ArticlePublisher preview available

The dual economy paradox: the case of Bangladesh and India

Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract and Figures

We aim to examine Lewis–Ranis–Fei (LRF) model’s predictions of economic development phases for Bangladesh and India. In this regard, we use annual data covering from 1990 to 2019 and apply robust econometric methods for estimating the sectoral (agriculture and non-agriculture) production functions to calculate the Marginal Productivity of Labor (MPL) and the labor reallocation effect. We find that both India and Bangladesh are in the second phase of the LRF model. Moreover, dynamic simulation reveals that Bangladesh will likely reach the LRF turning point before India due to the relatively high labor reallocation effect. Obtained results indicate that observed development pattern is due to country-specific economic and prevailing social characteristics. Based on the results, we also provide a few policy suggestions for both countries’ economic sustainability.
This content is subject to copyright. Terms and conditions apply.
Vol.:(0123456789)
SN Bus Econ (2023) 3:164
https://doi.org/10.1007/s43546-023-00540-2
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The dual economy paradox: thecase ofBangladesh
andIndia
SakibBinAmin1 · FarhanKhan2· MashiyatRafaKhan2· JaahinAzamOyishi2
Received: 17 April 2022 / Accepted: 25 July 2023 / Published online: 7 August 2023
© The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
Abstract
We aim to examine Lewis–Ranis–Fei (LRF) model’s predictions of economic devel-
opment phases for Bangladesh and India. In this regard, we use annual data cover-
ing from 1990 to 2019 and apply robust econometric methods for estimating the
sectoral (agriculture and non-agriculture) production functions to calculate the Mar-
ginal Productivity of Labor (MPL) and the labor reallocation effect. We find that
both India and Bangladesh are in the second phase of the LRF model. Moreover,
dynamic simulation reveals that Bangladesh will likely reach the LRF turning point
before India due to the relatively high labor reallocation effect. Obtained results
indicate that observed development pattern is due to country-specific economic and
prevailing social characteristics. Based on the results, we also provide a few policy
suggestions for both countries’ economic sustainability.
Keywords Economic development· Lewis–Ranis–Fei model· Lewis turning point·
Bangladesh· India· Economic sustainability
* Sakib Bin Amin
sakib.amin@northsouth.edu
Farhan Khan
farhan.khan008@northsouth.edu
Mashiyat Rafa Khan
mashiyatrafakhan@gmail.com
Jaahin Azam Oyishi
ja.oyishi@gmail.com
1 School ofBusiness andEconomics, North South University, 1229Dhaka, Bangladesh
2 School ofBusiness andEconomics, North South University, Dhaka1229, Bangladesh
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Chapter
Full-text available
In this paper, we discuss the stylized facts of Bangladesh’s energy sector, critically review the different policies of the government for powering up the nation in the last 50 years, identify existing controversies and finally indicate potential pathways to ensure future energy security. The novelty of the papers is twofold: First, prior literature did not study the in-depth policy analysis of the Bangladesh energy sector. Second, this paper contributes to the existing literature by providing strategic policy suggestions to the Bangladesh government for formulating its own set of energy policies to achieve its vision for 2041 of becoming a high-income country, after having cleared the interim goal of becoming a middle-income country at its 50th anniversary of independence. The paper also provides insights for other developing countries aspiring to become middle-income countries.
Article
Full-text available
The relationship between energy and output is one of the key issues in economic literature. Existing empirical studies have mainly used the neoclassical one-sector aggregate production function to examine the energy-output nexus and revealed inconclusive results. To address this issue, in this paper, we develop a two-sector model differentiating the energy sector from the conventional production sector to study the energy-output linkage for the Bangladesh economy. Using the annual data from 1985 to 2018, we conduct several unit root tests and reveal that our variables are stationary at their first difference. We further use the Johansen-Juselius cointegration and the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) bounds tests and find that the variables are cointegrated in the long-run. By using three robust estimators (Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares (DOLS), Fully Modified OLS (FMOLS), and Dynamic ARDL), we reveal that a 1% increase in energy can increase the output by 0.06–0.10% in the long-run. We also run the Granger causality test and Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) to check the long-run and short-run causality. Our results find a unidirectional causality running from energy to output in the long-run but not in the short-run. We recommend that a reliable supply of energy needs to be ensured for future sustainable development in Bangladesh.
Article
Full-text available
Inherited caste identity is an important determinant of life opportunity for a fifth of the world’s population, but is not given the same significance in global development policy debates as gender, race, age, religion or other identity characteristics. This review asks why addressing caste-based inequality and discrimination does not feature in intergovernmental commitments such as the Sustainable Development Goals, and whether it should. Taking India as its focus, it finds that caste has been treated as an archaic system and source of historical disadvantage due compensation through affirmative action in ways that overlook its continuing importance as a structure of advantage and of discrimination in the modern economy, especially post-liberalization from the 1990s. A body of recent literature from anthropology, economics, history and political science is used to explore the modern life of caste in society, economy and development. Questions are asked about caste as social hierarchy, the role of caste in post-liberalization rural inequality, in urban labor markets and in the business economy, and the effect of policies of affirmative action in public-sector education and employment. Caste is found to be a complex institution, simultaneously weakened and revived by current economic and political forces; it is a contributor to persisting national socioeconomic and human capital disparities, and has major impacts on subjective wellbeing. Caste effects are not locational; they travel from the village to the city and into virtually all markets. Caste persists in the age of the market because of its advantages – its discriminations allow opportunity hoarding for others; and the threat of the advancement of subordinated groups provokes humiliating violence against them. The evidence points to the need for policy innovation to address market and non-market discrimination and to remove barriers, especially in the informal and private sector; and to ensure caste has its proper place in the global development policy debate.
Article
Full-text available
This paper discusses the reason for economic growth and inter-sectoral wage inequality in Vietnam from the perspective of dynamic labor mobility during the period of 2004―2010. To analyze dynamic labor mobility, I revisit labor surplus theory under the dualistic economy as proposed by Lewis (1954). According to the analytical results, notably with the comparison between the marginal productivity of labor and the real wage rate in the agricultural sector, the marginal productivity of labor is still greater than the real wage rate in the sector. That is, the marginal productivity of labor is still 69.1 percent of the real wage rate as of 2010. Hence, it is plausible that the Vietnamese economy did not reach the turning point by the end of the decade, implying the existence of vast amounts of cheap labor in the agricultural sector and a continuously diverging real wage rate gap between agricultural and non-agricultural sectors. Vietnamese growth would be sustained awhile by the development of the non-agricultural sector with the absorption of cheap labor supplied from the agricultural sector.
Article
During the last decade, the Bangladesh economy grew consistently over 6 per cent annually; however, growth rate in the agriculture sector declined. Labour away from agriculture is evident; it is also evident real wages in the agriculture sector are rising. This could be an indication that Bangladesh is moving to a different stage of economic development. This article investigates whether Bangladesh is approaching a stage of economic development where marginal productivity of labour equals its price, called the Lewis turning point (LTP). We find that the reallocation of labour away from agriculture has had a positive but insignificant impact on economic growth in Bangladesh. We also find that the surplus agricultural labour has not fully been absorbed by the economy. Therefore, we conclude Bangladesh has yet to reach the LTP and suggest initiating policies (e.g., job creation in the service sector) that might speed up the country’s movement to the LTP.
Article
I. Statistical findings, 381; changes in the marginal productivity of labor in the subsistence sector, 381; changes in the wage rate in the subsistence sector, 384; relationship between the wage rate and marginal productivity in the subsistence sector, 387; elasticity of labor supply to the capitalist sector, 388; changes in the subsistence sector labor force, 390; concluding remarks, 394. — II. Examination of statistical studies by other writers, 395; comments on Fei-Ranis' conclusions, 395; comments on Jorgenson's conclusions, 398.— Appendix A: cross-sectional test of the marginal productivity theory, 400.— Appendix B: mathematical examinations of the changes in the capital-labor ratio, labor productivity, and the capital-output ratio, 401.