ArticlePDF Available

Enhancing Sustainability in a Government-Contracted Mobility-as-a-Service Model

Authors:

Abstract

This discussion paper revises the government-contracted Mobility-as-a-Service (MaaS) model by Wong et al. (1), by making the contracting entity maintaining the mobility system’s sustainability, likely to enhance sustainability compared to the current state. The achievement of sustainability objectives is ensured by dynamic transport mode pricing based on the total sum of each trip’s internal and external costs. By combining government-contracting and sustainability objectives, MaaS can overcome the most critical regulatory and operational challenges in the implementation process, such as the lack of incentives for active mobility and cooperation between public and private companies. To implement such a system, we propose a four-step approach, with policy mechanisms changing from information-based to mainly regulatory and economic (2). The initial goal is a journey planning tool that transparently shows time, distance, emissions, and full costs of a trip for a chosen transport mode and recommends more sustainable alternatives. The full version offers mobility bundles and budget solutions including ticketing, combined with full cost transport pricing that takes into consideration space-time dynamics. However, the proposed approach cannot overcome all the risks involved in a MaaS implementation. Individual user behavior is difficult to predict and part in the evaluation of this concept. The goal of this proposed MaaS model is to improve environmental and social sustainability by changing transport prices in relation to the full costs. This paper contributes to the recently started nine-year MCube mobility research cluster project, which aims to develop and test a MaaS model for the metropolitan region of Munich.
Enhancing Sustainability in a Government-Contracted Mobility-as-a-Service Model
1
2
First Author:
3
Daniel Schröder
4
Institute of Automotive Technology
5
Technical University of Munich, Garching, Germany, 85748
6
Email: schroeder@ftm.mw.tum.de
7
8
Second Authors:
9
Julia Kinigadner
10
Chair of Urban Structure and Transport Planning
11
Technical University of Munich, Munich, Germany, 80333
12
Email: julia.kinigadner@tum.de
13
14
Allister Loder
15
Chair of Traffic Engineering and Control
16
Technical University of Munich, Munich, Germany, 80333
17
Email: allister.loder@tum.de
18
19
Raoul Rothfeld
20
Chair of Transportation Systems Engineering
21
Technical University of Munich, Munich, Germany, 80333
22
Email: raoul.rothfeld@tum.de
23
24
Word Count: 4873 words
25
26
27
Submitted 29th July 2021
28
29
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
2
ABSTRACT
1
This discussion paper revises the government-contracted Mobility-as-a-Service (MaaS) model by Wong
2
et al. (1), by making the contracting entity maintaining the mobility system’s sustainability, likely to
3
enhance sustainability compared to the current state. The achievement of sustainability objectives is
4
ensured by dynamic transport mode pricing based on the total sum of each trip’s internal and external
5
costs. By combining government-contracting and sustainability objectives, MaaS can overcome the most
6
critical regulatory and operational challenges in the implementation process, such as the lack of incentives
7
for active mobility and cooperation between public and private companies. To implement such a system,
8
we propose a four-step approach, with policy mechanisms changing from information-based to mainly
9
regulatory and economic (2). The initial goal is a journey planning tool that transparently shows time,
10
distance, emissions, and full costs of a trip for a chosen transport mode and recommends more sustainable
11
alternatives. The full version offers mobility bundles and budget solutions including ticketing, combined
12
with full cost transport pricing that takes into consideration space-time dynamics. However, the proposed
13
approach cannot overcome all the risks involved in a MaaS implementation. Individual user behavior is
14
difficult to predict and part in the evaluation of this concept. The goal of this proposed MaaS model is to
15
improve environmental and social sustainability by changing transport prices in relation to the full costs.
16
This paper contributes to the recently started nine-year MCube mobility research cluster project, which
17
aims to develop and test a MaaS model for the metropolitan region of Munich.
18
19
Keywords: Mobility-as-a-Service, sustainability, transportation governance, MCube
20
21
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
3
INTRODUCTION
1
Until now, research into Mobility-as-a-Service (MaaS) has focused on its potential positive
2
impacts on the efficiency and sustainability of transport networks in metropolitan regions (35). These
3
positive aspects provide benefits to three distinct stakeholders, as follows:
4
Users: Access to flexible, personalized, on-demand mobility and seamless door-to-door travel.
5
Public sector: Improvements in the effectiveness and sustainability of the holistic transport
6
system, growth in employment and gross domestic product generated by new businesses.
7
Businesses: Creation of profitable markets for new transport services, new opportunities for
8
conventional transport and infrastructure businesses through innovative service concepts and co-
9
operations.
10
However, recent literature also points out several challenges and unanticipated implications of
11
MaaS, especially when discussion only focuses on its potential benefits rather than taking a more
12
comprehensive approach (4, 69).
13
In addition to such positive and negative effects, it is also necessary to define the MaaS system’s
14
objective and determine what it is supposed to be capable of. The literature provides a variety of standard
15
MaaS definitions, as summarized by Cruz et al. (10). This study uses the following definition, as laid
16
down by the House of Commons Transport Committee (11):
17
“MaaS is a term used to describe digital service, often smartphone apps, which people use to
18
access a range of public, shared, and private transport, using a system that integrates the planning,
19
booking and paying for travel”
20
In this paper, we extend this definition with features of a government-contracted MaaS model that
21
pursues the objective of sustainability. The concept further develops an idea presented by Wong et al. (1)
22
that is reproduced in Figure 1.
23
24
25
Figure 1 Mobility-as-a-Service under government contracting (1)
26
27
The figure illustrates a government-contracted MaaS implementation model. Like any MaaS
28
concept, it is intended to supply accessibility using multiple modes of transport. Additionally, the
29
government directly procures a mobility broker. Individual transport mode pricing can be implemented
30
and complemented by internal cross-subsidization or, where necessary, with financial support from the
31
public. It regulates network efficiency by incorporating a road user charge, while general pricing
32
(mobility subscriptions or credit packages) depends on a trip’s time of day (real time), geography
33
(location and road type) and modal (both spatial and temporal) properties. Other inputs such as
34
environmental and social considerations can also be included and are considered in this paper. In general,
35
the government-contracted MaaS model is a demand management concept that aims to provide societal
36
benefits.
37
Demanders Broker/
Aggregator Suppliers
Government
Subscriptions
Mobility packages
Mobility contracts
Asset/ Capacity
Accessibility delivery
Accessibility contracts
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
4
This paper seeks to continue and expand on the ideas of Wong et al. (1) regarding a government-
1
contracted MaaS model, combined with governmental sustainability objectives. It does this by
2
internalizing social and external costs of mobility options to the individual trip level. It discusses the
3
features, implementation steps, and requirements of such a new MaaS concept. The task and research
4
question of this discussion paper is to discuss the key features, implementation steps, and requirements of
5
a government-contracted MaaS model, in which the government pursues the objective of sustainability.
6
The concept is known in its abbreviated form as SuGov-MaaS.
7
After the introduction, the extensive literature review points out and categorizes the key
8
challenges of the MaaS implementation. The next section describes the features and the implementation
9
process of the presented MaaS model. Finally, the risks and benefits of the model are discussed, and the
10
paper concluded. This is the first paper of a research series focusing on MaaS in combination with full
11
cost-related pricing methods. Subsequent studies will reveal data, results and trials of the presented MaaS
12
model within a larger research cluster with the name of MCube. “MCube – Munich Cluster for the Future
13
of Mobility in Metropolitan Regions” is part of the BMBF (Federal Ministry of Education and Research
14
of Germany) clusters4future initiative and will receive 45 million euros in funding over the next nine
15
years.
16
17
CHALLENGES FACING MAAS
18
After conducting an extensive literature review on the subject of MaaS, we filtered the most
19
relevant papers in terms of the challenges of implementing MaaS and categorized and ranked them. The
20
ranking is based on assessments by well-known MaaS authors and frequency of occurrence. Accordingly,
21
the literature suggests six notable categories of MaaS challenges. The categories are in order of severity:
22
technical, individual, social, economic, operational, and regulatory (see Figure 2).
23
24
25
Figure 2 Overview of MaaS challenges
26
27
From a technical point of view, MaaS as defined in the introduction is already a relevant
28
product for the regional transport market. Safe transactions (10), unified data formats, and high data
29
quality (12) are all important aspects that need to be taken into consideration when developing a MaaS
30
application.
31
When it comes to implementing MaaS products, individual user behavior is a crucial element of
32
the system’s success. Hensher et al. (13) and Jittrapirom et al. (4) state that the key challenge for MaaS is
33
to attract users and motivate them beyond the stage of early adopters. It is hard to change the behavior of
34
users who are familiar with current solutions (14). This is especially true when insufficient marketing
35
information means that users are not aware of what impact the external and social costs of local
36
transportation options has (10). Even though the number of driving licenses among young cohorts in
37
Germany is declining, the rate of private car ownership has recently increased (15). Furthermore, most
38
Technical Transaction safety, data handling
Individual User motivation, awareness, social ties, personal preferences, willingness to pay
Social Equity, demographics (age, gender, income), MaaS communication and rhetoric
Economic Mobility market: global and local competition, exclusion, monopolies
Operational Cooperation of operators (public vs. private), profitability vs. sustainability, customization
Regulatory Data privacy and property, public infrastructure, interoperability, complexity
Severity
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
5
people around the world still want to own a car, according to Mulley (14), pointing out that for a MaaS
1
system to be successful, attitudes towards car ownership need to be changed (14).
2
It is not only on the individual but also on the societal level that there are significant challenges to
3
MaaS implementation. For example, Pangbourne et al. (6) reported that communication and rhetoric on the
4
subject of MaaS are too positive and that the problems associated with MaaS are not sufficiently addressed.
5
This can lead to unanticipated outcomes, with the result that change is no longer possible (6). Problems
6
related to the exclusion of people who do not have a bank account or a smartphone could pose substantial
7
threats to equity in society. This applies in particular to poor and old people (6). An understanding of
8
customer needs is related to demographics (age, gender, income) and psychographics (interests, opinions,
9
attitudes, values) (16). Equitable MaaS systems need to be able to fulfil the needs of diverse user groups.
10
On an economic level, it is important to know who has control of the MaaS app (10). There will be
11
enormous competition between potential MaaS providers and other travel application providers such as
12
public transport authorities, established companies and local governments and start-ups (10). If private
13
companies will be the sole MaaS broker, there will be a risk of a monopoly (6). This risk will be even higher
14
(10) in the case of a large company that cooperates with global data handlers (Google, Apple, Amazon) and
15
controls mobility pricing (8). This could lead to exclusion from the free market due to exclusive data
16
ownership and relationships (6), ultimately resulting in a negative impact on competition and a threat to
17
innovation itself (12).
18
An additional challenge lies in the cooperation between transport operators and service providers.
19
Willingness to cooperate can be affected by a lack of trust and an unequal distribution of power between
20
the operators (1). In particular, the conflicting objectives of private and public service providers can lead to
21
highly complex partnerships (4, 10). Monitoring contract flexibility (10), agreement on pricing (8) and the
22
allocation of revenue to each transport operator (14) are some of the most critical sources of conflict.
23
Partnerships between private and public operators involve a change of identity on both sides. Private
24
companies generally act on a national or global level and impede developments towards open-source
25
standards (12) while public transport is controlled by local governments (1). With MaaS, public authorities
26
face a dilemma due to decreases in monopoly and economies of scale (4).
27
Not only the cooperation between operators but also the MaaS operation itself creates several
28
challenges. Most operational challenges are related to the commercial success and profitability of the
29
operation, leading to an increase in the volume of trips and traffic rather than the desired reduction (6).
30
Additionally, an operation that focuses solely on commercial, monetary success would be unlikely to
31
promote active and healthy transport options (such as cycling and walking), since it does not take social
32
costs into consideration (6). Lyons et al. (8) determines a distinct conflict of interest between making a
33
profit and offering sustainability and equity. This is why Wong et al. realize that financial support and social
34
cost considerations are needed for a successful MaaS application (1). This and other conceptual
35
requirements are discussed in the next section.
36
The most acute challenges that MaaS faces are of a regulatory nature. The regulations relating to
37
digital platforms, including data privacy and data property, need to be adapted (10). At the same time,
38
public infrastructure changes are required and investments have to be made, while a legally compliant third-
39
party ticket selling framework also has to be established (12). The necessary interoperability and
40
information sharing between local governments, public transport authorities and private companies render
41
urban mobility governance with MaaS even more complex (6, 10). So far, mobility governance in urban
42
areas is highly mode-specific and operator-focused and, thus, not customer-oriented (6).
43
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
6
Coping with regulatory issues and generating revenue while being sustainable are key challenges
1
to be addressed by MaaS. It is against this background that Wong et al.’s government-contracted MaaS
2
model (Figure 1) will be conceptualized in the next section and further developed with the addition of
3
sustainability objectives.
4
5
SUGOV-MAAS CONCEPT
6
7
Features
8
Recent MaaS approaches have proven unsuitable due to the challenges involved. Wong et al. (1)
9
took the first step towards a new approach by bringing MaaS under a system of government contracting
10
(Figure 1). The features of their adaptation are presented in the introduction to this paper. Given that it is
11
unlikely to achieve the objective of sustainability, this section develops additional features for a
12
government-contracted MaaS with an integrated sustainability objective (SuGov-MaaS), as illustrated in
13
Figure 3.
14
15
16
Figure 3 Government-contracted MaaS with a sustainability objective
17
18
Figure 3 is an expansion of Figure 1 with additional elements to show the implementation of a
19
sustainability objective. In addition to accessibility standards (1), the government sets sustainability
20
standards, which can be defined, for instance, as delivering a certain percentage of low-emission transport
21
in the interest of environmental sustainability. This can be achieved by combining the pricing of the
22
individual modes of transport with the full cost calculations to achieve full cost transport pricing that
23
takes into consideration space-time dynamics.
24
25
𝐶𝑓𝑢𝑙𝑙 = 𝐶𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑛𝑎𝑙 + 𝐶𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑛𝑎𝑙 (1)
26
27
For the purpose of this paper, full costs 𝐶𝑓𝑢𝑙𝑙 are defined as the total sum of all internal costs
28
𝐶𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑛𝑎𝑙 and external costs 𝐶𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑛𝑎𝑙 incurred by a mode of transport (see Equation 1). External or social
29
costs describe all costs incurred through the use of a certain transport mode that users are not directly
30
aware of and that are not covered by their expenditures. These costs relate to, for example, environmental
31
damage, the health care system due to accidents or noise, land usage and many other factors. Future
32
studies will focus on the detailed definition and determination of external cost parameters, as interpreted
33
for the concept presented here. Internal costs comprise all those costs that the consumer is directly
34
Demanders Broker/
Aggregator Suppliers
Government
Subscriptions
Mobility packages
Mobility contracts
Asset/ Capacity
Accessibility & sustainability delivery
Accessibility contracts
+
Sustainability contracts
Full cost
calculator
Provides data for space-
time road pricing based
on full costs
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
7
concerned with. The internal costs incurred by most modes of transport have been covered in previous
1
work (17).
2
However, these costs depend greatly on location and time frame as well as on the mode of
3
transport. The full cost calculator is thus a dynamic, multimodal routing application that is able to
4
calculate total costs for each transport mode and recommend routes and transport modes that incur the
5
lowest full costs and thus represent the most sustainable trip. Active modes of travel frequently represent
6
the most sustainable alternative for short trips. This is why the government has to be able to cross-
7
subsidize or incentivize active travel modes such as walking and cycling in the MaaS application. This
8
can be achieved by introducing mobility budgets and limits to the application. Further details of this are
9
presented in the next section.
10
Governments can use this version of MaaS as a transport management tool and improve transport
11
efficiency and sustainability while considering social equity. Mobility management and pricing should
12
not be left to the open market or private companies. Rather, local governments should be responsible for
13
strategic transport planning and steering activities.
14
15
16
Implementation process
17
The development of government-contracted MaaS, as presented in the section above, requires a
18
structured framework. The implementation process can be divided into four levels, each representing a
19
step in the development towards the final government-contracted MaaS application, with an integrated
20
sustainability objective (Level 4 = SuGov-MaaS), that can be used as a transport network management
21
tool (Figure 4). According to Axsen et al.’s (2) categorization of policy mechanisms, the levels evolve
22
from being mainly information-based to mainly regulatory in Level 3 and mainly economic in Level 4.
23
The mechanisms are described in detail in the following.
24
25
26
Figure 4 Implementation levels for a government-contracted MaaS with a sustainability objective
27
28
In Level 1, a full cost calculator is developed as a web-based implementation. It includes a
29
function for routing from a chosen start point or current location to a chosen destination within a specific
30
region. Travel time, distance, emissions and full costs, including internal and external costs, are calculated
31
for the mode and route chosen, and shown transparently in the application. The user is given information
32
about alternative transport modes and routes, while a routing algorithm recommends more sustainable,
33
faster or lower-emission options. Dynamic routing is based on live data for each transport mode. For this
34
purpose, the web-tool is connected to the relevant operator’s interface as well as other application
35
programming interfaces (APIs) for live data (train arrival, shared vehicle locations, congested roads, etc.).
36
Level
1
Level
3
Level
2
Level
4
Full cost calculator
Standard MaaS platform
Government-contracted MaaS platform with
sustainability objective
Optimized government-contracted MaaS platform
with sustainability objective
Policy mechanisms
Mainly information-based
Mainly regulatory
Mainly economic
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
8
Schröder and Gotzler (18) used a similar approach and analyzed routes with randomized origin-
1
destination matrices in the metropolitan region of Munich (Figure 5).
2
3
4
Figure 5 Schematic illustration of the full cost calculator with example cost, time, distance and
5
emission calculations for different transport modes from (18)
6
7
Level 2 adds transactions and ticketing to the routing and planning mechanisms of Level 1. By
8
integrating these adaptations, it now represents a standard MaaS platform with extended planning
9
functions and full cost calculations. Operational and transactional integration is for all transport modes
10
and services in the region. Service and ticket prices are mainly defined by the operators, and intermodal
11
trips can be planned and paid for in the mobile application. The payment model is pay-as-you-go
12
(PAYG).
13
14
Figure 6 Schematic illustration of example Level 3 MaaS functionalities
15
16
In Level 3, the local government directly procures the mobility broker, as described in the
17
introduction, with the government-contracted MaaS model by Wong et al. (1). Dynamic pricing
18
mechanisms according to the time of day, geography (location and road type), modal properties (spatial
19
and temporal) and full costs are all integrated. Active and sustainable mobility according to full cost
20
calculations are promoted and incentivized based on the sustainability objectives of the government. The
21
pay model is still PAYG. Figure 6 shows an example scenario of functionalities in Level 3. The same trip
22
Time
Distance
Costs
Emissions
A
B
12.4 km
64 min
3.30 €
720 g
*Medium sized car with gasoline engine and 15k km annual mileage
*
6.86 €
3409 g
18.2 km
22 min
2.50 €
3.50 €
A
B
Monday, 8 am
A
B
Sunday, 2 pm
2.00
5.50
ticket
ticket
ticket
ticket
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
9
is planned for 2 pm on Sunday and 8 am on Monday. On the Sunday, the prices of trips by car enforced
1
by road tolls, or by public transport, are solely based on the static full costs of each transport mode. On
2
the Monday, the live data of the city traffic shows a high level of activity on streets and public railway
3
transport, which influences the dynamic full costs. Stop-and-go traffic increases the full costs due to
4
higher vehicle consumption and emission rates. The full costs of public railway transport decrease,
5
however, due to higher occupancy rates and, in turn, higher efficiency.
6
In the system’s ultimate form, a new mobility coin currency may be introduced in order to
7
decouple real-world currency from the dynamic prices in the MaaS application (19). This includes
8
additional pay and subscription models, mobility packages, and product bundles to increase the system’s
9
attractiveness to customers. Bundles and budget plans also offer new control opportunities for the
10
government. One example of a control mechanism is the introduction of a mobility budget for every
11
citizen, which limits access to non-sustainable transport modes but not to sustainable ones. Budget trading
12
is an option for increasing the available budget. Figure 7 shows an example scenario of the functionalities
13
in Level 4. At this level, the user has a certain weekly or monthly mobility coin budget, which increases
14
or decreases depending on the sustainability, time and location of the selected transport mode. At the end
15
of the time period, budget trading can take place. Any remaining budget can be sold, or, if it is depleted,
16
additional budget purchased.
17
18
Figure 7 Schematic illustration of example level 4 MaaS functionalities
19
20
The different levels of the implementation process utilize different kind of policy instruments.
21
While the first two rely primarily on information-based schemes, Level 3 and 4 use regulatory and
22
economic instruments. Level 3 tries to internalize external costs in the Pigouvian sense, which places
23
several limitation on the transportation systems (20, 21). For example, the market is large with many
24
different actors and transaction costs between the polluter and the polluted leading to the problem of who
25
exactly imposes congestion on whom. In other words, based on the Coase theorem, the “polluter pays”
26
principle of Pigou is not applicable to the complexity of a regional transport network. It is for this reason
27
-2.50 coins
-3.50 coins
A
B
Monday, 8 am
A
B
Sunday, 2 pm
-2.00 coins
-6.50 coins
ticket
ticket
ticket
ticket
Your current budget: 43.50 coins Your current budget: 43.50 coins
+2.50 coins ticket
+1.50 coins ticket
trade budget trade budget
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
10
that we propose in Level 4 a cap-and-trade approach, in which mobility budgets in the form of mobility
1
coins can be traded, in a similar way to carbon trading (21, 22). In such system, the cap-and-trade
2
approach gives MaaS users their own regulated market platform, where they can generate additional
3
income if they behave sustainable.
4
5
RISKS AND BENFITS
6
As described in the previous sections, the government-contracted MaaS model that integrates a
7
sustainability objective can overcome major difficulties in the implementation of MaaS. Regulatory issues
8
are addressed by the procuring local government. The conflict between profitability and sustainability is
9
solved by incentives and cross-subsidizations by the government in combination with dynamic full cost
10
pricing methods. However, the new MaaS model still faces challenges on operational and individual
11
levels. The following section critically discusses the tool’s requirements, risks, benefits and expected
12
impact.
13
The development of the proposed MaaS model is data-intensive. External cost indicators and
14
system boundaries need to be defined, as the final external cost values of different transport modes are
15
highly dependent on the system boundaries. The process of defining these factors is critical and represents
16
a major challenge in the MaaS concept presented here. In addition to predefined values and factors for
17
external costs, MaaS requires real-time road traffic and public transport occupancy data. Data availability
18
generally depends on the global data provider (Google / Apple) and the local authorities. To be
19
independent of global data handlers, the city needs to focus on its own data collection, using smart city
20
solutions such as live sensors, mobility patterns, and connectivity and communication between
21
infrastructure and cloud services.
22
Another crucial factor in the successful implementation of this MaaS model is the behavior of
23
citizens and users of the app. There may be multiple reasons for public reluctance to use the tool. In the
24
case of a MaaS with an integrated sustainability objective, full costs as a sustainability measurement
25
would not be acceptable to the public. People might not see sustainability as their objective or at least not
26
in such dimensions. The level of convenience offered by cars might be underestimated, meaning that the
27
majority of people do not wish to change their daily travel habits. Another approach could be to include
28
convenience in the full costs. However, it is very difficult to objectively quantify these factors. The
29
behavioral aspects of MaaS users will be examined by trials and citizen surveys in future MaaS studies.
30
Private operators or service providers pose an additional risk, since they are part of the free
31
market, and their main interests comprise the generation of revenue and expansion into other regions.
32
Unlike public transport authorities, private companies are not restricted to a specific region. Part of the
33
MaaS model has to be an extensive business plan, which potentially offers private companies an adequate
34
cooperation incentive in the form of expected profits. A smart balance of revenue redistribution and road
35
price will be a key factor of the model. Additionally, the procuring government needs to use its
36
considerable regional influence to provide platforms for communication, exchange, and cooperation
37
between operators. This MaaS concept is based on solid, shared sustainability goals that are acceptable to
38
and understood by all the stakeholders involved.
39
However, once a critical mass of users has been achieved, the government-contracted MaaS
40
model that integrates a sustainability objective will be able to ease traffic congestion and improve
41
sustainability by reducing car-focused travel while interconnecting the most sustainable transport modes
42
on intermodal trips. It can provide seamless, on-demand travel for citizens and, at the same time, foster
43
sustainable mobility for society.
44
45
CONCLUSIONS
46
This concept paper presented and discussed the key features, implementation steps, and
47
requirements of a government-contracted MaaS model that integrates a sustainability objective. The
48
literature review pointed out the key challenges facing the implementation of MaaS and categorized them
49
as technical, individual, social, economic, operational and regulatory, respectively. Cooperation between
50
private and public mobility service providers and the conflict between profitability and sustainability were
51
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
11
identified as the most critical factors. Adequate regulation is required to enable and support these complex
1
forms of cooperation. The MaaS model presented here incorporates the concept of space-time road or
2
transport mode pricing based on full cost calculations. With this pricing method, more sustainable
3
transport modes are incentivized and cross-subsidized by less sustainable travel (such as combustion
4
engine cars during rush hours). A four-level process was proposed for the development and
5
implementation of this MaaS concept. The transactional and operational integration of the tool is
6
gradually increasing, and additional features and pay methods are being applied step by step.
7
The proposed process will be applied in a research project within the MCube research cluster
8
funded by the BMBF’s (Federal Ministry of Education and Research of Germany) clusters4future
9
initiative. Over the next nine years, the implementation and trial of a MaaS model similar to the one
10
presented here is planned for the metropolitan region of Munich. Studies and research into external costs,
11
pricing methods, the impact of this MaaS and the behavior of citizens will follow.
12
13
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
14
The research by D.S. was conducted with basic research funding from the Technical University of
15
Munich and accomplished in part within the concept phase of the BMBF clusters4future initiative. We
16
acknowledge the financial support from the Technical University of Munich and the Federal Ministry of
17
Education and Research of Germany (BMBF).
18
19
AUTHOR CONTRIBUTIONS
20
The authors confirm their contributions to the paper as follows: as the first author: D.S.; study conception
21
and design: D.S., J.K., A.L., R.R.; literature review and literature processing: D.S.; development of new
22
concept: D.S., J.K., A.L., R.R.; concept features and implementation steps: D.S., A.L.; discussion: D.S.;
23
draft manuscript preparation: D.S.; supervision and amendment: J.K., A.L., R.R. All authors reviewed the
24
results and approved the final version of the manuscript.
25
REFERENCES
1. Wong, Y. Z., D. A. Hensher, and C. Mulley. Mobility as a Service (MaaS): Charting a Future
Context. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, Vol. 131, 2020, pp. 519.
2. Axsen, J., P. Plötz, and M. Wolinetz. Crafting Strong, Integrated Policy Mixes for Deep CO2
Mitigation in Road Transport. Nature Climate Change, Vol. 10, No. 9, 2020, pp. 809818.
3. Sampo Hietanen. "Mobility as a Service" - the New Transport Model?
https://silo.tips/download/sampo-hietanen-ceo-its-finland. Accessed January 29, 2021.
4. Jittrapirom, P., V. Caiati, A.-M. Feneri, S. Ebrahimigharehbaghi, M. J. A. González, and J. Narayan.
Mobility as a Service: A Critical Review of Definitions, Assessments of Schemes, and Key
Challenges. Urban Planning, Vol. 2, No. 2, 2017, pp. 1325.
5. Jittrapirom, P., V. Marchau, R. van der Heijden, and H. Meurs. Future Implementation of Mobility as
a Service (MaaS): Results of an International Delphi Study. Travel Behaviour and Society, Vol. 21,
2020, pp. 281294.
6. Pangbourne, K., M. N. Mladenović, D. Stead, and D. Milakis. Questioning Mobility as a Service:
Unanticipated Implications for Society and Governance. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and
Practice, Vol. 131, 2020, pp. 3549.
7. Kamargianni, M., W. Li, M. Matyas, and A. Schäfer. A Critical Review of New Mobility Services
for Urban Transport. Transportation Research Procedia, Vol. 14, 2016, pp. 32943303.
8. Lyons, G., P. Hammond, and K. Mackay. The Importance of User Perspective in the Evolution of
MaaS. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, Vol. 121, 2019, pp. 2236.
9. Karlsson, I., D. Mukhtar-Landgren, G. Smith, T. Koglin, A. Kronsell, E. Lund, S. Sarasini, and J.
Sochor. Development and Implementation of Mobility-as-a-Service a Qualitative Study of Barriers
and Enabling Factors. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, Vol. 131, 2020,
pp. 283295.
10. Cruz, C. O., and J. M. Sarmento. “Mobility as a Service” Platforms: A Critical Path Towards
Increasing the Sustainability of Transportation Systems. Sustainability, Vol. 12, No. 16, 2020,
p. 6368.
11. House of Commons Transport Committee. Mobility as a Service - Eighth Report of Session 2017-19.
https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201719/cmselect/cmtrans/590/590.pdf. Accessed March 11,
2021.
12. Li, Y., and T. Voege. Mobility as a Service (MaaS): Challenges of Implementation and Policy
Required. Journal of Transportation Technologies, Vol. 07, No. 02, 2017, pp. 95106.
13. Hensher, D. A., C. Q. Ho, and D. J. Reck. Mobility as a Service and Private Car Use: Evidence from
the Sydney MaaS Trial. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, Vol. 145, 2021,
pp. 1733.
14. Mulley, C. Mobility as a Services (MaaS) Does It Have Critical Mass? Transport Reviews, Vol. 37,
No. 3, 2017, pp. 247251.
15. Kuminhof, T. Längsschnitt: Ein Jahrzehnt Forschung Zur Mobilität Junger Erwachsener, Berlin,
29.11.2019.
16. Ho, C. Q., D. A. Hensher, and D. J. Reck. Drivers of Participant’S Choices of Monthly Mobility
Bundles: Key Behavioural Findings from the Sydney Mobility as a Service (MaaS) Trial.
Transportation Research Part C: Emerging Technologies, Vol. 124, 2021, p. 102932.
17. König, A., L. Nicoletti, D. Schröder, S. Wolff, A. Waclaw, and M. Lienkamp. An Overview of
Parameter and Cost for Battery Electric Vehicles. World Electric Vehicle Journal, Vol. 12, No. 1,
2021, p. 21.
Schröder, Kinigadner, Loder, Rothfeld
13
18. Schröder, D., and F. Gotzler. A Holistic Spatial and Cost Assessment of Urban Transport Options in
Munich. Journal of Urban Mobility (submitted), 2021.
19. Bogenberger, K., P. Blum, F. Dandl, L.-S. Hamm, A. Loder, P. Malcom, M. Margreiter, and N.
Sautter. MobilityCoins -- a New Currency for the Multimodal Urban Transportation System,
28.07.2021. http://arxiv.org/pdf/2107.13441v1.
20. Carlton, D. W., and G. C. Loury. The Limitations of Pigouvian Taxes as a Long-Run Remedy for
Externalities*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 95, No. 3, 1980, p. 559.
21. Verhoef, E., P. Nijkamp, and P. Rietveld. Tradeable Permits: Their Potential in the Regulation of
Road Transport Externalities. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design, Vol. 24, No. 4,
1997, pp. 527548.
22. Dales, J. H. Pollution, Property and Prices. An Essay in Policy-Making and Economics. Elgar,
Cheltenham, 2002.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
The constant introduction of new mobility options in urban transportation complexifies the mode choice of individual users. Relevant indicators have to give users a reliable guideline for mode choice as well as giving municipalities and industry a reasonable guideline for strategic orientation. Therefore, in this paper, a comprehensive assessment of transport options is conducted for indicators such as travel time, costs, CO2 emissions and external costs. The main added value of this paper is the method employed: Trips with origin-destination (OD) coordinates are routed for different transport modes using Open Trip Planner (OTP). In the next step, a cost model calculates these indicators for all transport modes. The presented method can compare privately-owned vehicles with different propulsion types with conventional as well as new public mobility services from a spatial perspective within the Munich area as a case study. The comprehensive information provided by these results helps mobility stakeholders in the decision-making process. The thematic analysis potential of the method is shown in figures which present the efficiency and sustainability of transport modes in different contexts. Recommendations for individual users, the mobility industry, and political decision-makers can be derived from these figures to implement measures for more sustainable and efficient mobility. Results include, that i) Individual users are more cost-efficient when using shared mobility services depending on the annual mileage (below 5,000 km for cars); ii) electric vehicles will be the most cost-efficient propulsion type and, at the same time, have the lowest CO2 emissions. The visualized interdependencies between the guiding principles for transport planners and transport modes allow providers of mobility-as-a-service (MaaS) platforms to integrate a variable pricing system according to these principles. Pricing models will be investigated in further studies.
Article
Full-text available
The launch of both battery electric vehicles (BEVs) and autonomous vehicles (AVs) on the global market has triggered ongoing radical changes in the automotive sector. On the one hand, the new characteristics of the BEV powertrain compared to the combustion type have resulted in new central parameters, such as vehicle range, which then become an important selling point. On the other hand, electric components are as yet not optimized and the sensors needed for autonomous driving are still expensive, which introduces changes to the vehicle cost structure. This transformation is not limited to the vehicle itself but also extends to its mobility and the necessary infrastructure. The former is shaped by new user behaviors and scenarios. The latter is impacted by the BEV powertrain, which requires a charging and energy supply infrastructure. To enable manufacturers and researchers to develop and optimize BEVs and AVs, it is necessary to first identify the relevant parameters and costs. To this end, we have conducted an extensive literature review. The result is a complete overview of the relevant parameters and costs, divided into the categories of vehicle, infrastructure, mobility, and energy.
Article
Full-text available
Australia’s first Mobility as a Service (MaaS) trial commenced in April 2019 in Sydney, running for two years. The objective of the trial is at least twofold – to assess interest in various MaaS subscription plans through bundling public transport, rideshare, car share and car rental with varying financial discounts and monthly subscription fees, in contrast to pay as you go (PAYG); and to assess the extent to which the use of the private car might change following a subscription to a monthly mobility bundle. This paper assesses the second objective by investigating the potential for changes in monthly car use in the presence of a MaaS program. There is no previous research that we are aware of that has tested the relationship between MaaS bundle uptake and private car use. The paper develops a joint discrete-continuous model system to explain the choice between monthly bundles and PAYG, and subsequently, the total monthly car kilometres. Controlling for monthly differences due to other influences such as seasonal travel activity, the findings suggest that the offered bundles do have an encouraging impact on private car use. Within the limits of what was tested under the Sydney MaaS trial, indicative evidence suggests that MaaS has the potential to change travel behaviour in a way aligned with sustainability objectives, although this evidence should not be taken as suggesting that MaaS is a commercially viable mobility strategy.
Article
Full-text available
Australia’s first Mobility as a Service (MaaS) trial commenced in April 2019 in Sydney. A key objective of the trial is to assess interest in various MaaS subscription plans through bundling public transport, ride share, car share and car rental with varying financial discounts and monthly subscription fees, in contrast to pay as you go (PAYG). This paper develops a mixed logit choice model to investigate the participants’ choice between PAYG and four subscription plans (or bundles) that were incrementally introduced over a 5-month period. This is the first paper to model real uptake as previous studies are based on stated preference data. New evidence is provided on what role financial savings, estimated using tracking technology embedded in the MaaS app, play in the context of modal offerings and a monthly subscription fee as well as socio-demographic and seasonal effects. Behaviourally, we present evidence on the extent of take up of each bundle relative to PAYG as well as elasticity estimates for all exogenous influences and estimates of willingness to pay and scenario assessment, particularly for how much someone would have to save over a previous month’s cost outlay to be willing to subscribe to a particular bundle in a subsequent month. Within the context of the trial, the findings suggest a substantial market for mobility bundles but PAYG is an option preferred by many, particularly those with varying travel needs. We are, however, not in a position yet to conclude that these choices necessarily align with a contribution to societal sustainability goals.
Article
Full-text available
Urban mobility is experiencing a profound change. Mobility patterns are becoming more complex, and typical home–work–home travel is no longer the rule, as journeys tend to connect multiple points in a rather inconstant pattern. This has changed the approach to transport planning. Existing transportation planning and operation approaches have been focussed on the ability to identify and forecast typical home–work/school–home travel and subsequently plan the transport system accordingly. The traditional approach has been: Forecast - > plan - > deliver. New mobility patterns and mobility solutions are characterised by greater flexibility, taking advantage of the “sharing concept” and simultaneously providing solutions that have lower greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. These dynamics and an evolving environment raise several new challenges at different levels, fostering the development of Mobility-as-a-Service (MaaS). This system transforms the physical transportation system into a commodity and takes advantage of the internet of things (IoT). However, the onset of MaaS solutions is anything but linear. Several business models have emerged, with different partners originating from different industries (e.g., technological, transport operators, infrastructure managers, etc.) developing their own solutions, often in competition with others. It is not unusual to find different MaaS solutions in the same city, which integrate different solutions. This paper intends to provide an analysis on the main challenges affecting mobility in general, and MaaS in particular, as well as the main business models used for delivering MaaS solutions. The paper uses a case study in Lisbon to illustrate some of the challenges.
Article
Full-text available
Mobility-as-a-Service (MaaS) has been argued as part of the solution to prevalent transport problems. However, progress from pilots to large-scale implementation has hitherto been slow. The aim of the research reported in this paper was to empirically and in-depth investigate how, and to what extent, different factors affect the development and implementation of MaaS. A framework was developed, with a basis in institutional theory and the postulation that formal as well informal factors on different analytical levels (macro, meso and micro) must be considered. The research was organised as a multiple case study in Finland and Sweden and a qualitative approach was chosen for data collection and analysis. A number of factors with a claimed impact on the development and implementation of MaaS was revealed. At the macro level, these factors included legislation concerning transport, innovation and public administration, and the presence (or not) of a shared vision for MaaS. At the meso level, (the lack of) appropriate business models, cultures of collaboration, and assumed roles and responsibilities within the MaaS ecosystem were identified as significant factors. At the micro level, people’s attitudes and habits were recognised as important factors to be considered. However, how the ‘S’ in MaaS fits (or not) the transport needs of the individual/household appears to play a more important role in adoption or rejection of MaaS than what has often been acknowledged in previous papers on MaaS. The findings presented in this paper provide several implications for public and private sector actors. Law-making authorities can facilitate MaaS developments by adjusting relevant regulations and policies such as transport-related subsidies, taxation policies and the definition of public transport. Regional and local authorities could additionally contribute to creating conducive conditions for MaaS by, for example, planning urban designs and transport infrastructures to support service-based travelling. Moreover, private actors have key roles to play in future MaaS developments, as both public and private transport services are needed if MaaS is to become a viable alternative to privately owned cars. Thus, the advance of MaaS business models that benefit all involved actors is vital for the prosperity of the emerging MaaS ecosystem.
Article
Full-text available
The rapid emergence of Mobility as a Service (MaaS) into the transport sector’s lexicon has brought with it an air of expectation that suggests a future mobility revolution. This paper focusses on the user perspective and offers a deepening of socio-technical thinking about MaaS and its prospects. It first provides an examination of what is understood to date about MaaS in what is a new but rapidly evolving body of literature. This highlights the concept of MaaS as a ‘mobility system beyond the private car’ and the new centrality of a ‘mobility intermediary’ layer in that system. The paper then focuses and elaborates upon its contention that MaaS is neither new nor revolutionary but is rather an evolutionary continuation in terms of transport integration. Emerging from an era of unimodal travel information systems becoming multimodal and then integrated multimodal information services, MaaS is now about adding seamless booking, payment and ticketing to the integration offer. The paper puts forward a ‘Levels of MaaS Integration (LMI) taxonomy’ analogous to the level 0–5 SAE taxonomy for automation of road vehicles. This taxonomy, designed around the user perspective (including cognitive user effort), concerns operational, informational and transactional integration that it is suggested reflect a hierarchy of user need. From a synthesis of insights from the ‘pre-MaaS’ literature concerning choice making for travel and the role of information, a MaaS behavioural schema is provided to illustrate potential consideration and adoption of MaaS from the user perspective. In concluding, the paper considers what a user perspective reveals for the future prospects of MaaS and in particular for the mobility intermediaries.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper we focus on the development of a new service model for accessing transport, namely Mobility as a Service (MaaS) and present one of the first critical analyses of the rhetoric surrounding the concept. One central assumption of one prevalent MaaS conceptualization is that transport services are bundled into service packages for monthly payment, as in the telecommunication or media service sectors. Various other forms of MaaS are being developed but all tend to offer door-to-door multi-modal mobility services, brokered via digital platforms connecting users and service operators. By drawing on literature concerned with socio-technical transitions, we address two multi-layered questions. First, to what extent can the MaaS promises (to citizens and cities) be delivered, and what are the unanticipated societal implications that could arise from a wholesale adoption of MaaS in relation to key issues such as wellbeing, emissions and social inclusion? Second, what are de facto challenges for urban governance if the packaged services model of MaaS is widely adopted, and what are the recommended responses? To address these questions, we begin by considering the evolution of intelligent transport systems that underpin the current vision of MaaS and highlight how the new business model could provide a mechanism to make MaaS truly disruptive. We then identify a set of plausible unanticipated societal effects that have implications for urban planning and transport governance. This is followed by a critical assessment of the persuasive rhetoric around MaaS that makes grand promises about efficiency, choice and freedom. Our conclusion is that the range of possible unanticipated consequences carries risks that require public intervention (i.e. steering) for reasons of both efficiency and equity.
Article
Transport CO2 emissions continue to grow globally despite advances in low-carbon technology and goal setting by numerous governments. In this Perspective, we summarize available evidence for the effectiveness of climate policies and policy mixes for road transport relative to 2030 and 2050 mitigation goals implied by the Paris Agreement. Current policy mixes in most countries are not nearly stringent enough. We argue that most regions need a stronger, more integrated policy mix led by stringent regulations and complemented by pricing mechanisms as well as other efforts to reduce vehicle travel. As road transport emissions are set to grow, stronger policy mixes are needed to reach mitigation goals. This Perspective considers the evidence for several policy types—strong regulation, pricing and reduced travel—and the best combination to reduce emissions for passenger and freight vehicles.
Article
This overview article proposes a revised approach to improve the urban realm, against the backdrop of new models for delivering transport services as digitalisation, collaborative consumption and autonomous technologies take hold. We propose the concept of modal efficiency illustrated through a conceptual framework situating both existing and emerging modes of transport around spatial and temporal dimensions. This framework helps us evaluate how the push towards smaller and more flexible transport services in questionable settings can have significant and adverse effects on road capacity, increasing congestion and in the longer term impacting urban form. We propose linking urban land use characteristics to travel price and modal efficiency to improve the broader transport system and guide the sustainable development of our cities. Mobility as a service (MaaS) based on shared mobility and modal integration constitutes a major opportunity to deliver on these ideals, if organised appropriately. Widely diverging service delivery models for MaaS are introduced, including commercially-motivated models (which may exacerbate efficiency issues), and systems which incorporate an institutional overlay. We propose consideration of a government-contracted model for MaaS, where road pricing is incorporated as an input into package price, defined by time of day, geography and modal efficiency. In amidst the hype of new mobility technologies and services, a critical assessment of the realm of possibilities can better inform government policy and ensure that digital disruption occurs to our advantage.