ArticlePDF Available

Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on International Aid

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This study combines the type of partners and the number of partnerships’ purposes to assess municipal partnerships’ effectiveness in bringing international aid. First, the study test whether inter-municipal cooperation (homogenous partners) is more effective than inter-governmental cooperation (heterogeneous partners) in increasing international aid at the local level. Second, the study tests whether partnerships with the sole purpose of raising international aid (single purpose) are more effective than partnerships with additional purposes (multiple purposes). Using panel data with 2,431 municipal-year observations, results confirm that inter-governmental partnerships with multiple purposes are the most effective partnership to increase international aid.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Public Organization Review (2023) 23:861–881
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11115-022-00676-z
Abstract
This study combines the type of partners and the number of partnerships’ purposes
to assess municipal partnerships’ eectiveness in bringing international aid. First,
the study test whether inter-municipal cooperation (homogenous partners) is more
eective than inter-governmental cooperation (heterogeneous partners) in increas-
ing international aid at the local level. Second, the study tests whether partnerships
with the sole purpose of raising international aid (single purpose) are more eective
than partnerships with additional purposes (multiple purposes). Using panel data
with 2,431 municipal-year observations, results conrm that inter-governmental
partnerships with multiple purposes are the most eective partnership to increase
international aid.
Keywords Municipal partnerships · International aid · Ecuador · Local
government performance · Wicksellian-eciency
Introduction
Local chief executives consider inter-municipal partnerships as part of their manage-
rial strategies to improve organizational performance across several dimensions, yet
executive experiences with such partnerships are not always successful (Bryson et
al., 2006; Fierlbeck, 2010; Matthews & Missingham, 2009). This variation in success
led to the necessity to research the characteristics of inter-municipal partnerships and
Accepted: 9 October 2022 / Published online: 7 November 2022
© The Author(s) 2022
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their
Impact on International Aid
Julio C.Zambrano-Gutiérrez1,2 · Claudia N.Avellaneda2
Julio C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez
julio.zambrano@tum.de
1 School of Social Sciences and Technology, Department of Governance, Technical
University of Munich, Richard-Wagner-Straße 1, Room B.257, 80333 Munich, Bavaria,
Germany
2 O’Neill School of Public and Environmental Aairs, Indiana University Bloomington,
Bloomington, Indiana, U.S.A.
1 3
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
their eect on the performance of public organizations (Bauer et al., 2020; Bryson et
al., 2015; Soukopová & Vaceková, 2018). Joining an inter-municipal partnership is
not a minor strategic decision for local chief ocials. Who the participants and what
the purpose will be are fundamental choices in starting a collaboration (Biddle &
Koontz, 2014; Emerson et al., 2012; Siddiki et al., 2017). This is because diverse par-
ticipants might improve organizational outcomes but also conict in the collaborative
process (Cuppen, 2012; Horwitz & Horwitz, 2007; Jehn, 1994; Jehn et al., 1999).
Also, multiple-purpose partnerships might increase legitimacy and representation but
also ambiguity in the mission of the collaboration (Rainey & Jung, 2015; Vangen &
Huxham, 2012). While previous research has explored separately the eect of the
type of cooperative partners and goal clarity on collaborative settings on organiza-
tional outcomes (Biddle & Koontz, 2014; Klok et al., 2018), scarce attention has been
devoted to examining whether the type of participating organizations (e.g., hetero-
geneous vs. homogeneous) and the number of goals (e.g., single vs. multi-purpose)
pursued in a collaborative arrangement inuence organizational outcomes.
To ll this gap, this study integrates the type of participating partners and the
number of partnership purposes for analyzing the eectiveness of municipal part-
nerships. To do so, the study classies municipal partnerships into a continuum that
ranges from homogeneous partners with a single purpose to heterogeneous partners
with multiple purposes. Specically, this study rst tests whether inter-municipal
cooperation (homogeneous partners) is more eective than inter-governmental (het-
erogeneous partners) cooperation in bringing international aid to municipal coers.
Second, this study also tests whether partnerships with the sole purpose of raising
international aid (single purpose) are more eective than partnerships including addi-
tional purposes, such as waste management (multiple purposes) in raising interna-
tional aid.
The study oers three contributions. First, the research introduces an integrative
framework that combines: (a) the type of participating partners and (b) the number
of partnership purposes to explain the eectiveness of the municipal partnership.
Second, the study advances theory by testing the underpinnings of goal-ambiguity
and transaction cost theories in a dierent setting – the 221 Ecuadorian municipalities
that combine a unitary decentralized system with a relatively new democracy. Third,
the study assesses local government performance based on integrative frameworks at
the partnership and organizational levels (Boyne, 2002; Emerson & Nabatchi, 2015).
Moreover, non-reimbursable international cooperation is used as a performance indi-
cator to measure “wicksellian-eciency”, which is based on the idea of seeking to
achieve economic benets (e.g., more municipal revenues) with the lowest politi-
cal costs (e.g., without increasing municipal taris) (Breton, 1998). Results from
cross-sectional time series data with 2,431 municipal-year observations conrm that
inter-municipal and single-purpose partnerships are eective strategies to bring in
non-reimbursable international cooperation. Nonetheless, inter-governmental and
multi-purpose types of partnerships outperformed in increasing international aid.
1 3
862
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
Municipalities as Partners Across inter-governmental Agreements
The reasons and factors that drive municipalities to engage in dierent types of part-
nerships have been signicantly discussed. Inter-municipal cooperation refers to a
managerial strategy to cope with societal high expectations about scal pressures,
collective action dilemmas, and the quality of public services (Bel & Warner, 2015;
Feiock 2013; Hulst & Van Montfort, 2007). However, the concept of inter-municipal
cooperation has an ambiguous denition. Some authors dene the term inter-munici-
pal as partnerships between municipalities (Steiner, 2003), while others allow for the
inclusion of other tiers of government and sectors (Hulst & Van Montfort, 2007). This
study refers to inter-municipal cooperation when two or more municipal govern-
ments formally agree to join eorts to manage and provide public goods and services.
Meanwhile, inter-governmental cooperation represents an instance in which one or
more municipal governments formally agree to join eorts with other tiers of govern-
ment to manage and provide public goods and services.
Apart from building a consensus around the conceptualization of municipal part-
nerships, the approach to studying the performance of municipal partnerships varies.
This is in part because performance variables can be measured in dierent ways,
across dierent dimensions (Boyne, 2003), and signal dierent performance results
(see Nicholson-Crotty, Theobald, & Nicholson‐Crotty, 2006). For example, the eec-
tiveness of inter-municipal cooperation has been measured based on the capacity to
reduce costs (Bel & Warner, 2015) and even in terms of accountability and respon-
siveness (Warner, 2006). Another set of studies has highlighted the complexity of
measuring the performance of a collaborative setting (Agrano, 2005; Emerson &
Nabatchi 2015; Moynihan et al., 2011). For example, a community could benet
from more access to new services for fewer costs in a public mental health network,
but it could be incompatible with the organizational mission of some service provid-
ers (Provan & Milward, 2001).
Emerson & Nabatchi (2015) encourage studying the performance of a collabo-
ration in a comprehensive way. A simplied version of their proposition includes
three elements: (1) whether performance measurement happens at the output or out-
come level, (2) whether performance measurement is about the organization (micro-
level) or the collaboration as a whole (macro-level), and (3) identifying the most
salient dimensions to evaluate the intersection between performance levels and unit
of analysis. For example, a participating organization may want to generate ecient
outputs and eective outcomes (see Boyne 2002). In a dierent unit of analysis, the
collaboration to which that participating organization belongs may aim to perform
actions with ecacy and obtain results with external legitimacy. Here, we assess the
performance of municipal partnership at the municipal level (micro-level) by assess-
ing the municipal eectiveness in rising international aid, which is the purpose (i.e.,
single-purpose), or one of the purposes (i.e., multi-purpose) of the municipal partner-
ship (see Table 1 for a detailed explanation).
1 3
863
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
Whom to Partner with? The Expected Eect of Municipal Partnerships
Voluntary cooperation among governmental jurisdictions holds great potential for
addressing complex problems with a broader scope. While cooperation arrangements
may generate benets by addressing gaps in governance — as existing mechanisms
and institutions fail to produce viable solutions (McKinney et al., 2014) coop-
erating also involves costs in designing, developing, and maintaining the arrange-
ment (Feiock & Scholz, 2010). Some costs include ceding some degree of autonomy,
as well as complying with rules, agendas, strategies, and contributions in time,
resources, and commitment. Thus, institutional arrangements have to overcome col-
lective action problems (Olson, 1965) and the transaction costs of designing, devel-
oping, maintaining, and enforcing the arrangement rules (Feiock, 2013; Woods &
Bowman, 2018). To overcome these costs, cooperation arrangements adapt to miti-
gate their transaction costs, as well as the defection, coordination, free-rider, and
gain-and-cost-division problems.
Performance
Level
Unit of
Analysis
Description
Output
(quantity)
Municipal
partnership
Ecacy translates into
whether the partnership was
able to manage international
cooperation. The quantity of
non-reimbursable international
cooperation (US dollars)
acquired through municipal
partnerships operationalizes
this performance indicator.
Output
(eciency)
Municipal
government
Eciency corresponds to
actions (outputs) with the
highest economic benet and
the lowest political cost (i.e.,
wicksellian-eciency). Non-
reimbursable international
cooperation (US dollars)
increases municipal rev-
enue without imposing extra
charges on the citizenry (e.g.,
municipal taris).
Outcome
(eectiveness)
Target goals The national government’s
goal is to devolve the respon-
sibility to manage interna-
tional cooperation from the
national to the subnational
governments. Eectiveness is
based on the extent to which
more international cooperation
is available at the municipal
level. Again, the quantity of
non-reimbursable international
cooperation (US dollars)
acquired through municipal
partnerships operationalizes
this performance indicator.
Table 1 Performance dimen-
sions to assess Ecuadorian
municipal partnerships
Source: adapted from Breton
(1998), Boyne (2002), and
Emerson & Nabatchi (2015)
1 3
864
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
In a cooperation arrangement, each participant organization contributes relative
strengths and weaknesses. Participants come with dierent motivations, capacity,
and incentives to address collective action problems. Participants’ incentives depend
on severity of the problem/need, scal health, policy preferences, and design of
agreement (Woods & Bowman, 2018). Consequently, the performance eects of an
existing cooperation arrangement should be a function of the group composition.
Homogeneity/heterogeneity of group composition inuence the costs and benets
of cooperation, making “who with whom” crucial (Zamani, 2016). While cooperative
arrangements among governments range widely in terms of policy objectives, they
also vary in composition (Bowman, 2004; Bowman & Woods, 2007; Piña & Avel-
laneda, 2018). Given the growing reliance of governments on multi-jurisdictional
cooperative agreements (Buenger et al., 2016), it is imperative to understand whether
the homogeneity or heterogeneity of group members aects cooperation performance
through the degree of goal attainment.
Inconsistencies exist as to whether cooperation with stronger/weaker peers
(e.g., heterogeneity) or equal peers (e.g., homogeneity) aects performance levels
(Fiol, 1994; Zamani, 2016). The performance eects of group composition have
received considerable attention in the literature on contests by focusing on situa-
tions in which symmetrical groups compete against each other (see Dechenaux et
al., 2015; Sheremeta, 2018, for overviews). There also exists a growing number of
studies investigating the performance eects of various types of asymmetries, includ-
ing group size (Abbink et al., 2010; Ahn et al., 2011), wealth (Heap et al., 2015), and
level of communication (Cason et al., 2017). Assessing performance eects across
various types of asymmetries including size, function, power, resources, repu-
tation, ideology, economic development, level of government, etc. — may explain
inconsistencies of results. Each type of group asymmetry is expected to have dier-
ent eects on cooperation eorts.
In studying inter-group contests, Fallucchi et al., (2020) follow Konrad’s (2009)
standard assumption of purely self-interested individuals to experimentally investi-
gate whether asymmetry or symmetry of group composition (e.g., homogeneous or
heterogeneous) contributes to a group’s success. Fallucchi et al. assumed that group
heterogeneity may increase the free-rider problem, as low-ability players may rest on
their laurels and rely on their high-ability peers’ eort: “within heterogeneous groups
only the member with the highest ability should exert any positive eort (the others
should free ride), while in homogeneous groups there is a continuum of optimal eort
combinations” (Fallucchi et al., 2020, p. 7). Interestingly, ndings of Fallucchi et al.,
(2020) indicate that heterogeneity within groups per se has no discernable eect on
group success.
The nature of group composition also may aect group cohesiveness which, in
turn, should aect performance. According to Deutsch’s (1949) theory of cooperation
and competition, cooperatively interdependent, interpersonal relations among mem-
bers increase “we-feeling’’ or cohesiveness, which in turn may result in ingroup-out-
group bias (Deutsch, 1949; Dion, 1973). However, this line of research has focused
on questions concerning the eects of cooperation and competition between groups
on subsequent relations between and within the groups (Kennedy & Stephan, 1977).
1 3
865
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
This study is interested in comparing performance eects of inter-municipal coop-
eration (a homogenous arrangement) versus inter-governmental cooperation that
involve municipalities and other tiers of government (a heterogeneous arrangement).
Heterogeneous cooperation arrangements should be more successful in mitigating
transaction costs and collective action problems for the following reasons. First,
joined-up governments possess greater technical knowledge, resources, administra-
tive help, and political power. This power translates into more capacity and legiti-
macy to enforce agreement rules. Moreover, because municipalities depend on other
levels of government, localities are expected to build a compliant reputation, thus
reducing the potential behavior of free-rider and promoting group-member cohe-
siveness. In sum, heterogeneous institutions can be expected to provide, on balance,
greater net benets to their participants. Therefore,
Hypothesis 1 Inter-governmental cooperation improves municipal performance
(e.g., in securing international aid) in a higher proportion, compared to inter-munic-
ipal cooperation.
On the other hand, collaborative arrangements between two or more organizations
are likely to pursue ambiguous goals (Rainey & Jung, 2015; Vangen & Huxham,
2012). This is because: (1) participating organizations might have distinct priorities
to invest resources to fulll multiple organizational and collaborative goals, (2) exter-
nal sources might have imposed collaborative goals, and (3) the true purposes to join
a collaboration are unknown or might change over time (Bryson et al., 2016; Chun &
Rainey, 2005; Rainey & Jung, 2015).
Indeed, goals in collaborations have been understood as a paradox in public
administration literature (Vangen & Huxham, 2012). A common driver to establish-
ing successful collaborations is to share core organizational goals that are compatible
with the purpose of the collaboration to facilitate a shared understanding between
participants (Bryson et al., 2015; Emerson et al., 2012). However, reaching a shared
understanding implies reciprocity, trust, and conict management to reconcile dif-
ferent positions. Due to the diculty of accomplishing shared understanding in
collaborative settings, public administration scholars coined the term “mutual under-
standing” to signal that participants in a collaboration do not need to fully agree on
each other’s perspectives to collaborate (Ansell & Gash, 2008; Emerson et al., 2012;
Vangen & Huxham, 2012).
While the relationship between goal ambiguity and collaborative performance is
understudied, the eect of goal ambiguity on an array of organizational outcomes
provided guidance to formulate the second hypothesis in this study. In fact, goal
ambiguity is associated with lower organizational performance (Chun & Rainey,
2005; Favero et al., 2016; Jung, 2011; Latham et al., 2008), increment in turnover
intention, and a reduction in job satisfaction in public sector organizations (Jung,
2014a, b). In an eort to better understand goal ambiguity in public organizations,
Rainey and Jung (2014) proposed a framework to disentangle the sources of goal
ambiguity. Table 2 contains a synthesis of the main elements that contribute to goal
ambiguity and their proposed expected eect on municipal performance.
1 3
866
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
Rainey and Jung (2014) dierentiate between environmental, executive, and
subunits sources to increase goal ambiguity in organizations. This study focuses on
Rainey and Jung propositions for collaborative settings. Specically, collaboration
between other tiers of government can bring dierent sources of democratic account-
ability that could increase the tension between participating organizations about the
prioritization of multiple goals. Furthermore, collaborations without a hierarchical
structure to execute collaborative routines could hinder the coordination and priori-
tization to pursue multiple collaborative goals. Finally, the translation from collab-
orative purpose to operational goals can increase the perceptions of goal ambiguity
for public managers and employees of organizational subunits participating in a
collaborative setting. Collaborating in pursuing more than one goal may result in
managers’ and employees’ prioritization issues, which may be resolved through indi-
vidual-value alignment rather than through organizational-value alignment. Thus, the
second hypothesis for this study can be formulated in the following way:
Hypothesis 2 Municipal partnerships with multiple purposes increase goal ambigu-
ity and are negatively associated with municipal performance (e.g., in securing inter-
national aid).
The Linkage Between International aid Funds and Local Government
Performance: The Ecuadorian case
Local government performance has been comprehensibly analyzed at the organiza-
tional and partnership unit of analysis (Boyne, 2002; Emerson & Nabatchi, 2015).
On the one hand, Emerson & Nabatchi (2015) proposed a matrix for assessing the
Component Factor Subfactor Expected eect
on municipal
performance
Environmental Constitution-
al and Legal
Principles
for Struc-
ture and
Process of
Governance
Democratic
Accountability
Negative
Inuence of
Formal and
Informal
Political
Authorities
Other
Governments
Undetermined
Executive Executive
Delegation
of Authority
Hierarchical
Complexity
Negative
Subunit Man-
ager’s Goal
Ambiguity
(perceived)
Employee’s
Goal Ambiguity
(perceived)
Negative
Table 2 The expected eect of
multiple goals in the perfor-
mance of a collaboration
Note: Adapted from Rainey
and Jung (2014)
1 3
867
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
productivity of collaborative governance regimes (e.g., municipal partnerships) at
dierent levels (e.g., outputs, outcomes) and units of analysis (e.g., participant orga-
nizations, collaboration, target goals). On the other hand, Boyne (2002) described
a comprehensive list of performance indicators for organizations by merging the
inputs-outputs-outcomes (IOO) model and the economy-eciency-eectiveness
(3Es) model.
We applied both the collaborative and organizational approaches to assessing the
performance of the Ecuadorian local governments in this study. In fact, the quantity
of non-reimbursable international cooperation (US dollars) is the variable to opera-
tionalize municipal performance. Table 1 provides three reasons to consider acquiring
more international aid as a valid performance indicator for the Ecuadorian case. First,
municipal governments have the discretion to join municipal partnerships to man-
age international cooperation. Municipal partnerships (i.e., mancomunidades) are
strategies for municipal governments to manage international cooperation after the
Ecuadorian legislation devolved this responsibility (competence) from the national
to the subnational governments (CNC, 2011; CRE, 2008). Second, Ecuadorian law
denes non-reimbursable international cooperation (international aid) as a mecha-
nism to receive resources for contributing to or complementing initiatives to fulll
governmental strategic planning (COPFP, 2010, Art. 65). We argue that municipal
governments seek international aid based on the principles of wicksellian-eciency.
Breton (1998) denes wicksellian eciency as the connection between the costs
(e.g., municipal taris) and benets of public goods: the capacity to generate the
highest economic benet with the lowest political cost. It is dierent from economic
eciency because it does not assume perfect competition since governments have the
capacity to inuence prices (tax-prices) and public goods are not homogeneous. Also,
it is dierent from political eciency because it is not about competition between
politicians and mutually exclusive policies. Thus, the main argument is that political
and economic competition (see Stigler 1972 for a detailed denition) are not indepen-
dent and, in fact, both are necessary to increase wicksellian-eciency.
Finally, the eectiveness of the devolution policy regarding international coop-
eration is conditional on the capacity of local governments to manage international
cooperation, which can be measured by the amount of non-reimbursable interna-
tional cooperation (US dollars) available at the municipal level through municipal
partnerships.
Data and Methods
The above hypotheses will be tested in the context of the 221 Ecuadorian municipali-
ties. The Territorial Organization section in the Ecuadorian Constitution allows sub-
national governments to form “mancomunidades” (inter-governmental cooperation
and/or inter-municipal cooperation) for managing their responsibilities (CRE, 2008,
Art. 243). For example, municipal decentralized autonomous governments (munici-
pal GADs for its acronym in Spanish) could form inter-municipal cooperation to
jointly provide solid waste management to their communities.
1 3
868
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
The Ecuadorian Constitution created the National Council of Competences (CNC
for its acronym in Spanish) to regulate and coordinate the devolution of responsibili-
ties from the national to subnational governments (CRE, 2008, Art. 269). The CNC
is responsible for evaluating the fulllment of the inter-municipal and inter-govern-
mental partnerships (COOTAD, 2010, Art. 287) and keeps administrative records,
including membership and purpose(s) of each partnership. The CNC provided a list
of all the subnational government agreements, along with their memberships and
purposes, registered between 2011 and 2018 after an ocial request (CNC, 2019).
The Ministry of Ecuadorian Foreign Relationships and Human Mobility (MREMH
for its acronym in Spanish) maintains a database with information about international
aid and cooperation based on donors’ reports. After an ocial request, MREMH
provided non-reimbursable international cooperation (international aid) in US dollars
at the municipal level for the 2007–2018 period (MREMH, 2019). Given the nature
of the data, it was possible to identify for each year and for each of the 221 munici-
pal GADs the funds granted and assigned for concept of international aid through
their respective partnerships. This study focuses on the donors’ granted monies that
are not directly given to the municipality but to the municipal partnership. In sum,
the unit of analysis for this study is municipality-year’s total international aid funds
assigned to a given municipality but administered by the respective awarded munici-
pal partnership. It is important to note that it is not possible to dierentiate monies
granted through each inter-municipal and/or inter-governmental agreement but only
the aggregated amount for the concept of municipal partnerships.
Additional data to control for municipal traits came from the Ecuadorian Central
Bank (BCE, 2019), the Ministry of Economy and Finance (MEF, 2019), and the
National Institute of Statistics and Census (INEC, 2019). Data from the BCE and
INEC are publicly available, and MEF provided data related to subnational govern-
ments’ budgets after an ocial request. This study includes information for all 221
Ecuadorian municipalities between 2007 and 2018. The nal database is a balanced
panel with 2,431 municipality-year observations.
Dependent Variable
This study uses the amount of international aid yearly assigned to a municipality
through inter-municipal and/or inter-governmental partnerships whose single pur-
pose or one of multiple purposes is securing international aid. This study measures
the performance of a municipality through its partnership eectiveness. The interna-
tional aid is quantied in US dollars and corresponds to the non-reimbursable monies
granted through international cooperation and registered at the MREMH. As men-
tioned before, it is not possible to assess the performance of individual partnerships
due to unavailable data. The unit of analysis is the “municipal year,” which captures
the aggregated value of international aid channeled through all the municipal partner-
ships, whose single goal or one of their multiple goals is securing international aid.
1 3
869
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
Independent Variables
This study distinguishes the performance of Ecuadorian municipal partnerships
based on their purpose and membership. A municipal partnership can have a single
or multiple purposes. Single purpose means the sole reason to form a partnership
was to manage international cooperation and obtain international aid. Multiple pur-
poses means that managing international cooperation and obtaining international aid
was only one of the partnerships’ purposes or goals. Additional goals or purposes
may include solid waste management, environmental sanitation, and water supply.
A municipality may belong to none, one, or several partnerships. Figure 1 shows an
example of the variation in the number of partnerships within one of the 24 Ecuador-
ian provinces at the municipal level. It could be that municipalities did not have any
partnerships to manage international cooperation and obtain international aid in a
particular year or through the entire period of study (2007–2018). On the other hand,
in our sample 20% of the Ecuadorian municipalities belonged at least to one partner-
ship with the goal of managing international cooperation and securing international
aid.
Because the type of members is a key aspect of a partnership, here we focus on
it. Municipalities can create horizontal and vertical cooperation agreements. On one
hand, inter-municipal cooperation happens when the members of the partnership
are only municipalities, thus illustrating a homogeneous partnership. On the other
Fig. 1 Example of the number of partnerships to manage international cooperation and secure interna-
tional aid at the municipal level in a given Ecuadorian province. Note: Ecuador has 24 provinces. The
gure illustrates the 15 municipalities within the province of Azuay in the Ecuadorian Andean region
1 3
870
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
hand, inter-governmental cooperation includes a more diverse type of members. For
the Ecuadorian case, inter-governmental cooperation includes at least one province
(state-level), one municipality (local-level), and one rural parish (local-rural level) as
members of the partnership.
The number of municipalities participating in a partnership to manage international
cooperation and secure international aid is available in Table 3. Of the 221 Ecuador-
ian municipalities, 84 municipalities joined a partnership during our period of analy-
sis. Inter-municipal cooperation with the single purpose of managing international
cooperation to secure international aid was the most popular type of partnership, as
approximately 55% of participating municipalities joined this type of collaborative
agreement. On the other extreme of the continuum, 14% of participating municipali-
ties joined an inter-governmental agreement with multiple purposes — international
cooperation to secure international aid, in addition to solid waste management, envi-
ronmental sanitation, and water supply. In relative terms, municipalities represent
approximately 36% of the members in the inter-governmental cooperation type of
partnership.
The analysis below includes four dierent types of municipal partnerships. Each
independent variable in Table 4 represents the number of times a municipality has
joined a type of municipal partnership.
Control Variables
During the study’s period of analysis, CNC ocially devolved the responsibility to
manage international cooperation and secure international aid from the national to
subnational governments in September 2011 (CNC, 2011) and implemented since
2012. Therefore, this study controls for this policy change through a dichotomous
indicator, labeled international aid devolution policy, which equals one (1) from 2012
to 2018 and zero (0) otherwise.
In 2013, the Presidential Decree No. 16 introduced unforeseen barriers to civil
society organizations, including international NGOs (PD16, 2013). Civil society
organizations perceived that the national government had a wide range of discre-
tion to renew the legal status of their organizations after Presidential Decree No.16
Inter-municipal Inter-governmental Munici-
palities per
participating
organizations
Single-
purpose
46 20 66 out of 97
Multi-
purpose
612 18 out of 43
Munici-
palities
per
partici-
pating
organi-
zations
52 out of 52 32 out of 88
Table 3 Number of municipali-
ties participating in each type of
partnership as a fraction of total
participating local government
organizations
1 3
871
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
was in place. As a result, several civil society organizations stop their operations in
Ecuador which reduced the amount of international aid available at the subnational
and municipal levels (see Zambrano-Gutiérrez & Avellaneda, C.N., 2021; Zambrano-
Gutiérrez & Avellaneda, C.N., 2022a for a reference). Legal status regulatory policy
captures this contextual change over time, and it is operationalized with a dichoto-
mous indicator equal to one (1) between 2015 and 2018 and zero (0) otherwise.
The CNC provides information about other subnational government partnerships,
unrelated to international aid, that were operating in a municipality. As a result, this
study includes the number of other partnerships in a municipality to control for other
collaborative eorts that could have an eect on collaborative capacity.
The MREMH database identies donors’ country of origin, donor organizations,
as well as the organization at the municipal level that implemented projects with
international aid funds. For example, the origin of the international aid funds could be
the United States, channeled through the USAID and implemented by a municipality.
This study includes an index to capture donor supply using factor analysis. The donor
supply index has an eigenvalue of 2.74, accounting for 92% of the variance for the
donor variables.
Ecuadorian municipalities rely heavily on transfers from the central government
(see Zambrano-Gutiérrez & Avellaneda, C.N., 2022b for a reference). However,
nancial support from the central government varies over time and across munici-
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Source
Dependent variable
International aid (US$
thousand)
0.27 4.60 (MREMH,
2019)
Independent variables
Single-purpose and
inter-municipal
0.13 0.34 (CNC, 2019)
Multi-purpose and
inter-municipal
0.02 0.12 (CNC, 2019)
Single-purpose and
inter-governmental
0.05 0.24 (CNC, 2019)
Multi-purpose and
inter-governmental
0.04 0.19 (CNC, 2019)
Control variables
International aid devolution
policy (yes = 1)
0.58 0.49 (CNC, 2011)
Legal status regulatory policy
(yes = 1)
0.33 0.47 (PD16, 2013)
Central government interna-
tional aid (US$ thousand)
65.47 342.02 (MREMH,
2019)
Other partnerships (#
partnerships)
0.39 0.62 (CNC, 2019)
Supply index 0.0 1.0 (MREMH,
2019)
Fiscal dependency (%) 67.17 14.88 (MEF, 2019)
Gross domestic product (US$
million)
361.71 1771.36 (BCE, 2019)
Population (thousands) 70.59 240.49 (INEC, 2019)
Table 4 Descriptive statistics
1 3
872
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
Table 5 Correlation matrix
Variable 1 23 4 5 678910 11 12 13
1International aid 1
2Single-purpose and inter-municipal -0.0108 1
3Multi-purpose and inter-municipal 0.0383* -0.0496* 1
4 Single-purpose and inter-governmental -0.0088 0.0987* -0.0285 1
5 Multi-purpose and inter-governmental 0.2432* -0.0758* 0.2018* -0.0436* 1
6International aid devolution policy 0.0487* 0.2314* 0.1072* 0.1354* 0.1147* 1
7 Legal status regulatory policy -0.0413* 0.1383* 0.0641* 0.0896* 0.0685* 0.5976* 1
8 Central government international aid 0.0512* -0.0431* -0.0874* 0.0631* 0.0579* -0.1274* -0.3194* 1
9 Other partnerships -0.0281 0.2881* 0.0449* 0.1202* -0.0565* 0.4537* 0.4655* -0.1580* 1
10 Supply index 0.0159 -0.0465* -0.0394 0.2520* -0.0529* 0.0428* -0.0720* 0.4531* -0.0309 1
11 Fiscal dependency 0.0161 0.0529* -0.0798* 0.0317 -0.0168 -0.0965* -0.1387* -0.0881* 0.0111 -0.2114* 1
12 Gross domestic product -0.0055 -0.1266* -0.0614* 0.0171 -0.0627* 0.0838* 0.0699* 0.2264* -0.0473* 0.5305* -0.4414* 1
13 Population 0.0046 -0.0872* -0.0265 -0.0208 -0.0213 0.0129 0.0128 0.1865* -0.0856* 0.6099* -0.2472* 0.5460* 1
Note: * p < 0.05
1 3
873
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
palities. For that reason, the analysis controls for: (1) central transferences as a pro-
portion of the total municipal revenue (i.e., scal dependence), and (2) the level of
international aid secured by the central governments and then redirected to munici-
palities. Finally, the municipal economy’s size (i.e., GDP) and the municipal popu-
lation control for local capacity to acquire international aid funds. Table 4 provides
descriptive statistics and sources for all variables.
Methods
The Variance Ination Factor (VIF:2.14) suggests that multi-collinearity is not an
issue. Moreover, the correlation matrix (Table 5) reports no serious correlations issues
among the explanatory variables. All models in Table 6 used two-way xed eects
regression to analyze within-municipality changes. Municipal xed-eects allow us
to control for observable and unobservable factors that do not change over time. This
is important because current evidence suggests that group size, function, resources,
reputation, ideology, economic development, and location are factors xed over time
but have eects on partnerships (Abbink et al., 2010; Ahn et al., 2011; Heap et al.,
2015). For example, municipalities can join a partnership because of territorial prox-
imity. Additionally, year xed-eects allow us to include over time trends that can
aect cross-sectional time-series. Standard errors are clustered by municipality to
account for potential correlations between observations from the same municipality
during the analysis period. Control variables are lagged one period to improve iden-
tication of models in Table 5.
Findings
Table 6 reports results to examine whether the integration of partnership member-
ship and purpose inuence the municipal eectiveness in securing international
aid. Based on the results, inter-municipal cooperation with a single-purpose and
inter-governmental cooperation with a multi-purpose are positively associated with
municipal eectiveness in securing international aid. However, municipality mem-
bers of inter-governmental partnerships (with partners from dierent tiers of govern-
ment) with multiple purposes were the most eective cases in attaining international
aid funds. In fact, one extra inter-governmental cooperation with multiple purposes
increases by about 45% the level of international aid in a municipality, holding all
else constant. Meanwhile, inter-municipal cooperation was an eective partnership
to secure international aid if the sole purpose of the partnership was to secure and
manage international aid. For each extra inter-municipal partnership with the single
goal of securing international aid, a municipality tended to increase international aid
by approximately 3%.
Although not the focus of this study, the legal status regulatory policy enacted by
the Ecuadorian government in 2015 had a negative eect on the level of international
aid secured by municipalities. Additionally, one standard deviation increased in the
number of inhabitants in a municipality is associated with a 12% increase in interna-
tional aid funds.
1 3
874
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
The supplementary material for this study in Annex 1 contains other model speci-
cations in which each dimension of the municipal partnership is analyzed at a time.
Specically, one model tested the eect of the type of partnerships (inter-municipal
vs. inter-governmental) and another one the eect of purpose (single purpose vs.
multiple purpose). On one hand, inter-governmental cooperation was more eective
for securing international aid than inter-municipal cooperation. For each extra part-
nership involving dierent tiers of government (i.e., province, municipality, and rural
parishes), a municipality increased its international aid by approximately 14%. On
the other hand, multiple purpose cooperation was more eective to raise international
aid, compared to single purpose cooperation. For each extra partnership in which the
purpose was not only to manage international cooperation and secure international
aid but also to accomplish other goals (e.g., solid waste management), a municipality
increased the level of international aid by approximately 27%.
Interna-
tional aid
(logged)
Single-purpose and inter-municipal 0.0317*
(0.0157)
Multi-purpose and inter-municipal 0.0338
(0.0408)
Single-purpose and inter-governmental 0.0017
(0.0182)
Multi-purpose and inter-governmental 0.3738***
(0.0120)
International aid devolution policy 0.0719+
(0.0367)
Legal status regulatory policy -0.1373***
(0.0374)
Central government international aid (logged) -0.0036
(0.0047)
Other partnerships (# partnerships) 0.0241+
(0.0137)
Supply index -0.0088
(0.0158)
Fiscal dependency (%) 0.0003
(0.0007)
Gross domestic product (logged) 0.0010
(0.0206)
Population (thousands) 0.0005**
(0.0002)
Constant -0.0448
(0.1075)
Municipality xed-eects Yes
Year xed-eects Yes
Observations 2431
Municipalities 221
R2(within) 0.0693
Table 6 The eect of type
of members and purpose in
a municipal partnership on orga-
nizational outcomes
Note: control variables lagged
one period
Cluster standard er rors in
parentheses: +p < 0 .10, *p < 0.05,
**p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.
1 3
875
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
Discussion
Both extremes in the continuum of municipal partnerships were successful in
improving municipal performance. Both inter-municipal cooperation with a single
purpose and inter-governmental cooperation with multiple purposes contribute to
increasing municipal international aid. Interestingly, while inter-governmental coop-
eration appears more eective than inter-municipal cooperation, partnerships with
a single purpose do not necessarily outperform partnership with multiple purposes.
Thus, this study’s rst hypothesis is supported. Nevertheless, additional research
should explore whether the superior role of inter-governmental cooperation arrange-
ments applies to other (a) settings, (b) levels of governments, and (c) policy goals,
such as waste management, infrastructural works, environmental management, etc.
Interna-
tional aid
(logged)
Interna-
tional aid
(logged)
Inter-municipal cooperation 0.0265
(0.0200)
Inter-governmental cooperation 0.1336***
(0.0372)
Single-purpose cooperation 0.0199+
(0.0113)
Multi-purpose cooperation 0.2378***
(0.0341)
International aid devolution policy 0.0901*0.0784*
(0.0354) (0.0366)
Legal status regulatory policy -0.1302*** -0.1335***
(0.0373) (0.0373)
Central government international aid
(logged)
-0.0004 -0.0020
(0.0046) (0.0047)
Other partnerships (# partnerships) 0.0139 0.0208
(0.0121) (0.0132)
Supply index -0.0201 -0.0113
(0.0165) (0.0156)
Fiscal dependency (%) 0.0004 0.0004
(0.0007) (0.0007)
Gross domestic product (logged) -0.0163 -0.0057
(0.0183) (0.0192)
Population (thousands) 0.0005** 0.0005***
(0.0002) (0.0002)
Constant 0.0109 -0.0228
(0.0964) (0.1018)
Municipality xed-eects Yes Yes
Year xed-eects Yes Yes
Observations 2431 2431
Municipalities 221 221
R2(within) 0.0589 0.0651
Annex 1 The eect of type
of members and purpose in
a municipal partnership on orga-
nizational outcomes
Note: control variables lagged
one period
Cluster standard er rors in
parentheses: +p < 0 .10, *p < 0.05,
**p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001
1 3
876
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
Likewise, further exploration is needed to determine whether performance eects of
inter-organizational cooperation exhibit a tipping point both in terms of the number
of members and levels of government involved in the partnership.
Unlike the rst hypothesis, our second hypothesis fails to be supported. Findings
suggest that in the Ecuadorian inter-municipal and inter-governmental partnership
contexts, multiplicity of goals seems not to obstruct goal achievement, contrary to
those studies that report a negative relationship between goal ambiguity and organi-
zational performance (Chun & Rainey, 2005; Favero et al., 2016; Jung, 2011; Latham
et al., 2008). In fact, the expectation, based on Rainey and Jung (2014) framework
described in Table 2, was that collaboration with other tiers of government boosts
issue prioritization at the partnership level given multiple interests from dierent
organizations. Issue prioritization at the cooperative arrangement, however, may
increase perceptions of goal ambiguity inside the municipality and, consequently,
municipal performance is negatively aected.
Our contradictory results contribute to the theoretical understanding of goal ambi-
guity in collaborative settings. Our nding calls for further research on the perfor-
mance eects of goal ambiguity in collaborative arrangements pursuing goals in a
dierent policy area to see if the results hold. Securing international aid is a tangible
and visible goal, and this salient nature may mitigate the potential ambiguous eects
of adding more goals to the collaborative arrangement. Therefore, more studies
should explore the performance eects of goal ambiguity in collaboration arrange-
ments in dierent settings, other levels of government, and across other policy areas.
Our study shows evidence that municipal partnerships with multiple purposes and
with members from dierent tiers of government are the most eective strategies
to boost municipal performance in securing foreign aid. Attaining extra revenue at
the local level is a necessity in developing and transitioning economies. Resource
scarcity deprives local governments from delivering so much needed goods and ser-
vices. The Ecuadorian case depicted in this study provides dierent perspectives to
better understand the role of goals and the nature of partners in collaborative regimes.
Moreover, Ecuador is an interesting case because it shows evidence from collabora-
tions that were the result of municipal choice instead of mandates. Thus, it could
be that municipalities that have voluntarily chosen their partners to collaborate on
multiple purposes are less likely to “fail into their role in the collaboration” (Bryson
et al., 2006, p. 45) compared to those municipalities forced to participate in a pre-
determined collaborative arrangement.
Unfortunately, due to data availability, it is impossible to disentangle other dimen-
sions of performance in collaboration. For example, the level of equity is unclear
among participating organizations since it is unknown whether the non-reimbursable
international cooperation was fairly and/or equitable distributed across participating
organizations. For instance, it could be that multiple-purpose partnerships were more
successful because the destination of the international aid funds secured through the
partnership was linked to attaining the other goals of the partnership. For example,
the international aid could be used to improve waste management for all the mem-
bers of the partnership. On the contrary, when the partnership solely exists to secure
and manage international aid, chances are the target and distribution are perceived
by donors to be less transparent. As a result, attaining international aid as a single
1 3
877
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
purpose fails to boost municipal coers in a higher proportion. Finally, further stud-
ies are needed to determine the collaborative governance process of secured monies
from international aid.
Conclusion
This study contributes by applying an integrative framework to predict municipal
performance through cooperation. It extends and expands explanations of collabora-
tion based on goal ambiguity and type of partners. The results also contribute to a
better understanding of collaboration, a trendy strategy and research endeavor that
requires more attention in both developing and transitioning economies. Findings
indicated that the number of goals and type of members aect collaboration out-
comes and thus municipal eectiveness in achieving the pursued goals. In responding
to whom to partner with, our results reveal optimistic implications. Findings suggest
that both inter-municipal (homogenous partners) and inter-governmental cooperation
boost collaboration outcomes and, in turn, municipal performance.
Our results also depict that inter-governmental cooperation targeting multiple
goals is superior to inter-municipal cooperation with a single goal when securing
international aid. In responding to whether single-purpose or multiple-purpose col-
laboration matters, our results suggest that it depends on the nature of the members.
Multi-purpose collaboration overperforms single-purpose collaboration but only
through inter-governmental but not through inter-municipal collaboration. It seems
that heterogeneity in membership brings members with dierent capacities, degrees
of interest, and willingness to bear the costs necessary to attain goals.
We conclude that the nature of partners and the number of goals in a collaborative
arrangement matter for understanding performance in securing international aid both
at the member-level and at the collaboration as a whole (Emerson & Nabatchi, 2015).
Moreover, inter-municipal and inter-governmental collaboration contribute to boost
international aid. However, inter-governmental and multiple purpose collaboration
arrangements outperform inter-municipal and single-purpose collaboration arrange-
ments in increasing international aid. And the enactment of regulations also tends to
decrease municipal eectiveness in securing international aid. Given the emphasis on
maximizing partnership eorts in the public sector, we recommend new research on
collaboration in dierent policy areas, across other settings, and including other lev-
els of government to explore whether our ndings hold. New research may shed light
on whether contingencies exist in the purpose-collaboration and member nature-col-
laboration relationships.
Funding Open Access funding enabled and organized by Projekt DEAL.
Declarations All authors certify that they have no aliations with or involvement in any organization or
entity with any nancial interest or non-nancial interest in the subject matter or materials discussed in
this manuscript.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License,
which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long
1 3
878
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative
Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this
article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line
to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use
is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission
directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/
licenses/by/4.0/.
References
Abbink, K., Brandts, J., Herrmann, B., & Orzen, H. (2010). Intergroup conict and intra-group punishment
in an experimental contest game. American Economic Review, 100(1), 420–447
Agrano, R. (2005). Managing collaborative performance: Changing the boundaries of the state?. Public
Performance & Management Review, 29(1), 18-45.
Ahn, T., Isaac, R. M., & Salmon, T. C. (2011). Rent seeking in groups. International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 29(1), 116–125
Ansell, C., & Gash, A. (2008). Collaborative governance in theory and practice. Journal of Public Admin-
istration Research and Theory, 18(4), 543–571
Bauer, Z., AbouAssi, K., & Johnston, J. (2020). Cross-sector collaboration formality: The eects of institu-
tions and organizational leaders.Public Management Review,1–23
BCE (Banco Central del Ecuador) (2019). Estadísticas Sector Real. Available at: https://contenido.bce.n.
ec/documentos/PublicacionesNotas/Catalogo/CuentasNacionales/Anuales/Dolares/IndiceCtasNac.
htm
Biddle, J. C., & Koontz, T. M. (2014). Goal specicity: A proxy measure for improvements in environ-
mental outcomes in collaborative governance. Journal of Environmental Management, 145, 268–276
Bowman, A. O. (2004). Horizontal federalism: Exploring interstate interactions. Journal of Public Admin-
istration Research and Theory, 14(4), 535–546
Bowman, A. O., & Woods, N. D. (2007). Strength in numbers: Why states join interstate compacts. State
Politics & Policy Quarterly, 7(4), 347–368
Boyne, G. A. (2002). Theme: Local government: Concepts and indicators of local authority performance:
An evaluation of the statutory frameworks in England and Wales. Public Money and Management,
22(2), 17–24
Boyne, G. A. (2003). Sources of public service improvement: A critical review and research agenda. Jour-
nal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 13(3), 367–394
Breton, A. (1998). Competitive governments: An economic theory of politics and public nance. Cam-
bridge University Press
Bryson, J. M., Ackermann, F., & Eden, C. (2016). Discovering collaborative advantage: The contributions
of goal categories and visual strategy mapping. Public Administration Review, 76(6), 912–925
Bryson, J. M., Crosby, B. C., & Stone, M. M. (2006). The design and implementation of Cross-Sector col-
laborations: Propositions from the literature. Public Administration Review, 66, 44–55
Bryson, J. M., Crosby, B. C., & Stone, M. M. (2015). Designing and implementing cross-sector collabora-
tions: Needed and challenging. Public Administration Review, 75(5), 647–663
Buenger, M. L., Litwak, J. B., Masters, R. L., & McCabe, M. H. (2016). The evolving law and use of inter-
state compacts. ABA Section of Administrative Law and Regulatory Practice
Cason, T. N., Sheremeta, R. M., & Zhang, J. (2017). Asymmetric and endogenous within-group communi-
cation in competitive coordination games. Experimental Economics, 20(4), 946–972
Chun, Y. H., & Rainey, H. G. (2005). Goal Ambiguity and Organizational Performance in U.S. Federal
Agencies. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 15(4), 529–557. https://doi.
org/10.1093/jopart/mui030
CNC (Consejo Nacional de Competencias) (2011). Resolución No. 0009-CNC-2011
CNC (Consejo Nacional de Competencias) (2019).Mancomunidades y Consorcios inscritos en el Consejo
Nacional de Competencias
COOTAD (Código Orgánico de Organización Territorial, Autonomía y Decentralización) (2010). Registro
Ocial No.303
COPFP (Código Orgánico de Planicación y Finanzas Públicas) (2010). Registro Ocial No.306.
1 3
879
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
J. C. Zambrano-Gutiérrez, C. N. Avellaneda
CRE (Constitución de la República del Ecuador) (2008). Registro Ocial No.449.
Cuppen, E. (2012). Diversity and constructive conict in stakeholder dialogue: Considerations for design
and methods. Policy Sciences, 45(1), 23–46
Dechenaux, E., Kovenock, D., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2015). A survey of experimental research on contests,
all-pay auctions and tournaments. Experimental Economics, 18(4), 609–669
D. P., Moynihan S., Fernandez S., Kim K. M., LeRoux S. J., Piotrowski B. E., Wright K., Yang (2011)
Performance Regimes Amidst Governance Complexity. Journal of Public Administration Research
and Theory 21(Supplement 1) i141-i155 muq059 10.1093/jopart/muq059
Deutsch, M. (1949). A theory of co-operation and competition. Human Relations, 2(2), 129–152
Dion, K. L. (1973). Cohesiveness as a determinant of ingroup-outgroup bias. Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 28(2), 163
Emerson, K., & Nabatchi, T. (2015). Evaluating the productivity of collaborative governance regimes: A
performance matrix. Public Performance & Management Review, 38(4), 717–747
Emerson, K., Nabatchi, T., & Balogh, S. (2012). An integrative framework for collaborative governance.
Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 22(1), 1–29
Fallucchi, F., Fatas, E., Kölle, F., & Weisel, O. (2020). Not all group members are created equal: Hetero-
geneous abilities in inter-group contests.Experimental Economics,1–29
Favero, N., Meier, K. J., & O’Toole Jr, L. J. (2016). Goals, trust, participation, and feedback: Linking
internal management with performance outcomes. Journal of Public Administration Research and
Theory, 26(2), 327–343
Feiock, R. C. (2013). The institutional collective action framework. Policy Studies Journal, 41(3), 397–425
Feiock, R. C., & Scholz, J. T. (2010). Self-organizing governance of institutional collective action dilem-
mas: An overview.Self-Organizing Federalism: Collaborative Mechanisms to Mitigate Institutional
Collective Action Dilemmas,3–32
Fierlbeck, K. (2010). Public health and collaborative governance. Canadian Public Administration, 53(1),
1–19. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1754-7121.2010.00110.x
Fiol, C. M. (1994). Consensus, diversity, and learning in organizations. Organization Science, 5(3),
403–420
GERMÀ, BEL MILDRED E., WARNER (2015) INTER-MUNICIPAL COOPERATION AND COSTS:
EXPECTATIONS AND EVIDENCE. Public Administration 93(1) 52-67 10.1111/padm.12104
Heap, S. P. H., Ramalingam, A., Ramalingam, S., & Stoddard, B. V. (2015). ‘Doggedness’ or ‘disengage-
ment’? An experiment on the eect of inequality in endowment on behaviour in team competitions.
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 120, 80–93
Horwitz, S. K., & Horwitz, I. B. (2007). The eects of team diversity on team outcomes: A meta-analytic
review of team demography. Journal of Management, 33(6), 987–1015
Hulst, R., & Van Montfort, A. (Eds.). (2007). Inter-municipal cooperation in Europe (Vol. 238). Dordrecht:
Springer.
INEC (Instituto Nacional de Estadísticas y Censos) (2019). Estadísticas. Available at: https://www.ecua-
dorencifras.gob.ec/estadisticas/
Jehn, K. A. (1994). Enhancing eectiveness: An investigation of advantages and disadvantages of value-
based intragroup conict. International Journal of Conict Management, 5(3), 223–238
Jehn, K. A., Northcraft, G. B., & Neale, M. A. (1999). Why dierences make a dierence: A eld study of
diversity, conict and performance in workgroups. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(4), 741–763
Jung, C. S. (2011). Organizational goal ambiguity and performance: Conceptualization, measurement, and
relationships. International Public Management Journal, 14(2), 193–217
Jung, C. S. (2014a). Why are goals important in the public sector? Exploring the benets of goal clarity for
reducing turnover intention. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 24(1), 209–234
Jung, C. S. (2014b). Organizational Goal Ambiguity and Job Satisfaction in the Public Sector. Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory, 24(4), 955–981. https://doi.org/10.1093/jopart/mut020
Keith G., Provan H. Brinton, Milward (2001) Do Networks Really Work? A Framework for Evaluat-
ing Public-Sector Organizational Networks. Public Administration Review 61(4) 414-423
10.1111/0033-3352.00045
Kennedy, J., & Stephan, W. G. (1977). The Eects of Cooperation and Competition on Ingroup-Outgroup
Bias 1. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 7(2), 115–130
Klok, P., Denters, B., Boogers, M., & Sanders, M. (2018). Inter-municipal cooperation in the Netherlands:
The costs and the eectiveness of polycentric regional governance. Public Administration Review,
78(4), 527–536
1 3
880
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
Inter-municipal vs. Inter-governmental Cooperation: Their Impact on…
Latham, G. P., Borgogni, L., & Petitta, L. (2008). Goal setting and performance management in the public
sector. International Public Management Journal, 11(4), 385–403
Matthews, N., & Missingham, B. (2009). Social accountability and community forest management: The
failure of collaborative governance in the Wombat Forest. Development in Practice, 19(8), 1052–1063
McKinney, M. J., Harmon, W., & Johnson, S. (2014). Working across boundaries: People, nature, and
regions. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy
MEF (Ministerio de Economía y Finanzas) (2019). Cédulas Presupuestarias periodo 2008–2018 [Data
set]. Received on 10/07/2019.
MREMH (Ministerio de Relaciones Internacionales y Movilidad Humana) (2019). Cooperación Interna-
tional Database. Received on 10/07/2019.
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard Univer-
sity Press
PD16 (Presidential Decree Nº 16) (2013).Presidencia de la República del Ecuador
Piña, G., & Avellaneda, C. N. (2018). Municipal isomorphism: Testing the eects of vertical and horizon-
tal collaboration. Public Management Review, 20(4), 445–468
Rainey, H. G., & Jung, C. S. (2015). A conceptual framework for analysis of goal ambiguity in public
organizations. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 25(1), 71–99
Reto, Steiner (2003) The causes spread and eects of intermunicipal cooperation and municipal mergers in
Switzerland. Public Management Review 5(4) 551-571 5 10.1080/1471903032000178581
Sean, Nicholson-Crotty Nick A., Theobald Jill, Nicholson-Crotty (2006) Disparate Measures: Public
Managers and Performance-Measurement Strategies. Public Administration Review 66(1) 101-113
10.1111/j.1540-6210.2006.00559.x
Sheremeta, R. M. (2018). Behavior in group contests: A review of experimental research. Journal of Eco-
nomic Surveys, 32(3), 683–704
Siddiki, S., Kim, J., & Leach, W. D. (2017). Diversity, Trust, and Social Learning in Collaborative Gover-
nance. Public Administration Review, 77(6), 863–874. https://doi.org/10.1111/puar.12800
Soukopová, J., & Vaceková, G. (2018). Internal factors of inter-municipal cooperation: What matters most
and why? Local Government Studies, 44(1), 105–126
Stigler, G. J. (1972). Economic competition and political competition.Public Choice,91–106
Vangen, S., & Huxham, C. (2012). The Tangled Web: Unraveling the Principle of Common Goals in
Collaborations. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 22(4), 731–760. https://doi.
org/10.1093/jopart/mur065
Warner, M. E. (2006). Inter-municipal Cooperation in the US: A regional governance solution?. Urban
public economics review, (6), 221-239.
Woods, N. D., & Bowman, A. O. (2018). Collective action and the evolution of intergovernmental coop-
eration. Policy Studies Journal, 46(3), 487–509
Zamani, M. (2016). Cooperative learning: Homogeneous and heterogeneous grouping of Iranian EFL
learners in a writing context. Cogent Education, 3(1), 1149959
Zambrano, J. C., & Avellaneda, C. N. (2021). The Eect of Regulatory Burden on the Eectiveness of
Intergovernmental Collaborations: The Case of Subnational Partnerships for Managing International
Cooperation. Revista Brasileira de Políticas Públicas e Internacionais, 6(3), 22–49
Zambrano-Gutiérrez, J. C., & Avellaneda, C. N. (2022a). The (un) intended Eects of Regulatory Burden
on Policy Eectiveness: The Case of Regulations Targeting NGOs. Journal of Policy Studies, 37(1),
15–25
Zambrano-Gutiérrez, J. C., & Avellaneda, C. N. (2022b). Municipal response to scal and governance
reforms: Eects of stricter debt limits across jurisdictions. International Journal of Public Adminis-
tration, 45(7), 590–603
Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps
and institutional aliations.
1 3
881
Content courtesy of Springer Nature, terms of use apply. Rights reserved.
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Terms and Conditions
Springer Nature journal content, brought to you courtesy of Springer Nature Customer Service Center
GmbH (“Springer Nature”).
Springer Nature supports a reasonable amount of sharing of research papers by authors, subscribers
and authorised users (“Users”), for small-scale personal, non-commercial use provided that all
copyright, trade and service marks and other proprietary notices are maintained. By accessing,
sharing, receiving or otherwise using the Springer Nature journal content you agree to these terms of
use (“Terms”). For these purposes, Springer Nature considers academic use (by researchers and
students) to be non-commercial.
These Terms are supplementary and will apply in addition to any applicable website terms and
conditions, a relevant site licence or a personal subscription. These Terms will prevail over any
conflict or ambiguity with regards to the relevant terms, a site licence or a personal subscription (to
the extent of the conflict or ambiguity only). For Creative Commons-licensed articles, the terms of
the Creative Commons license used will apply.
We collect and use personal data to provide access to the Springer Nature journal content. We may
also use these personal data internally within ResearchGate and Springer Nature and as agreed share
it, in an anonymised way, for purposes of tracking, analysis and reporting. We will not otherwise
disclose your personal data outside the ResearchGate or the Springer Nature group of companies
unless we have your permission as detailed in the Privacy Policy.
While Users may use the Springer Nature journal content for small scale, personal non-commercial
use, it is important to note that Users may not:
use such content for the purpose of providing other users with access on a regular or large scale
basis or as a means to circumvent access control;
use such content where to do so would be considered a criminal or statutory offence in any
jurisdiction, or gives rise to civil liability, or is otherwise unlawful;
falsely or misleadingly imply or suggest endorsement, approval , sponsorship, or association
unless explicitly agreed to by Springer Nature in writing;
use bots or other automated methods to access the content or redirect messages
override any security feature or exclusionary protocol; or
share the content in order to create substitute for Springer Nature products or services or a
systematic database of Springer Nature journal content.
In line with the restriction against commercial use, Springer Nature does not permit the creation of a
product or service that creates revenue, royalties, rent or income from our content or its inclusion as
part of a paid for service or for other commercial gain. Springer Nature journal content cannot be
used for inter-library loans and librarians may not upload Springer Nature journal content on a large
scale into their, or any other, institutional repository.
These terms of use are reviewed regularly and may be amended at any time. Springer Nature is not
obligated to publish any information or content on this website and may remove it or features or
functionality at our sole discretion, at any time with or without notice. Springer Nature may revoke
this licence to you at any time and remove access to any copies of the Springer Nature journal content
which have been saved.
To the fullest extent permitted by law, Springer Nature makes no warranties, representations or
guarantees to Users, either express or implied with respect to the Springer nature journal content and
all parties disclaim and waive any implied warranties or warranties imposed by law, including
merchantability or fitness for any particular purpose.
Please note that these rights do not automatically extend to content, data or other material published
by Springer Nature that may be licensed from third parties.
If you would like to use or distribute our Springer Nature journal content to a wider audience or on a
regular basis or in any other manner not expressly permitted by these Terms, please contact Springer
Nature at
onlineservice@springernature.com
Conference Paper
Full-text available
For the sustainable competitiveness of the country and the development of economic security, it is of particular importance to significantly improve the blocks of economic sustainability and resource efficiency, by ensuring the knowledge factor and the adoption of digital technologies.
Article
Full-text available
The idea of governance has permeated the debates on the state’s transformation at the regional level since the 1990s. However, operationalization difficulties have limited our knowledge of the phenomenon. This article contributes to filling this gap by examining the inter-jurisdictional dimension of regional governance. From a network perspective, the article studies the emergence of inter-municipal networks from different local collaborative mechanisms. Based on the institutional collective action framework, the study analyzes the prevalence of network structures associated with different types of social capital (bonding/bridging) in three inter-municipal networks in the Los Lagos Region in Chile. The application of exponential random graph models (ERGM) revealed evidence supporting the consistent prevalence of bonding in the three networks studied. The findings also showed the networks’ coexistence with structures decentralized in more complex regional networks.
Article
Full-text available
Desde los noventa, la idea de gobernanza ha permeado los debates acerca de la transformación del Estado a escala regional, sin embargo, las dificultades de su operacionalización han limitado nuestro conocimiento. Este articulo busca contribuir con esta brecha, examinando la dimensión interjurisdiccional de la gobernanza regional. Aplicando la perspectiva de análisis de redes, se estudia la formación de las redes intermunicipales que se configuran a partir de diferentes mecanismos de colaboración. Con base en el marco de acción colectiva institucional, el articulo analiza la prevalencia de estructuras de relacionamiento asociadas a diferentes tipos de capital social (bonding – capital social vinculo ‒ y bridging – capital social puente ‒) en tres redes intermunicipales de la región de Los Lagos, en Chile. Por medio de la aplicación de modelos de grafos aleatorios exponenciales (ERGM), se obtiene evidencia para sustentar la consistente prevalencia de bonding en las tres redes estudiadas y su coexistencia con estructuras descentralizadas en las redes de mayor complejidad regional.
Article
Full-text available
With the goal of improving effectiveness and efficiency, worldwide cross-sector collaboration has become a central governance arrangement. Given this trend, research has focused on illustrating examples of collaborations over time and/or identifying collaboration's drivers and effects. Yet, as cross-sector collaborations are more prevalent, governments have changed the rules for civil society organizations to become part of cross-sector collaboration across policy domains. While some regulations can be seen as a precondition to start a collaboration, over-regulated contexts can become a burden for participating organizations, thus hindering collaboration sustainability. However, little knowledge exists as to how regulatory changes influence performance effects of cross-sector collaboration. To fill this gap, this research focuses on all the 2007-2018 Ecuadorian subnational partnerships that manage international cooperation to test whether adoption of further regulations or regulatory burden targeting civil society organizations compromises the amount of international aid subnational governments secure. We also expect that the economic diversity in a jurisdiction amplifies the performance effects of regulatory burden. Findings suggest that regulatory burden negatively influenced governance capacity to obtain international aid, particularly in jurisdictions with high economic diversity.
Article
Full-text available
Existing studies see foreign donors as (a) brokers between sustainable development goals (SDGs) and aid-recipient countries’ needs, or (b) intruders into aid-recipient countries’ internal affairs. The intruder view has triggered regulations of NGOs (nongovernmental organizations) in aid-recipient countries. However, little is known, empirically, about how foreign donors respond to regulatory burden. We suggest regulatory burden adds uncertainty and turbulence to the operating context, negatively affecting government effectiveness in securing aid. This negative effect is moderated by the number of foreign donors operating in a jurisdiction. Propositions are tested in a data set derived from the 221 Ecuadorian municipalities during 2007-2018. Findings suggest regulations of NGOs have decreased municipalities’ ability to secure international cooperation. This negative effect is larger in municipalities with a higher presence of donor supply. These results encourage policy makers to consider counterproductive costs of overregulating foreign NGOs and other civil society organizations when designing regulatory tools.
Article
Full-text available
The effectiveness of fiscal rules in limiting governmental indebtedness and expenditures has mixed results. This inconclusiveness may suggest debt-limit effects on fiscal outcomes may be moderated by other factors. Although literature has addressed the moderating effects government size has on fiscal outcomes, scarce research has done so with the type of jurisdictions making up a unit of government. Consequently, this study tests whether the type (e.g., urban and rural vs. urban) of administrative jurisdictions moderates the effect of debt limits on municipal debt and spending. Results confirm that municipalities with different types of jurisdictions increase both level of indebtedness and investment expenditure, despite a stricter debt limit being in place.
Article
Full-text available
Competition between groups is ubiquitous in social and economic life, and typically occurs between groups that are not created equal. Here we experimentally investigate the implications of this general observation on the unfolding of symmetric and asymmetric competition between groups that are either homogeneous or heterogeneous in the ability of their members to contribute to the success of the group. Our main finding is that relative to the benchmark case in which two homogeneous compete against each other, heterogeneity within groups per se has no discernable effect on competition, while introducing heterogeneity between groups leads to a significant intensification of conflict as well as increased volatility, thereby reducing earnings of contest participants and increasing inequality. We further find that heterogeneous groups share the labor much more equally than predicted by theory, and that in asymmetric contests group members change the way in which they condition their efforts on those of their peers. Implications for contest designers are discussed.
Article
Full-text available
This study tests whether vertical and horizontal collaborative arrangements generate organizational isomorphic pressures. Using neo-institutional theory, we explore whether local governments emulate their peers when they are (1) bound through collaborative agreements/associations (mimetic pressures), and/or (2) scrutinized by central government through a vertical agreement (coercive pressures). Municipal isomorphism is measured by municipality-dyad convergence across time based on: (1) the number of central-government grant applications submitted by municipalities and (2) use of information technologies. We test for changes in divergence between dyads on these measures using data from all possible dyads generated from 207 Chilean municipalities over 10 years (2005–2014). After controlling for potential confounding factors, findings show mimetic and coercive pressures, from horizontal and vertical forms of governance, reduce a municipal dyad’s divergence in terms of grant applications and use of information technologies. However, collaboration effects on municipal isomorphism are contingent on the type of collaboration. While formal municipal agreements increase a municipal dyad’s convergence, municipal associations unexpectedly seem to decrease it.
Article
This research examines collaboration formality as a function of institutional characteristics of organizations as well as personal characteristics of their leaders, in a non-Western context. Using a dataset of local governments and non-profits in Lebanon, we find organizations characterized by resource insufficiency and large staff size, and whose leaders have experience in the other sector to be motivated to use formal arrangements in cross-sectoral collaboration; those with female leaders opt for informal arrangements. A variety of characteristics of both institutions and their leaders affect formality of collaboration arrangements used by local governments and non-profits; yet, these effects exhibit cross-sector heterogeneity.
Article
This article examines the effects of the structure of intermunicipal cooperatives (IMCs) on the perceived transaction costs and benefits of IMCs. Hypotheses based on a polycentric theory of regional governance are tested using data from Dutch municipalities. The findings are mixed. In line with polycentric theory, networks characterized by a multiplicity of territorial scales reduce IMC transaction costs. Contrary to polycentric theory, however, if IMCs are organized under a uniform legal regime, lower costs and higher benefits are reported. Structural factors that dominate the debate between polycentrism and monocentrism prove to be of limited importance. On the other hand, the results indicate support for the hypotheses that intermunicipal trust (as a cultural variable) contributes to perceptions of effective and efficient cooperation.