ArticlePDF Available

Have we been here before? Phases of financialization within the twentieth century in the US

Authors:
  • Labour Institute of the General Confederation of Greek Workers (INE GSEE)

Abstract and Figures

This paper explores the process of financialization from a historical perspective during the course of the twentieth century. We identify four phases of financialization: the first from the 1900s to 1933 (early financialization), the second from 1933 to 1940 (transitory phase), the third between 1945 and 1973 (de-financialization), and the fourth period picks up from the early 1970s and leads to the Great Recession (complex financialization). Our findings indicate that the main features of the current phase of financialization were already in place in the first period. We closely examine institutions within these distinct financial regimes and focus on the relative size of the financial sector, the respective regulation regime of each period, the intensity of the shareholder value orientation, as well as the level of financial innovations implemented. Although financialization is a recent term, the process is far from novel. We conclude that its effects can be studied better with reference to economic history.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Have we been here before? Phases of
financialization within the twentieth century
in the US
Apostolos Fasianos
Council of Economic Advisors, Greek Ministry of Finance, Athens, Greece and University of Limerick, Ireland
Diego Guevara*
School of Economics, National University of Colombia, Bogotá, Colombia
Christos Pierros
Department of Economics, University of Athens, Greece
This paper explores the process of financialization from a historical perspective during the
course of the twentieth century. We identify four phases of financialization: the first from
the 1900s to 1933 (early financialization), the second from 1933 to 1940 (transitory phase),
the third between 1945 and 1973 (de-financialization), and the fourth period picks up
from the early 1970s and leads to the Great Recession (complex financialization). Our findings
indicate that the main features of the current phase of financialization were already in place in
the first period. We closely examine institutions within these distinct financial regimes and focus
on the relative size of the financial sector, the respective regulation regime of each period, the
intensity of the shareholder value orientation, as well as the level of financial innovations imple-
mented. Although financialization is a recent term, the process is far from novel. We conclude
that its effects can be studied better with reference to economic history.
Keywords: financialization, monetary regimes, speculation
JEL codes: E42, E44, B52
1 INTRODUCTION
When did financialization start? While there is much literature on the increasing domi-
nance of finance in the United States after 1970, little work to date has attempted to inves-
tigate whether financialization was taking place earlier. Whereas few authors consider
financialization as an evolutionary process that can be traced back to pre-capitalist socie-
ties, most analysts emphasize the neoliberal period beginning in the 1980s.
Financialization, as Sawyer (2013/2014) appropriately describes it, is a process that
widely varies in form and intensity across time and space. Accordingly, by utilizing
*Corresponding author: email: dieguevarac@unal.edu.co. The views expressed in this article
are those of the authors only and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Greek Ministry
of Finance or the Council of Economic Advisors. We thank the two anonymous referees for their
plentiful advice, as well as Stephen Kinsella, Antoine Godin, Costas Koutsikouris, Elizabeth
Dunn, and the participants of the 1st Grenoble Post-Keynesian Conference, Money, Crises,
and Capitalism,for their valuable comments. All remaining errors are ours. This work is partially
funded by the Institute for New Economic Thinking.
Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1, Spring 2018, pp. 3461
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
The Lypiatts, 15 Lansdown Road, Cheltenham, Glos GL50 2JA, UK
and The William Pratt House, 9 Dewey Court, Northampton MA 01060-3815, USA
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
empirical and qualitative analytical tools coming from different schools of thought, we
identify distinct phases of financialization during the twentieth century in the US. In
particular, we examine the resemblance of financializations characteristics in the
early twentieth century with those of the contemporary period, questioning whether
the current phase of financialization is a vaguely different repetition of its older coun-
terpart, as observed, for example, in the early 1900s.
To carry out our task, we divide the sample period into four distinct regimes,
marked by structural breaks in the institutional setting of the economy, which affected
the functioning of the financial sector. The first period of early financialization lasts
from the beginning of the twentieth century up until 1933, as the New Deal agreement
brought significant changes in financial regulation and policy orientation. The second
period (19331940) reflects the transitory phase of the economy that leads to the third
period, the Golden Age of Capitalist Development(19451973). The crisis of 1973
heralded the end of the Golden Age. Last, we apply Dumenil and Levys (2011) defi-
nition of neoliberalism as financialized capitalismto link the fourth period of com-
plex financialization with 19742010.
We contribute to the relevant literature by exploring financialization from a historical
perspective and pointing out different varieties of financialization throughout the twen-
tieth century in the US. While most studies focus on a few criteria to establish evidence
of financialization, we employ a plethora of empirical and qualitative indicators that
allow us to formulate a synthetic argument for the pace and the form of financialization
in each distinct regime. We argue that financialization, characterized by an increased
role for the financial sector along with higher complexity across financial objectives
and institutions, is merely the current phase of a historical process that has been unfold-
ing since the dawn of the twentieth century. In our view, the early 1930s period presents
a significant resemblance to the current phase of financialization.
Financialization is associated with financial booms and busts and has a negative
impact on the real production of the economy, as it results in unemployment and high-
lights income inequalities. History shows that the degree of financialization is a policy
variable. For instance, in the postwar period, policymakers implemented a range of
policy instruments (such as full employment policies of a Keynesian flavor) and
enforced a strong regulatory environment in order to restrict the uncontrolled explo-
sion of finance. The implications of our findings could point towards policies that
could reverse the destabilizing effects that financialization has on society.
The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses theoretical contributions with
respect to financialization; Section 3 looks at the data relating to the financialization pro-
cess, focusing on the importance of the US financial sector; and Section 4 provides an
analysis of the course of financialization throughout the twentieth century, paying close
attention to the interaction between financial innovations and the regulatory environ-
ment, as well as to the degree of shareholder value orientation in the US economy.
We also scrutinize the commitment of fiscal and monetary policies to full employment
and low-inflation targeting and examine whether the economic system is prone to finan-
cial collapse. The penultimate section (Section 5) summarizes our findings, which formu-
late and support our argument, while the last section (Section 6) concludes.
2 VARIETIES OF FINANCIALIZATION
Financialization is a broad concept with multiple dimensions interacting in the economic,
social, and institutional domain. The most common definition for financialization is the
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 35
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
one provided by Epstein (2005, p. 1), who refers to the process as the increasing impor-
tance of financial markets, financial motives, financial institutions, and financial elites in
the operation of the economy and its governing institutions, both at the national and
international level.In a similar vein, Vercelli (2013/2014, p. 5) defines financialization
as the process of evolution which has progressively increased the crucial role of money
in the economy and society shaping the forms of exchange, circulation, distribution, and
accumulation of exchange value.
Although both definitions are rather broad, they capture the complex nature of
financialization and its links to the underlying institutional structures. However, the
absence of a single criterion that would integrate every dimension of financialization
renders the establishment of relevant evidence a rather challenging task for empirical
researchers (Raza et al. 2016).
The broadness and the importance of financialization led several authors to an investiga-
tion of a rather wide scope regarding the origins of the phenomenon, and triggered a debate
on whether financialization dates centuries back or whether it constitutes a unique charac-
teristic of the current phase of capitalism. Following Sawyer (2013/2014), we identify two
large strands of literature on financialization. The first examines the evolution and the size
of the financial sector and has its origins in both mainstream and heterodox schools of
thought. For instance, Vercelli (2013/2014, p. 21) associates financialization with the
penetration of different forms of money in society through financial innovations, and iden-
tifies a secular tendency towards financializationthat originates in ancient civilizations,
although he recognizes two distinct phases of financialization in the twentieth century.
Mainstream authors tend to highlight the positive consequences of financialization, for
example, in most cases arguing in favor of a long-run positive association between the
magnitude of finance and economic growth, referring to it as financial development
or financial deepening.They employ several proxies, such as the size of the economys
banking sector, its loan provision capacity, or measure the relative importance of the
financial sector, by going back as far as their data sources allow (see Greenwood and
Scharfstein 2013).
A few notable exceptions performed after the financial crisis of 2008 highlighted
the possibility of a non-linear relationship between financialization and economic
growth, suggesting that a stronger financial sector contributes to growth only up to
a certain threshold while further financialization affects growth adversely (see Law
and Singh 2014). Also, Schularik and Taylor (2012) explored the association between
various leverage structures, money, and the likelihood of financial crises since 1870.
They emphasize the importance of credit on financial instability and argue that the prewar
period presented much less dominance of credit and finance, acknowledging the Great
Depression as an exceptional case in that period.
Similarly, heterodox authors largely examine the destabilizing impact of financia-
lization on the economic and social domain. This literature strand, deriving mainly
from post-Keynesian and Marxist schools of thought, tends to associate financializa-
tion with the era of neoliberalism, which began in the 1980s for most developed
economies, and describes it as a different form of capitalism in which finance has
become more dominant than it previously had been and has penetrated into various
realms of society (Sawyer 2013/2014). Table 1 presents some pertinent studies in
each approach that are employed in this paper.
Next we provide an overview of several of the listed approaches to financialization,
among which is a strand of research that focuses on the submission of the production
process to the principles of financial liquidity. For instance, Palley (2007, p. 2) sug-
gests that financialization is a process whereby financial markets, financial
36 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
institutions, and financial elites gain greater influence over economic policy and econ-
omic outcomes.This process is characterized by a slight shift in income toward capi-
tal, a change in the composition of payments to capital that has increased the interest
share, and an increase in the financial sectors share of total profits(ibid., p. 14). Simi-
larly, Orlean (1999) associates financialization with the restructuring of the internal
organization of the firm, as a response to the increasingly powerful interests of the
stock market.
Table 1 Financialization in the economics literature
Approaches Pertinent studies
Financial development / increasing size of the
financial sector
King and Levine (1993)
Rousseau and Wachtel (2000)
Greenwood and Scharfstein (2013)
Philippon (2015)
Increasing importance of financial markets /
increasing power of financial elites and rentier
class
Arrighi (1994)
Epstein (2001)
Dumenil and Levy (2002)
Epstein and Jayadev (2005)
Palley (2007)
Dallery (2008)
Vercelli (2013/2014)
Regimes of accumulation / corporations engaged
in profit-making in the financial sector
Arrighi (1994)
Lavoie (1995)
Boyer (2000)
Stockhammer (2004)
Krippner (2005)
Van Treeck (2008a)
Hein (2008)
Shareholder value orientation Lavoie (1995)
Lazonick and OSullivan (2000)
Aglietta and Breton (2001)
Cutler and Waine (2001)
Stockhammer (2004)
Froud et al. (2006)
Roberts et al. (2006)
Dallery (2008)
Hein (2008)
Financial innovations / debt-led consumption and
distribution
Hilferding (1910)
Palley (1994)
Phillips (1996)
Dutt (2005)
Bhaduri, Laski, and Riese (2006)
Montgomerie (2006)
Hein and van Treeck (2008)
Hein (2009)
Low-inflation targeting Palley (1999)
Epstein (2001)
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 37
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
This approach is close to the view that financialization refers to the increasing
power of the rentier class. It derives from the earlier works of Hilferding (1910) and
Lenin (1916) and has been more recently advocated by Dumenil and Levy (2002) and
Epstein and Jayadev (2005). However, this view could be considered as too narrow, as
it focuses solely on the rentier class, while currently the firm has become the battle-
groundfor different agents, including workers, managers, shareholders, and financiers
(Stockhammer 2005/2006).
According to advocates of shareholder value orientation,the growth pattern of the
firm has shifted from retain and investto downsize and distribute(Lazonick and
OSullivan 2000). In particular, shareholders are considered to have a short-term orienta-
tion with respect to firmsprofits, as they are interested in higher dividend payments and
higher stock prices, which is in stark contrast to the managersaim for long-run growth of
the firm.
1
Higher dividend payments imply lower retained earnings, while higher stock
prices translate to low equity issuance (Hein and van Treeck 2008). Therefore, financing
of investments becomes feasible only through the use of external means, such as higher
loans and increased leverage ratios, which render the firms financially fragile.
Close to the shareholder value orientation norm is the definition provided by
Arrighi (1994) and Krippner (2005), according to which financialization is a pattern
of accumulation, where profit is accrued primarily due to financial activities and
less so due to production or trade activities. Arrighis and Krippners definitions coin-
cide with the shareholder value orientation view in the fact that productive firms
engage in financial activities, either because the expected profit in the financial market
is higher than the corresponding profit in the goods market, or because the conditions
associated with high dividend payments are so strict that they essentially force firms to
seek additional gains in the financial market. As put by Dallery (2008, p. 492), the
profit rate has become an end in itself.Nevertheless, as noted by several authors,
2
the impact of this process has ambiguous results on accumulation, with the institu-
tional setting of the economy defining its ultimate goal and the associated regime
(Stockhammer 2004).
A considerable amount of research has focused on financial innovations as a feature of
financialization. Hilferding (1910) looked at financial derivatives as a tool of capturing
the essence of speculation, which lies solely in the exchange value (Sotiropoulos 2012).
In addition, Phillips (1996) links the intensity of financial innovation to the volume of
trading in the financial markets.
Financial innovation has also been extended to the rise of new consumption
patterns, bound to higher household debt structures with distributional implications
(Palley 1994; Dutt 2005). Hein and Mundt (2013) suggest that stagnating wages are
linked to increased household debt and result in debt-led consumption booms, while
Bhaduri et al. (2006) focus on the wealth effect on consumption, where higher levels
of financial wealth induce households to spend more, given financial deregulation.
1. Interestingly, the shareholder value orientation fits well, and even validates, Minskys
financial instability hypothesis (Charles 2016). In short, Minsky advocates that modern capitalist
economies are inherently unstable due to increasing financial fragility being built up during per-
iods of prolonged financial tranquility. As indicated by Lavoie and Seccareccia (2001), the pro-
cyclical debt ratios require that the growth rate of investment is higher than the one of retained
profits, which is not necessarily always the case. In periods of financialization, however, share-
holder value orientation imposes a higher distribution of dividends, reducing thereby retained
profits. In tandem with low interest rates, this reflects the period of tranquility that allowed finan-
cial fragility to build up in the Minksyan interpretation of financial crises (Charles 2016).
2. See, for example, Boyer (2000), Hein (2008), Lavoie (1995), and van Treeck (2008b).
38 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
Lastly, Montgomerie (2006) looks at the introduction of credit cards, which allowed
more financial institutions to enter the credit market.
Financialization varies in terms of pace and form, and one can identify periods of
financialization as well as of de-financialization (Sawyer 2013/2014). However, com-
paring distinct periods of financialization is not an easy task, since there are too many
factors to account for change and capitalism cannot necessarily be characterized by
compartmentalized sub-epochs(Orhangazi 2008, p. 24). The comparison becomes
even trickier, as different schools of thought in economics consider different indica-
tors, proxies, and definitions to measure financialization.
In identifying distinct phases of financialization in the US economy, we assume that
capitalism is a prerequisite for the process of financialization, as well as a certain
degree of financial development, in the sense that financial instruments become
commonplace.
3
Hence, we select the beginning of the twentieth century as our starting point, as it
satisfies our methodological assumption: (a) US capitalism had already been in place
for a significant amount of time; and (b) it was a period characterized by a fairly devel-
oped financial sector that gave birth to modern consumer credit (Calder 1999; Feretti
2008). Thereafter, we divide the period into four distinct regimes associated with struc-
tural breaks in the institutional setting of the economy in order to make comparisons in
terms of institutions, policies, and economic outcomes in each period. These structural
changes in capitalism did not occur within the period of a calendar year, rather they
took place gradually. For this reason, developments during the 1930s and 1970s
could only function as proxies of an ongoing change, the effects of which were
observed in late 1940s and early 1980s, respectively.
3 THE IMPORTANCE OF THE US FINANCIAL SECTOR
Our analysis begins by looking at the role of the financial sector in economic activ-
ity, as measured by a number of criteria addressed in the literature. Figure 1 shows
the sum of the profits and wages in the US financial sector as a share of GDP for the
period 19002012. The upward trend is clearly evident, even from the early twenti-
eth century, and is only disrupted by the run-up to World War II. Up until 1933, the
increase in the income share of finance more than doubled (111 percent), while the
associated yearly rate of growth, on average, was about 2.5 percent. Between 1934
and World War II the income share of finance indicated a tremendous drop of almost
60 percent and a yearly growth rate of 4 percent, reflecting the impact of the Great
Depression on the financial sector. In the postwar years until 1973, the increase in
the income share of finance was relatively moderate (35 percent), with the yearly growth
3. A number of researchers trace financialization to a period before capitalism, even as far
back as 5000 years (for example, Graeber 2011), by tracing the the evolution of debt instruments
along with the evolution of various social norms such as different modes of exchange, that is,
gifts. Others (for example, the Monthly Review approach) consider financialization as a form
of mature capitalism stemming from the production of an economic surplus which cannot be
absorbed in the sectors of production or consumption. Finance, therefore, facilitates the absorp-
tion of this surplus, thereby preventing the stagnation of the productive sector (see Baran and
Sweezy 1966; Lapavitsas 2013). For the purpose of this paper we follow the broader approach
of Hilferding (1910), who explored the transformation of capitalism which he termed as Finanz-
kapital,to reflect the increasingly greater role of banks as intermediaries of investment capital to
monopolistic firms.
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 39
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
rate of the share being equal to 2 percent. Lastly, after 1974, the US economy witnessed an
overall rise in the share of finance by 30 percent with a yearly growth rate of about
1 percent.
The increasing importance of the financial sector is also depicted by the share of
consumption expenditure on financial goods and services, reported in Figure 2. Expen-
diture for financial products in the 1930s was slightly higher than health expenditure
and significantly higher than expenditure for medicine. In recent years, finance-related
expenditure has grown only moderately compared to other types of expenditure,
though the amount is higher in absolute terms.
Another measure of the importance of the financial sector is its level of sophistication,
otherwise known as financial depth.In the literature, the most common proxy for finan-
cial depth is broad money (M2) or the stock of liquid liabilities (M3) expressed as ratios
of GDP. Figure 3 shows the ratio of broad money over GDP in the US for the period
19002010. Despite the high variability throughout most of the century, broad money
over GDP indicates distinct trends across each phase of financialization we explored.
The period 19001933 indicated a relatively steady yearly rate of money growth of
around 1 percent. The period between the financial crash and the beginning of World
War II indicated a similar yearly rate of growth, though with extreme fluctuations due
to the higher uncertainty.
4
During the Golden Age of capitalism (19451973) the
Year
1960
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
19101900
Income share of finance
1920 1930 1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Note: The estimations for the income share of finance refer to the value added of the factors of production,
while GDP excludes the spending on defense to adjust for the tremendous effect on spending during World
War II.
Source: Estimations based on Philippon (2015).
Figure 1 Income share of finance in the US (19002012)
4. The fluctuations could be explained by high uncertainty, which, as pointed out by Keynes
(1936), leads to the hoarding of money.
40 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
1930 1940
0.00
0.05
0.10
1950 1960 1970
Year
1980 1990 2000 2010
Finance Health Insurance Medicine
Source: Estimations based on Mehra et al. (2011) and Philippon (2015).
Figure 2 Consumption by type of expenditure as a share of GDP for the US economy
(19302010)
Year
1960
0.5
0.7
0.8
0.9
19101900
Broad money/GDP
1920 1930 1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
0.6
Source: Estimations based on Schularick and Taylor (2012).
Figure 3 Broad money over GDP for the US economy (19002010)
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 41
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
ratio of broad money to GDP plummeted, with an average yearly decline of 0.6 percent.
The neoliberal phase showed increases in the monetary base of the US economy, espe-
cially after 2000, indicating a yearly growth rate of almost 1 percent, similar to the first
phase of financialization.
These figures provided an overview of the importance of the US financial sector
during the twentieth century, providing a primary indication that finance was already
prominent in the early 1900s, that is, the first period we examine. The following sec-
tion tracks the evolution of financialization in depth, using methodological instruments
derived mainly from the post-Keynesian tradition.
4 EVIDENCE OF FINANCIALIZATION IN THE US ECONOMY IN THE
TWENTIETH CENTURY
In this section we use empirical estimates to assess the relative importance of finance
throughout the twentieth century in the US economy. Similar attempts have been carried
out by several authors. Among them, Krippner (2005) constructed two indicators for
financialization for the post-WWII period. Her first indicator relates to the ratio of profits
of corporations stemming from financial activity, while the second compares the profits
between the financial and the productive sectors. Both of these indexes provide support
for the rise of financialization in the 1970s. However, due to data limitations, the analysis
did not include the interwar period.
Stockhammer (2004), by dividing the share of interest and dividend payments by
the share of profits, empirically tested the hypothesis that short-run investment in
financial instruments is preferred to long-run investment in real capital. His hypothesis
is rejected for Germany and perhaps the UK, but is valid for France and the US. Van
Treeck (2008b) employed a Kaleckian growth rate of investment function for the US
to find that interest and dividend payments have a significant negative impact on accu-
mulation, while Orhangazi (2008) found that on a micro-firm level, financial profits
have a negative impact on large firms but a positive one on small firms, as financial
profits relax the financial constraints.
These attempts vary in methodology and in each samples period, yet they reach
similar conclusions. However, none of the above extends its analysis prior to World
War II. In the following sub-section, we attempt to shed some light on issues related
to financialization throughout the twentieth century in the US, with the use of descrip-
tive statistics.
4.1 Fiscal, monetary policy and capital mobility
We commence our analysis by presenting the fiscal and monetary policy framework
that underlined each distinct period under consideration, ultimately determining the
dynamics of the financialization process. In particular, we assess the role of fiscal
policy in promoting full employment and question whether monetary policy has
been accommodative to the financial sector.
Of course the scope and the implementation of fiscal and monetary policies could not
be examined in isolation but rather within a regulatory framework, which facilitates the
attainment of fiscal and monetary targets. For this reason we pay particular attention to
capital mobility as a stimulating factor of the process of financialization. According to
Crotty and Epstein (1996), capital controls have a detrimental impact on the ability of
42 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
the rentiers and financiers to avoid regulation, simultaneously accommodating full
employment and redistributional policies. In this sense, unregulated capital mobility con-
stitutes a further argument in favor of the presence of financialization.
In the first period under examination, the global monetary system was dictated
by the gold standard,which included movements of gold between central banks,
as a response to international non-financial transactions (Eichengreen and Temin
1997). The aim of the gold standard was to secure price stability and constrain fiscal
expansion, reflecting the mentality and the type of conduct of economic elites
(ibid., p. 187).
This condition had a considerable effect on the money supply and the balance sheet
of the central banks. As shown by Godley and Lavoie (2007, ch. 6), the system favored
the exporting countries, since a deficit in the current account of the importing country
implied a reduction of gold reserves of the central bank, which ought to be counter-
balanced by an increase in the Treasury bills held by the central bank. This effect
gave rise to the twin deficit phenomenon in the importing countries. Given that gov-
ernments did not favor budget deficits, another option for rebalancing the current
account was deflating the economy, with the main burden being laid upon wages,
as was the case before World War I (Eichengreen and Temin 1997).
In the US, the lack of a central monetary authority controlled by the government
prior to 1913 allows us to safely assume that the interests of the financial sector
were de facto accommodated. Financial regulation, carried out by the state govern-
ments, could hardly be thought of as effective (Komai and Richardson 2011). In regard
to foreign competition and imposed imbalances by the gold standard framework, the
current-account deficit at the turn of the century was reversed to a surplus in the run-up
to World War I, since the UKs major supplier of war machinery was the US (Arrighi
1994, p. 278). This tendency was further heightened after World War I when the US
experienced massive inflows of capital due to its strong productivity growth as com-
pared to major European countries, as well as the uncertainty created by the inability of
the latter to honor their debt commitments (Arrighi 1994). Besides, the free movement
of capital under the gold standard regime posed no obstacles on these capital inflows
(Crotty and Epstein 1996).
In this context, the specific conditions of that time favored the US financial sector;
however, in terms of monetary policy, the outcome is ambiguous. Although there are
considerable elements in favor of an accommodative monetary policy, they arguably
do not suffice to reach reliable conclusions. Nevertheless, in regard to fiscal policy,
non-commitment to full employment was clearly evident.
The fiscal policy inaugurated under the leadership of Franklin Roosevelt in 1933
marked a regime change in terms of policy goals, when a set of acts was implemented
to combat recession and unemployment. According to Papadimitriou (2008), these fis-
cal interventions were a close approximation to an employer of last resort policy
schemes, even though they were not sufficiently successful as to render demand for
labor inelastic.
5
However, fiscal targets were not the only structural change that had taken place.
The dogma of central-bank independence had been abandonded, with the Fed being
5. According to Minsky (1968) a direct job creation policy, such as an employer of last resort
scheme, creates a perfectly inelastic demand for labor, since individuals in the labor force will be
employed regardless of the wage level or the unemployment level. For a thorough discussion on
the theoretical background of the employment of last resort policies, see Kaboub (2007).
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 43
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
now under the direct control of the government (Epstein and Schor 1995).
6
More impor-
tantly, capital controls were imposed simultaneously in several economies in search of
an alternative to the already collapsed pegged exchange rates regime policy (Mitchener
and Wandschneider 2013). Therefore we observe a coordinated shift in the framework
under which economic policy was conducted, which, in its several aspects, contrasted
with the process of financialization. As noted by Orhangazi (2008, p. 28), the dominance
of financial capital had come to an end, inaugurating a new stage of capitalism and
bringing forth a new phase of financialization.
The system that emerged under the Bretton Woods Conference agreement ensured
the convertibility of the US dollar to gold, effectively providing stable exchange
rates. The Bretton Woods exchange-rate regime reflected the dominance of the dollar,
by allowing it to function as inconvertible world money and, hence, of the Fed in the
global monetary framework.
In addition, a clear distinction between the interests of productive and financial
capital could be observed, with the former supporting the maintenance of effective
capital controls which clearly opposed the interests of the latter (Ferguson 1984).
The agreement was accompanied by a set of policy goals, in which the maintenance
of full employment had a central role, while the monetary policy was bound to serve the
fiscal (Marglin and Schor 1990). Particularly for the US, we observe a clear detach-
ment from processes related to financialization.
Nevertheless, the collapse of Bretton Woods brought a new political agenda, set
forth by Thatcher and Reagan in the 1980s, that gradually led to central-bank indepen-
dence, zero inflation targeting, free capital movements, and the abandonment of full
employment. The new order in the area of global finance increased the level of
instability in the global financial system, while triggering the growth of international
financial markets (Lapavitsas 2013).
According to Palley (1999, p. 106), central banks were characterized by a clear
deflationary policy bias. Given that the majority of the board members were previously
employed in the financial sector, the institutionalization of central-bank independence
implied the promotion of financial interests by the monetary policy. In addition, Palley
(ibid., p. 120) refers to three regimes of monetary policy in a Phillips curve: (a) high
inflation and low unemployment, which implies high bargaining power for labor;
(b) moderate inflation and unemployment, which boosts aggregate demand in the
short-run, with moderate inflation reflecting sufficient demand; and (c) low inflation
with high unemployment, which favors the financial sector. In this context, zero inflation
policies and central-bank independence promote the interests of the financial sector
against labor and productive capital.
In addition, the 1980s marked a period of abolition of barriers to trade and capital
movement which gained ground after the legally binding General Agreements on Tariff
and Trade (GATT) and North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) treaties, while
fiscal policy was downgraded, given the tax cuts on business and rich households
(Crotty and Epstein 1996). Hence, we observe a new shift of the economic policy fra-
mework towards the opposite direction of the corresponding framework in the 1930s.
Overall, the fiscal and monetary framework of conducting policy experienced dramatic
changes within the twentieth century, where a phase of free-market orientation was suc-
ceeded by a policy regime in which the fiscal instruments had a critical role in economic
6. It should be noted that even though monetary policy was conducted in order to support the
full employment fiscal target, its potentials were not fully exploited (Mitchener and Wandsch-
neider 2013).
44 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
activity. The roots of this change can be traced both in the economic and the political
sphere; however, free-market orientation resurged in the latest phase of financialization,
with its main features in terms of policymaking resembling those in the early 1900s.
4.2 Shareholder value orientation
The shareholder value orientation can be viewed as the pressure on managers to ensure
short-term profits at the expense of firmslong-run growth.
7
This distribution of cor-
porate profits in favor of the shareholders could potentially have a considerable impact
on the non-financial corporations(NFCs) accumulation rate since the lower level of
retained earnings ought not to suffice so as to finance investment in the productive
activity. By using this approach, the similarities between the first and the fourth per-
iods of financialization are striking.
The rise of the joint stock company in the first period provided financial institutions
with the option to control corporations by placing their representatives on corporations
boards, by holding their stocks, and by the provision of higher loans (Orhangazi 2008,
p. 24). As an immediate result of this condition, financing capitalists were actually
monitoring managers (DeLong 1991). From a similar point of view, the productive
capital was financialized (Pineault 2001, cited in Orhangazi 2008, p. 27), which, in
combination with the developments in the stock market, had a detrimental impact
on the sustainability of the economic system (Keynes 1936, p. 160).
The intense regulation and interventionist policies in the second period paid off in
the third, where the boom in fixed capital formation signified a transition towards a
long-run orientation with respect to firmsgrowth (Marglin and Schor 1990). Overall,
this period was characterized by financial tranquility, where the pressure on managers,
by financiers and stockholders, was reduced (Orhangazi 2008, p. 30).
However, in the last period, this pressure once again resurged, in a rather formal
manner, as compared to the first one. For instance, the imposition of the so-called
return-of-equity (ROE) norm was indicative of the ultimate goal of management,
which was to maximize the return value to shareholders.
To proxy the level of shareholder value orientation, we focus on the controversy
that arises between the dividend payments and the internal financing of investments.
8
Table 2 presents the average shares of net dividend payments and retained earnings
over corporate profits after tax. The first period spans the years 1929 to 1932; there-
fore, the related values are a mere reflection of the irregularity of the Great Depression,
where corporations were distributing sums that exceeded their profits, presumably to
sustain the price of their shares.
However, the blurred depiction of the first period is somewhat restored in view of
the second period, where no dramatic changes in the institutional framework of the
associated variables were observed. Specifically, distributed profits accounted for 87
percent of the overall profits, implying an overwhelming originate and distribute
orientation (Sawyer 2013/2014).
7. The switch in the mentality of entrepreneurs towards the pursuit of prospective, and even
speculative, profit as compared to the mentality of the entrepreneurs in the late nineteenth century
was already noted by Keynes (1936, p. 159) in the interwar period.
8. Possibly the most notable feature of the shareholder value orientation relates to the increasing
short-run investment in financial assets at the expense of investing in real assets (Stockhammer
2004). Nevertheless, due to data limitations regarding interest payments between sectors, we
were unable to assess this feature for the period under examination.
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 45
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
This condition is reversed in the third period, with retained earnings accounting for
61 percent of profits, which comes in line with the investment boom in the Golden
Age. However, in the latest period, the pressure on managers is depicted in the higher
share of net dividends, accounting for 53 percent of profits. In advance, the intensity of
the distribution of profits becomes higher in the period close to the Great Recession.
For instance, the average shares of net dividend payments and retained earnings in the
period between 1995 and 2008 were equal to 64 percent and 36 percent, respectively.
Subsequently, we examine corporationsexternal debt, paying much attention to the
corporate bond and equity issuance. Corporate bond issuance, depicted in Figure 4a,
presents high volatility in the first period of financialization, yet it fluctuates at a
considerably higher level than equity issuance. This pattern is followed in the second
period; in the third, bond issuance stabilizes around 1.5 percent of GDP, to explode in
the latest phase of financialization.
With respect to equity issuance, there was a clear negative trend close to the 1920s,
where an extreme short-term rise took place due to the stock-market rally, as reported
Table 2 Average share of net dividend payments and retained earning to corporate
profits after tax (excluding depreciation allowances) in the US
Dividends Retained earnings
1st period 10.41 9.39
2nd period 0.87 0.13
3rd period 0.39 0.61
4th period 0.53 0.47
Source: National Income and Product Accounts.
Year
1960 1970
0.00
0.02
0.03
1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1980 1990 2000 2010
0.01
0.04
Gross equity issuance Gross corp. bond issuance
Source: Estimations based on Baker and Wurgler (2000) and Philippon (2015).
Figure 4a Gross equity issuance and gross corporate bond issuance over GDP for
the US economy (19102010)
46 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
in the abrupt increase of the market value, which led to the financial collapse in 1929.
After World War II, equity issuance remained relatively stable, with a small increase in
the average level in the fourth period, while following a cyclical pattern. By contrast,
the market value of equities (see Figure 4b) presented both an upward-sloping trend
and a cyclical pattern, with a widely increasing volatility of the latter. These are
well illustrated in Table 3, which provides an overview of the average bond and equity
issuance and the corresponding volatilities for each period.
Lastly, we focus on mergers and acquisitions, which according to Hein (2009)
reflect the pressure on managers by the use of hostile takeovers. Figure 5 depicts
the value of mergers and acquisitions for the period 19002013. The intensity of mer-
ger activity is clearly evident during the 1920s, followed by a period of tranquility after
the financial collapse of the late 1920s. However, after the late 1960s, and especially
around the millennium, a second explosive wave of mergers takes place.
0.00
1.00
1900
Market value of equity
1920 1940 1960
Year
1980 2000
0.50
1.50
Source: Estimations based on Baker and Wurgler (2000) and Philippon (2015).
Figure 4b Market value of equity over GDP for the US economy (19002012)
Table 3 Corporate gross bond issuance and gross equity issuance over GDP for the
US economy (19092012)
Gross bond issuance over GDP Gross equity issuance over GDP
Mean Volatility Mean Volatility
1st period 2.25% 25.24% 1.09% 62.13%
2nd period 1.62% 38.24% 0.24% 51.17%
3rd period 1.51% 17.59% 0.44% 34.55%
4th period 2.41% 31.10% 0.62% 37.64%
Source: Estimations based on Baker and Wurgler (2000) and Philippon (2015).
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 47
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
Overall, evaluating shareholder value orientation in a consistent manner is not an
easy task, given the data limitations and the distinct institutional framework in each
period. However, our analysis suggests that common elements are present between
the first and the fourth period under consideration, providing support for the argument
in favor of financialization in the early 1900s.
4.3 Financial regulatory framework, financial innovations, and household credit
4.3.1 Regulatory framework
The banking sectors involvement in securitization has been extensively regulated since
the mid-nineteenth century. However, a loophole in the associated regulatory framework
allowed national banks to enter the securities market by setting up affiliated trusts (White
1986). Numerous banks had already broadened their operations through their bond
departments; nevertheless, the growing securities market
9
seemed at that time a source
of considerable profit, in which traditional banks were not allowed to participate (ibid.).
The introduction of affiliates as an institutional partner of the commercial banks allowed
the latter to overcome regulation and gain access to this profitable market.
The number of US national banks engaged in securitization was 11 times higher in
1931 compared to 1921, while the banks that were mostly interested in the bond market
rather than commercial activity more than doubled (Peach 1941). The participation of
Year
1960
0.00
0.10
0.15
19101900
M&As value
1920 1930 1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
0.05
Source: Estimations based on Jovanovic and Rousseau (2005) and Philippon (2015).
Figure 5 Value of mergers and acquisitions in the US (19002013)
9. Securitization commenced around 1860, with the introduction of railroad bonds and a
further introduction of mortgage-backed securities in the 1880s (Chancellor 1999). In the
early 1900s the terms meaning shifted, mostly referring to the use of uninsured deposits as col-
laterals for issuing new loans which in turn were used for the purchase of stocks or bonds. After
the 1970s, issued securities were backing every single debt instrument, a practice not irrelevant
to the financial regulatory framework. Nowadays, the term is mostly employed to refer to com-
plex financial products, especially asset-backed securities such as collateralized debt obligations
(CDOs).
48 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
banks and their affiliates in bond issuing rose from 36.8 percent to 61.8 percent, while
the share of bonds issued by all banks increased from 22 percent to 44.6 percent (US
Senate 1931, cited in White 1986). A contributing factor was also the increased com-
petition for deposits (White 1986). According to Dymski (1991), during the 1920s,
immense competition for deposits increased interest costs, leading banking institutions
on a quest for high return, that is, riskier loans.
The higher leverage structure also served the purchase of stocks, which implies
higher stock prices and, therefore, capital gains. Speculation during the 1920s rendered
the US economy financially fragile. The intensive securitization, with the use of unin-
sured deposits as collateral in combination with the stock-market rally, led to the stock-
market crash in 1929.
The outbreak ofthe Great Depression was followed both by interventionist policies and
legislative initiatives, which aimed to prevent any further deterioration of the economy
and control the potentially destabilizing threats of the financial activity in the productive
sector. The most critical policy response with respect to the functioning of the financial
sector was the GlassSteagall Act, passed in 1933.
Specifically, policymakers were particularly concerned with the involvement of banks
in the securities market, as they were identified as one of the major causes for the massive
bank failures during the Great Depression (Crawford 2011). For this reason, banks were
offered the choice to engage in either commercial or investment banking activities. The
introduction of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) ensured the protection
of depositors from defaults in commercial banks, while the newly established Securities
and Exchange Commission (SEC) regulated financial practices.
The intense regulation, in combination with weak foreign competition, resulted in
financial tranquility, where the pressure on managers by financiers and stockholders
was reduced (Orhangazi 2008, p. 30).
In the first two decades after World War II, the US economy achieved an almost full
employment state, experiencing only minor recessions and modest inflation periods
(Minsky 1986, p. 50), while financial activity was carried out under the control of the
Fed with the use of the Feds discount window and open-market operations (ibid., p. 52).
However, the institutional changes in the financial sector and, in general, the attempts
to regulate its functioning lacked a coherent theoretical framework that would allow for
a dynamic and continuous regulating process (Minsky 1986, pp. 4345). This argument
is verified by the fact that during the 1960s, a period characterized by strong invest-
ment growth, financial innovation in the money market that is, by introducing the
certificate of deposits, real estate investment trusts (REITs), and the commercial
paper rendered the Feds controlling instruments ineffective, since the latter were
not adapted to the new financial environment.
More importantly, the structure of debt had a critical role in the period at hand. As
a follow-up to the Great Depression, government debt started rising and even sur-
passed private debt during World War II, reaching a record level of 113 percent of
GDP (see Figure 6). Indeed, it was the first time that public debt penetrated into
firmsand householdsbalance sheets as a financial asset (Minsky 1986, pp. 3738).
A seemingly financially tranquil period was disrupted by a wave of financial episodes.
Minsky (1986, pp. 97101) described in detail the developments in the financial sector
that led to the credit crunch of 1966 and the liquidity squeeze in 19691970. Focusing
particularly on the money market, financial institutions collateralized the liability side of
their balance sheet for the first time after World War II; this resulted in high levels of
instability in the financial sector and reduced financing of tangible capital investments.
Also, rising public debt in the hands of the public and other financial institutions, along
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 49
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
with an increasing rate of financial innovations, suggests a deeply rooted transformation
that consequently resulted in a debt-oriented financial environment during the neoliberal
era of financialization (fourth period).
In 1975, the Securities Amendment Acts were passed in order to set up the National
Market and the National Clearing System, aimed at enhancing liquidity and competition,
yet they failed to deliver results (Komai and Richardson 2011). In the same year, the
fixed minimum commission rates were repealed as anti-competitive regulation.
In the 1980s, a large-scale deregulation process took place, with the GlassSteagall
Act being gradually relaxed by the Fed
10
and eventually repealed in 1996
11
(Crawford
2011). At the same time, US financial institutions, keen on becoming aggressively
competitive on a global scale, lobbied for loose regulation (Komai and Richardson
2011). Finally, the reform of FDIC to FDICIA (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Improvement Act), in 1991, institutionalized the too big to faildoctrine (ibid.). The
remaining regulations were carried out on the basis of addressing moral hazard and
information asymmetries.
4.3.2 Financial innovationsgrowth rate
Financial innovations stand at the core of financialization, as they allow the financial
sector to overcome regulatory barriers and therefore increase its relative economic
power (Bhaduri 2011). Until recently, numerous authors perceived them as a
Year
1960
0.0
2.0
19101900 1920 1930 1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
2.5
0.5
1.0
1.5
Total debt Private debt Government debt
Source: Estimations based on Philippon (2015).
Figure 6 Total debt-to-GDP, private-debt-to-GDP, and government-debt-to-GDP
for the US economy (19002012)
10. According to Crawford (2011) the Fed reinterpreted the Act in the 1980s, allowing com-
mercial banks to have 5 percent gains from holding securities. The threshold was further relaxed
to 10 percent by the end of the decade and in 1996 the margin was set to 25 percent.
11. Officially the GlassSteagall Act was abandoned in 1998.
50 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
contributor to economic development and prosperity (Bernstein 1996), as they
increase risk sharing, lower transaction costs, and reduce information and agency
costs(Merton and Perold 1997, p. 108). Only a few scholars highlighted the other
side of the coin. One of them was Hyman Minsky (1990, p. 60), who stressed that
economies with financial innovations that are driven by market prospects are structu-
rally conducive to booms and busts.
The quantitative assessment of the role of financial innovation as a contributing fac-
tor to the financialization process is a complicated task, as it is not possible to point out
which innovation contributed to the process to what extent. Figure 7 represents the
share of financial patents registered in the US economy as a share of all registered
patents in the country for most of the twentieth century as a proxy of the relative
share of growth of financial innovations.
It is evident that the trend of new financial patents is steadily increasing throughout this
period, representing what Minsky (1986, p. 111) described as an internal process of a
capitalist system with a sophisticated financial sector. This steady rate of growth in
financial innovation suggests that the links between financial innovation and financiali-
zation should not be rooted in technological improvement per se. Instead, the institu-
tional and policy forces, which allow the financial innovations to be employed by the
financial institutions, should be more important. To assess the contribution of financial
innovations in the expansion of the financial sectors role in each period, we track pre-
ceding innovations moving in tandem with regulatory developments in the domain of
finance throughout the twentieth century.
4.3.3 Household indebtedness
Today, perhaps the most notable example of financial innovations affecting the macro-
economic environment is household credit. For instance, Palley (2007, p. 24) suggests that:
Borrowing is also supported by steady financial innovation that ensures a flow of new finan-
cial products allowing increased leverage and widening the range of assets that can be
Year
1960
0.012
0.022
19101900 1920 1930
Share of patents and inventions in finance
1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
0.014
0.018
0.020
0.016
Source: Estimations based on Jovanovic and Rousseau (2005).
Figure 7 Patents on inventions and trademarks in finance as a share of all patents
registered in the US (19001996)
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 51
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
collateralized. Additionally, credit standards have been lowered in recent years, which has
made credit even more easily available to households, firms, and financial investors.
Figure 8 depicts the fluctuations in household debt as a percentage of income through-
out the twentieth century. Household debt peaked at almost 60 percent of GDP in the
early 1930s (the first period of financialization), a record that was not surpassed until
the mid 1980s. Later on, the accumulation of secured debt progressed sharply and
reached a peak at the origins of the subprime crisis, when mortgage borrowing col-
lapsed along with real-estate prices. Interestingly, the level of household indebtedness
comoves largely with inequality, another outcome of finanicalization.
12
From a
demand viewpoint and in a context of stagnant real wages, this result might either
be because households tend to preserve demand at stable levels (see Iacoviello
2008; Krueger and Perri 2006), or because low- and middle-class households get
indebted to imitate the consumption norms of the upper classes
13
(see Christen and
Morgan 2005; van Treeck 2014). A similar conclusion is reached by Kapeller and
Schütz (2014), according to whom the need of lower-income households to preserve
Time
1960
0.8
1910 1920 1930
Household debt to GDP
Income inequality
1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
1.0
0.2
0.6
0.4
Household debt Inequality
Source: Estimations based on Philippon (2015) and The World Top Income Database.
Figure 8 Household debt to GDP and income inequality for the US economy
(19122012)
12. For a discussion on the links between financialization and inequality, see for example Lin
and Tomaskovic-Devey (2013).
13. Nevertheless, it has been pointed out that the association between income inequality and
household debt is not necessarily symmetric in the case of the twentieth-century US (Fasianos
et al. 2017).
52 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
consumption at subsistence level induces their level of indebtedness. In this sense,
income inequality ultimately leads to financial fragility.
It was the early 1900s that gave birth to what is known today as modern consumer
credit.As reported by Feretti (2008, p. 17), two innovations in consumer credit, iden-
tified during the 1920s, were the following: a peculiar method for credit based on the
instalment plan, where money is lent or a good is sold on the condition that the bor-
rower or purchaser repays the loan with fixed payments to be made at regular times
over a specified periodand an array of particular sources of credit other than the tra-
ditional historic pawnbrokers and/or illegal money lenders.
The levels of household credit in the economy were also noteworthy in the early
1930s. As Calder (1999, p. 18) indicates:
American household finance was remade after 1915 [leading to] rising level[s] of consumer debt
. [P]ersonal debt increased at rates well ahead of the rate of population growth .From
1920 to 1929, the volume of consumer debt soared upward 131 percent, from $3.3 billion to
$7.6 billion outstanding. The Depression interrupted this rising curve, but by 1937 consumer
debt reached its pre-Depression levels and continued rising upwards, until it was halted by
credit controls during World War II.
However, in contrast to todays consumer borrowing, debt was hardly used for con-
sumption of non-essential things or goods of minimum value. Instead, it was primar-
ily used for purchases of assets with increasing value or with productive purposes
(Feretti 2008).
Possibly the most notable innovation boosting household credit is the promotion
of risk management techniques. Asymmetric information (moral hazard and adverse
selection) in the credit market reduces lendersability to estimate the capacity of
borrowers to service their debts. Indeed, the primary aim of risk management is to
handle this risk of default (Langley 2008). As such, risk management allows for
greater credit expansion with supposedly minimal risk to the resilience of the finan-
cial system.
Until the third period under examination, the risks involved in the process of col-
lateralized and consumer borrowing were monitored primarily through relational
and face-to-face practices(Leyshon and Thrift 1999). Contemporary techniques
in risk management (for example, credit reporting and scoring) removed the physical
proximity hitherto required for managing such uncertainties (Guseva and Rona-Tas
2001; Marron 2007). A typical example of higher sophistication in the credit market
is the launch of risk-based pricing, in other words, the tailoring of the loanspriceto
a borrowers probability of default, with the borrowers probability being estimated
upon their past credit records. Lastly, advancements in marketing techniques for
advertising financial products increased the customer base of banks and other finan-
cial institutions (Bertrand et al. 2010).
Indeed, financial liberalization played a large role in unlocking the landscape so that
financial innovations could come into play. A direct effect of financial liberalization
was the large-scale removal of credit constraints for a big portion of households.
The process of removing credit constraints was termed the democratization of credit
by former Federal Reserve Governor Lawrence Lindsey in 1997, as it reflects the
increasingly wider access to credit by middle- and lower-income households. While
the extent to which credit constraints are binding varies over time, across countries,
and across financial institutions within each country, their presence has a considerable
effect on the composition and magnitude of debt holdings on balance sheets of house-
holds (Kent et al. 2007).
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 53
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
4.4 Leverage structures and financial crises
Before taking a final step in the assessment of the financialization process, we examine
a last condition for the aggregate economy, related to the leverage structures of banks
and corporations. In particular, we follow the notion provided by the two most distin-
guished authors of the Old Institutionalist School, namely Veblen (1904) and Minsky
(1986), who both highlighted the inner tendency of the macrofinancial system towards
financial fragility, due to the imposition of increasing leverage, which renders the eco-
nomic system prone to financial collapse (Argitis 2013).
Figures 9a and 9b present the leverage ratios of the non-financial corporations and
the banking sector. It is evident that both sectors follow a similar pattern in terms of
building leverage structures: enormous debt in the first period, equally massive
deleveraging in the second, upwards tendency of leverage in the third that continues
in the last period, reaching unprecedented levels and thus dramatically increasing
financial fragility.
Figure 10 presents the frequency of financial crises between 1870 and 2012.
Although it refers to financial crises on a global scale, the importance of the US
financial sector in the global economy during the twentieth century is such that
most of the important financial episodes were domestic. In particular, the most
severe financial crises (those of 19061907, 1929, and 20072008) occurred in
the US. No crises were reported in the third period under examination (1945
1973), as the liquidity levels were sufficient and the leverage was low. Indeed the
low-leverage period, evident in Figures 9a and 9b, coincides with financial tranqui-
lity, and is located mainly in the Golden Age, thus providing evidence for Veblens
and Minskys analyses. Nevertheless, in the period of early financialization and the
period of re-financialization, banks and NFCs increased their leverage, and crises are
much more frequent.
Non-financial corporations
1925
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
1945 1965
Year
1985
Note: We estimate the non-financial corporationsleverage ratio as NFCsshort- and long-term debt over
capital stock, with all variables expressed in real terms.
Source: Estimations based on Schularick and Taylor (2012).
Figure 9a Leverage ratio of US non-financial corporations (19261996)
54 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
0.2
1900
Banks
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1920 1940
Year
1960 1980 2000
Note: To measure the leverage ratio of the US banking setor, we follow Schularick and Taylor (2012)
using the ratio of bank loans over money. Bank loans are defined as the end-of-year amount of outstanding
domestic currency lending by domestic banks to domestic households and non-financial corporations.
Money is defined as broad money.
Source: Estimations based on Schularick and Taylor (2012).
Figure 9b Leverage ratio of the US banking sector (19002010)
8
6
4
2
Year
1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
0
Frequency of financial crises
Source: Estimations based on Bordo et al. (2001) and Schularick and Taylor (2012).
Figure 10 Frequency of global financial crises (18782012)
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 55
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
5 ASSESSING THE FINANCIALIZATION PROCESS IN THE US ECONOMY
DURING THE TWENTIETH CENTURY
In this section, we evaluate the preceding analysis to formulate an argument in favor of
or against the existence of financialization in the periods under consideration. Table 4
presents our findings. Each row denotes a characteristic of financialization and each
column the corresponding period. Note that the bar in the cells indicates that the exam-
ination of data and characteristics could not provide conclusive results.
It is straightforward from the table that during the first period under consideration
key features of financialization (such as the dominance of the financial sector over the
economic activity, financial deregulation, shareholder value orientation, and household
indebtedness with distributional effects) were already in place, thus justifying the
notion of a period of early financialization. Economic policy orientation also appeared
to stimulate the process of financialization, even though the results for monetary policy
are only suggestive and not conclusive.
In the third period, the conditions are clearly reversed, with most features highlight-
ing the ongoing process of de-financialization. The end of the Golden Age initiated a
second wave of financialization in the final period under consideration, in a more con-
crete form, as is evidenced in the last column of Table 4.
6 CONCLUDING REMARKS
This paper explored the process of financialization throughout the last century and pro-
vided evidence of its deep roots at the beginning of the twentieth century. In order to
carry out our analysis, we divided our sample period into four distinct phases: the
first period ends with the initiation of the New Deal in 1933, the second covers the
remainder of the 1930s until the outbreak of World War II, the third is the Golden
Age (19451973), and the fourth refers to the neoliberal phase of capitalism, following
the oil crisis of 1973 and the beginning of financial deregulation in the US.
Table 4 Evidence for financialization
1st period 2nd period 3rd period 4th period
(190033) (193440) (194573) (19742010)
Dominance of financial sector Yes No No Yes
Income share/size of the
financial sector
Moderate high Moderate low Moderate low High
Financial regulation No Yes Yes No
Shareholder value orientation Yes No Yes
Intensity of financial
innovation
Moderate Moderate High High
Household indebtedness Moderate high Low Moderate High
Income inequality High Low Low High
Commitment to full
employment
No Yes Yes No
Low inflation targeting ––No Yes
Free capital mobility Yes No No Yes
Leverage structures/inclina-
tion to financial crises
High Low Low High
56 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
The resemblance in the conditions between the first and the fourth period is remark-
able. In spite of institutional and formal differences, the presence of primary indicators
of financialization, as discussed in this paper, satisfy our main hypothesis, which is
that the first period under consideration indeed constitutes an early form of financia-
lization. The second period can be viewed as a transitional phase to de-financialization,
which occurred in the third period under our consideration.
We have shown that the income share of the financial sector rises considerably in the first
and the last period, while being significantly lower in the second and third periods. There-
fore, it is not an exaggeration to conclude that the period starting from 1973 till the global
financial crisis of 2008 could be termed as a period of re-financialization,considering the
large resemblance to the 1920s in terms of the importance of finance in the economy.
Pressure on managers to attain short-term profits, contrary to the firmslong-run
growth, was evident both at the beginning of the twentieth century and in the modern
period. This condition has a severe impact on the financial stability of the economic sys-
tem, since it reduces fixed capital formation or pushes the leverage ratios upwards, indu-
cing financial fragility.
It seems also that financial innovations, which historically constitute a means for
the financial system to avoid regulation and thus a significant feature of financialization,
do not work in a vacuum. We showed that the rate of growth of financial patents and innova-
tions grew at a steady pace throughout the twentieth century. Of the utmost importance, how-
ever, is whether the implemented regulatory framework allows financial intermediaries to
apply new technologies in order to skirt regulation. In line with Minsky (1986), we suggest
that the adoption of new technologies in finance ought to be backed by an institutional
regulatory framework, and properly addressedbypromotingregulationasadynamicpro-
cess. The empirical investigation of this relationship serves as a topic for further research.
There are also significant discrepancies in terms of economic policy between the
four periods under examination. For example, the full employment goal was a key
priority for policymakers in the second and third periods. Additionally, the dominance
of the productive sector and the strengthening of unions are also key features of the
third period of de-financialization. In advance, monetary policy conducted under a
financialized regime, as is the case in the fourth period, emphasizes the interests of
the financial sector, while neglecting those of the productive sector and the working
class. In full contrast, monetary policy in the second and the third period aimed to sup-
port fiscal stimulus, and therefore enhanced aggregate demand.
Lastly, the first and especially the last period of financialization shows tremendous
rises in the levels of household credit, while in the second and third periods the levels
are moderate. Apart from the purely economic outcomes, such as households ending
up indebted and financially fragile, this issue becomes critical when considered as an
infringement on the cultural setting of the society, with households being bound to the
interests of the financial sector. Further, more vast accumulation of household debt
leads to financial booms and busts, such as the ones the US witnessed in 2007. There-
fore, the need for regulation is evident in this domain as well.
This paper shows that financialization is not a modern facet of neoliberal capitalism, but
a multi-dimensional process present throughout the twentieth century. Considering the
large resemblances with the 1920s in terms of the importance of finance in the economy,
it is not an exaggeration to conclude that the period running from 1973 until the global
financial crisis of 2008 could be termed as a period of re- financialization.Economic his-
tory teaches us that the destabilizing consequences of the financialization process can
only be moderated by appropriate policies and institutional changes, possibly similar to
those implemented during the Golden Age of Capitalism.
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 57
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
REFERENCES
Aglietta, M. and R. Breton (2001), Financial systems, corporate control and capital accumula-
tion,Economy and Society, 30(4), 433466.
Argitis, G. (2013), Veblenian and Minskian financial markets,European Journal of Economics
and Economic Policies: Intervention, 10(1), 2843.
Arrighi, G. (1994), The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times,
London: Verso.
Baker, M. and J. Wurgler (2000), The equity share in new issues and aggregate stock returns,
The Journal of Finance, 55(5), 22192257.
Baran, P.A. and P.M. Sweezy (1966), Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic
and Social Order, New York: NYU Press.
Bernstein, P.L. (1996), Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk, Chichester, UK: John Wiley.
Bertrand, M., D. Karlan, S. Mullainathan, E. Shafir, and J. Zinman (2010), Whats advertising
content worth? Evidence from a consumer credit marketing field experiment,Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 125(1), 263306.
Bhaduri, A. (2011), Financialization in the light of Keynesian Theory,PSL Quarterly Review,
64(256), 721.
Bhaduri, A., K. Laski, and M. Riese (2006), A model of interaction between the virtual and the
real economy,Metroeconomica, 57, 412427.
Bordo, Michael, B. Eichengreen, D. Klingebiel, and M.S. Martinez-Pieria (2001), Is the crisis
problem growing more severe?Economic Policy, 16(32), 5282.
Boyer, R. (2000), Is a finance-led growth regime a viable alternative to Fordism? A preliminary
analysis,Economy and Society, 29(1), 111145.
Calder,L.(1999),Financing the American Dream: A Cultural History of Consumer Credit,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Chancellor, E. (1999), Devil Take the Hindmost: A History of Financial Speculation, 1st edn,
New York: Farrar, Straus, Giroux.
Charles, S. (2016), Is Minskys financial instability hypothesis valid?Cambridge Journal of
Economics, 40, 427436.
Christen, M. and R.M. Morgan (2005), Keeping up with the Joneses: analyzing the effect of
income inequality on consumer borrowing,Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 3(2),
145173.
Crawford, C. (2011), The repeal of the GlassSteagall act and the current financial crisis,Jour-
nal of Business &Economics Research, 9(1), 127134.
Crotty, J. and G. Epstein (1996), In defense of capital control,Socialist Register, 32(32), 118149.
Cutler, T. and B. Waine (2001), Social insecurity and the retreat from social democracy: occu-
pational welfare in the long boom and financialization,Review of International Political
Economy, 8(1), 96117.
Dallery, T. (2008), Post-Keynesian theories of the firm under financialization,Review of Radi-
cal Political Economics, 41(4), 492515.
De Long, J.B. (1991), Did J.P. Morgans men add value? An economists perspective on finan-
cial capitalism,in P. Temin (ed.), Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on
the Use of Information, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 205249.
Dumenil, G. and D. Levy (2002), The profit rate: where and how much did it fall? Did it
recover? (USA 19482000),Review of Radical Political Economy, 34, 437461.
Dumenil, G. and D. Levy (2011), The Crisis of Neoliberalism, London and Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Dutt, A.K. (2005), Conspicuous consumption, consumer debt and economic growth,in
M. Setterfield (ed.), Interactions in Analytical Political Economy: Theory, Policy and
Applications,NewYork:M.E.Sharpe,pp.155178.
Dymski, G. (1991), From Schumpeterian credit flows to Minskian fragility: the transformation
of the US banking system, 19271990,Mimeo, Department of Economics, University of
Southern California.
58 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
Eichengreen, B. and P. Temin (1997), The gold standard and the great depression,National
Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No 6060. Cambridge, MA: NBER.
Epstein, G.A. (2001), Financialization, rentier interests, and central bank policy,Paper pre-
pared for PERI Conference on Financialization of the World Economy,78December,
University of Massachusetts, Amherst.
Epstein, G.A. (2005), Financialization and the World Economy, Cheltenham, UK and North-
ampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Epstein, G.A. and A. Jayadev (2005), The rise of rentier incomes in OECD countries: financial-
ization, central bank policy and labor solidarity,in G.A. Epstein (ed.), Financialization and
the World Economy, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp. 4674.
Epstein, G.A. and J.B. Schor (1995), The structural determinants and economic effects of capi-
tal controls in the OECD,in U.T. Banuri and J.B. Schor (eds), Financial Openness and
National Autonomy, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 136161.
Fasianos, A., H. Raza, and S. Kinsella (2017), Exploring the link between household debt and
income inequality: an asymmetric approach,Applied Economics Letters, 24(6), 404409.
Ferguson, T. (1984), From normalcy to new deal: industrial structure, party competition, and
American public policy in the great depression,Industrial Organization, 38, 4194.
Ferretti, F. (2008), A historical primer on consumer credit reporting systems: a lesson for EU
policy makers?International Journal of Communication Law and Policy, 12, 92119.
Froud, J., S. Johal, A. Leaver, and K. Williams (2006), Finanicalization and Strategy: Narrative
and Numbers, London and New York: Routledge.
Godley, W. and M. Lavoie (2007), Monetary Economics: An Integrated Approach to Credit,
Money, Income, Production and Wealth, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Graeber, D. (2011), Debt: The First 5000 Years, London: Melville Press.
Greenwood, R. and D. Scharfstein (2013), The growth of finance,Journal of Economic Per-
spectives, 27(2), 328.
Guseva, A. and A. Rona-Tas (2001), Uncertainty, risk, and trust: Russian and American credit
card markets compared,American Sociological Review, 66(5), 623646.
Hein, E. (2008), Financialization in a comparative static, stock-flow consistent post-Kaleckian
distribution and growth model,IMK Macroeconomic Policy Institute, Working Paper, No
2008-21, Düsseldorf: Hans Böckler Foundation.
Hein, E. (2009), A (post-)Keynesian perspective on financialization,IMK Macroeconomic
Policy Institute, Studies, No 2009-1, Düsseldorf: Hans Böckler Foundation.
Hein, E. and M. Mundt (2013), Financialization, the financial and economic crisis, and the
requirements and potentials for wage-led recovery,in M. Lavoie and E. Stockhammer
(eds), Wage-Led Growth: An Equitable Strategy for Economic Recovery, London: Palgrave
Macmillan, pp. 153186.
Hein, E. and T. van Treeck (2008), Finanicalization in post-Keynesian models of distribution
and growth asystematicreview,IMK Macroeocnomic Policy Institute, Working Paper
No 2008-10, Düsseldorf: Hans Böckler Foundation.
Hilferding, R. (1910 [1981]), Finance Capital: A Study of the Latest Phase of Capitalist Devel-
opment, London and Boston: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Iacoviello, M. (2008), Household debt and income inequality, 19632003,Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 40(5), 929965.
Jovanovic, B. and P.L. Rousseau (2005), General purpose technologies,Handbook of Eco-
nomic Growth, 1, 11811224.
Kaboub, F. (2007), Employment guarantee programs: a survey of theories and policy experi-
ences,Levy Economics Institute, Working Paper No 498, Annandale-on-Hudson, NY:
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.
Kapeller, J. and B. Schütz (2014), Debt, boom, bust: a theory of MinskyVeblen cycles,Jour-
nal of Post Keynesian Economics, 36(4), 781814.
Kent, C., C. Ossolinski, and L. Willard (2007), Household indebtedness: sustainability and
risk,Paper presented at the Reserve Bank of Australia Financial System: Structure and
Resilienceconference, August.
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 59
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
Keynes, J.M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London and
New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
King, R.G. and R. Levine (1993), Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right,Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 108(3), 717737.
Komai, J. and G. Richardson (2011), A brief history of regulations regarding financial markets
in the United States: 1789 to 2009,National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper
No 17443, Cambridge, MA: NBER.
Krippner, G. (2005), The financialization of the American economy,Socioeconomic Review,3(2),
173208.
Krueger, D. and F. Perri (2006), Does income inequality lead to consumption inequality?
Evidence and theory,The Review of Economic Studies, 73(1), 163193.
Langley, P. (2008), Financialization and the consumer credit boom,Competition Change,12(2),
133147.
Lapavitsas, Costas (2013), The financialization of capitalism: profiting without producing,City,
17(6), 792805.
Lavoie, M. (1995), The Kaleckian model of growth and distribution and its neo-Ricardian and
neo-Marxian critiques,Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(6), 789818.
Lavoie M. and M. Seccareccia (2001), Minskys financial fragility hypothesis: a missing
macroeconomic link?in R. Bellofiore and P. Ferri (eds), Financial Fragility and Investment
in the Capitalist Economy: The Economic Legacy of Hyman Minsky, Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp. 7697.
Lazonick, W. and M. OSullivan (2000), Maximizing shareholder value: a new ideology for
corporate governance,Economy and Society, 29(1), 1335.
Law, Siong Hook and Nirvikar Singh (2014), Does too much finance harm economic
growth?Journal of Banking &Finance, 41, 3644.
Lenin, V.I. (1916 [1988]), Imperialism, the Higher Stage of Capitalism: A Popular Outline,
New York: International Publishers.
Leyshon, A. and N. Thrift (1999), Lists come alive: electronic systems of knowledge and the
rise of credit scoring in retail banking,Economy and Society, 28(3), 434466.
Lin, Ken-Hou and Donald Tomaskovic-Devey (2013), Financialization and US income inequal-
ity, 19702008,American Journal of Sociology, 118(5), 12841329.
Marglin, S.A. and J. Schor (1990), The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar
Experience, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Marron, D. (200), Lending by numbers: credit scoring and the constitution of risk within Amer-
ican consumer credit,Economy and Society, 36(1), 103133.
Mehra, R., F. Piguillem, and E.C. Prescott (2011), Costly financial intermediation in neoclassical
growth theory,Quantitative Economics, 2(1), 136.
Merton, R.C. and A.F. Perold (1997), A model of contract guarantees for credit-sensitive,
opaque financial intermediaries,European Finance Review,1,113.
Minsky, H.P. (1968), Effects of shifts of aggregate demand upon income distribution,American
Journal of Agricultural Economics,50(2),328339.
Minsky, H.P. (1986), Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, New Haven, CT and London: Yale
University Press.
Minsky, H.P. (1990), Schumpeter: finance and evolution,in A. Heertje and M. Perlman (eds),
Evolving Technology and Market Structure: Studies in Schumpeterian Economics,Ann
Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press, pp. 5174.
Mitchener, K.J. and K. Wandschneider (2013), Capital controls and recovery from the financial
crisis of 1930,University of Warwick, Working Paper No 132, Centre for Competitive
Advantage in the Global Economy, Department of Economics.
Montgomerie, J. (2006), The financialization of the American credit card industry,Competition
and Change, 10(3), 301319.
Orhangazi, O. (2008), Financialization and the US Economy, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton,
MA: Edward Elgar.
Orlean, A. (1999), Le pouvoir de la Finance, Paris: Odile Jacob.
60 Review of Keynesian Economics, Vol. 6 No. 1
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
Palley, T.I. (1994), Debt, aggregate demand, and the business cycle: an analysis in the spirit of
Kaldor and Minsky,Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 16, 371390.
Palley, T.I. (1999), Plenty of Nothing: The Downsizing of the American Dream and the Case for
Structural Keynesianism, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Palley, T.I. (2007), Financialization: what it is and why it matters,Levy Economics Institute,
Working Paper No 525, Annandale-on-Hudson, NY: Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.
Papadimitriou, D. (2008), Promoting equality through an employment of last resort policy,Levy
Economics Institute, Working Paper No 545, Annandale-on-Hudson, NY: Levy Economics
Institute of Bard College.
Peach, W.N. (1941), The Security Affiliates of National Banks, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press.
Philippon, T. (2015), Has the US finance industry become less efficient? On the theory and
measurement of financial intermediation,American Economic Review, 105(4), 14081438.
Phillips, K.P. (1996), Boiling Point: Democrats, Republicans, and the Decline of Middle-Class
Prosperity, New York: Random House.
Pineault, E. (2001), Finance capital and the institutional foundations of capitalist finance: theo-
retical elements from Marx to Minsky,Unpublished paper, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en
Sciences Sociales, Paris.
Raza, Hamid, B. Gudmundsson, G. Zoega, and S. Kinsella (2016), Two thorns of experience:
financialisation in Iceland and Ireland,International Review of Applied Economics, 30(6),
119.
Roberts, J., P. Sanderson, R. Barker, and J. Hendry (2006), In the mirror of the market: the dis-
ciplinary effects of company/fund manager meetings,Accounting, Organization and
Society, 31(3), 277294.
Rousseau, P.L. and P. Wachtel (2000), Equity markets and growth: cross-country evidence on
timing and outcomes: 19801995,Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, 19331957.
Sawyer, M. (2013/2014), What is financialization?International Journal of Political Econ-
omy, 42(4), 518.
Schularick, M. and A.M. Taylor (2012), Credit booms gone bust: monetary policy, leverage
cycles, and financial crises, 18702008,The American Economic Review, 102(2), 10291061.
Sotiropoulos, D. (2012), Hilferding on derivatives,The European Journal of the History of
Economic Thought, 22(1), 7796.
Stockhammer, E. (2004), Financialization and the slowdown of accumulation,Cambridge
Journal of Economics, 28(5), 719741.
Stockhammer, E. (2005/2006), Shareholder value orientation and the investment profit puzzle,
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 28(2), 193216.
Van Treeck, T. (2008a), A synthetic, stock-flow consistent macroeconomic model of financial-
ization,Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33(3), 467493.
Van Treeck, T. (2008b), Reconsidering the investmentprofit nexus in finance-led economies:
an ARDL-based approach,Metroeconomica, 59(3), 371404.
Van Treeck, T. (2014), Did inequality cause the US financial crisis?Journal of Economic
Surveys, 28(3), 421448.
Vercelli, A. (2013/2014), Financialization in a long-run perspective,International Journal of
Political Economy, 42(4), 1946.
US Senate (1931), Hearing on S.R. 71. Before the Committee on Banking and Currency, 71st
Congress, 2nd Session.
Veblen, T. (1904), The Theory of Business Enterprise, New York: Scribers Sons.
White, E.N. (1986), Before the GlassSteagall Act: an analysis of the investment banking activ-
ities of national banks,Explorations in Economic History, 23(1), 3355.
Have we been here before? US financialization in the twentieth century 61
© 2018 The Author Journal compilation © 2018 Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd
Downloaded from Elgar Online at 01/22/2018 06:35:07AM
via free access
... The first is viewing it through the lens of a historical process occurring in a single place, a transformation of land uses and social lives towards the aim of profitability for a few interested parties. This investigation will also demonstrate that the process that we call Financialization today can historically be better conceptualized as a series of advances and retreats in financial power (Fasianos et al., 2018) going back at least as far as the initial European colonization of Aotearoa in the 19th century. This approach, however, will only be a major focus for the first two chapters and is sporadically returned to later in the book when discussing other case studies beyond that of the Kumeu River Valley. ...
... Moreover, financialization changed the way managers and shareholders face their agency problems because executive pay structures and the threat of hostile takeovers also aligned the interest of managers and shareholders (Crotty, 1990;Lazonick & O'Sullivan, 2000;Stockhammer, 2004;van Treeck, 2009a;Fasianos et al., 2018). The overall outcome is that shareholder-oriented managers have little incentives to reduce dividend payouts to finance profitable investment opportunities. ...
Conference Paper
Full-text available
Previous literature has studied extensively the factors affecting R&D investment decisions and the effects of financialization on physical capital formation. This paper adds to this literature by arguing that dividend payouts have a negative effect on firm-level R&D. External financing constraints imply that firms tend to use internal funds to finance R&D investment but, due to shareholder-oriented corporate governance and the growing importance of financial performance indicators, managers often prioritize the payout of dividends over investment. To verify empirically the existence of a trade-off between dividend payouts and R&D investment, we use a dynamic two-step system GMM estimator and financial information from ORBIS for a sample of 6,787 publicly listed firms from 72 countries during the period 2010-2018. The regression results show that dividend payouts have a negative impact on firm-level R&D investment. This finding indicates that short-term shareholder value orientation undermines firm-level R&D activities and gives support for the view that stakeholders that are interested in the long-term growth of the firm should be empowered. JEL Classification: G35; O3
... The past four decades and more have been characterised as an era of intense financialisation. This was not the first era of financialisation (Vercelli, 2013, Fasianos et al, 2018. The present era of financialisation has its own specific characteristics, which impact on the economy and society, though the focus here is on implications for monetary policy. ...
Chapter
Monetary policy is inevitably operated by a central bank in the context of a specific banking and financial system and responding to the economic issues of the time. Financialisation in the present era, broadly the past four decades, has not only involved the continuing growth of the financial sector but also a more market-orientated banking system, development of securitisation, and growth of shadow banking. The past decade has also seen the adoption of quantitative easing (QE) and other forms of ‘unconventional’ monetary policy. This chapter explores the implications of aspects of financialisation for the transmission mechanisms of monetary policy and the objectives of monetary policy. It also considers the future of inflation targeting in light of experience, and financial stability as a key objective of monetary policy. The challenges of climate change and the possible implications for monetary policy are also considered.
... One way or another, modo palpatim, modo saltatim 24 refers to the phenomenon of financialisation when increasing attention is devoted to financial activity within the nonfinancial sector (i.e., financialisation is meant to follow a more financial income-seeking activity rather than pursuing productivity-increasing innovation/investments, whereby growing a proportion of financial assets within the total assets, cash-flow-exceeding income from financial activity and escalating payouts to stockholders compared to equity are in the cards, etc.). 25 The early stages of financialisation were already recognisable during the first half of the 20th century (Fasianos et al. 2018), while it really accelerated from the 1980s onwards with the deregulation of financial markets and the intensifying globalisation driven by the development of ICT as general-purpose technology. Although there is no single definition, financialisation essentially means that, along that course, debt-to-equity ratios started to increase, whereby the share of financial services relative to other sectors within the national income followed a continuously growing path. ...
Article
Full-text available
This contribution addresses the puzzle of whether Industry 4.0 is able to autochthonously bring back the real economy (non-financial corporate sector) into the consciousness of the financial sector. It is all the more important since the conventional wisdom over financialisation says that it cannot be reversed without re-establishing the command of the social and collective over the private and individual for the modern era. Our paper argues that a healthy diffusion of Industry 4.0 is doomed unless some directionality is set within the financialisation process. To this end, by building on the relevant lessons of complexity science, it investigates the complex nexus among financialisation, zombification and Industry 4.0 development, an aspect which is not even sporadically examined in the literature. After presenting a short stock take on excessive financialisation, the paper deciphers the main systemic channels of zombification affecting negatively the outlooks of Industry 4.0. Some important policy recommendations are drawn as well.
Preprint
Full-text available
Corporate financialization (CF) comprises a major subfield of financialization studies centered on the belief that significant changes in corporate governance and business models have been driven by financial imperatives, profoundly impacting investment habits, labor policies, organizational practices, and the distribution of revenues. Experiencing explosive growth in recent years, the field has become mired in conceptual ambiguity, mirroring problems with financialization studies as a whole. While seeking to restore some conceptual clarity and clearly delineate the boundaries of the concept, this paper attempts a comprehensive review of empirical work on CF. At the core of the field we identify four sub-fields, each addressing distinct aspects of the way business models have become financialized under the influence of shareholder value principles. Our dissection of the literature shows, however, that these theories mostly remain under substantiated. The connection of financialization strategies to key outcomes of interest, like declining investment and rising inequality, remains nebulous in most cases. Beyond this, we identify key weaknesses in the way shareholder value orientation-the causal lynch pin of CF accounts-has been theorized. The field as a whole has paid insufficient attention to the variegated and uneven nature of the shareholder revolution, which has prevented a single uniform set of governance principles from diffusing. The critique concludes with a call for caution and nuance in employing the corporate financialization framework, emphasizing its role as just one part of a multifaceted transformation within capitalism. Alongside it, other pivotal structural forces, such as intangibilization, monopolization, and globalization, demand equal attention. The overarching aim of this review is to urge greater clarity, conceptual discipline, and a holistic perspective in future investigations into the dynamics of financialized capitalism.
Article
Full-text available
During the past decades, industrial capitalism has been transformed into something which has been dubbed ‘Casino Capitalism’, ‘Turbo Capitalism’ or ‘Money Manager Capitalism’ by different authors: financial accumulation has outpaced real accumulation. This process of ‘financialisation’ has been discussed quite intensively in the literature with respect to its historical determinants and its macroeconomic effects, yet it has not been studied thoroughly whether the shift from the production and allocation of commodities and services towards the origination and distribution of loans and assets as the main activity of non-financial companies challenges our theoretical principles and, therefore, demands a new macroeconomic approach. The objective of this paper is to argue in a preliminary way that financialisation is not merely to be understood as the relative growth of the financial sector based on a deepening of financial intermediation but as a structural transformation of the core business of non-financial firms. This is based on an extended post-Keynesian theory of monetary production and an application of Minskian short- and long-term instability cycles.
Article
Full-text available
Finansallaşma, ekonomi politik literatüründe kapitalizmin dönüşümünü açıklamak için kullanılan kavramlardan biridir. Ekollerin finansallaşma argümanlarındaki farklılıklar, kavramın kullanımını zorlaştırmakta ve kavramın açıklama gücünü zayıflatmaktadır. Bu nedenle makalede, finansallaşma uzun dönemli ve tarihsel bir bakış açısıyla ele alınmaktadır. Çalışmanın amacı farklı tanımlardan hareketle finansallaşmanın, kapitalist birikim ilişkileri içindeki rolünü analiz etmektir. Betimleyici analiz yöntemiyle elde edilen bulgulara göre kapitalist çevrimler sırasında ortaya çıkan finansal genişleme ile sermaye birikiminin, maddi üretim sürecinde ortaya çıkan tıkanmalardan dolayı finansal alana kayması olguları arasındaki farklılık, kavramın işlevselliğini de belirlemektedir. Bu ayırımın netleştirilmesiyle, finansallaşmanın sermaye açısından bir tercihten çok, sistemin ortaya çıkardığı bir zorunluluk olduğu anlaşılabilir. Bu zorunluluk, sermaye birikim sürecinde herhangi bir tıkanma olmasa dahi ortaya çıkan artık değerin yeniden bölüşümü için kritik bir belirleyiciliğe sahiptir.
Article
Full-text available
The literature on financialization tends to overemphasize the increasing size of the financial sector vis-á-vis the rest of the non-financial business sector, usually excluding from the analysis the inter-sectoral relationships between firms. Moreover, few studies have utilized the analytical tools of network theory and the notion of centrality, despite the fact that they conceptualize financialization as the rising centrality of the financial sector. This paper attempts to address these issues and explore the evolution of financialization in the US economy before and after the subprime crisis, investigating the changes in the position of the financial sector. Informed by financial geography and the framework of Global Financial Networks (GFN), we also shed light on the impacts of financialization on those advanced business services sectors that complement financial activity, such as accounting, law, business consulting, and other business services firms. Empirically, we estimate backward and forward inter-sectoral linkages, clustering coefficients, and measures of centrality, utilizing a long time-series of input–output tables at a highly disaggregated level, in order to study the inter-sectoral evolution of financialization in the US.
Article
We argue that in the US there is a causal relationship running unidirectionally from negative shocks in capital productivity to negative variations in the wage share. We sustain that, faced with a capital productivity decrease, the US firm sector pushes wages down to maximize the rate of profit. Through asymmetric SVAR techniques that are robust to endogeneity and structural breaks; we show that decreases in capital productivity unidirectionally cause decreases in the wage share. We offer some possible explanations for that.
Article
Full-text available
We investigate the relationship between household debt and income inequality in the USA, allowing for asymmetry, using data over the period 1913–2008. We find evidence of an asymmetric cointegration between household debt and inequality for different regimes. Our results indicate household debt only responds to positive changes in income inequality, while there is no evidence of falling inequality significantly affecting household debt. The presence of this asymmetry provides further empirical insights into the emerging literature on household debt and inequality.
Article
The decline of the profit rate since World War II, up to the early 1980s, is now widely acknowledged, and a new upward trend has been identified. This study presents new computations of profit rates using a definition like that used by Marx in Volume III of Capital, where profits correspond to total surplus-value, as well as a definition of the rate of profit that impacts individual firms, taking account of interest, taxes, and inventories. We show that both the level and trend of a specific group of industries (such as Railroads), called Highly Capital Intensive Industries, whose capital-labor ratio is very large, are totally different from that of other industries. (Their profit rate is very low and did not decline.) When these industries are removed from the data set, the downward trend of the profit rate and the limited recovery can be more clearly observed. Overall, between 1948 and 1982, the profit rate was divided by a coefficient ranging between 2 and 7, depending on the sector and definition of the profit rate. The profit rate in 2000 is still only half of its value in 1948. Finally, we show that the decline of the productivity of capital was the main factor in the fall of the profit rate, though the decline of the share of profits also contributed to this evolution.
Article
We explain the 2008 crisis in Iceland and Ireland with an emphasis on the role financialisation played in destabilising these countries’ economies. The two small open economies share similarities in that both countries had capital inflows before the crisis, ending with a sudden stop. However, the mechanisms of the crisis, which induced the capital flows, the factors that influenced them and their effects on the real economy differed due to differences in currency regimes and the response to the crises. We investigate the link between financialisation and the transmission channels of financialisation on the macroeconomy, using ARDL methodology. Finally, we suggest policy prescriptions to limit the scale and scope of similar crises in the future while highlighting the institutional differences between the two economies.
Chapter
In 2008/09 the world economy was hit by a decline in real GDP, the scale of which had not been seen for generations. The so-called ‘Great Recession’ started with the collapse of the sub prime mortgage market in the United States in summer 2007, and it gained momentum following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. Under the conditions of deregulated and liberalized international financial markets, the financial and real crisis spread rapidly across the world, reaching another climax with the euro crisis which began in 2010. Although recovery has already started in late 2009 — albeit with different speeds in different countries — the world economy is far from having overcome the causes of the crisis which are rooted in long-run developments since the early 1980s. We hold that the severity of the present crisis is due to the following medium- to long-run developments, in particular in the advanced capitalist economies but also affecting the emerging market economies: the inefficient regulation of financial markets; an increasing inequality in the distribution of income; and rising imbalances at the global (and at the euro area) level.1 These developments have been dominated by the policies aimed at the deregulation of labour markets, the reduction of the level of government intervention in the market economy and of government demand management, the redistribution of income from (lower) wages to profits and top management salaries, and the deregulation and liberalization of national and international financial markets.
Book
Every economics textbook says the same thing: Money was invented to replace onerous and complicated barter systems—to relieve ancient people from having to haul their goods to market. The problem with this version of history? There’s not a shred of evidence to support it. Here anthropologist David Graeber presents a stunning reversal of conventional wisdom. He shows that 5,000 years ago, during the beginning of the agrarian empires, humans have used elaborate credit systems. It is in this era, Graeber shows, that we also first encounter a society divided into debtors and creditors. With the passage of time, however, virtual credit money was replaced by gold and silver coins—and the system as a whole began to decline. Interest rates spiked and the indebted became slaves. And the system perpetuated itself with tremendously violent consequences, with only the rare intervention of kings and churches keeping the system from spiraling out of control. Debt: The First 5,000 Years is a fascinating chronicle of this little known history—as well as how it has defined human history, and what it means for the credit crisis of the present day and the future of our economy.
Article
Özgür Orhangazi brings together a comprehensive analysis of financialization in the US economy that encompasses the historical, theoretical, and empirical sides of the issues. He explores the origins and consequences of the dramatic rise of financial markets in the US economy and focuses on the impacts of this process of 'financialization' on the operations of the non-financial corporate sector.