mintzberg, 1979; Roberts, 2004;
Schanzenbach and Sitkoff, 2020; SEC, 2000; Williamson, 1981, 1985 and Creative Commons icons. By Alena, Alessandro Suraci, Alzam, barurezeki, Adrien Coquet,
Gregor Cresnar, DC Icons, Eliricon, b farias, Endang rmansyah, Didzis Gruznovs, Dan Hetteix, Hironicons, David Khai, Gan Khoon Lay, Tommy Lau, Magicon, Murat
Mustafa, RROOK, Fery Saputra, Sri, Creative, Stall, Amethyst Studio, Marc Torrada, Numeralia Vita Zein, and Viktorijareut, licensed under CC-BY-3.0.).
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
10
dedicated wardens of a company mission, which in B&J are the so-called
Class I directors as set off by the large green dashed oval on the left side
of Fig. 4.
The wardens of the mission risk, however, being mere window
dressing to woo customers or avoid scrutiny. For instance, in the wake of
the Black Lives Matter movement in the US, rms rushed to create
management positions responsible for diversity, equity, and inclusion
(DEI) matters. These DEI ofcers have been downsized since they
reached a maximum in 2021 while experiencing a high turnover with
only 1.8 years of service on average (Rogers and Temple-West, 2023).
This brings to the fore that the credibility of environmental and social
commitments lessens when they depend on the will of executives caught
in the grip of shareholder-centric governance (Agafonow and Perez,
2023b, 2024a).
The crux of the matter is that, to strengthen the credibility of envi-
ronmental and social commitments the wardens of the mission cannot be
accountable to shareholders despite not being accountable to contingent
or tangential non-equity stakeholders either (Rounds & Rounds, 2020).
There are thus two known ways out of this predicament: 1) either the so-
called replacement mechanism which allows a settlor to designate trust-
worthy successors to keep checking on duciaries, normally used in
Charitable and Purpose Trusts (Rounds Jr. and Rounds, 2020; Sitkoff,
2004), or self-perpetuating board membership where board members
designate like-minded individuals to ll vacant positions, commonly
found in nonprots (Hansmann, 2000). While the former has recently
been employed in the outdoor clothing company Patagonia, Inc. (Aga-
fonow and Perez, 2024a), the latter characterizes B&J, which is illus-
trated with the link γ in the elongated and right-leaning green dashed
oval on the left side of Fig. 4, where the designation of Class I directors is
off limits to Unilever.
Notwithstanding the reduction of the marginal cost of pressing one
more MNE fullled by dedicated wardens of the mission, they would
have difculties displacing the prot-maximizing goal that lies at the
root of the expropriation of rent from stakeholders unless they are in
control of the organizational drivers of environmental and social com-
mitments. For instance, benet corporations that in most US jurisdic-
tions are meant to combine prot with social or environmental goals,
designate one director who on paper oversees the latter goals (MacLeod
Heminway, 2017). Yet this director is given neither precedence over nor
has authority to prevent other executives from meddling with the drivers
of these goals, making her role ineffectual in practice (Agafonow and
Perez, 2017).
There are two known ways for the wardens of the mission to exert
such control: 1) either the so-called fractionation of trusteeship which
seeks to counteract the inuence of a single, powerful duciary in the
management of assets by means of splitting this role, so that the du-
ciarys actions are overseen by a co-trustee (Langbein, 1996; Sitkoff,
2004), or 2) neutralizing the inuence of the agents of rival interests
like, for instance, dedicated directors appointed by minority share-
holders so that these agents have an upper hand in the control of specic
areas under their authority. The former has recently been implemented
in Patagonia, Inc. (Agafonow and Perez, 2024a), and the latter is found
in B&J whose Class I directors can block the actions of the CEO in spe-
cic areas as discussed earlier. This is illustrated with two separate
chains of links running in parallel to each other within the large green
dashed oval on the left side of Fig. 4.
In keeping with the archetypical MNE, the CEOs in charge of sub-
sidiaries are designated by the board of directors, or a dedicated com-
mittee within it, back in the headquarters (illustrated with the link
η
* on
the right side of Fig. 4). In contrast, the CEO of B&J is designated by an
appointment committee whose steering is shared between the repre-
sentatives of both Unilever and non-equity stakeholders, as described
earlier and illustrated with the link
ι
inside the large green dashed oval
on the left side of Fig. 4.
Lastly, non-equity stakeholders hardly count on standing to launch
legal proceedings against the decisions of MNE executives, if anything
because under the best interest doctrine (Schanzenbach and Sitkoff,
2020)see the link
ν
* on the right side of Fig. 4the business judgment
rule keeps the cost of endless judicial reviews under control by assuming
that executives manage MNE in good faith unless conicts of interest
exist (Easterbrook and Fischel, 1996). This rule has carried over into
benet corporations in the US, where the non-equity stakeholders that
benet from the social or environmental mission of these companies
paradoxically lack legal standing to sue executives for breach of purpose
(MacLeod Heminway, 2017). B&J has solved this problem granting the
wardens of the mission recourse to an injunction which, if invoked,
would seek the intervention of courts to redress a breach of the merger
agreement (SEC, 2000), where all of the above mechanisms have been
agreed upon. This is illustrated with the links
ρ
and
π
inside the elon-
gated and left-leaning green dashed oval on the left side of Fig. 4.
5.1. Environmental governance in Institutional Ecological Economics
That B&J has escaped the attention of the contenders for the expla-
nation of value creation attests to how primitive the theory of the rms
is, at least in certain scholarly traditions. For instance, whereas main-
stream economists acknowledge that they have construed the rm as a
ction that intendedly deviates from its real-world namesake (Dem-
setz, 1983, p. 377), conventional stakeholder theorists admit that the
boundaries of the rm remain fuzzy in their scholarship where there is
no ‘insidethat distinguishes the rm from the market (Phillips et al.,
2019, p. 3).
Progress toward a more realistic account of the rm started, how-
ever, long ago with Coase (1937, p. 388), who bought into the rm as a
space for the wielding of conscious power,paving the way for a richer
understanding of the market economy where in-house production serves
to reduce the cost of transactions up to the point where inputs can be
secured more cheaply by outsourcing their production to the market.
The view of Coase (1937), however, simplies the market economy
to a dichotomy between market and hierarchy (i.e., bureaucracy). It was
not until decades later that further types were added to these two
discrete structures, including international institutions (Dietz et al.,
2003; Stern, 2011), hybrids (Hennart, 1993; M´
enard, 1996; Williamson,
1985, 1991), self-organized local communities (Ostrom, 1990), non-
prot organizations (Valentinov, 2008, 2012), public bureaus (Wil-
liamson, 1999), and clans (Ouchi, 1980; Ouchi and Price, 1978).
Except for Ostrom (1990) and the literature she has inspired on the
governance of common pool resources (CPR), we agree with Paavola
and Adger (2005) that the environment has not featured prominently in
this scholarship. The last two decades have witnessed, however, a
gradual awakening of scholars that have seen in this scholarship the
bases for the design of new governance structures that could plausibly
serve environmental or social goals (e.g., Agafonow, 2020; Agafonow
and Perez, 2023b, 2024a; Bradley, 2021; Ferguson-Cradler, 2024;
Greenwood and Holt, 2008; Gui et al., 2017; Mauerhofer, 2019b,
Mauerhofer, 2019a; M´
enard, 2011; Nygaard, 2022; Paavola and Adger,
2005; Polski, 2005; Pr´
evost and Rivaud, 2018; Rametsteiner, 2002;
Roggero, 2015; Schlüter, 2007; Slavíkov´
a et al., 2010; S¨
oderbaum,
1992; Solomon, 1999; Stern, 2011; Thees and Olschewski, 2017; Val-
entinov, 2008, 2012, 2013; van der Burg, 2000; van Griethuysen, 2012).
Unfortunately, the empirical study of novel structures remains wanting
because, with a few exceptions, this scholarship has been diverted by the
exegesis of economic thought.
Even so, a few general governance structures have been proposed
making possible a preliminary comparison with the overhauled MNE
that B&J kindles. These structures are positioned along the dashed en-
velope curve of Fig. 5, meaning that every point of the envelope rep-
resents transactions made possible by the corresponding governance
structure housing them. Therefore, transactions are sorted into different
structures that, however costly they may be, are the most cost-effective
mechanisms to safeguard the viability of these transactions. For
instance, should the transactions that the orange-dashed section of the
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
11
envelope houses be governed by the market, the latter would incur
substantially higher governance costs as the solid section of the red
curve illustrates, leading to the failure of these transactions. The market
is thus far from being an all-purpose structure for the governance of real-
world economies.
Thus, franchises and joint ventures are but two exemplars of hybrids,
which are network structures positioned between markets and hierar-
chies. M´
enard (2011) has suggested that Ostrom (1990), self-organized
local communities could be construed as other kinds of hybrids that
internalize the sustainable exploitation of CPRs. Similarly, Nygaard
(2022) proposes that a circular economy hinges on organizations acting
as networks that reach out beyond their bureaucratic boundaries to
pursue low-carbon objectives across the supply chain preventing eco-
opportunism.
These kinds of hybrids can be illustrated by the orange cost curve of
Fig. 5, which means that they take on environmental objectives whose
achievement has traditionally failed when pursued by the bureaus of the
government. There may thus be room for the government to outsource
some corporate social responsibility (CSR) to these hybrids because they
can more cost-effectively govern a certain array of transactions.
Valentinov (2013), on the other hand, submits that hierarchies
pursuing CSR are a functional equivalent of vertical integration [] It
involves the internalization of the societal environment in order to
forestall the hazards that would result from it otherwise(p. 321). This
points to another array of transactions whose governance may be
handed out to for-prot enterprises, bringing about net gains in the
reduction of governance costs, which the blue cost curve of Fig. 5 il-
lustrates. We must emphasize, however, that the feasibility of
outsourcing CSR to either for-prot hybrids or for-prot hierarchies
depends on whether the risk of eco-opportunism, like greenwashing, can
be mitigated through credible commitments (Agafonow and Perez,
2023b, 2024a).
In contrast, we see the overhauling of MNEs along the lines of B&J as
a discrete structure on its own merits. To the extent that every complex
organization like a MNE is subject to the separation of ownership and
control (Fama and Jensen, 1983), property rights are attenuated because
no single private individual can centralize all the rights of control
(Grossman and Hart, 1986; Schlager and Ostrom, 1992). This attenua-
tion is higher, however, in B&J because it has innovated rearranging its
bundle of property rights by putting the drivers that alter the environ-
mental and social commitments off-limits to equity holders. If the aca-
demic community accepts that partitioning the rights of control in the
way shown herein is novellet alone feasible for B&J actually existsit
would merit a dedicated place in Fig. 5 as illustrated by the thick green
cost curve.
5.2. Limitations
Because the mechanism of B&J may not be foolproof, a reection on
the circumstances under which it could fail can help further the design of
organizations that better adapt to the constraints that the Anthropocene
imposes, thus preventing Nature and other relevant stakeholders from
being shortchanged ex post, during the contract execution stage.
One of the weaknesses of B&Js mechanism paradoxically lies in the
self-perpetuating status of Class I directors (i.e., the wardens of the
mission) which, by being accountable to no one but themselves, akin to
the trustees of ownerless non-prots, shields their role of mission war-
dens from the interference of Unilever. Despite such a shield serving to
protect the subsidiarys environmental and social commitments, it
drives the issue of accountability one level deeper raising the familiar
question: Who monitors the monitor?(Milgrom and Roberts, 1992, p.
497).
To be sure, board self-perpetuation paves the way for likeminded
people to ll vacant positions which, in the best-case scenario, will keep
alive the values of B&Js founders, and the track records of many suc-
ceeding Class I directors show that they have been engaged in social or
environmental advocacy before joining the company (Agafonow and
Perez, 2017). Yet we can imagine a scenario where oversights in the
screening of candidates lead to the admission of directors whose values
align more with Unilevers shareholders than with B&Js stakeholders.
There is perhaps a way to go one level deeper in safeguarding stake-
holder accountability, which consists in fractionating trusteeship (Lang-
bein, 1996; Sitkoff, 2004) so that the role of mission wardens is split
between Class I directors and a credible co-trustee. This is an arrange-
ment that Patagonia, Inc. has recently put into practice (Agafonow and
Perez, 2024a) and whose details fall outside the scope of this article.
Another weakness of B&Js mechanism may be its liability to Uni-
levers tactics to put pressure on Class I directors. For instance, in the
wake of B&Js decision to halt its licensing agreement with an Israeli
company (Kingsley, 2022), Unilever withheld the payment of Class I
directors:
Member of the board claimed [] that the freeze was a ‘pressure
tactic prior to a mediation that took place last week. Anuradha
Mittal, chair of the Ben & Jerrys board, said: ‘Despite them freezing
our salaries, we are continuing to do our work because our delity is
to Ben & Jerrys.(Evans, 2022a, p. online).
However, because the merger agreement attributes authority to B&J
and its board over [t]otal compensation (including Bonuses) of any
employees at or above the level of Ofcer (SEC, 2000, p. 94), this
conict may pave the way for the injunction (illustrated in Fig. 4 with an
umbrella) to be put to a test once again, as it happened back in the 2000s
(Agafonow and Perez, 2017).
6. Conclusion
If MNEs are to credibly meet the challenge of sustainability, it is high
time that they are overhauled to reckon with the nite ecosystem ser-
vices that mark the Anthropocene (Engel et al., 2008; Waters et al.,
2016; Wunder, 2015). This is a design undertaking that pivots on a
Fig. 5. Governance costs as a function of the attenuation of property rights:
Cost-effective transactions are positioned along the dashed envelope curve and
housed in the governance structures that make them possible. The attenuation
of property rights is higher the more real-world structures depart from the
hypothetical centralization of the rights of control by a single private individual
(Authorsown based on Agafonow, 2020, p. 189; Williamson, 1991).
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
12
mechanism-based methodology which, despite thriving in other sciences
(Chibucos et al., 2014; Darden et al., 2018; Smith et al., 2005; Steel,
2008), remains underexploited in the social sciences (Hedstr¨
om and
Swedberg, 2005; Pajunen, 2008, 2010).
Rewriting corporate charters to include an environmental or social
mission, as recent articles have it (e.g., Segrestin et al., 2021; Serres
et al., 2022), would not do because non-equity stakeholders normally
nd it too costly to litigate against MNEs. Thus, the design challenge is to
spell out how the rights of control (Grossman and Hart, 1986) can be
partitioned to reduce the marginal cost that these stakeholders bear
when pressing one more MNE to uphold environmental and social
commitments. This is because these kinds of stakeholders are contingent
and tangential (Rounds & Rounds, 2020), hence lacking bargaining
power to make MNEs comply should the conguration of property rights
remain unchanged.
The focus on MNEs above other kinds of rms is not arbitrary for
MNEs combine two important characteristics that make their impact on
ecosystems more acute, namely, a geographical outreach that intensies
the impact of international trade on ecosystems (Lenzen et al., 2012) and
the capability to cash in on natural resources and other stakeholders by
haggling and bargaining more aggressively, thus maximizing rent sur-
plus for shareholders (Baumol, 1967; Brickley et al., 2016; Chandler Jr.,
1999; Jensen and Meckling, 1998; Milgrom and Roberts, 1992; Min-
tzberg, 1979; Roberts, 2004; Williamson, 1981, 1985).
Comparing the mechanisms of Unilevers B&J with an archetypical
MNE, this research has set off by contrast how B&J deviates from
business as usual to accommodate the constraints imposed by the
Anthropocene. B&J has thus built a governance structure that tackles
several obstacles that burden todays MNEs, including the high marginal
cost that stakeholders bear when engaging with one more MNE across
the value chain; the conict of interests of making the wardens of the
mission accountable to shareholders; the meddling of MNE executives
with the organizational drivers of environmental and social commit-
ments; the appointment of key MNE executives behind stakeholders
back; and a limited recourse to the courts for stakeholders. B&Js answer
to these obstacles perhaps blaze a trail that can galvanize humanity into
overhauling MNEs to cope with the Anthropocene.
CRediT authorship contribution statement
Alejandro Agafonow: Writing review & editing, Writing original
draft, Visualization, Validation, Supervision, Software, Resources,
Project administration, Methodology, Investigation, Funding acquisi-
tion, Formal analysis, Data curation, Conceptualization. Marybel Perez:
Writing review & editing, Writing original draft, Visualization,
Validation, Supervision, Software, Resources, Project administration,
Methodology, Investigation, Funding acquisition, Formal analysis, Data
curation, Conceptualization.
Declaration of competing interest
This research does not include data collected from human subjects,
and it relies on evidence based on publicly available archival data.
Therefore, we believe there is no conict of interest to report, nor does it
require informed consent from the ethical review board of the authors
institution.
Data availability
Data is archival and publicly available
References
Agafonow, A., 2015. Value creation, value capture, and value devolution: where do
social enterprises stand? Adm. Soc. 47 (8), 10381060. https://doi.org/10.1177/
0095399714555756.
Agafonow, A., 2020. From hybrid organizations to social-purpose hierarchies: toward a
transaction cost economics of social enterprises. J. Interdiscip. Econ. 32 (2),
180199. https://doi.org/10.1177/0260107919846791.
Agafonow, A., Donaldson, C., 2015. The economic rationale behind the social business
model: A research agenda. Social Business 5 (1), 516. https://doi.org/10.1362/
204440815X14267607784721.
Agafonow, A., Perez, M., 2017. The transaction costs of stakeholder board membership.
The case of ben & Jerrys homemade, Inc, pp. 131. https://doi.org/10.2139/
ssrn.3667602. SSRN online library.
Agafonow, A., Perez, M., 2023a. Bean-counting research and the mismanagement of
knowledge production in business schools. Prometheus. Critical Studies in
Innovation 39 (2), 79100. https://doi.org/10.13169/prometheus.39.2.0079.
Agafonow, A., Perez, M., 2023b. How A social Enterprise wanes: the transaction costs of
credible commitments at Etsy.com. J. Interdiscip. Econ. 35 (1), 83101. https://doi.
org/10.1177/02601079211038239.
Agafonow, A., Perez, M., 2024a. In search of a non-anthropocentric middle-range theory
of the rm: on how the Patagonia purpose trust granted a controlling stake to nature.
Ecol. Econ. 217 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2023.108076.
Agafonow, A., Perez, M., 2024b. When an A is NOT an A in academic research, or how A-
journal list metrics inhibit exploratory behaviour in academia. J. Interdiscip. Econ.
36 (1), 105121. https://doi.org/10.1177/02601079231152118.
Altman, N., Krzywinski, M., 2017. Interpreting P values. Nat. Methods 14 (3), 213214.
https://doi.org/10.1038/nmeth.4210.
Andersson, U., Cuervo-Cazurra, A., Nielsen, B.B., 2014. From the editors: explaining
interaction effects within and across levels of analysis. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 45 (9),
10631071. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2014.50.
Arp, R., Smith, B., Spear, A.D., 2015. Building Ontologies with Basic Formal Ontology.
The MIT Press.
Arrow, K., Bolin, B., Costanza, R., Dasgupta, P., Folke, C., Holling, C.S., Jansson, B.-O.,
Levin, S., M¨
aler, K.-G., Perrings, C., Pimentel, D., 1995. Economic growth, carrying
capacity, and the environment. Ecol. Econ. 15 (2), 9195. https://doi.org/10.1016/
0921-8009(95)00059-3.
Babbie, E.R., 2021. The Practice of Social Research, 15th ed. Cengage Learning, Inc.
Baker, G.P., 2000. The use of performance measures in incentive contracting. Am. Econ.
Rev. 90 (2), 415420. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.2.415.
Barney, J.B., 2018. Why resource-based theorys model of prot appropriation must
incorporate a stakeholder perspective. Strateg. Manag. J. 39 (13), 33053325.
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2949.
Baumol, W.J., 1967. Business Behavior, Value and Growth (Revised Ed). Harcourt, Brace &
World, Inc.
Baumol, W.J., Litan, R.E., Schramm, C.J., 2007. Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism, and
the Economics of Growth and Prosperity. Yale University Press.
Ben & Jerrys Homemade Inc, 2015. 2015 Social & Environmental Assessment Report.
http://www.benjerry.com/about-us/sear-reports/2015-sear-report.
Ben & Jerrys Homemade Inc, 2018. Social & Environmental Assessment Report. SEAR
Reports. https://www.benjerry.com/about-us/sear-reports/2018-sear-report.
Ben & Jerrys Homemade Inc. Our History. Retrieved May 16, 2017, from. http://www.
benjerry.com/about-us#1timeline.
Blaikie, N., 2010. Designing social research. In: The Logic of Anticipation, 2nd ed. Polity
Press.
Bradley, P., 2021. An institutional economics framework to explore sustainable
production and consumption. Sustainable Production and Consump. 27, 13171339.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.02.035.
Brickley, J.A., Smith, C.W., Zimmerman, J.L., 2016. Managerial Economics and
Organizational Architecture, 6th ed. McGraw-Hill Education. doi: 978-0-07-352314-
9.
Brown, C., 1990. Firms choice of method of pay. Ind. Labor Relat. Rev. 43 (3) https://
doi.org/10.1177/001979399004300311, 165-S-182-S.
Buckley, P.J., Doh, J.P., Benischke, M.H., 2017. Towards a renaissance in international
business research? Big questions, grand challenges, and the future of IB scholarship.
J. Int. Bus. Stud. 48 (9), 10451064. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-017-0102-z.
Cartwright, N., 2004. Causation: one word, many things. Philos. Sci. 71 (5), 805820.
https://doi.org/10.1086/426771.
Chandler Jr., A.D., 1999. The Visible Hand. The Managerial Revolution in American
Business. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Chibucos, M.C., Mungall, C.J., Balakrishnan, R., Christie, K.R., Huntley, R.P., White, O.,
Blake, J.A., Lewis, S.E., Giglio, M., 2014. Standardized description of scientic
evidence using the evidence ontology (ECO). Database 2014 (bau075), 111.
https://doi.org/10.1093/database/bau075.
Coase, R.H., 1937. The nature of the rm. Economica 4 (16), 386405. https://doi.org/
10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x.
Coase, R.H., 1988. The nature of the rm: meaning. The J. Law, Economics, and Organiz.
4 (1), 1932. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a036944.
Coase, R.H., 1991. Prize Lecture. The Nobel Foundation. December 9. https://www.nobe
lprize.org/prizes/economic-sciences/1991/coase/lecture/.
Coff, R.W., 1999. When competitive advantage Doesnt Lead to performance: the
resource-based view and stakeholder bargaining power. Organ. Sci. 10 (2), 119133.
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.10.2.119.
Craver, C.F., Darden, L., 2013. In Search of Mechanisms: Discoveries across the Life
Sciences. University of Chicago Press.
Daly, H.E., 1990. Sustainable development: from concept and theory to operational
principles. Popul. Dev. Rev. 16, 2543. https://doi.org/10.2307/2808061.
Darden, L., Kundu, K., Pal, L.R., Moult, J., 2018. Harnessing formal concepts of biological
mechanism to analyze human disease. PLoS Comput. Biol. 14 (12), 110. https://
doi.org/10.1371/journal.pcbi.1006540.
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
13
Dasgupta, P., 2008. Nature in economics. Environ. Resour. Econ. 39 (1), 17. https://doi.
org/10.1007/s10640-007-9178-4.
Dasgupta, P., 2021a. The Economics of Biodiversity: The Dasgupta Review. HM Treasury.
Dasgupta, P., 2021b. Economics Natures way. Good economics demands that we
manage nature better. Finanance & Development. September. 1619. https://www.
imf.org/en/Publications/fandd/issues/2021/09/economics-and-nature-dasgupta.
Demsetz, H., 1983. The structure of ownership and the theory of the rm. J. Law Econ.
26 (2), 375390. https://doi.org/10.1086/467041.
Dietz, T., Ostrom, E., Stern, P.C., 2003. The struggle to govern the commons. Science 302
(5652), 19071912. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1091015.
Doh, J.P., Eden, L., Tsui, A.S., Zaheer, S., 2023. Developing international business
scholarship for global societal impact. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 54 (5), 757767. https://doi.
org/10.1057/s41267-023-00603-4.
Easterbrook, F.H., Fischel, D.R., 1996. The Economic Structure of Corporate Law.
Harvard University Press.
Editorial board., 2022. America is struggling to counter Chinas intellectual property
theft. Financial Times. April 18. https://www.ft.com/content/1d13ab71-bffd-4d6
3-a0bf-9e9bdfc33c39.
Edmondson, B., 2014. Ice Cream Social. The Struggle for the Soul of Ben & Jerrys.
Berrett-Koehler Publishers, Inc.
Engel, S., Pagiola, S., Wunder, S., 2008. Designing payments for environmental services
in theory and practice: an overview of the issues. Ecol. Econ. 65 (4), 663674.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.03.011.
Evans, J., 2022a. Unilever stops paying Ben & Jerrys board members in Israel dispute.
Financial Times. August 3. https://www.ft.com/content/8d071311-7cbe-46c
4-b8a7-5f25e40e258b.
Evans, J., 2022b. Ben & Jerrys vs Unilever: how a star acquisition became a legal
nightmare. Financial Times. October 11. https://www.ft.com/content/30efd99
3-8c23-4f1b-9385-132bbba3d863.
Fama, E.F., Jensen, M.C., 1983. Separation of ownership and control. J. Law Econ. 26
(2), 301325. https://doi.org/10.1086/467037.
Ferguson-Cradler, G., 2024. Institutionalism, the corporation, and the climate crisis. The
Anthropocene Review 0 (0), 122. https://doi.org/10.1177/20530196241227641.
Gorg, H., Greenaway, D., 2004. Much ado about nothing? Do domestic rms really
benet from foreign direct investment? World Bank Res. Obs. 19 (2), 171197.
https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/lkh019.
Greenwood, D.T., Holt, R.P.F., 2008. Institutional and ecological economics: the role of
technology and institutions in economic development. J. Econ. Issues 42 (2),
445452. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2008.11507153.
Grossman, S.J., Hart, O.D., 1986. The costs and benets of ownership: A theory of
vertical and lateral integration. J. Polit. Econ. 94 (4), 691719. https://doi.org/
10.1086/261404.
Gui, E.M., Diesendorf, M., MacGill, I., 2017. Distributed energy infrastructure paradigm:
community microgrids in a new institutional economics context. Renew. Sust. Energ.
Rev. 72, 13551365. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2016.10.047.
Haber, S. (Ed.), 2002. Crony Capitalism and Economic Growth in Latin America: Theory
and Evidence. Hoover Institution Press.
Hansmann, H.B., 2000. The Ownership of Enterprise. The Belknap Press of Harvard
University Press.
Hardin, G., 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science 162 (3859), 12431248. https://
doi.org/10.1126/SCIENCE.162.3859.1243.
Hayek, F.A., 2011. The constitution of liberty. In: Hamowy, R. (Ed.), The Collected
Works of F. A. Hayek. The De Nitive Edition, vol. XVII. The University of Chicago
Press, pp. 37583.
Hedstr¨
om, P., Swedberg, R., 2005. Social mechanisms: An introductory essay. In:
Hedstr¨
om, P., Swedberg, R. (Eds.), Social Mechanisms. An Analytical Approach to
Social Theory. Cambridge University Press, pp. 131.
Hennart, J.-F. (1993). Explaining the Swollen Middle: Why Most Transactions Are A Mix
of Market and HierarchyOrgan. Sci., 4(4), 529547. doi: https://doi.org/https
://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.4.4.529.
Hoskisson, R.E., Gambeta, E., Green, C.D., Li, T.X., 2018. Is my rm-specic investment
protected? Overcoming the stakeholder investment dilemma in the resource-based
view. Acad. Manag. Rev. 43 (2), 284306. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2015.0411.
Hsiung, B., Gunning, J.P., 2002. Ronald Coases method of building more realistic
models of choice. Review of Political Economy 14 (2), 227239. https://doi.org/
10.1080/09538250220126537.
Ioannidis, J.P.A., 2003. Genetic associations: false or true? Trends Mol. Med. 9 (4),
135138. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1471-4914(03)00030-3.
Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1998. Divisional performance measurement. In:
Jensen, M.C. (Ed.), Foundations of Organizational Strategy. Harvard University
Press, pp. 345361.
Kazmin, A., Sciorilli Borrelli, S., 2023. Italy strips Chinas Sinochem of its inuence as
Pirellis largest investor. Financial Times. June 18. https://www.ft.com/content/d6
9554c0-0252-4ef1-81a4-c3699ead4a54?shareType=nongift.
Kingsley, P., 2022. Unilever Sells ben & Jerrys business in Israel, defusing dispute. New
York Times. June 29. https://www.nytimes.com/2022/06/29/world/middleeast/
unilver-ben-and-jerrys-israel.html#:~:text=JERUSALEM%20%20Unilever%
20said%20on%20Wednesday,the%20Israeli%2Doccupied%20West%20Bank.
Kolk, A., Pinkse, J., 2008. A perspective on multinational enterprises and climate change:
learning from an inconvenient truth? J. Int. Bus. Stud. 39 (8), 13591378. https://
doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2008.61.
Konara, P., Lopez, C., Shirodkar, V., 2021. Environmental innovation in foreign
subsidiaries: the role of home-ecological institutions, subsidiary establishment mode
and post-establishment experience. J. World Bus. 56 (6), 101261 https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.jwb.2021.101261.
Langbein, J.H., 1996. The uniform prudent investor act and the future of trust investing.
Iowa Law Review 81, 641669.
Lazear, E.P., 1986. Salaries and piece rates. J. Bus. 59 (3), 405431.
Lazear, E.P., 2018. Compensation and incentives in the workplace. J. Econ. Perspect. 32
(3), 195214. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.32.3.195.
Lenzen, M., Moran, D., Kanemoto, K., Foran, B., Lobefaro, L., Geschke, A., 2012.
International trade drives biodiversity threats in developing nations. Nature 486
(7401), 109112. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature11145.
Li, C., Ahn, J., Bu, J., Meyer, K.E., 2023. The value of publishing in JIBS. J. Int. Bus. Stud.
54 (9), 16881699. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-023-00630-1.
Lipton, P., 2004. Inference to the Best Explanation, 2nd ed. Routledge.
MacLeod Heminway, J., 2017. Corporate purpose and litigation risk in publicly held U.S.
Benet Corporations. Seattle University Law Review 40 (2), 611682.
March, J.G., Simon, H.A., 1993. Organizations, 2nd ed. Blackwell Publishers.
Mauerhofer, V., 2019a. An introduction and overview on law, politics and governance:
institutions, organizations and procedures for ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 165,
106396 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.106396.
Mauerhofer, V., 2019b. Legal institutions and ecological economics: their common
contribution for achieving a sustainable development. Ecol. Econ. 156, 350359.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.09.023.
M´
enard, C., 1996. On clusters, hybrids, and other strange forms: the case of the French
poultry industry. J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 152 (1), 154183.
M´
enard, C., 2011. A new institutional economics perspective on environmental issues.
Environ. Innov. Soc. Trans. 1 (1), 115120. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
eist.2011.04.002.
Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., 1992. Economics, Organization and Management. Prentice Hall,
Inc.
Mintzberg, H., 1979. The Structuring of Organizations: A Synthesis of the Research.
Prentice-Hall.
Mintzberg, H., 1981. Organization Design: Fashion or Fit? Harvard Business Review.
January, pp. 103116.
Mintzberg, H., 1983. Power in and around Organizations. Prentice Hall, Inc.
Muradian, R., 2001. Ecological thresholds: a survey. Ecol. Econ. 38 (1), 724. https://
doi.org/10.1016/S0921-8009(01)00146-X.
Murphy, E.A., 1978. Epidemiological strategies and genetic factors. Int. J. Epidemiol. 7
(1), 714. https://doi.org/10.1093/ije/7.1.7.
Nygaard, A., 2022. From linear to circular economy: a transaction cost approach to the
ecological transformation of the rm. Circ. Econ. Sustain. 2 (3), 11271142. https://
doi.org/10.1007/s43615-022-00158-w.
Oetzel, J., Doh, J.P., 2009. MNEs and development: a review and reconceptualization.
J. World Bus. 44 (2), 108120. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2008.05.001.
Ostrom, E., 1990. Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action. Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, E., 2009. A general framework for analyzing sustainability of social-ecological
systems. Science 325 (5939), 419422. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1172133.
Ouchi, W.G., 1980. Markets, bureaucracies, and clans. Adm. Sci. Q. 25 (1), 129141.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2392231.
Ouchi, W.G., Price, R.L., 1978. Hierarchies, clans, and theory Z: A new perspective on
organization development. Organ. Dyn. 7 (2), 2544. https://doi.org/10.1016/
0090-2616(78)90036-0.
Paavola, J., Adger, W.N., 2005. Institutional ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 53 (3),
353368. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.09.017.
Pajunen, K., 2008. The nature of organizational mechanisms. Organ. Stud. 29 (11),
14491468. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840607096384.
Pajunen, K., 2010. A black box of stakeholder thinking. J. Bus. Ethics 96 (S1), 2732.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-011-0940-8.
Pencavel, J.H., 2012. Work effort, on-the-job screening, and alternative methods of
remuneration. Res. Labor Econ. 35 (35th Anniversary Retrospective), 537570.
https://doi.org/10.1108/S0147-9121(2012)0000035042.
Peteraf, M.A., 1993. The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view.
Strateg. Manag. J. 14 (3), 179191. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250140303.
Phillips, R.A., Barney, J.B., Freeman, E.R., Harrison, J.S., 2019. Stakeholder theory. In:
Harrison, J.S., Barney, J.B., Freeman, E.R., Phillips, R.A. (Eds.), The Cambridge
Handbook of Stakeholder Theory. Cambridge University Press, pp. 318. https://doi.
org/10.1017/9781108123495.001.
Polski, M., 2005. The institutional economics of biodiversity, biological materials, and
bioprospecting. Ecol. Econ. 53 (4), 543557. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ecolecon.2004.09.024.
Popper, K.R., 1971. Conjectural knowledge: my solution of the problem of induction.
Rev. Int. Philos. 25 (95/96), 167197.
Prebisch, R., 1977. Statement by Raúl Prebisch. CEPAL Rev. 3, 279284.
Pr´
evost, B., Rivaud, A., 2018. The World Banks environmental strategies: assessing the
inuence of a biased use of new institutional economics on legal issues. Ecosyst.
Serv. 29, 370380. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2017.03.014.
Rametsteiner, E., 2002. The role of governments in forest certicationa normative
analysis based on new institutional economics theories. Forest Policy Econ. 4 (3),
163173. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1389-9341(02)00004-7.
Roberts, J., 2004. The Modern Firm: Organizational Design for Performance and Growth.
Oxford University Press.
Rogers, T.N., Temple-West, P., 2023. Exits of diversity executives shake faith in US
companiescommitments. Financial Times. July 13. https://www.ft.com/content/
b39193d2-c722-45e5-ac49-0c5ff51d17b5?shareType=nongift.
Roggero, M., 2015. Adapting institutions: exploring climate adaptation through
institutional economics and set relations. Ecol. Econ. 118, 114122. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.07.022.
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
Ecological Economics 222 (2024) 108232
14
Rounds Jr., C.E., Rounds, C.E.I., 2020. Loring and Rounds: A Trustees Handbook.
Wolters Kluwer Law & Business.
Rygh, A., 2019. Social value creation by multinational enterprises. Crit. Perspect. Int.
Bus. 16 (1), 4775. https://doi.org/10.1108/cpoib-07-2017-0040.
Schanzenbach, M.M., Sitkoff, R.H., 2020. Reconciling duciary duty and social
conscience: the law and economics of ESG investing by a trustee. Stanford Law Rev.
72, 381454.
Schick Jr., T., Vaughn, L., 2014. How to Think about Weird Things: Critical Thinking for
a New Age, 7th ed. McGraw-Hill.
Schlager, E., Ostrom, E., 1992. Property-rights regimes and natural resources: A
conceptual analysis. Land Econ. 68 (3), 249262. https://doi.org/10.2307/
3146375.
Schlüter, A., 2007. Institutional change in the forestry sectorthe explanatory potential
of new institutional economics. Forest Policy Econ. 9 (8), 10901099. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.forpol.2006.11.001.
SEC, 2000. Ben & Jerrys Homemade, Inc. Denitive Proxy Statement Relating to Merger
or Acquisition. https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/.
Segrestin, B., Hatchuel, A., Levillain, K., 2021. When the law distinguishes between the
Enterprise and the corporation: the case of the new French law on corporate purpose.
J. Bus. Ethics 171 (1), 113. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-020-04439-y.
Serres, C., Hudon, M., Maon, F., 2022. Social corporations under the spotlight: A
governance perspective. J. Bus. Ventur. 37 (3), 123. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jbusvent.2022.106192.
Simon, H.A., 1996. The Sciences of the Articial, 3rd ed. The MIT Press.
Sitkoff, R.H., 2004. An agency costs theory of trust law. Cornell Law Rev. 89 (3),
621684.
Slavíkov´
a, L., Kluv´
ankov´
a-Oravsk´
a, T., Jílkov´
a, J., 2010. Bridging theories on
environmental governance. Ecol. Econ. 69 (7), 13681372. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.02.015.
Smith, B., 2008. Ontology (science). In: Eschenbach, C., Grüninger, M. (Eds.), Formal
Ontology in Information Systems. Proceedings of the Fifth International Conference
(FOIS 2008) (Pp. 2135). IOS Press. https://doi.org/10.3233/978-1-58603-923-3-
21.
Smith, B., Ceusters, W., Klagges, B., K¨
ohler, J., Kumar, A., Lomax, J., Mungall, C.,
Neuhaus, F., Rector, A.L., Rosse, C., 2005. Relations in biomedical ontologies.
Genome Biol. 6 (5), 115. https://doi.org/10.1186/gb-2005-6-5-r46.
S¨
oderbaum, P., 1992. Neoclassical and institutional approaches to development and the
environment. Ecol. Econ. 5 (2), 127144. https://doi.org/10.1016/0921-8009(92)
90042-Q.
Solomon, B.D., 1999. New directions in emissions trading: the potential contribution of
new institutional economics. Ecol. Econ. 30 (3), 371387. https://doi.org/10.1016/
S0921-8009(99)00021-X.
Speed, M., Levingston, I., Wheatley, J., 2024. Unilever to split off ice cream business and
cut 7,500 jobs. Financial Times. March 19. https://www.ft.com/content/c7b44b4a-e
4c7-45b4-8831-c07c2172b181?shareType=nongift.
Stake, R.E., 2003. Case Studies. In: Denzin, N.K., Lincoln, Y.S. (Eds.), Strategies of
Qualitative Inquiry, 2nd ed. Sage, pp. 134164.
Steel, D., 2008. Across the Boundaries: Extrapolation in Biology and Social Science.
Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/
9780195331448.001.0001.
Stern, P.C., 2011. Design principles for global commons: natural resources and emerging
technologies. Int. J. Commons 5 (2), 213232. https://doi.org/10.18352/ijc.305.
Thees, O., Olschewski, R., 2017. Physical soil protection in forests - insights from
production-, industrial- and institutional economics. Forest Policy Econ. 80, 99106.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2017.01.024.
Thomas, D., 2023. Unilever: Cornetto maker defends decision to stay in Russia. BBC
News. July 4. https://www.bbc.com/news/business-66101852.
Uehara, T., 2013. Ecological threshold and ecological economic threshold: implications
from an ecological economic model with adaptation. Ecol. Econ. 93, 374384.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2013.06.014.
UK Lawyers for Israel, 2021. London Stock Exchange asked to downgrade Unilevers
Premium Listing. November 12. https://www.ukl.com/london-stock-exchange-
asked-to-downgrade-unilevers-premium-listing.
Valentinov, V., 2008. The transaction cost theory of the non-prot rm: beyond
opportunism. Nonprot Volunt. Sect. Q. 37 (1), 518.
Valentinov, V., 2012. The economics of the nonprot sector: insights from the
institutionalism of John R. Commons. Social Science J 49 (4), 545553.
Valentinov, V., 2013. Corporate social responsibility and sustainability: insights from
Boulding and Luhmann. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. World Ecol. 20 (4), 317324. https://
doi.org/10.1080/13504509.2013.808282.
Van Assche, A., 2018. From the editor: steering a policy turn in international business
opportunities and challenges. J. Int. Bus. Policy 1 (34), 117127. https://doi.org/
10.1057/s42214-018-0013-0.
van der Burg, T., 2000. Neo-classical economics, institutional economics and improved
sheries management. Mar. Policy 24 (1), 4551. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0308-
597X(99)00008-1.
van Griethuysen, P., 2012. Bona diagnosis, bona curatio: how property economics
claries the degrowth debate. Ecol. Econ. 84, 262269. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ecolecon.2012.02.018.
van Zanten, J.A., van Tulder, R., 2018. Multinational enterprises and the sustainable
development goals: an institutional approach to corporate engagement. J. Int. Bus.
Policy 1 (34), 208233. https://doi.org/10.1057/s42214-018-0008-x.
Waters, C.N., Zalasiewicz, J., Summerhayes, C., Barnosky, A.D., Poirier, C., Gałuszka, A.,
Cearreta, A., Edgeworth, M., Ellis, E.C., Ellis, M., Jeandel, C., Leinfelder, R.,
McNeill, J.R., Richter, D., deB., Steffen, W., Syvitski, J., Vidas, D., Wagreich, M.,
Williams, M., Wolfe, A. P, 2016. The Anthropocene is functionally and
stratigraphically distinct from the Holocene. Science 351 (6269), 110. https://doi.
org/10.1126/science.aad2622.
Williamson, O.E., 1981. The modern corporation: origins, evolution, Attributes. J. Econ.
Lit. 19 (4), 15371568.
Williamson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. The Free Press and
Collier Macmillan Publisher, Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting.
Williamson, O.E., 1991. Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete
structural alternatives. Adm. Sci. Q. 36 (2), 269296. https://doi.org/10.2307/
2393356.
Williamson, O.E., 1993. The evolving science of organization. J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 149
(1), 3663.
Williamson, O.E., 1999. Public and private bureaucracies: A transaction cost economics
perspectives. J. Law Econ. Org. 15 (1), 306342. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/
15.1.306.
Wunder, S., 2015. Revisiting the concept of payments for environmental services. Ecol.
Econ. 117, 234243. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.08.016.
Zeng, Y., Maxwell, S., Runting, R.K., Venter, O., Watson, J.E.M., Carrasco, L.R., 2020.
Environmental destruction not avoided with the sustainable development goals.
Nature Sustainability 3 (10), 795798. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41893-020-0555-
0.
Zenger, T.R., Hesterly, W.S., 1997. The disaggregation of corporations: selective
intervention, high-powered incentives, and molecular units. Organ. Sci. 8 (3),
209222. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.8.3.209.
A. Agafonow and M. Perez
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
Patagonia, an outdoor clothing company thrust into the limelight by a New York Times full-page ad that in 2001 invited customers not to buy its own gear, has recently responded to the inherently low capacity of firms to supply ecosystem services. Since the firm is a generic term encompassing many different bundles of property rights, the specific mechanism of the Patagonia Purpose Trust is researched to find whether it has plausibly locked the company in on preserving ecosystems through its environmentally driven community investment, product re-design, and supply chain overhaul. A mechanism-based methodology is employed, organizing the units of observation in keeping with a formal ontology and benchmarking Patagonia’s mechanism against the generic templates of a corporation and a charitable Trust to highlight what is distinct about Patagonia. The findings are that, in a nutshell, Patagonia’s mechanism consists of: 1) increasing the opportunity cost of not redressing a breach of purpose by designating an ascertained beneficiary with an unequivocal interest in Nature’s preservation; 2) offsetting fiduciaries’ influence on asset management with a countervailing mechanism; and 3) designing a procedure centered on the renewal of credible co-trustees to keep checking on fiduciaries in the long run.
Article
Full-text available
Notorious cases of corporate misconduct often revolve around the misapplication of pay to performance. Yet many business schools have too easily given themselves up to these kinds of high-powered incentives in the management of research. This practice is contrary to the very management knowledge taught in business school classrooms and it can wreak havoc with business schools' mission of knowledge production. The reduction of managing research to a bean-counting performance evaluation, that is, keeping count of discrete units of research outputs as A-class journal hits and citation counts, has arguably tilted the scales in favor of form and against content. This undermines both the quality of knowledge produced and the autonomy that academics need to create knowledge. Much as combat sports, football or soccer, and democratic societies prevent certain traits and actions from conferring an unfair advantage, academics need to reclaim the principle of a level playing field to prevent practices inimical to the academic enterprise.
Article
Full-text available
On account of the leverage that the Academy of Management (AOM) has, via its positioning in the highest tiers of the A-journal lists currently used to adjudicate promotions and tenure evaluations, it is urgent to assess the premises and assumptions upon which the so-called pluralist model of scholarly impact, advocated by academics with executive responsibilities in the AOM, is built. Our findings are that the pluralist model is liable to three crucial problems: ecological bias, specific knowledge and pre-emptive costs. Consistent with extant performance evaluation scholarship, promotions and tenure evaluations must build instead on: (a) a qualitative evaluation of scholarly contributions unencumbered by ordinality assumptions; (b) the narrowing of the span of control of academics, moving supervisory authority away from the line structure and back into the hands of true peers; and (c) muting the incentives that prevent academics from focusing on riskier and long-term horizon outputs, which are pillars in agreement with known accounts of how exploratory behaviour has been successfully managed at IBM, Google, the SAS Institute and Nokia, to name but a few cases. JEL Codes: 123, O31
Article
Full-text available
Ownership and control have been the strategic focus of organizational analyses to achieve performance. The emergence of sustainable strategies has, however, confronted conventional organizational theory because performance has become a complex concept containing both social elements and environmental dimensions together with conventional economic aspects. Increased climate change, temperature risk, and environmental hazards, as well as intertwined social consequences, create a need for new theoretical insights to understand the emerging circular organization of product lifecycle networks. The ongoing climate crisis calls for new institutional approach that challenges future organizational structures. We present a framework for integrating low-carbon ecological transformation from linear to sustainable circular inter-organizational networks. The global and circular economy increases performance ambiguity, the uncertainty of eco-opportunism, information asymmetry, and transaction costs. Consequently, sustainability makes it necessary to integrate and control organizations throughout the supply chain to avoid eco-opportunism and to economize transaction costs.
Article
The transition to a zero-emissions world entails vast political economic restructuring. How resources are mobilized, what sorts of technological infrastructures are constructed, who funds, controls and has claim to profits from investments contributing to the green transition will shape political economies for generations to come. This article suggests that early 20th-century American institutionalism and subsequent legal institutionalist literatures provide a valuable resource for energy transitions scholars and other social scientists, activists, and policy-makers of the energy transition. The article summarizes some of the major lines of thought in classical and legal institutionalism and briefly outlines three areas in which they can inform thinking about political economies of the Anthropocene. First, these literatures are generative of creative thinking on how business activity is organized and help overcome reductionist public-private dichotomies. Second, the history of institutionalist and progressive thought in the New Deal-era runs parallel, in revealing ways, to thinking based on environmental, social and governmental (ESG) principles in the present. Lastly, the article discusses radical proposals for transformation of private property and investment in the thought of institutionalist Adolf Berle relevant to simultaneously addressing both climate and inequality crises.
Book
Business firms around the world are experimenting with new organizational designs, changing their formal architectures, their routines and processes, and their corporate cultures as they seek to improve their current performance and their growth prospects. In the process they are changing the scope of their business operations, redrawing their organization charts, redefining the allocation of decision-making authority and responsibility, revamping the mechanisms for motivating and rewarding people, reconsidering which activities to conduct in-house and which to out-source, redesigning their information systems, and seeking to alter the shared beliefs, values and norms that their people hold. In this book, John Roberts argues that there are predictable, necessary relationships among these changes that will improve performance and growth. The organizations that are successful will establish patterns of fit among the elements of their organizational designs, their competitive strategies and the external environment in which they operate and will go about this in a holistic manner. The Modern Firm develops powerful conceptual frameworks for analyzing the interrelations between organizational design features, competitive strategy and the business environment. Written in a non-technical language, the book is nevertheless based on rigorous modeling and draws on numerous examples from eighteenth century fur trading companies to such modern firms such as BP and Nokia. Finally the book explores why these developments are happening now, pointing to the increase in global competition and changes in technology. Written by one of the world's leading economists and experts on business strategy and organization, The Modern Firm provides new insights into the changes going on in business today and will be of interest to academics, students and managers alike. The Modern Firm was the Economist Best Business Book of the Year 2004.
Article
Young management scholars often wonder to what extent they should emphasize international business scholarship in their career. In this commentary, we argue that, in addition to its intellectual merits, publishing in the leading outlet in the field, Journal of International Business Studies (JIBS), also pays financially on a par with publishing in other top management journals. Our claim is based on an analysis of the impact of JIBS publications on a strategy faculty’s nine-month salary for a sample of 396 strategy professors from the business schools of 59 research-oriented US public universities from 2015 to 2019. Employing multilevel modeling, we find that publishing in JIBS significantly increases faculty’s annual salary by, on average, more than US$3,000, which is equivalent to the salary gains for publishing in leading general management and strategy journals. Thus, the recognition of JIBS is on par with that of other top management journals, and IB as a field of study is a financially rewarding career path. Moreover, JIBS may offer a blueprint for other business and management journals to build reputation by continuously publishing papers with high standards that continuously develop insights and theory relevant to contemporary business.
Article
The purpose of this JIBS editorial is to outline the vision and mission of the new JIBS Societal Impact Advisory Committee (SIAC). We define “societal impact” as research that has potential effects outside academia, for example, on communities, economies, environments, and other actors. We propose that societal impact is especially important for international business (IB) research but also particularly challenging, given the cross-national dimensions of IB and the differing social, economic, and political preferences faced by MNEs across the contexts in which they operate. We reference the Responsible Research in Business and Management (RRBM) movement and other professional association initiatives as potential sources of inspiration and guidance for understanding the societal impact of IB research generally and the vision and mission of the SIAC in particular. We outline some implications for IB scholarship to improve its societal impact and conclude by describing SIAC’s roles and responsibilities as related to JIBS authors, editors, reviewers, and the broader IB scholarly and practice communities.
Book
An introduction to the field of applied ontology with examples derived particularly from biomedicine, covering theoretical components, design practices, and practical applications. In the era of “big data,” science is increasingly information driven, and the potential for computers to store, manage, and integrate massive amounts of data has given rise to such new disciplinary fields as biomedical informatics. Applied ontology offers a strategy for the organization of scientific information in computer-tractable form, drawing on concepts not only from computer and information science but also from linguistics, logic, and philosophy. This book provides an introduction to the field of applied ontology that is of particular relevance to biomedicine, covering theoretical components of ontologies, best practices for ontology design, and examples of biomedical ontologies in use. After defining an ontology as a representation of the types of entities in a given domain, the book distinguishes between different kinds of ontologies and taxonomies, and shows how applied ontology draws on more traditional ideas from metaphysics. It presents the core features of the Basic Formal Ontology (BFO), now used by over one hundred ontology projects around the world, and offers examples of domain ontologies that utilize BFO. The book also describes Web Ontology Language (OWL), a common framework for Semantic Web technologies. Throughout, the book provides concrete recommendations for the design and construction of domain ontologies.
Article
A series of new legal statutes for profit-seeking social ventures has emerged across geographic and institutional settings. Extant studies commonly do not make a clear distinction between these ventures. Such confusion leads to blurriness in research design and methodology, thereby limiting the relevance of findings. Moreover, researchers, entrepreneurs, and policymakers often lack a clear view of the unique organizational and governance aptitudes these ventures call for, to sustain and grow over time. Thus, this study has two objectives: (1) to clarify the panorama of novel companies that legally commit themselves to a social mission, gathered under the term “social corporation,” by providing a comprehensive typology of these organizations and (2) to identify the governance capabilities that social corporations develop to be sustainable and avoid mission drift in the long run. Our analysis of corporate-governing documents leads us to classify social corporations into three types: hard-law, soft-law, and bylaw. In addition to this typology, our multiple case study uncovers five key governance capabilities of social corporations related to performance, conformance, and responsibility—the main pillars of organizational governance. Overall, our work contributes to a better understanding of novel forms of social entrepreneurship emerging on the market. More important, it casts light on the governance processes that characterize them.