ArticlePDF Available

Democracy in the neighborhood and foreign direct investment

Authors:

Abstract

The determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) have been extensively studied. Even though there is extensive research in the area, most of it is based on analyzing the effects of host country characteristics on FDI flows, and yet there is little research on how neighboring country characteristics play a role in facilitating FDI flows to host countries. This paper analyzes the association between the democracy level in neighboring countries and FDI flows to host countries. Using bilateral FDI flows from the OECD countries, with a large host country sample, we find that countries surrounded by democratic countries attract higher FDI flows. Furthermore, we find evidence that countries that are surrounded by neighboring countries with good institutions tend themselves to have better institutions, experience lower civil conflict, and have higher political stability and hence indirectly attract higher FDI flows. Our findings suggest that if neighboring countries act in such way as to become more democratic, FDI flows to these countries would be higher since not only does improving the quality of democracy attract more FDI inflows, but also being surrounded by neighboring advanced democratic countries will also lead to higher FDI flows to them.
Rev Dev Econ. 2020;00:1–29.
|
1
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode
Received: 1 February 2018
|
Revised: 15 June 2020
|
Accepted: 4 August 2020
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12720
REGULAR ARTICLE
Democracy in the neighborhood and foreign direct
investment
MehmetPinar1
|
ThanasisStengos2
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution and reproduction
in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
© 2020 The Authors. Review of Development Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1Business School, Edge Hill University,
Ormskirk, United Kingdom
2Department of Economics and Finance,
University of Guelph, Guelph, Ontario,
Canada
Correspondence
Mehmet Pinar, Business School, Edge Hill
University, St Helens Road, Ormskirk L39
4QP, United Kingdom.
Email: mehmet.pinar@edgehill.ac.uk
Funding information
Research Investment Fund of Edge
Hill University; Natural Sciences and
Engineering Research Council of
Canada, Grant/Award Number: 401004;
British Academy, Grant/Award Number:
AF140068
Abstract
The determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) have
been extensively studied. Even though there is extensive
research in the area, most of it is based on analyzing the
effects of host country characteristics on FDI flows, and
yet there is little research on how neighboring country
characteristics play a role in facilitating FDI flows to host
countries. This paper analyzes the association between the
democracy level in neighboring countries and FDI flows to
host countries. Using bilateral FDI flows from the OECD
countries, with a large host country sample, we find that
countries surrounded by democratic countries attract higher
FDI flows. Furthermore, we find evidence that countries
that are surrounded by neighboring countries with good in-
stitutions tend themselves to have better institutions, experi-
ence lower civil conflict, and have higher political stability
and hence indirectly attract higher FDI flows. Our findings
suggest that if neighboring countries act in such way as
to become more democratic, FDI flows to these countries
would be higher since not only does improving the quality
of democracy attract more FDI inflows, but also being sur-
rounded by neighboring advanced democratic countries will
also lead to higher FDI flows to them.
KEYWORDS
democracy, democracy in the neighborhood, foreign direct
investment, institutions, neighborhood characteristics
2
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) have been extensively studied in the literature
(see, for example, Blonigen & Piger, 2014, for an extensive list of determinants). Even though there is
extensive research on the determinants of FDI flows, most of this research is based on the source, and
the effect of host countries’ characteristics on FDI flows, and there is little research on how neighbor-
ing country characteristics play a role in FDI flows to host countries.
The linkages between neighboring country characteristics, however, have been examined in the
literature. For instance, Easterly and Levine (2000) find that growth levels of countries are positively
associated with the growth levels in their neighboring countries, and policies in neighboring coun-
tries are contagious (see also Kelejian, Murrell, & Shepotylo, 2013, where governance in neighbor-
ing countries is positively associated with countries’ own governance levels). Similarly, Bosker and
Garretsen (2009) find that the institutional quality of countries and of their neighbors has a direct
effect on their long-term economic development. Recently, Qureshi (2013) finds that conflicts in
neighboring countries reduce bilateral trade. To our knowledge, recent literature has only consid-
ered the relevance of host country characteristics in attracting FDI flows. For instance, in a seminal
paper, Alfaro, Kalemli-Ozkan, and Volosovych (2008) find that the institutional quality of the host
country explains the Lucas paradox (Lucas, 1990) suggesting that the reason why rich countries do
not invest in poor countries is due to poor institutions in the latter (see also Pinar & Volkan, 2018).
Similarly, Jensen (2003) finds that democratic countries attract relatively higher FDI flows compared
to authoritarian regimes—see also Jakobsen and de Soysa (2006) and Asiedu and Lien (2011), where
democratization in most countries leads to higher FDI flows. One potential reason for this is that the
democratization process contributes to greater FDI openness, leading to higher FDI flows (see, for
example, Pandya, 2014). In a recent paper, Bekaert, Harvey, Lundblad, and Siegel (2014) show that
the reduction in political risk, which is captured by various institutional quality proxies of the host
country, leads to a significant increase in FDI levels (see also Economou, Hassapis, Philippas, &
Tsionas, 2017 where institutional factors are determinants of FDI both for the OECD and developing
countries).1 Even though the political, democratic, and institutional setting in the host country is ex-
tensively investigated, the effect of democratization of neighboring countries on FDI flows to the host
country has not yet been examined in the literature, and this paper intends to fill this gap.
There are many channels that can affect FDI in a country through different characteristics of its
neighboring countries (see Section2 for a detailed discussion on some of these channels). An obvious
one is for FDI to depend on the present and expected future performance of a given country, which in
turn depends on the level of competition between the respective country and its neighboring countries.
As discussed above, countries that have better institutional settings receive relatively higher capital
flows, and neighboring countries would compete to improve their institutional quality setting to attract
higher capital flows. In that respect, it is not surprising to expect that neighbors’ institutional setting
matters for FDI where the diffusion of information and institutional framework is stronger (see, for
example, Easterly & Levine, 2000; Kelejian et al., 2013; Ward & Dorussen, 2015). In this paper we
argue that neighboring countries that compete to attain a better institutional environment to attract
FDI create positive spillover effects on each other, suggesting that institutional agglomerations tend
to attract more investment.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F21; F23; F3
|
3
PINAR ANd STENGOS
We use gravity models and dynamic panel data estimation techniques and find that countries sur-
rounded by good democracies attract higher FDI flows. For robustness, we control for different neigh-
boring country characteristics such as the rule of law, political stability, civil conflict, and the market
size, and our results remain robust. Furthermore, the results are also robust to the use of different
samples and estimation techniques.
The paper is organized as follows. In Section2 we discuss briefly how neighboring country char-
acteristics play a role in countries’ economic, social and political outcomes and discuss how these
factors might also play a role in attracting FDI flows to host countries. Section3 discusses the data
and variables used in this paper, and also provides details on how neighboring country characteristics
are obtained. Section4 presents the estimation technique, and Section5 offers the results. Section6
concludes.
2
|
NEIGHBORING COUNTRY CHARACTERISTICS AND
THEIR EFFECT ON OTHER COUNTRIES
In this section we discuss the effects of neighboring country characteristics on other countries and
discuss how these factors might play direct and/or indirect roles in attracting higher FDI flows to host
countries.
It is a long-established finding that countries with higher market access (MA) and/or market po-
tential (MP), which is measured by the closeness of a country to other high-income countries, tend to
have a higher income (see, for example, Crafts & Venables, 2003; Redding & Venables, 2004; Liu &
Meissner, 2015), with access to the export market found to be one of the main factors behind this rela-
tionship (see Bosker & Garretsen, 2012; de Sousa, Mayer, & Zignago, 2012). Even though the above
papers examined the relationship between MA and economic development of a country, recent studies
also examined the link between FDI and MA. For instance, Blanco (2012) finds that the surrounding
market potential has a significant positive effect on net FDI flows to Latin American countries. At a
regional level, multinational firms in the German border region show a significant preference to invest
in the neighboring Czech regions (Schäffler, Hecht, & Moritz, 2017). Similar spillover effects on
neighboring regions have been found in Polish counties, with those counties identified as special eco-
nomic zones having a strong positive employment impact in the host county as well as in neighboring
counties (Cizkowicz, Cizkowicz-Pekala, Pekala, & Rzonca, 2017).
Another effect across neighboring countries is the spillover of social, economic, and political pol-
icies and outcomes. In particular, policies are found to be contagious when countries surrounded by
other countries with better institutions also have a better institutional setting. For example, Kelejian
et al. (2013) find that governance in neighboring countries is positively related to the countries’ own
governance levels. Similarly, Ward and Dorussen (2015) find that public knowledge of the impor-
tance of governance leads to higher diffusion of good governance to neighboring countries. One of
the practical implications of this is the establishment and enlargement of the European Union. In
order to join the EU, countries need to follow the Copenhagen criteria that require ‘stable conditions
guaranteeing democracy and the rule of law’, something that led to the diffusion of democracy and in-
stitutional quality within Europe. Furthermore, institutional quality in neighboring countries is found
to be important in affecting economic growth and development. For instance, Easterly and Levine
(2000) show that the economic performance of a country is good if its neighbors have relatively higher
economic growth. On the other hand, Bosker and Garretsen (2009) find that not only does countries’
own institutional quality matter for long-term economic development but also the institutional quality
of neighboring countries directly explains development levels. In other words, being surrounded by
4
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
countries with better institutional quality not only leads to better governance but also increases gross
domestic product (GDP) per capita. In this paper we examine whether these indirect linkages between
neighboring and host country affect FDI flows.
The other channel that is found to be important in affecting a country’s income level is political
unrest or instability in neighboring countries. For instance, Ades and Chua (1997) find that political
instability in a neighboring country may lead to lower economic performance by decreasing the mag-
nitude of trade and expenditure on education and increasing the expenditure on the military. Qureshi
(2013) finds that conflict in neighboring countries reduces bilateral trade. Furthermore, conflict in
neighboring countries may lead to inflows of refugees (Moore & Shellman, 2007), resulting in an in-
creased probability of violence and civil war (Salehyan & Gleditsch, 2006; Blattman & Miguel, 2010),
as well as an adverse effect on health and education of refugee-hosting economies (Baez, 2011).
Bandyopadhyay, Sandler, and Younas (2014) find that both domestic and transnational terrorism in
the host country have a negative effect on FDI (see also Gaibulloev & Younas, 2016, who show that
higher conflict levels lead to lower levels of domestic bank lending). In a more recent paper, Filer and
Stanišić (2016) show that terror incidents not only lower FDI flows to host countries but also lead to
lower investment to neighboring countries. However, Hegre (2014) finds that the democracies have
less conflict than semi-democracies, suggesting that the establishment of long-lasting democracies
has some mitigating effect on conflict.
Based on the previous literature, we expect that democratic institutions in neighboring countries
are key in affecting the allocation of FDI. If a country is surrounded by countries that have strong
democratic institutions, these neighboring countries are less likely to experience conflict (see, for
example, Hegre, 2014), which would then decrease the likelihood of the host country experiencing
conflict (Salehyan & Gleditsch, 2006; Blattman & Miguel, 2010). Furthermore, if a host country is
surrounded by countries that have good institutions, this would also improve the economic outcomes
of the host country (Bosker & Garretsen, 2009), and would lead to improvements in its institutional
quality (Kelejian et al., 2013; Ward & Dorussen, 2015). Overall, being surrounded by countries that
have well-developed institutions would increase the likelihood of countries improving their economic
and institutional outcomes and decrease the likelihood of them experiencing conflict. Therefore, if a
host country is surrounded by countries that have better institutions, this would make the host country
a relatively safer and socioeconomically more desirable place in which to invest compared to other
host countries that are surrounded by countries that have worse institutions. As a result, we expect that
host countries surrounded by countries that have good institutions are likely to attract more FDI flows.
In Section5 we will examine whether this theoretical expectation holds empirically. This proposition
has been analyzed by the contagion effect concerning financial flows (see, for example, Kaminsky &
Reinhart, 2000; Corsetti, Pericoli, & Sbracia, 2005; Forbes & Warnock, 2012; Dell'Erba & Reinhardt,
2015); however, whether neighboring characteristics directly affect FDI flows has not yet been exam-
ined, something that we intend to do in this paper.
Given the above discussion on potential direct and indirect links between neighboring country
characteristics and FDI to a host country, we will examine whether these characteristics play a direct
or indirect role in FDI flows to host countries. In particular, we will examine two channels by which
the quality of institutions in the neighboring countries can affect FDI flows to a country. Firstly, we
will examine whether investing countries consider regional institutional quality to play a direct role
in attracting FDI. Secondly, we will analyze the indirect relationship of institutional quality in neigh-
boring countries and other factors in the host country, such as the effects of neighboring institutional
quality on other factors in the host country.
|
5
PINAR ANd STENGOS
3
|
DATA AND VARIABLES
Our paper uses panel data of FDI flows from 34 OECD countries to 143 host countries between 1993
and 2012 as the dependent variable (see the list of the countries used in Table A1 in Appendix A).
The OECD provides FDI flows from OECD countries to host countries between 1985 and 2013;
however, most of the FDI flow data before the 1993 period and for 2013 had many missing values and
therefore are excluded from the analysis.2 The reason for the exclusion of the period before 1993 was
our attempt to include as many OECD countries as possible in our analysis since some of the OECD
countries became independent after 1991, and they did not have data for FDI flows.3 Still, our data set
covers a period of analysis that is longer than those used by the recent studies—for example, Mishra
and Jena (2019) used the period 2001–12, Belgibayeva and Plekhanov (2019) used bilateral FDI flows
for the period 2008–12, Xu (2019) considered the period 2001–12, and Donaubauer, Neumayer, and
Nunnenkamp (2020) cover the period 2001–12.
3.1
|
Institutional quality
There are many measures of institutional quality, but one of the most commonly used in the literature
is the democracy index from the Polity IV project (i.e. Polity 2). This index captures three elements
that are directly related to the protection of property rights and other aspects that are important to at-
tract FDI. These three essential elements are described as follows:
One is the presence of institutions and procedures through which citizens can express
effective preferences about alternative policies and leaders. Second is the existence of
institutionalized constraints on the exercise of power by the executive. The third is the
guarantee of civil liberties to all citizens in their daily lives and acts of political partici-
pation. (Marshall, Gurr, & Jaggers, 2016, p. 14).
Knutsen (2011) finds that the relatively democratic countries have higher protection of property rights.
Hence, we use a democracy proxy as our primary institutional quality measure, which consists of yearly
data between 1993 and 2012 for 167 countries. We do not use small countries with little or no flows of
FDI, and we ended up having data for 143 host countries.
We also use some other institutional quality proxies that are commonly used in the literature as
controls in our robustness analysis, such as the rule of law measure from the World Governance
Indicators constructed by the World Bank (Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2013). The effects of the
rule of law on economic growth have been extensively examined through the mitigation of violence,
the protection of property rights, institutional checks on government and control of private capture and
corruption (see Haggard & Tiede, 2011, for theoretical and empirical analysis of the effect of the rule
of law on aspects mentioned above).
3.2
|
Neighboring country characteristics
For a host country i, we proceed to calculate the institutional quality of its neighboring countries by
taking the average of the institutional quality values of the neighboring countries. For a given time t,
we obtain the neighboring country institutional quality proxy as
6
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
where
N_INS𝑖𝑡
is the average institutional quality of neighboring countries of country i at time t, and
INSt
is an
n×1
vector of observations on institutional quality levels for n countries. Finally, W is a
n×n
weighting matrix defined as
where m is the total number of neighbors of country i.4 Here, our main neighboring institutional quality
measure is the democracy score; however, we have neighboring institutional quality proxies by using the
rule of law, political stability, and absence-of-violence components from the World Governance Indicators
as an additional set of control variables.
We also construct conflict and market size measures of neighboring countries similarly (see
Section2 for details of their importance). It is also possible that a given country might not be sur-
rounded by larger markets, but located to be close to high-income countries. Therefore, we also con-
struct a market potential (MP) measure at a given time t similarly to the Redding and Venables (2004)
market potential measure as follows:
where
MP𝑖𝑡
is the market potential of country i at time t and
Dist𝑖𝑗
is the great circle distance between
capital cities of countries i and j.
3.3
|
Other control variables
In line with the literature on the determinants of FDI and gravity models, we also control for source
and host country characteristics such as the market size of the source and host countries (i.e. GDP
of source and host countries, respectively), population and land areas of source and host countries.
Another important factor that has been considered in gravity models while examining bilateral
trade and FDI flows is regional trade agreements (e.g. Baier & Bergstrand, 2007, Balgati, Egger, &
Pfaffermayr, 2008; Ullah & Inaba, 2012; Thangavelu & Narjoko, 2014; Chenaf-Nicet and Rougier,
2016; Martínez-San Román, Bengoa, & Sánchez-Robles, 2016; Cherif & Dreger, 2018), which we
will also include in our estimations. Furthermore, we control for civil conflict and institutional quality
of the host country. The definitions and sources of the variables used are presented in Table A2, and
summary statistics are provided in Table A3.
4
|
METHODOLOGY
In general, it is hard to account for all the factors that might affect FDI flows since capital flows
are potentially affected by hard-to-measure country-specific factors such as culture, trust, and social
N_INS𝑖𝑡 =WINSt
𝑖𝑗 =
1
mif iand j
0 otherwise,
MP𝑖𝑡 =ij
GDP𝑗𝑡
Dist
𝑖𝑗
|
7
PINAR ANd STENGOS
capital. This could potentially lead to an omitted variable bias. Furthermore, a positive relationship
between (countries’ own and neighboring countries’) institutions and FDI flows might be due to
reverse causality. To account for the first concern (omitted variables and unobserved country hetero-
geneity), we use the gravity model with fixed effects. Although the gravity model is known for its ap-
plication in the trade flows—see, for example, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and see Head and
Mayer (2014) for an overview of the use of gravity models in trade flows—gravity models have also
been used to examine bilateral FDI flows (Head & Ries, 2008; Bergstrand & Egger, 2011; Petri, 2012;
Bellos & Subasat, 2012; Thangavelu & Narjoko, 2014; Mishra & Jena, 2019; Xu, 2019; Belgibayeva
& Plekhanov, 2019; Donaubauer et al., 2020). Therefore, our first estimation method is to use the fol-
lowing gravity model estimation specification:
where
Fi,j,t
is the FDI flows from country i (source) to j (host) at time period t. X includes the control vari-
ables that account for the size of the source and host economies, such as income, population, land area,
and other host country characteristics such as conflict and institutional quality. Furthermore, we include
the distance between the source and host country (Distancei,j) to account for information asymmetries and
transaction costs. Languagei,j and Colonyi,j are dummy variables taking the value 1 if countries share a
common language and have had a colonial link, respectively, and 0 otherwise.
RTA𝑖𝑗𝑡
is a dummy variable
taking the value 1 if countries i (source) and j (host) have a regional trade agreement at time period t 0 zero
otherwise. Finally, we include
NXj,t
as the characteristics of the neighboring countries that might affect the
FDI flows to host countries such as the quality of institutions, market potential of the host country, market
size of the neighboring countries, and civil conflict.
Since the unobserved variables might be correlated with country-pair characteristics, we also con-
trol for country-pair fixed effects (Baier & Bergstrand, 2007). Finally, even though the gravity model
accounts for time-invariant country effects and fixed time effects, the results obtained may be affected
by endogeneity. The system generalized method of moments (GMM) has been one of the most popular
methods to account for potential endogeneity while examining the determinants of FDI flows (see, for
example, Asiedu & Lien, 2011; Bandyopadhyay et al., 2014; Aziz, 2018; Saini & Singhania, 2018;
Neanidis, 2019, for the use of GMM). As such, we apply the system GMM estimator suggested by
Blundell and Bond (1998) where the lagged levels and first differences are used as instruments for the
endogenous variables. In sum, this paper uses two popular methods in examining the determinant of
the FDI flows to ensure the robustness of our findings.
5
|
EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
5.1
|
Gravity model estimates
We begin our analysis with the estimation of the gravity model. Table1 presents the results when
we control for year and source-country fixed effects (YSFE) and year and country-pair fixed effects
(YCPFE) when we use democracy as a proxy for institutional quality. In columns 1–4 we control for
the year and source-country fixed effects and use a different set of control variables. In column 1 we
use the lagged FDI flows and democracy in the host and neighboring countries of the host country.
We find that not only do democratic countries receive relatively higher FDI flows but also countries
(1)
ln (
Fi,j,t
)
=𝛽0+ln
(
Fi,j,t1
)
+X
j,t1𝛽j+X
i,t1𝛽i+𝛿1ln(𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒)𝑖𝑗 +𝛿2(𝐿𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑢𝑎𝑔𝑒)
𝑖𝑗
+
𝛿
3
(𝐶𝑜𝑙𝑜𝑛𝑦)
𝑖𝑗
+𝛿
4
(𝑅𝑇 𝐴)
𝑖𝑗𝑡
+𝜸
(
NX
j,t1)
+𝛼
j
+𝛼
t
+𝜇
i,j,t
,
8
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 1 Gravity model estimations
Variables
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
YSFE (1) YSFE (2) YSFE (3) YSFE (4) YCPFE
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.834*** (0.00431) 0.820*** (0.00458) 0.759*** (0.00571) 0.735*** (0.00615) 0.747*** (0.00401)
Democracyj,t–1 0.0444*** (0.00456) 0.0333*** (0.00457) 0.0204*** (0.00457) 0.0190*** (0.00462) 0.0254*** (0.00527)
N_Democracyj,t–1 0.0186*** (0.00517) 0.00893* (0.00518) 0.0121** (0.00521) 0.00959* (0.00522) 0.0135** (0.00592)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 1.174*** (0.0477)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.556*** (0.0209) 0.527*** (0.0209) 0.637*** (0.0208)
ln(Population)i,t–1 −0.560*** (0.0472)
ln(Population)j,t–1 −0.0969*** (0.0249) −0.0428* (0.0249) −0.121*** (0.0295)
ln(Area)i,t–1 −0.241*** (0.0217)
ln(Area)j,t–1 −0.102*** (0.0159) −0.0538*** (0.0163) −0.110*** (0.0197)
RTAi,j,t0.852*** (0.0590) 0.246*** (0.0714)
Languagei,j0.475*** (0.0742)
Colonyi,j0.758*** (0.120)
Distancei,j−0.376*** (0.0319)
Observations 28,872 28,872 28,272 28,272 28,272
Number of pairs 3,905
R-squared .836 .837 .843 .845 .838
R-squared (within) .113
R-squared (between) .943
Notes: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country j at time t. Democracy and N_Democracy are the institutional quality
proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the host country, respectively. Languagei,j and Colonyi,j takes the value 1 if source (country i) and host (country j) share a common language
and have had a colonial link, respectively. Distancei,j is the distance between the capital cities of the source and host countries. RTAi,j,t takes the value 1 if source (country i) and host (country j) have a
regional trade agreement at time t, and 0 otherwise. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.
|
9
PINAR ANd STENGOS
that are surrounded by relatively democratic countries also receive higher FDI flows where the coef-
ficients on host country democracy and democracy level of neighboring countries are positive and
statistically significant at the 1% level. On the other hand, the coefficient of lagged FDI inflows is
positive, suggesting that the current FDI flows are positively correlated with the FDI inflows in the
previous year. Column 2 of Table1 gives the estimation results when we include the RTA dummy
variable as an additional control variable, and in line with the previous literature, we find that host
countries receive relatively higher FDI flows if they have regional trade agreements with source coun-
tries. In column 3 we include additional controls for host country characteristics, such as the market
size (i.e. GDP), population, and area. In line with the empirical literature, we find that countries with
larger market sizes receive relatively higher FDI flows, whereas countries with larger populations and
areas receive relatively lower FDI flows. In column 4 we also include language and colony dummies,
which take the value 1 if source and host share a common language and have had a colonial link, re-
spectively. We also control for the geographical distance between the capital cities of the source and
host countries. All estimates of the other variables are in agreement with the existing literature, as we
find that if investing and host countries share a common language and have had a colonial link, host
countries tend to receive higher FDI flows. Finally, if the source and host countries are further away
from each other, there are lower levels of FDI flows. Finally, column 5 introduces year and country-
pair fixed effects (where we drop the dummy variables as these variables are captured by the country-
pair fixed effect and do not vary over time). Similarly to the previous cases, we find that countries that
have a relatively larger market size invest more and also receive more investment. The relationship
between the level of democracy in the host country and FDI flows is positive and significant at the
1% level. Furthermore, the coefficient on the democracy level of neighboring countries is positive and
significant at the 5% level.
Overall, results from columns 1–5 control for the year, source, and country-pair fixed effects, and
suggest that the OECD countries invest relatively more in countries that are democratic and also if
host countries are surrounded by other democratic countries. Regarding the other variables that we
controlled for, coefficient estimates have the expected signs. The results for all specifications confirm
that the democracy level of neighboring countries positively affects FDI flows. In particular, a one
standard deviation increase in the democracy level of neighboring countries (i.e., 5.585) leads to a
7.54% increase in FDI flows to host countries (based on the coefficient of the democracy level of
neighboring countries in column 5). For a country that receives average FDI flows of $461 million,
a one standard deviation increase in the democracy level of neighboring countries leads to a $43.75
million increase in FDI flows.
5.2
|
Estimation results: Controlling for other neighboring country
characteristics
It is possible that the association between institutional quality in neighboring countries and FDI flows to
host countries might be due to omitted variables relating to neighboring country characteristics. Table2
presents the results when we control for other neighboring country characteristics such as civil conflict in
the host and civil conflict in the neighboring country, market size of the neighboring countries (measured
by the average GDP levels of neighboring countries), and the market potential of the host country when
we include the year and country-pair fixed effects as in the specification used in column 5 of Table1. In all
these specifications, besides the additional neighboring country characteristics, we include the lagged FDI
flows to examine the dynamic aspect of FDI flows, democracy in the host and neighboring countries, and
the market size of the source and host countries. In column 1 of Table2 we first control for civil conflict
10
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 2 Controlling for other neighboring characteristics
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.774*** (0.00730) 0.773*** (0.00736) 0.769*** (0.00739) 0.767*** (0.00749)
Democracyj,t–1 0.0300*** (0.00548) 0.0333*** (0.00543) 0.0324*** (0.00555) 0.0341*** (0.00566)
N_Democracyj,t–1 0.0115* (0.00633) 0.0118* (0.00639) 0.0179*** (0.00638) 0.0131* (0.00685)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 0.466*** (0.0227) 0.466*** (0.0228) 0.476*** (0.0228) 0.477*** (0.0229)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.491*** (0.0210) 0.467*** (0.0214) 0.511*** (0.0213) 0.498*** (0.0222)
Conflictj,t–1 −0.0696*** (0.0180) −0.0740*** (0.0182) −0.0629*** (0.0181) −0.0645*** (0.0183)
N_Conflictj,t–1 −0.0122* (0.00661) −0.0131* (0.00671) −0.0120* (0.00691) −0.0121* (0.00701)
ln(N_GDP)j,t–1 0.0502*** (0.0161) 0.0469*** (0.0161)
ln(Market potential)j,t–1 1.172*** (0.130) 1.154*** (0.132)
Observations 28,272 28,007 28,272 28,007
Number of pairs 3,905 3,874 3,905 3,874
R-squared .8357 .8359 .8361 .8364
Notes: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country j at time t. Democracy and N_Democracy are the institutional
quality proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the host country, respectively. Conflict and N_Conflict are the conflict levels in the host and neighboring countries of the host country,
respectively. N_GDP represents the average GDP of the neighboring countries of the host country. All estimations are obtained after controlling for the year and country-pair fixed effects. *, **, and ***
denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.
|
11
PINAR ANd STENGOS
in the host country and its neighboring countries. Both coefficients on civil conflict in the host country and
its neighboring countries enter the regressions with the expected negative sign and both are statistically
significant. In column 2 of Table2 we control for the average market size of the neighboring countries,
and we find that an increase in the average market size of neighbors leads to a rise in the FDI flows to
the host country. In column 3 we also control for the market potential of the host country as neighboring
countries might not directly be relatively rich themselves, but the host country may still be close enough
to richer countries. We find that countries with higher market potential (i.e. countries that are close to
high-income countries) also receive relatively higher FDI flows. Finally, in column 4 we control for all
these neighboring characteristics. When we control for all factors, we find that all of the neighboring char-
acteristics enter the regressions with the expected signs. Civil conflict in the host country and neighboring
countries depresses FDI flows to host countries. If the host country is surrounded by relatively larger
markets and also has higher market potential, it also tends to receive higher FDI flows. Finally, even after
controlling for additional neighboring country characteristics, the coefficient on the democracy level of
neighboring countries is still significant at the 10% level.
In Table2 we controlled for the year and country-pair fixed effects. However, some studies analyze
how FDI might affect the institutional quality of the host country (e.g. Demir, 2016) while others in-
vestigate the importance of the institutional setting in attracting FDI (e.g. Alfaro et al., 2008) resulting
in endogeneity. To address this issue, we use the system GMM estimator proposed by Blundell and
Bond (1998).
Table3 controls for the neighboring country characteristics with the system GMM estimator, where
both institutional quality proxies and conflict in the host and neighboring countries are considered as
endogenous variables.5 In our regressions, we utilized 3–5 lags of endogenous variables as instrumen-
tal variables.6 In all cases, the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions suggests that we cannot reject
the null hypothesis of instrument validity. Even after accounting for the potential endogeneity, our
main finding remains the same, with democratic countries and countries that are surrounded by rela-
tively better democracies receiving relatively higher FDI flows. Compared to Table2, once we control
for potential endogeneity, we find that the coefficients on civil conflict in neighboring countries and
the average market size of the neighboring countries still have the expected signs, but they now be-
come insignificant.7 Countries with higher market potential still receive relatively higher FDI flows,
but the coefficient drops from 1.154 to 0.466 (see column 4 of Tables2 and 3, respectively). The co-
efficient of democracy of neighboring countries with the system GMM estimator is nearly three times
as large as in the corresponding country-pair fixed effects estimation (0.0390 versus 0.0131 from
column 4 of Tables2 and 3, respectively). The coefficient on the democracy level of the host is also
positive and significant at the 5% level when we control for all neighboring country characteristics.
Furthermore, coefficients on the remaining control variables (i.e. lagged FDI flows, the market size of
the source and host countries) are positive and significant at the 1% level.
Our findings suggest that a unit increase in democracy score in the host and neighboring countries
would lead to a rise in FDI flows to host countries of roughly 3.5% and 4%, respectively. A one stan-
dard deviation increase in the democracy level of neighboring countries (i.e. 5.585) leads to a 24.33%
increase in FDI flows to host countries (based on the coefficient of the democracy level of neighboring
countries in column 4 of Table3). For a country that receives average FDI flows of $461 million, a one
standard deviation increase in the democracy level of neighboring countries leads to a $112.16 million
increase in FDI flows. On the other hand, the estimated coefficient of lagged FDI flows is 0.819 in
column 4 where we control for all neighboring country characteristics, which would suggest that the
long-run effect of a unit increase in the democracy level of neighboring countries is roughly 24%.8
Overall, our main finding (i.e. the quality of institutions in neighboring countries is positively
associated with FDI flows) is robust after accounting for various fixed effects (results obtained with
12
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
the gravity model), other neighboring country characteristics such as the market size and potential
and conflict in neighboring countries, and even after tackling potential endogeneity problem (results
obtained with system GMM estimations).
5.3
|
Results with the use of different samples
We carry out robustness checks of our findings when we use different samples to test whether our
findings are driven by some particular set of countries, and the results are presented in Table4. We
use the same set of neighboring country characteristics in our analysis to compare our findings with
the baseline finding, which is in column 4 of Table3 using the full sample case.
In column 1 of Table4 we exclude the islands from our analysis to examine whether the defini-
tion of closest neighbor for island countries affect our results or not. We find that the effect of the
democracy level in neighboring countries increases when compared to the baseline sample. This is
something that was expected as the effect of contagious countries on each other would be larger when
compared to islands that are relatively secluded from each other.
In column 2 we exclude the European Union countries from the list to examine whether our results
might be driven by the membership of the EU, since entry and membership of the EU require conver-
gence in democratic institutions through EU legislation as well as economic convergence through the
TABLE 3 Controlling for other neighboring characteristics with system GMM
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.820*** (0.00671) 0.820*** (0.00671) 0.819*** (0.00680) 0.819*** (0.00678)
Democracyj,t–1 0.0361** (0.0173) 0.0365** (0.0175) 0.0342** (0.0172) 0.0342** (0.0174)
N_Democracyj,t–1 0.0325** (0.0166) 0.0343** (0.0165) 0.0370** (0.0182) 0.0390** (0.0193)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 0.392*** (0.0202) 0.391*** (0.0202) 0.401*** (0.0206) 0.400*** (0.0206)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.369*** (0.0212) 0.365*** (0.0218) 0.382*** (0.0206) 0.377*** (0.0213)
Conflictj,t–1 −0.0240 (0.0430) −0.0205 (0.0436) −0.0191 (0.0433) −0.0152 (0.0440)
N_Conflictj,t–1 −0.0148 (0.0151) −0.0148 (0.0152) −0.0143 (0.0152) −0.0141 (0.0153)
ln(N_GDP)j,t–1 0.0107 (0.0164) 0.00838 (0.0165)
ln(Market
potential)j,t–1
0.452*** (0.112) 0.466*** (0.119)
Observations 28,272 28,007 28,272 28,007
Number of pairs 3,905 3,874 3,905 3,874
AR(3) (p-value)a .984 .993 .984 .994
Overidentification
test (p-value)b
.097 .110 .103 .119
Notes: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country
j at time t. Democracy and N_Democracy are the institutional quality proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the
host country, respectively. Conflict and N_Conflict are the conflict levels in the host and neighboring countries of the host country,
respectively. N_GDP represents the average GDP of the neighboring countries of host country. All estimations utilize the system
GMM estimation technique and use 3–5 lags for the endogenous variables. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%
level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.
aArellano–Bond test that the third-order autocorrelation in residuals is 0. First- second-order autocorrelations are not reported as they
are rejected at the 10% significance level.
bHansen J-test for overidentification of restrictions in GMM estimation.
|
13
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 4 System GMM estimations with different samples
Variables
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
No islands No EU No euro zone No OECD No SSA No high income
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.813*** (0.00724) 0.808*** (0.00750) 0.816*** (0.00717) 0.817*** (0.00781) 0.822*** (0.00719) 0.805*** (0.00850)
Democracyj,t–1 0.0372** (0.0175) 0.0379** (0.0169) 0.0391** (0.0178) 0.0337** (0.0165) 0.0368** (0.0179) 0.0366** (0.0176)
N_Democracyj,t–1 0.0529** (0.0220) 0.0514** (0.0211) 0.0433** (0.0215) 0.0454** (0.0217) 0.0468** (0.0219) 0.0511** (0.0229)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 0.406*** (0.0215) 0.475*** (0.0244) 0.428*** (0.0222) 0.462*** (0.0261) 0.394*** (0.0234) 0.484*** (0.0271)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.390*** (0.0225) 0.414*** (0.0241) 0.392*** (0.0228) 0.422*** (0.0270) 0.348*** (0.0236) 0.428*** (0.0292)
Conflictj,t–1 −0.0218 (0.0449) −0.0128 (0.0440) −0.0234 (0.0458) −0.0122 (0.0459) 0.0322 (0.0481) −0.0145 (0.0449)
N_Conflictj,t–1 −0.00498 (0.0161) −0.0110 (0.0153) −0.00673 (0.0161) −0.00895 (0.0156) 0.0106 (0.0154) −0.00351 (0.0171)
ln(N_GDP)j,t–1 −0.00181 (0.0179) −0.000729 (0.0167) 0.00415 (0.0162) 0.0149 (0.0181) −0.0227 (0.0218) 0.00100 (0.0194)
ln(Market
potential)j,t–1
0.346*** (0.125) 0.647*** (0.191) 0.560*** (0.153) 0.571*** (0.202) 0.662*** (0.125) 0.576*** (0.208)
Observations 26,133 22,808 25,503 19,754 21,865 18,204
Number of pairs 3,615 3,341 3,668 2,889 2,945 2,611
AR(3) (p-value)a .936 .868 .790 .849 .652 .802
Over-identification
test (p-value)b
.169 .180 .106 .175 .323 .262
Notes: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country j at time t. Democracy and N_Democracy are the institutional
quality proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the host country, respectively. Conflict and N_Conflict are the conflict levels in the host and neighboring countries of the host country,
respectively. N_GDP represents the average GDP of the neighboring countries of the host country. All estimations utilize the system GMM estimation technique and use 3–5 lags for the endogenous
variables. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.
aArellano–Bond test that the third-order autocorrelation in residuals is 0. First- second-order autocorrelations are not reported as they are rejected at the 10% significance level.
bHansen J-test for overidentification of restrictions in GMM estimation.
14
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
European Structural and Investment Funds.9 When the EU countries are excluded from our sample,
the coefficients of the democracy level of the host countries and neighboring countries are still posi-
tive and statistically significant at the 5% level. In column 3 we exclude the subgroup of EU countries
from our sample which are also part of the euro zone. In that case, the democracy levels in the host
and neighboring countries remain positive and significant at the 5% level. In column 4 we exclude the
OECD countries from the host country group, and the results of our main variable of interest (neigh-
boring democratic institutions) remain significant.
In column 5 we exclude the countries in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) from our analysis since the
neighboring country characteristics have been found to be important for this region (Easterly &
Levine, 2000). Furthermore, factors that attract FDI to this region are found to be different compared
to other developing countries (Asiedu, 2002), and improvements in institutional quality in this region
have fallen behind other developing regions (Asiedu, 2004), even though market access to this region
has had a positive effect in recent years (Bosker & Garretsen, 2012). The positive effect of neighbor-
ing institutional quality on FDI flows to host countries remains significant after excluding the SSA
countries from our analysis.
We exclude the high-income countries from our analysis in column 6.10 Similarly to the EU case,
institutional quality in both host and neighboring countries remains a significant factor, with relatively
higher coefficients estimates compared to the baseline ones.
Finally, irrespective of the sample used, coefficients on the lagged FDI, the market size of the
source and host country, and host country market potential remain positive and significant at the 1%
level.
5.4
|
Controlling for additional host country characteristics
We also control for some other characteristics of the host country since they could be correlated with
neighbor country characteristics, and their omission could lead to omitted variable bias. For instance,
to be part of the EU, countries need to follow the Copenhagen criteria that require ‘stable condi-
tions guaranteeing democracy [and] the rule of law’. This enables countries to trade freely, hence
increasing trade, financial integration, and infrastructure integration through the European Structural
and Investment Funds Regulations. In other words, the initial conditions to be part of the EU (i.e.
institutional, political, and economic requirements) provided a way to promote trade, financial, and
structural integration. To control whether the diffusion of institutional quality (i.e. institutional qual-
ity levels in the neighboring countries) does not have an effect on FDI flows through these factors,
we control for capital account openness, trade openness, and infrastructure levels in the host country.
Furthermore, Asiedu and Lien (2011) find that democracy promotes higher FDI flows if and only
if a host country has a natural resource rent that is less than a given threshold, and as such, we also
control for oil rents of the host country. Table5 presents the results when we control for capital open-
ness (measured as the updated capital account openness measure of Chinn & Ito, 2006, 2008), trade
openness (measured as the total value of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP), infrastructure
(measured as the number of telephone lines per 100 people) and oil rents (measured as the value of
oil rents as a percentage of GDP) of the host country, which are obtained from World Development
Indicators of the World Bank, respectively. Columns 1–4 report the results when we include capital
account openness, trade openness, infrastructure level, and oil rents of the host country in the analysis
one at a time, respectively. We find that countries that trade more and with better infrastructure also
receive relatively higher FDI flows. Finally, column 5 of Table5 controls for all these factors; now
capital openness becomes negative and significant. More importantly, after accounting for additional
|
15
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 5 System GMM results with additional host country characteristics
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.820*** (0.00678) 0.814*** (0.00693) 0.816*** (0.00670) 0.818*** (0.00659) 0.816*** (0.00666)
Democracyj,t–1 0.0390** (0.0190) 0.0427** (0.0202) 0.0367** (0.0176) 0.0487** (0.0202) 0.0395* (0.0202)
N_Democracyj,t–1 0.0379* (0.0212) 0.0469** (0.0227) 0.0406* (0.0211) 0.0508** (0.0225) 0.0494** (0.0225)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 0.397*** (0.0206) 0.406*** (0.0208) 0.403*** (0.0206) 0.402*** (0.0209) 0.401*** (0.0207)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.380*** (0.0221) 0.404*** (0.0214) 0.335*** (0.0280) 0.359*** (0.0237) 0.361*** (0.0296)
Conflictj,t–1 −0.0214 (0.0464) 0.0260 (0.0566) 0.00872 (0.0494) 0.00260 (0.0563) 0.0880 (0.0586)
N_Conflictj,t –1 −0.00211 (0.0161) 0.00506 (0.0185) 0.00529 (0.0172) −0.00214 (0.0177) 0.00399 (0.0185)
ln(N_GDP)j,t–1 0.00581 (0.0169) −0.0168 (0.0172) −0.0212 (0.0185) 0.00452 (0.0168) −0.0322* (0.0190)
ln(Market potential)j,t–1 0.472*** (0.123) 0.407*** (0.117) 0.420*** (0.127) 0.516*** (0.109) 0.360*** (0.109)
Capital opennessj,t–1 −0.0825 (0.126) −0.267*** (0.0952)
Trade opennessj,t–1 0.00483*** (0.000561) 0.00436*** (0.000625)
ln(Phones per 100)j,t–1 0.148*** (0.0570) 0.144*** (0.0550)
Oil rentsj,t–1 0.00412 (0.00427) 0.00161 (0.00403)
Observations 27,515 27,679 27,851 27,634 26,675
Number of pairs 3,826 3,848 3,873 3,837 3,759
AR(3) (p-value)a .740 .934 .949 .961 .796
Overidentification test
(p-value)b
.131 .148 .139 .135 .131
Notes: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country j at time t. Democracy and N_Democracy are the institutional
quality proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the host country, respectively. Conflict and N_Conflict are the conflict levels in the host and neighboring countries of the host country,
respectively. N_GDP represents the average GDP of the neighboring countries of host country. All estimations utilize the system GMM estimation technique and uses 3–5 lags for the endogenous
variables. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.
aArellano–Bond test that the third-order autocorrelation in residuals is 0. First- second-order autocorrelations are not reported as they are rejected at the 10% significance level.
bHansen J-test for overidentification of restrictions in GMM estimation.
16
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
host country characteristics, the effects of host country and neighboring countries’ institutional set-
tings on FDI flows remain significant.
5.5
|
Controlling for alternative institutional quality measures
We have chosen the democracy measure as our main institutional quality measure as it captures various
aspects of the institutional setting (see Section3 for discussion). To control whether our results are robust
to additional measures of institutional quality, we further control for, on the one hand, the rule of law
and, on the other hand, political stability and absence-of-violence measures from the World Governance
Indicators. The former is one of the most common measures used to assess institutional quality, whereas
the latter can be considered as an additional control for political stability. Similarly to the previous cases,
we use the institutional quality measures (democracy and the rule of law) and civil conflict measures
as endogenous variables in our estimations. Table6 summarizes the results when we include the rule
of law in the host country and the rule of law in the neighboring countries in our analysis. We find that
the rule of law in the host country does matter for FDI flows as countries with better-functioning legal
systems attract relatively higher FDI flows, yet the effect of the rule of law in the neighboring countries
is negative and statistically insignificant. We repeat our analysis by including political stability and the
absence-of-violence proxy. Our findings for the political stability proxy are similar to those for the rule
of law, where higher levels of political stability in the host country attract higher capital flows, yet the
political stability proxy in neighboring countries is not significant. The remaining factors are in line with
the findings of the previous tables. Moreover, most importantly, the democracy level in both the host
country and neighboring countries positively and significantly affects the levels of FDI flows.
5.6
|
Results with the use of alternative democracy proxy
We used the democracy index from the Polity IV project as our proxy to measure the quality of demo-
cratic institutions of the host and the neighboring countries of the host country. To control whether our
results are robust to an alternative proxy of democratic institutions, we use the Varieties of Democracy
(V-DEM) indicator of political corruption index. The index is arrived at by taking the average of the
public sector corruption index, the executive corruption index, the indicator for legislative corruption
and the indicator for judicial corruption (for details, see Coppedge et al., 2020; Pemstein et al., 2020),
which could be considered as a measure of political accountability (for examinations of the impact of
democratic accountability on FDI flows, see Kolstad & Villanger, 2008; Doytch & Eren, 2012; Bailey,
2018). The political corruption index ranges between 0 and 1, and higher values represent a higher pres-
ence of corruption in executive, legislative, and judicial levels. To be consistent with the democracy
index of Polity IV, we reverse the measure so that higher values represent lower political corruption.
Table7 presents the results when we re-estimate the equations of Tables2 and 3 with the use of
the political corruption variable as a proxy for democratic accountability instead of the democracy
index from Polity IV. The results reported in columns 1–4 and 5–8 of Table7 are obtained with the
gravity and system GMM models, respectively. With either estimation method, we find that political
corruption in the host and the neighboring countries is a significant determinant of the FDI flows to
the host country. Furthermore, in all cases, the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions suggests
that we cannot reject the null hypothesis of instrument validity. Overall, we find that the quality of the
democratic institutions in the neighboring countries of the host country is a significant determinant
of the FDI flows to the host country even after using an alternative proxy for democratic institutions.
|
17
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 6 System GMM estimations with additional institutional quality measures
Lags used
Rule of law Political stability
3–5 3+ 3–5 3+
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.823*** (0.00697) 0.823*** (0.00679) 0.823*** (0.00675) 0.823*** (0.00670)
Democracyj,t–1 0.0435*** (0.0157) 0.0328** (0.0135) 0.0273** (0.0136) 0.0254** (0.0124)
N_Democracyj,t–1 0.0462** (0.0201) 0.0396** (0.0178) 0.0372** (0.0179) 0.0297* (0.0163)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 0.389*** (0.0205) 0.386*** (0.0202) 0.385*** (0.0202) 0.384*** (0.0201)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.337*** (0.0297) 0.318*** (0.0268) 0.347*** (0.0229) 0.342*** (0.0219)
Conflictj,t–1 −0.0226 (0.0430) 0.00408 (0.0366) 0.0615 (0.0480) 0.0377 (0.0412)
N_Conflictj,t–1 0.00119 (0.0149) 0.000182 (0.0132) 0.000538 (0.0144) 0.00744 (0.0133)
ln(N_GDP)j,t–1 0.0158 (0.0238) 0.00458 (0.0211) −0.0125 (0.0170) −0.0126 (0.0163)
ln(Market potential)j,t–1 0.798*** (0.136) 0.709*** (0.129) 0.695*** (0.122) 0.659*** (0.117)
Rule of lawj,t–1 0.220* (0.115) 0.291*** (0.102)
N_Rule of lawj,t–1 −0.178 (0.178) −0.122 (0.150)
Political stabilityj,t–1 0.344*** (0.0973) 0.312*** (0.0828)
N_Political stabilityj,t–1 −0.0722 (0.126) 0.0263 (0.109)
Observations 26,120 26,120 26,120 26,120
Number of pairs 3,867 3,867 3,867 3,867
AR(3) (p-value)a .999 .999 .997 .997
Over-identification test (p-value)b .060 .120 .101 .189
Notes: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country j at time t. Democracy and N_Democracy are the institutional
quality proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the host country, respectively. Conflict and N_Conflict are the conflict levels in the host and neighboring countries of the host country,
respectively. N_GDP represents the average GDP of the neighboring countries of host country. Rule of law and N_Rule of law represent the quality of rule of law in host country and neighboring
countries of the host country, respectively. Political stability and N_Political stability represent the quality of political stability in host country and neighboring countries of the host country,
respectively. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.
aArellano–Bond test that the third-order autocorrelation in residuals is 0. First- second-order autocorrelations are not reported as they are rejected at the 10% significance level.
bHansen J-test for overidentification of restrictions in GMM estimation.
18
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 7 Gravity and system GMM estimations with the use of the political corruption variable as a democratic accountability proxy
Variables
Gravity model System GMM
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
ln(FDI flows)i,j,t–1 0.772***
(0.00725)
0.769***
(0.00732)
0.768***
(0.00727)
0.767***
(0.00735)
0.824***
(0.00615)
0.824***
(0.00618)
0.824***
(0.00629)
0.823***
(0.00635)
Political corruptionj,t–1 0.753***
(0.126)
0.860***
(0.126)
0.824***
(0.124)
0.774***
(0.128)
0.615***
(0.122)
0.684***
(0.109)
0.666***
(0.112)
0.623***
(0.125)
N_Political corruptionj,t–1 0.353**
(0.154)
0.308**
(0.156)
0.335**
(0.148)
0.274*
(0.157)
0.299**
(0.132)
0.472*
(0.245)
0.331**
(0.136)
0.278*
(0.146)
ln(GDP)i,t–1 0.470***
(0.0225)
0.475***
(0.0227)
0.479***
(0.0225)
0.477***
(0.0227)
0.385***
(0.0194)
0.383***
(0.0194)
0.387***
(0.0244)
0.389***
(0.0249)
ln(GDP)j,t–1 0.450***
(0.0216)
0.446***
(0.0214)
0.465***
(0.0211)
0.476***
(0.0227)
0.352***
(0.0212)
0.362***
(0.0263)
0.347***
(0.0297)
0.370***
(0.0361)
Conflictj,t–1 −0.0363**
(0.0178)
−0.0373**
(0.0180)
−0.0351
(0.0612)
−0.0334
(0.0640)
N_Conflictj,t–1 −0.0140**
(0.00652)
−0.0207***
(0.00678)
−0.00354
(0.00682)
−0.00440
(0.00684)
ln(N_GDP)j,t–1 0.0190
(0.0168)
0.0262
(0.0166)
−0.0674
(0.0797)
−0.0287
(0.0862)
ln(Market potential)j,t–1 0.895***
(0.128)
0.912***
(0.129)
0.158
(0.794)
0.245
(0.824)
Observations 28,578 28,531 28,796 28,313 28,578 28,313 28,578 28,313
Number of pairs 3,935 3,904 3,935 3,904 3,935 3,904 3,935 3,904
R-squared .8355 .8345 .8346 .8360
AR(3) (p-value)a .928 .847 .868 .907
Over-identification test (p-value)b .233 .207 .180 .211
Note: The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the foreign direct investment flows from source country i to host country j at time t. Political corruption and N_Political corruption are the
political corruption proxies for the host country and neighboring countries of the host country, respectively. Conflict and N_Conflict are the conflict levels in the host and neighboring countries of the
host country, respectively. N_GDP represents the average GDP of the neighboring countries of the host country. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust
standard errors are reported in parentheses.
aArellano–Bond test that the third-order autocorrelation in residuals is 0. First- second-order autocorrelations are not reported as they are rejected at the 10% significance level.
bHansen J-test for overidentification of restrictions in GMM estimation.
|
19
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE 8 Possible indirect links between neighboring institutional quality and host country characteristics
Host country characteristics
Democracy (Polity IV) in
neighboring countries
Democracy (Political corruption) in
neighboring countries
Rule of law in neighboring
countries
Political stability in
neighboring countries
Democracy (Polity IV) 0.719*** (0.00328) 11.22*** (0.0561) 3.319*** (0.0167) 3.672*** (0.0225)
Democracy (Political
corruption)
0.0227*** (0.000194) 0.868*** (0.00233) 0.257*** (0.000779) 0.259*** (0.00106)
Rule of law 0.0706*** (0.000717) 2.956*** (0.00856) 0.902*** (0.00246) 0.894*** (0.00362)
Political stability 0.0707*** (0.000677) 2.330*** (0.00981) 0.676*** (0.00294) 0.784*** (0.00365)
Conflict −0.0510*** (0.00082) −1.030*** (0.0154) −0.278*** (0.00467) −0.328*** (0.00672)
ln(GDP) 0.101*** (0.00115) 4.052*** (0.0206) 1.279*** (0.00621) 1.210*** (0.00753)
ln(GDP per capita) 0.106*** (0.00109) 4.330*** (0.0126) 1.350*** (0.00396) 1.319*** (0.00553)
Notes: Different host country characteristics are used as dependent variables. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Robust standard errors are reported in
parentheses.
20
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
5.7
|
Possible indirect channels of neighboring institutional quality
We have examined how institutional quality in neighboring countries directly affects FDI flows to
host countries. We now examine briefly how neighboring institutional quality might also affect other
factors in the host country that are also found to be important in attracting FDI flows to these countries.
Table8 suggests some possible ways in which institutional quality in neighboring countries (i.e.
two proxies of democracy, the rule of law, and political stability in the neighboring countries) might
influence some other characteristics of the host country. This table presents regression results that
summarize the association between host country characteristics and the institutional quality of the
neighboring countries after controlling for year effects.
The significant associations between neighboring institutions and the characteristics of the host
country are in line with the existing literature. We find that countries that are surrounded by other
countries with good institutions will also have a good institutional setting (see, for example, Kelejian
et al., 2013, who show that the rule of law in neighboring countries has a direct effect on the rule
of law of the home country after accounting for a variety of control variables). Even though the rule of
law and political stability in neighboring countries are not significant in our results, improvements of
these in neighboring countries can affect the rule of law and political stability in the host countries,
something that, in turn, was found to be important in attracting higher FDI flows. In other words,
better rule of law and higher political stability in neighboring countries leads to higher capital flows
to host countries via their effect on the host country’s institutional setting. Similarly, countries that
are surrounded by better democracies tend to be more democratic themselves, suggesting that the
democratic neighbors have not only a direct but also an indirect effect on FDI flows to host countries.
Moreover, being surrounded by countries with good institutions leads not only to higher institutional
quality for a given host country but also to higher levels of economic development—see, for exam-
ple, seminal papers by Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001) and Rodrik et al. (2004) which
show that institutional quality is one of the main determinants of long-term economic development.
Furthermore, these countries achieve higher development levels since there is a significant correlation
between market size (i.e. GDP) and standard of living (i.e. GDP per capita) with neighboring institu-
tions (see, for example, Bosker & Garretsen, 2009, who found that the neighboring institutions have
a direct effect on economic development of countries). Furthermore, countries that are surrounded by
good institutions experience lower civil conflict and have higher political stability.
Overall, Table8 summarizes some channels by which the institutional quality of neighboring
countries and as well the institutional quality of the host country might play a role in attracting higher
levels of FDI. In our analysis, we provided the direct link that democratic institutions of the neigh-
boring countries do indeed matter for the FDI flows to host countries, yet these channels need to be
further explored to disentangle how and why institutions matter for attracting capital.
6
|
CONCLUSIONS AND DISCUSSION
In this paper we examine whether democratic institutions in neighboring countries matter for FDI
flows to host countries. We find that investing countries not only look at the democratic institutions
of the host country but also evaluate the democratic institutions in neighboring countries when they
decide to invest. In particular, we find that countries that are democratic and surrounded by other
democratic countries receive relatively higher FDI flows. Our results were robust to the choice of
different estimation techniques (gravity model and system GMM), different samples, and another set
of neighboring country characteristics such as the conflict in neighboring countries, market size of
|
21
PINAR ANd STENGOS
the neighboring countries, and market potential of the host country. We also controlled for alternative
measures of institutional quality settings and used an alternative proxy for democratic institutions,
and we find that democratic institutions in neighboring countries still matter for FDI flows to host
countries. Furthermore, in some specifications, we find that civil conflict in neighboring countries
also leads to lower levels of FDI flows to host countries, and countries that are close to relatively
larger markets also receive more FDI flows. In all specifications, we also find that host countries that
have higher market potential (i.e. if a host country is relatively closer to high-income countries) also
receive relatively higher FDI flows. Furthermore, we briefly investigated potential indirect links of
neighboring country institutional settings with other factors in the host country. For instance, we find
that countries that are surrounded by neighbors that have better institutions tend to have a better in-
stitutional setting themselves. In other words, improvements in neighboring institutions also increase
the FDI flows to host countries through their effect on a better institutional setting of the host country.
Considering both the direct and indirect effects of the democracy level of neighboring countries, its
impact on FDI flows is significant in both the short and long term.
Our study provides empirical support for the importance of neighboring country characteristics on
the FDI location choice. Even though the institutional theory is one of the most utilized frameworks in
this research, its use in empirical work is relatively small (see, for example, Blonigen & Piger, 2014;
Nielsen et al., 2017). In this paper our empirical findings show that it is not only the institutional
setting of the host countries that matters for the location choice of the FDI but also the institutional
setting of the neighboring countries. Therefore, future studies should incorporate neighboring country
characteristics into their analysis.
Our results suggest that if neighboring countries act together to improve their institutional quality,
FDI flows to these countries will be much higher since not only does improving their institutional
quality attracts more FDI inflows but also being surrounded by neighboring countries that have better
institutional quality will also lead to higher FDI flows. In other words, regions that are clustered with
relatively low institutional quality (or with lower democratic institutions) can attract higher levels of
FDI flows by acting together and improving their institutional settings.
We should note that we analyzed FDI flows from the OECD countries to an extensive list of host
countries. We found that the OECD countries give importance to the institutional quality setting of the
host country and also whether countries are surrounded by other countries with good institutions when
investing. However, investments made by emerging and developing countries have become important
in recent years. For instance, it has been found that emerging economies have a better willingness to
operate in countries that have relatively poor institutions (see, for example, Aleksynska & Havrylchyk,
2013). For example, Chinese outward investments go to countries that have relatively poor institutions
(see, for example, Kolstad & Wiig, 2012). Hence, even though a better institutional setting in neigh-
boring countries matters for the OECD countries, it might not do so in the case of emerging economies
investing in other countries. As a result, countries that are surrounded by countries with relatively poor
institutions might receive relatively lower FDI flows from the OECD countries, but might receive
relatively higher investment from emerging markets. This can then lead to divergence in the evolution
of institutional settings, depending on the origins of the FDI flows. This is potentially a new research
area, which needs to be investigated in the future.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Mehmet Pinar is grateful to the financial support from the British Academy's Advanced Newton
Fellowship (AF140068) and the Research Investment Fund of Edge Hill University. Thanasis Stengos
acknowledges the financial support from the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council
of Canada (401004). The authors are grateful to the participants of the 4th International Conference
22
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
on Applied Theory, Macro and Empirical Finance (2018) and two anonymous reviewers for their
comments.
DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT
The data used in this paper is derived from public domain resources. The detailed data sources are
given in the Appendix.
ORCID
Mehmet Pinar https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5518-188X
Thanasis Stengos https://orcid.org/0000-0002-7771-1121
ENDNOTES
1 Note that we discuss only some of the papers that analyze the importance of democracy, political risk, and institu-
tional setting in the host countries, among many other factors that are found to be important, such as the financial
openness of a country, institutional distance between source and host country, trade openness, tax levels, and differ-
ences in wage levels in two countries—see Blonigen and Piger (2014) and Nielsen, Asmussen, and Weatherall (2017)
for a review of literature on determinants of FDI.
2 The detailed bilateral FDI flows from OECD countries to partner countries can be obtained from https://stats.oecd.
org/index.aspx?DataS etCod e=FDI_FLOW_PARTNER.
3 For instance, Estonia and Slovenia gained their independence in 1991 and both the Czech Republic and Slovakia
became independent nations in 1993 after the dissolution of Czechoslovakia.
4 When a country is an island, we consider the closest country in terms of distance between capital cities of countries.
Note that we also repeated our analysis by excluding islands from the sample, and the results are presented in Section
5.
5 The choice of endogenous variables is in line the recent literature analyzing similar relationships. For instance,
Asiedu and Lien (2011) use a similar estimation technique considering democracy as an endogenous variable,
whereas, Qureshi (2013) considers conflict in the host and neighboring countries as endogenous variables.
6 The first two orders of autocorrelation are rejected at the 10% significance level. However, in all cases, the Arellano–
Bond test that the third-order autocorrelation in residuals is 0 is not rejected and we used third or higher lags as
instrumental variables.
7 We also included the average GDP per capita levels of neighboring countries in our regressions and found that the co-
efficient on average GDP per capita of neighboring countries is not significant after controlling for other neighboring
country characteristics.
8 Note that the coefficient estimates are obtained with log-level regressions and the estimated percentage change is
calculated as
100 (
e
0.0390(10.819)
1
)
.
9 We exclude the EU countries from the year that they became a member. We also redo our analysis by only excluding
those countries from the sample which were members during the whole period and the results are similar to those
reported here; these results are available upon request from the authors.
10 We use the World Bank classification to exclude the high-income countries from the analysis.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical
Investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.
Ades, A., & Chua, H. B. (1997). Thy neighbor’s curse: Regional instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic
Growth, 2(3), 279–304.
Aleksynska, M., & Havrylchyk, O. (2013). FDI from the south: The role of institutional distance and natural resources.
European Journal of Political Economy, 29, 38–53.
|
23
PINAR ANd STENGOS
Alfaro, L., Kalemli-Ozkan, S., & Volosovych, V. (2008). Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? An
empirical investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2), 347–368.
Anderson, J., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas. American Economic Review, 93, 170–192.
Asiedu, E. (2002). On the determinants of foreign direct investment to developing countries: Is Africa different? World
Development, 30(1), 107–119.
Asiedu, E. (2004). Policy reform and foreign direct investment in Africa: Absolute progress but relative decline.
Development Policy Review, 22(1), 41–48.
Asiedu, E., & Lien, D. (2011). Democracy, foreign direct investment and natural resources. Journal of International
Economics, 84(1), 99–111.
Aziz, O. G. (2018). Institutional quality and FDI inflows in Arab economies. Finance Research Letters, 25, 111–123.
Baez, J. E. (2011). Civil wars beyond their borders: The human capital and health consequences of hosting refugees.
Journal of Development Economics, 96(2), 391–408.
Baier, S., & Bergstrand, J. (2007). Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of
International Economics, 71(1), 72–95.
Bailey, N. (2018). Exploring the relationship between institutional factors and FDI attractiveness: A meta-analytic re-
view. International Business Review, 27, 139–148.
Balgati, B. H., Egger, P., & Pfaffermayr, M. (2008). Estimating regional trade agreement effects on FDI in an interde-
pendent world. Journal of Econometrics, 145(2), 194–208.
Bandyopadhyay, S., Sandler, T., & Younas, J. (2014). Foreign direct investment, aid, and terrorism. Oxford Economic
Papers, 66(1), 25–50.
Bekaert, G., Harvey, C. R., Lundblad, C. T., & Siegel, S. (2014). Political risk spread. Journal of International Business
Studies, 45(4), 471–493.
Belgibayeva, A., & Plekhanov, A. (2019). Does corruption matter for sources of foreign direct investment? Review of
World Economics, 155, 487–510.
Bellos, S., & Subasat, T. (2012). Corruption and foreign direct investment: A panel gravity model approach. Bulletin of
Economic Research, 64, 565–574.
Bergstrand, J., & Egger, P. (2011). Gravity equations and economic frictions in the world economy. In D. Bernhofen, R.
Falvey, D. Greenaway, & U. Kreickemeier (Eds.), Palgrave handbook of international trade. Basingstoke: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Blanco, L. R. (2012). The spatial interdependence of FDI in Latin America. World Development, 40(7), 1337–1351.
Blattman, C., & Miguel, E. (2010). Civil war. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 3–57.
Blonigen, B. A., & Piger, J. (2014). Determinants of foreign direct investment. Canadian Journal of Economics, 47(3),
775–812.
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of
Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.
Bosker, M., & Garretsen, H. (2009). Economic development and the geography of institutions. Journal of Economic
Geography, 9(3), 295–328.
Bosker, M., & Garretsen, H. (2012). Economic geography and economic development in Sub-Saharan Africa. World
Bank Economic Review, 26(3), 443–485.
Chenaf-Nicet, D., & Rougier, E. (2016). The effect of macroeconomic instability on FDI flows: A gravity estimation
of the impact of regional integration in the case of Euro-Mediterranean agreements. International Economics, 145,
66–91.
Cherif, M., & Dreger, C. (2018). Do regional trade agreements stimulate FDI? Evidence for the Agadir, MERCOSUR
and AFTA regions. Review of Development Economics, 22(3), 1263–1277.
Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions.
Journal of Development Economics, 81(1), 163–192.
Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2008). A new measure of financial openness. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research
and Practice, 10(3), 309–322.
Cizkowicz, P., Cizkowicz-Pekala, M., Pekala, P., & Rzonca, A. (2017). The effects of special economic zones on em-
ployment and investment: A spatial panel modeling perspective. Journal of Economic Geography, 17(3), 571–605.
Coppedge, M., Gerring, J., Knutsen, C. H., Lindberg, S. I., Teorell, J., Altman, D., … Ziblatt, D. (2020). V-Dem
[Country–Year/Country–Date] Dataset v10. Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project. https://doi.org/10.23696/
vdemds20
24
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
Corsetti, G., Pericoli, M., & Sbracia, M. (2005). ‘Some contagion, some interdependence’: More pitfalls in tests of
financial contagion. Journal of International Money and Finance, 24(8), 1177–1199.
Crafts, N., & Venables, A. J. (2003). Globalization in history: a geographical perspective. In M. D. Bordo, A. M. Taylor,
& J. G. Williamson (Eds.), Globalization in historical perspective, (chapter 7). Chicago: The University of Chicago
Press.
de Sousa, J., Mayer, T., & Zignago, S. (2012). Market access in global and regional trade. Regional Science and Urban
Economics, 42(6), 1037–1052.
Dell’Erba, S., & Reinhardt, D. (2015). FDI, debt and capital controls. Journal of International Money and Finance, 58,
29–50.
Demir, F. (2016). Effects of FDI flows on institutional development: Does it matter where the investors are from? World
Development, 78, 341–359.
Donaubauer, J., Neumayer, E., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2020). Financial market development in host and source countries
and their effects on bilateral foreign direct investment. World Economy, 43(3), 534–556.
Doytch, N., & Eren, M. (2012). Institutional determinants of sectoral FDI in Eastern European and Central Asian
Countries: The role of investment climate and democracy. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 48, 14–32.
Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (2000). Troubles with the neighbours: Africa’s problem, Africa’s opportunity. Journal of
African Economies, 7(1), 120–142.
Economou, F., Hassapis, C., Philippas, N., & Tsionas, M. (2017). Foreign direct investment determinants in OECD and
developing countries. Review of Development Economics, 21(3), 527–542.
Filer, R. K., & Stanišić, D. (2016). The effect of terrorist incidents on capital flows. Review of Development Economics,
20(2), 502–513.
Forbes, K. J., & Warnock, F. E. (2012). Capital flow waves: Surges, stops, flight, and retrenchment. Journal of
International Economics, 88(2), 235–251.
Gaibulloev, K., & Younas, J. (2016). Conflicts and domestic bank lending. Public Choice, 169(3–4), 315–331.
Haggard, S., & Tiede, L. (2011). The rule of law and economic growth: Where are we? World Development, 39(5),
673–685.
Head, K., & Mayer, T. (2014). Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In G. Gopinath, E. Helpman, & K.
Rogoff (Eds.), Handbook of international economics, Vol. 4 (pp. 131–195). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Head, K., & Ries, J. (2008). FDI as an outcome of the market for corporate control: Theory and evidence. Journal of
International Economics, 74, 2–20.
Hegre, H. (2014). Democracy and armed conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 51(2), 159–172.
Jakobsen, J., & De Soysa, I. (2006). Do foreign investors punish democracy? Theory and empirics, 1984–2001. Kyklos,
59(3), 383–410.
Jensen, N. M. (2003). Democratic governance and multinational corporations: Political regimes and inflows of foreign
direct investment. International Organization, 57(3), 587–616.
Kaminsky, G., & Reinhart, C. (2000). On crises, contagion and confusion. Journal of International Economics, 51(1),
145–168.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2013). Worldwide governance indicators project. Retrieved from http://info.
world bank.org/gover nance/ wgi/index.aspx#home
Kelejian, H. H., Murrell, P., & Shepotylo, O. (2013). Spatial spillovers in the development of institutions. Journal of
Development Economics, 101, 297–315.
Knutsen, C. H. (2011). Democracy, dictatorship and protection of property rights. Journal of Development Studies,
47(1), 164–182.
Kolstad, I., & Villanger, E. (2008). Determinants of foreign direct investment in services. European Journal of Political
Economy, 24, 518–533.
Kolstad, I., & Wiig, A. (2012). What determines Chinese outward FDI? Journal of World Business, 47(1), 26–34.
Liu, D., & Meissner, C. M. (2015). Market potential and the rise of US productivity leadership. Journal of International
Economics, 96(1), 72–87.
Lucas, R. E. (1990). Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? American Economic Review, 80(2), 92–96.
Marshall, M. G., Gurr, T. R., & Jaggers, K. (2016). Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions
1800–2015. Vienna, VA: Center for Systemic Peace. Retrieved from http://www.syste micpe ace.org/inscr data.html
Martínez-San Román, V., Bengoa, M., & Sánchez-Robles, B. (2016). Foreign direct investment, trade integration and
the home bias: Evidence from the European Union. Empirical Economics, 50, 197–229.
|
25
PINAR ANd STENGOS
Mayer, T., & Zignago, S. (2011). Notes on CEPII’s distances measures: The GeoDist database (CEPII Working Paper
2011–25). Paris: Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales. Retrieved from http://www.cepii.
fr/PDF_PUB/wp/2011/wp201 1-25.pdf
Mishra, B. R., & Jena, P. K. (2019). Bilateral FDI flows in four major Asian economies: A gravity model analysis.
Journal of Economic Studies, 46(1), 71–89.
Moore, W. H., & Shellman, S. M. (2007). Whither will they go? A global study of refugees’ destinations, 1965–1995.
International Studies Quarterly, 51(4), 811–834.
Neanidis, K. C. (2019). Volatile capital flows and economic growth: The role of banking supervision. Journal of
Financial Stability, 40, 77–93.
Nielsen, B. B., Asmussen, C. G., & Weatherall, C. D. (2017). The location choice of foreign direct investments:
Empirical evidence and methodological challenges. Journal of World Business, 52(1), 62–82.
Pandya, S. S. (2014). Democratization and foreign direct investment liberalization, 1970-2000. International Studies
Quarterly, 58(3), 475–488.
Pemstein, D., Marquardt, K. L., Tzelgov, E., Wang, Y.-T., Medzihorsky, J., Krusell, J. … von Römer, J. (2020). The
V-Dem measurement model: Latent variable analysis for cross-national and cross-temporal expert-coded data (V-
Dem Working Paper No. 21, 5th ed.). Gothenburg: Varieties of Democracy Institute, University of Gothenburg.
Petri, P. A. (2012). The determinants of bilateral FDI: Is Asia different? Journal of Asian Economics, 23, 201–209.
Pinar, M., & Volkan, E. (2018). Institutions and information flows, and their effect on capital flows. Information
Economics and Policy, 43, 34–47.
Qureshi, M. S. (2013). Trade and thy neighbor’s war. Journal of Development Economics, 105, 178–195.
Redding, S., & Venables, A. J. (2004). Economic geography and international inequality. Journal of International
Economics, 62(1), 53–82.
Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions Over Geography and
Integration in Economic Development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165.
Saini, N., & Singhania, M. (2018). Determinants of FDI in developed and developing countries: A quantitative analysis
using GMM. Journal of Economic Studies, 45(2), 348–382.
Salehyan, I., & Gleditsch, K. S. (2006). Refugees and the spread of civil war. International Organization, 60(2), 335–366.
Schäffler, J., Hecht, V., & Moritz, M. (2017). Regional determinants of German FDI in the Czech Republic: New evi-
dence on the role of border regions. Regional Studies, 51(9), 1399–1411.
Thangavelu, S. M., & Narjoko, D. (2014). Human capital, FTAs and foreign direct investment flows into ASEAN.
Journal of Asian Economics, 35, 65–76.
Ullah, M. S., & Inaba, K. (2012). Impact of RTA and PTA on Bangladesh’s export: Application of a gravity model.
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 12, 445–460.
Ward, H., & Dorussen, H. (2015). Public information and performance: The role of spatial dependence in the worldwide
governance indicators among African countries. World Development, 74, 253–263.
Xu, T. (2019). Economic freedom and bilateral direct investment. Economic Modelling, 78, 172–179.
SUPPORTING INFORMATION
Additional Supporting Information may be found online in the Supporting Information section.
How to cite this article: Pinar M, Stengos T. Democracy in the neighborhood and foreign
direct investment. Rev Dev Econ. 2020;00:1–29. https://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12720
26
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
APPENDIX A
TABLE A1 Countries used in the analysis
Afghanistan Estonia* Lebanon Saudi Arabia
Albania Ethiopia Liberia Senegal
Algeria Finland* Libya Sierra Leone
Angola France* Lithuania Singapore
Argentina Gabon Luxembourg* Slovakia*
Armenia Gambia Madagascar Slovenia*
Australia* Georgia Malawi Somalia
Austria* Germany* Malaysia South Africa
Azerbaijan Ghana Mali Spain*
Bangladesh Greece* Mexico* Sri Lanka
Belarus Guatemala Moldova Sudan
Belgium* Guinea Mongolia Swaziland
Bolivia Guinea-Bissau Morocco Sweden*
Botswana Guyana Mozambique Switzerland*
Brazil Haiti Myanmar Syria
Bulgaria Honduras Namibia Tajikistan
Burkina Faso Hungary* Nepal Tanzania
Cameroon Iceland* Netherlands* Thailand
Canada* India New Zealand* Togo
Central Afr. Rep. Indonesia Nicaragua Trinidad &
Tobago
Chad Iran Niger Tunisia
Chile* Iraq Nigeria Turkey*
China Ireland* Norway* Turkmenistan
Colombia Israel* Oman Uganda
Congo, Dem. Rep. Italy* Pakistan Ukraine
Congo, Rep. Jamaica Panama United Arab
Emirates
Costa Rica Japan* Papua New Guinea United
Kingdom*
Côte d'Ivoire Jordan Paraguay United States*
Croatia Kazakhstan Peru Uruguay
Cyprus Kenya Philippines Uzbekistan
Czech Rep.* Korea, Dem. Rep. Poland* Venezuela
Denmark* Korea, Rep.* Portugal* Vietnam
Dominican Rep. Kuwait Qatar Yemen
Ecuador Kyrgyzstan Romania Zambia
Egypt Laos Russia Zimbabwe
El Salvador Latvia Rwanda
Notes: Countries with * are the OECD countries.
|
27
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE A2 Variables, definitions and sources
Variable Definition Source
Aggregate FDI inflows Aggregate FDI inflows (measured in U.S.
dollars)
World Bank – World
development Indicators (WDI)
FDI inflows Bilateral FDI flows from OECD countries to
host countries (measured in U.S. dollars)
OECD. Available via: https://data.
oecd.org/
GDP Gross Domestic Product (in constant 2010
U.S. dollars)
World Bank – WDI
GDP per capita GDP divided by the population World Bank – WDI
Population Country’s total population World Bank – WDI
Land area Country's total area (measured in km square) World Bank – WDI
Language Dummy variable indicating if a language is
spoken by at least 9% of the population in
source and host countries
Mayer and Zignago (2011)
Colony Dummy variable indicating whether source
and host countries have ever had a colonial
link
Mayer and Zignago (2011)
Distance Distance between most important cities/
agglomerations between source and host
countries
Mayer and Zignago (2011)
Regional trade agreements Dummy variable indicating whether a source
and host country has a regional trade
agreement in a given period or not.
World Trade Organisation.
Available via: https://rtais.
wto.org/UI/Publi cMain tainR
TAHome.aspx
Democracy Polity 2 measure ranges between −10
and+10, which suggests full autocracy and
democracy, respectively.
Polity IV Project, Political
Regime Characteristics and
Transitions, 1800–2015,
Available via: http://www.syste
micpe ace.org/inscr data.html
Rule of law Rule of law captures perceptions of the extent
to which agents have confidence in and abide
by the rules of society, and in particular the
quality of contract enforcement, property
rights, the police, and the courts, as well as
the likelihood of crime and violence, which
ranges between −2.5 and+2.5, where higher
score represents better rule of law.
Rule of law component of the
World Governance Indicators
(Kaufmann et al. 2013)
Available via: http://info.world
bank.org/gover nance/ wgi/#home
Political stability and
Absence of Violence
Political Stability and Absence of Violence/
Terrorism measures perceptions of the
likelihood of political instability and/or
politically motivated violence, including
terrorism. This measure ranges between −2.5
and+2.5, where higher score represents
higher political stability.
Political stability and absence
of violence component of the
World Governance Indicators
(Kaufmann et al. 2013)
Available via: http://info.world
bank.org/gover nance/ wgi/#home
(Continues)
28
|
PINAR ANd STENGOS
Variable Definition Source
Conflict Magnitude score of episode(s) of civil
violence and warfare, ethnic violence and
warfare involving that state in that year.
Center for Systemic Peace (CSP)
Major Episodes of Political
Violence, 1946–2015, URL:
www.syste micpe ace.org/warli
st.htm
Conflict in neighboring
countries
Sum of all societal (civil and ethnic) MEPV
magnitude scores for all neighboring
countries
Center for Systemic Peace (CSP)
Major Episodes of Political
Violence, 1946–2015, URL:
www.syste micpe ace.org/warli
st.htm
Capital account openness A measure of capital account liberalization
where the index ranges between 0 and 1,
where higher score represents more open
capital account. This index is based on IMF's
Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements
and Exchange Restrictions.
Chinn and Ito (2006, 2008).
Updated data available via:
http://web.pdx.edu/~ito/Chinn
-Ito_websi te.htm
Trade openness Total imports and exports of goods divided by
GDP, in %
World Bank – WDI
Phone Fixed telephone subscriptions (per 100
people)
World Bank – WDI
Oil rents/GDP Oil rents divided by GDP, in % World Bank – WDI
TABLE A2 (Contined)
|
29
PINAR ANd STENGOS
TABLE A3 Summary statistics
Variable Mean
Std.
Dev. Min Max Obs
ln (FDI flows) 9.46 8.91 0 25.87 38,891
Democracy in host country 4.38 6.27 −10 10 38,198
Democracy in neighbouring countries 3.83 5.44 −10 10 38,599
Rule of law in host country −0.01 1.07 −2.67 2.00 36,366
Rule of law in neighbouring countries −0.11 0.89 −1.91 1.98 36,366
Political stability of law in host country −0.15 1.01 −3.32 1.66 36,366
Political stability in neighbouring countries −0.22 0.77 −2.13 1.69 36,366
ln(Source country GDP) 26.80 1.57 22.76 30.37 38,891
ln(Host country GDP) 25.12 2.05 19.30 30.37 38,094
ln (Source country population) 16.48 1.55 12.48 19.57 38,891
ln (Host country population) 16.51 1.51 12.48 21.02 38,888
ln (Source land area) 12.05 1.58 7.86 16.03 38,891
ln (Host land area) 12.45 1.79 6.51 16.61 38,891
Common language dummy variable 0.09 0.29 0 1 38,891
Colony dummy variable 0.04 0.20 0 1 38,891
ln (Distance) 8.42 0.99 2.95 9.88 38,891
RTA dummy variable 0.29 0.46 0 1 38,891
Civil conflict in host country 0.51 1.41 0 10 38,599
Civil conflict in neighbouring countries 2.18 3.77 0 29 38,599
ln (Average GDP of neighbouring countries) 25.90 1.78 19.97 30.37 38,526
ln (Market Potential) 17.52 0.25 16.63 17.93 38,891
... This, in turn, leads to lower levels of civil conflict, increased political stability, and indirectly attracts higher flows of foreign direct investment (FDI). This suggests that the presence of positive institutional spillovers from neighboring countries can have a significant impact on enhancing the investment climate and economic prospects within a given country (Pinar & Stengos, 2021). ...
Thesis
With the irrevocable change in the Arab world over the last decade, fully understanding the economic and political impact of the Arab Spring is paramount for policymakers. This dissertation consists of three empirical essays on the Arab Spring which attempt to capture causal relationships between Arab Spring and some political and economic factors. Exogenous shocks such as the experiences of revolution are treated as natural experiments which minimize problems of endogeneity and selection. Therefore, these essays are analyzed based on the synthetic control method and synthetic difference-in-differences. The first essay concerns the impact of the Arab Spring on economic growth, corruption and democracy. I focused on Tunisia and Libya as a case study of Arab Spring countries using the synthetic control method (SCM). I found that there was a negative impact of the Arab Spring on economic growth after 2010 for both Tunisia and Libya. On the other hand, the results suggested that although there was a substantial increase in democracy after the Arab Spring for both Tunisia and Libya, democracy sharply decreased in 2015 in Libya due to armed conflict. Surprisingly, the results showed that there was a substantial increase in corruption in both Libya and Tunisia after the Arab Spring. In the second essay, I estimated the Arab Spring's impact on foreign aid by using the synthetic difference-in-difference method. I examine whether the Arab Spring affects the distribution of foreign aid. I argue that the conflict may respond differently to different types of aid because of the objectives and aid-giving motives. The results indicate that, following the Arab Spring, there was a general increase in total foreign aid to affected countries, with exceptions for certain donors and a stronger increase for "non-traditional Western allies," with the United States being the largest contributor. Also, the findings suggest that, following the Arab Spring, various donors increased foreign aid to affected nations, particularly in government and civil society support, as well as humanitarian aid, with the United States focusing on government and civil society aid in Tunisia, Libya, and Syria, European countries emphasizing government and civil society aid in Libya and Tunisia, and Multilateral aid generally increasing, except for government and civil society aid in Yemen. In the third essay, I studied the spillover effect of the Arab Spring by investigating its influence on nearby countries concerning economic growth, bilateral trade, and foreign direct investment. I aimed to address how proximity to Arab Spring countries impacts the economic growth, bilateral trade, and foreign direct investment of neighboring economies. The results found that countries located within 2000 kilometers of Arab Spring nations experienced a significant negative impact on both real GDP and net inflow of foreign direct investment (FDI). However, the negative effects on bilateral trade were not statistically significant, suggesting that engaging in trade with Arab Spring countries did not necessarily harm the economic growth of neighboring countries.
... Wahyu (2017) estimates that telecommunication infrastructures impact on FDI inflows. Lastly, Pinar and Stengos (2020) point out that democracy in the domestic economy tends to attract investment from abroad. ...
Article
Full-text available
The aim of the paper is to determine the effect of the Multinational Enterprises of the United States (US-MNE) in the reduction of poverty in a group of 18 developing countries where they operate for the period 2009-2018. Furthermore, the determining factors of the attraction of US-MNE to these countries are estimated and it is tested whether they affect poverty. A dynamic panel data econometric methodology (sys-GMM) is followed. It is found that US-MNE positively influence poverty reduction, and that significant determinants for attracting these companies are at the same time poverty reducing factors. Consequently, the US-MNE can be considered as a central mechanism of the dynamics of poverty in developing countries. The document contributes to the limited literature that quantitatively analyses the role of MNE in reducing poverty.
... Using voice and accountability, rule of law, and government effectiveness from the World Governance Indicators, they found that spatial institutional spillovers are statistically significant and economically important. Pinar and Stengos (2021) discussed that the requirements of the Copenhagen criteria led to increased diffusion of institutional quality in the EU. Similarly, conflict in neighbouring countries is likely to spillover and affect the economic conditions (De Groot, 2010). ...
Article
Full-text available
Recent work documents that even though partisan polarization may have detrimental economic and social outcomes, polarized societies lead to better governance and less corruption. However, the effect of corruption on partisan polarization has been mostly ignored by the literature. By using various measures of partisan polarization and corruption, this paper demonstrates that corrupt behaviours are associated with more partisan polarization in the European Union, indicating that a stronger presence of corruption leads to higher partisan polarization. The findings are robust to the use of different polarization measures, methodologies, and a battery of control variables. This paper’s main finding, increased corruption leading to increased partisan polarization, provides another important mechanism beyond the standard socio-economic factors that led to the current rise in support of parties opposing to European Union and rise of populist parties in European Union. Polarized societies tend to generate inefficient economic outcomes and the alleviation of corruption could improve economic outcomes by decreasing partisan polarization.
Article
This paper examines spatial spillovers in the formation of preferential trade agreements (PTAs) through a new channel of institutional proximity. Our dependent variable is the status of PTAs between country attributes within a country‐pair. The explanatory variable of interest is the status of PTAs in neighbouring country‐pairs that share proximity in institutional development. We consider democracy and economic freedom as the main aspects of institutions, and use both as the fundamental components of institutional distance between country‐pairs. Employing a spatial econometric method, we find strong evidence of the institutional interdependence of PTAs: country‐pairs tend to influence each other's decision on the formation and the chosen type of PTAs (i.e., deep or shallow), such a neighbourhood effect increases with institutional proximity and is more prominent for the decisions on the type of PTAs. The institutional spatial channel is robust to various robustness checks.
Article
Full-text available
El objetivo del documento es determinar el efecto de las Empresas Multinacionales de Estados Unidos (EMN-EU) en la reducción de la pobreza en un grupo de 45 países de ingreso alto y medio-alto donde operan para el periodo 2009-2018. También se estiman los factores determinantes de la atracción de EMN-EU a esos países y se verifica si inciden en la pobreza. Se emplea una metodología econométrica de datos de panel dinámica (sys-GMM). Para el análisis se considera la muestra total y submuestras de países en función de su estatus comercial con EU. Se encuentra que las EMN-EU influyen positivamente en la reducción de la pobreza y que los determinantes significativos de su atracción son al mismo tiempo factores reductores de pobreza. En consecuencia, las EMN-EU pueden ser consideradas como un mecanismo central de la dinámica global de la pobreza.
Article
This paper proposes that country-pairs sharing homogeneity in domestic institutions tend to sign preferential trade agreements (PTAs) interdependently, and such an interdependence effect decreases with institutional differential. Using spatial econometrics, we take democracy and economic freedom as fundamental components of the spatial weight matrix. The baseline results support our hypothesis from both the panel data over 1996 to 2017 through a probit model and the cross-sectional data through a spatial autoregressive probit model. We also employ a compound spatial weight matrix to account for the institutional differential and geographical distance simultaneously, which confirms the role of domestic institutions in the evolution of PTAs. Our findings are robust to the correction of potential endogeneity in the spatial weight matrix, and we provide not only novel evidence for the spatial effect of institutional differential on the domino-like spread of PTAs, but also some insights on the relationship between regionalism and multilateralism.
Article
Full-text available
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to examine the determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) flows from some leading developed countries (the USA, Japan, Germany, the Netherlands, the UK and France) into major four Asian economies (China, Korea, India and Singapore). Design/methodology/approach Using one basic and four augmented versions of gravity model technique, the authors tried to examine the determinants of bilateral FDI flows in four major Asian economies. The study used World Development Indicators, CEPII, KOF and Heritage Foundation data for period 2001–2012. Findings The results revealed that besides the market size for host and source country, other criteria such as distance, common language and common border also influence foreign investors. Other macroeconomic factors such as inflation rate and real interest rate are among the key factors that attract more FDI. In addition to economic factors, institutional and infrastructural factors such as telecommunication, degree of openness, index of globalisation and index of economic freedom also stimulate the international investors from the developed world to the major Asian countries. Research limitations/implications It is altogether possible that only a set of home country specific characteristics or host country specific characteristics does not matter when determining FDI. Most empirical studies using indices such as the index of globalisation and economic freedom are subject to certain methodological limitations such as model selection, parameter heterogeneity, outliers and moral hazard. Practical implications More distance between the host and source country would result in less FDI flows due to more managerial and raw material supply chain cost. Similarly, more gross domestic product (GDP) and per capita income (PCI) are leading to more FDI flows into Asian economics. Therefore, major Asian economies should frame their economic policies in such a manner where these counties can strengthen their GDP as well as PCI. Furthermore, above countries should open its economy more and more for better FDI flows as it seems that economic globalisation and economic freedom are major determinants of bilateral FDI flows. The negative impact of inflation and interest rate should be controlled. Social implications From policy perspective, higher scores of economic, social and political globalisation also attract high FDI to the host country. On the same line higher scores in economic freedom mean that less restrictions in terms of economic policies and the policy environment are conducive for free trade and resource transfers. Higher scores in trade freedom, investment freedom and freedom from corruptions also show more developed and conducive policy environment. In the same reasoning higher scores in the composite index of economic freedom which takes information from trade freedom, investment freedom and freedom from corruption and others also encourage flow of FDI in to the host country. Originality/value This is the first paper which combines the globalisation index, economic freedom index and distance along with some major macroeconomic variables.
Article
Full-text available
We examine the empirical role of information flows and institutional quality in explaining the capital flows per capita across countries, and their role in explaining the so-called Lucas paradox -low levels of capital flows to poor countries. The findings of this paper suggest that countries with better institutions and high information flows receive high capital flows, and information flows also provides a partial explanation to the Lucas Paradox. The latter result is significant even after controlling for institutional quality, financial openness and human capital differences across countries, and using instrumental variable for information flows. This paper also examines the indirect effects of institutional quality on capital flows per capita through its impact on information flows and finds that countries with better institutional quality have higher levels of information flow. Accounting this indirect effect is economically important and papers that do not account for this indirect effect of institutions on capital flows per capita would underestimate the effect of institutions on capital flows per capita. Findings of this paper suggest that relatively poorer countries should improve their institutional quality and increase their access to worldwide information and promote investments in communications infrastructure to attract long-term capital flows.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we examine the links among banking supervision, the volatility of financial flows, and economic growth. In particular, we explore whether banking regulation mitigates the adverse effects of capital flows volatility on economic growth. Using cross-country data over four decades, we find that banking supervision promotes economic growth by dampening the negative impact of volatile capital flows. The findings hold for both aggregate capital flows and its various components, and for both its net and gross counterparts, while they are also robust for various indicators of regulatory policies. The results support the argument that bank regulatory policy rules designed to ensure financial stability are beneficial to long-run economic growth.
Article
The paper provides a cross-country empirical analysis of the impact of corruption on foreign direct investment flows. The gravity model augmented with joint effects of corruption in the origin and destination countries determines differentiated patterns of investment flows between countries with various levels of control of corruption. The estimates point towards greater investment flows between countries with good control of corruption. Moreover, if control of corruption in the destination country improves, investment flows from cleaner countries rise more strongly than those from countries with a higher incidence of corruption. The resulting shift towards a greater share of investment from low-corruption countries may further reinforce the strengthening of economic and political institutions that keep corruption in check.
Article
Economic freedom (freedom from the intervention of government) is essential for doing business, so economic freedom of both the home country and the host country are important for bilateral foreign direct investment. However, though some literature has investigated the role of host country's economic freedom in bilateral direct investment, no literature has studied the role of home country's economic freedom. This paper has studied this issue in a gravity model with a sample of 155 countries. This paper has also employed some effective estimation techniques of gravity model to incorporate the zero observations and adopted quantile regression method. The findings indicate that economic freedom of both the home country and the host country are positively correlated with bilateral direct investment, and the economic freedom of home country has even stronger explanatory power for foreign direct investment. Hence, promoting the economic freedom may encourage more outward foreign direct investment than inward direct investment.
Article
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to investigate the potential determinants of FDI, in developed and developing countries. Design/methodology/approach This paper investigate FDI determinants based on panel data analysis using static and dynamic modelling for 20 countries (11 developed and 9 developing), over the period 2004-2013. For static model estimations, Hausman (1978) test indicates the applicability of fixed effect/ random effect, while GMM (dynamic model) is used to capture endogeneity and unobserved heterogeneity. Findings The outcome across different countries depict diverse results. In developed countries FDI seek policy related determinants (GDP growth, trade-openness and freedom index); and in developing country FDI showed positive association for economic determinants (gross fixed capital formulation (GFCF), trade openness and efficiency variables). Research limitations/implications The destination of FDI is limited to 20 countries in present paper. The indicator of institutional environment namely economic freedom index used in paper has received some criticism in calculations. Practical implications The paper enlists recommendations for future FDI policies and may assist government in providing tactical framework for skill development thereby increasing manufacturing growth rate. The paper also throws light on vertical and horizontal capital inflows considering resource, strategy and market seeking FDI. Originality/value The paper uncovers important features like macro-economic variables especially country wise efficiency scores; policy variables; GFCF and freedom index, for determining FDI inflows in 20 countries using panel data methods and provide a roadmap for developed and developing countries. The study highlights endogeneity and unobserved heteroscedasticity by applying GMM-one and two-step procedure.
Article
The integration of emerging markets into the global economy is heavily promoted by foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows. Among the factors explaining the location of FDI, regional trade agreements (RTAs) can be relevant for emerging markets, as they can promote economic integration and increase the attractiveness of the region for foreign investors. This paper investigates the impact of South–South trade agreements on the FDI decision of multinationals, where the Agadir, mercado comun del sur (MERCOSUR), and ASEAN free trade area (AFTA) agreements are considered. Three panels of countries are defined, where the members joined a specific agreement or not. Non-Gulf Arab states are compared to better performing regions in Latin America and Southern and Eastern Asia. The analysis provides evidence that openness to foreign trade and financial markets are among the main catalysts to attract FDI, provided that business-friendly institutions exist in the host country. Other variables, like the size of the industrial sector, urbanization rates, and external debt appear to be important in some cases. The integration of China into the world economy is a specific trigger for FDI to Asian destinations. Since RTAs influence the market size by reducing barriers to trade, their impact operates via GDP growth and openness. Gains from the agreement are striking for Latin America and Asia, but not for Arab states. To attract more FDI, business-friendly institutional reforms and mechanisms to support new firm foundation should be implemented in this region.
Article
This study empirically examines the impact of institutional quality on FDI inflows in the Arab region. The analysis is performed by employing system GMM estimation in panel data comprising 16 Arab countries over the period 1984–2012. The study finds that the institutional quality variables of economic freedom, ease of doing business and international country risk (ICRG) have a positive and significant impact on FDI inflows in Arab economies. The results of this study have several implications for policy makers.
Article
This meta-analysis attempts to synthesize and review decades of research on the relationship between institutional factors and host country foreign direct investment (FDI) attractiveness. Using prior tests derived from 97 primary studies, we find support for prior theoretical predictions that institutional factors such as political stability, democracy, and rule of law attract FDI, while others such as corruption, tax rates and cultural distance deter it. Further evidence suggests a need for exploration of moderating factors that may influence previous key findings. Specifically, environmental effects such as level of development, region of destination, and competitive industry environment have varying influence on the strength and significance of the relationship. We also explore a number of methodological and economic moderating variables, providing additional interesting insights into previous empirical analyses. We conclude with suggestions for future research that stress a call for further contextualization of the relationship.