ArticlePDF Available

Royalty Rates and Non-disclosure Agreements in SEP licensing: Implications for Competition Law

Authors:

Abstract

Requiring a Non-Disclosure Agreements (NDAs) is a common business practice used to safeguard the commercial interests of a licensor and a licensee in intellectual property licensing matters. The recent litigation involving Standard Essential Patents (SEP) has, however, raised doubts over the practice of patentees requiring NDAs before licensing SEPs to putative licensees. It has been argued that the inclusion of royalty rates in NDAs leads to discriminatory pricing of technology — a violation of the commitment to licence under fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND) terms. That is, licensees cannot know if they receive non-discriminatory terms, if they cannot compare their licences due to NDAs. This article examines this issue from both theoretical and practical perspectives, and concludes that the inclusion of royalty rates in NDAs may be justified in view of the technological and commercial realities involved in SEP licensing.
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3092219
TILEC Discussion Paper
TILEC
Validity of Non-Disclosure Agreements in
SEP Licensing
By
Vikas Kathuria and Jessica C. Lai
DP 2018-004
ISSN 1572-4042
January 2018
ISSN 2213-9419 http://ssrn.com/abstract=3092219
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3092219 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3092219
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3092219 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3092219
Article
Full-text available
The Internet of Things is advancing as a new technological paradigm with enormous economic and societal implications. Network connectivity provides the basis. With this in mind, past and current conflicts surrounding the licensing and enforcement of standard essential patents (SEPs) in the information and communications technology (ICT) sector cast a shadow over IoT development. Focusing on the European approach based on competition law, this article explores the extent to which the existing legal framework, which has been mainly developed against the backdrop of problems in the mobile industry, will be capable of responding adequately to the challenges raised by the IoT.
Article
Full-text available
Startups are faced with legal issues. To boost the business, it should help Iranian startups not get involved with legal issues. One of the main problems of Iranian startups is the lack of prototype contracts. The purpose of this study is to provide a clear and practical strategy for starting businesses to succeed in the field of law and help owners of these types of businesses to regulate professional and professional contracts, as well as to inform them of the rights of the parties during Doing a deal and all the rules and regulations that can help them with their work during work. This article will provide key definitions in this area as well as practical examples for better understanding of the content provided, including examples. Principal contracts, number of pages, guarantees, and so on, so that the owners of these businesses safely idle استارتاپ ها با مسائل حقوقی مواجه می شوند. برای رونق کسب و کار باید به استارتاپ های ایرانی کمک کرد تا گرفتار مسائل حقوقی نشوند. یکی از مشکلات اصلی استارتاپ های ایرانی فقدان قراردادهای نمونه اولیه می باشد. هدف از انجام این مطالعه ، ارائه راهکاری عملی و واضح برای کسب و کارهای استارتاپی به منظور موفقیت در حوزه حقوقی و کمک به صاحبان این نوع از مشاغل به منظور تنظیم قرارداد های کاری اصولی و حرفه ای و همچنین مطلع کردن آنها از حقوق طرفین در حین انجام یک معامله و تمام ضوابط و قوانینی که در حین کار می تواند آنها را در احقاق حقوقشان یاری کند، می باشد.این مقاله ، به ارائه تعاریف کلیدی در این زمینه و همچنین نمونه هایی عملی برای تفهیم بهتر مطالب ارائه شده ، از جمله نمونه قرارداد های اصولی ، تعداد صفحاتی آن، تضمین ها و ... پرداخته است تا صاحبان این مشاغل با خیال راحت بتوانند کسب و کار نوپای خود را به صورت قانونی و با تضمین اجرایی ، توسعه بدهند و از چالش های قانونی موجود در راه خود با خبر باشند تا متحمل ضرر و زیان ناخواسته نشوند.
Article
Full-text available
Startups are faced with legal issues. To boost the business, it should help Iranian startups not get involved with legal issues. One of the main problems of Iranian startups is the lack of prototype contracts. The purpose of this study is to provide a clear and practical strategy for starting businesses to succeed in the field of law and help owners of these types of businesses to regulate professional and professional contracts, as well as to inform them of the rights of the parties during Doing a deal and all the rules and regulations that can help them with their work during work. This article will provide key definitions in this area as well as practical examples for better understanding of the content provided, including examples. Principal contracts, number of pages, guarantees, and so on, so that the owners of these businesses safely idle استارتاپ ها با مسائل حقوقی مواجه می شوند. برای رونق کسب و کار باید به استارتاپ های ایرانی کمک کرد تا گرفتار مسائل حقوقی نشوند. یکی از مشکلات اصلی استارتاپ های ایرانی فقدان قراردادهای نمونه اولیه می باشد. هدف از انجام این مطالعه ، ارائه راهکاری عملی و واضح برای کسب و کارهای استارتاپی به منظور موفقیت در حوزه حقوقی و کمک به صاحبان این نوع از مشاغل به منظور تنظیم قرارداد های کاری اصولی و حرفه ای و همچنین مطلع کردن آنها از حقوق طرفین در حین انجام یک معامله و تمام ضوابط و قوانینی که در حین کار می تواند آنها را در احقاق حقوقشان یاری کند، می باشد.این مقاله ، به ارائه تعاریف کلیدی در این زمینه و همچنین نمونه هایی عملی برای تفهیم بهتر مطالب ارائه شده ، از جمله نمونه قرارداد های اصولی ، تعداد صفحاتی آن، تضمین ها و ... پرداخته است تا صاحبان این مشاغل با خیال راحت بتوانند کسب و کار نوپای خود را به صورت قانونی و با تضمین اجرایی ، توسعه بدهند و از چالش های قانونی موجود در راه خود با خبر باشند تا متحمل ضرر و زیان ناخواسته نشوند.
Article
Full-text available
Few legal issues in recent years have captured the public's attention more powerfully than litigation over standard essential patents ("SEPs"). This Article explains how SEP litigation overlaps with two other major centers of patent litigation – litigation involving smartphones and patent assertion entities ("PAEs"). It observes that attempting to pre-empt patent hold-ups by imposing blanket ex ante disclosure obligations and royalty caps on standard setting organizations ("SSOs") is misdirected and counterproductive. Instead, the solution lies in clear and balanced rules to determine "fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory" (FRAND) royalties and injunctive relief. This solution will help parties make more realistic assessments of their options and help adjudicators resolve SEP disputes. Correctly framed, implementers bear the burden of proving the breach of a FRAND commitment. FRAND royalties should, in the absence of comparable licenses, focus on apportioning the profits based on the relative importance of the patented technology in the covered product. Royalties should be measured at the time the standard is set but generally should not be discounted for the possibility of invalidity and non-infringement. Discriminatory licenses can be hard to detect, but targeted initiatives and improved transparency would make the task easier. Injunctions should be granted based the wording and intent of the relevant FRAND commitment, conduct of the parties, and proof that the Assistant Professor, The John Marshall Law School. I am grateful to Logan Breed, Mike Carrier, as well as the participants of the AIPLA Computer and Electronic Summit, the McAndrews, Held & Malloy LLC Comprehensive IP Litigation Update, the IP Scholars' Roundtable, the IP on the Edge Conference, and the Faculty Work in Progress Workshop for their helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to Dean Ralph Ruebner for the summer research grant awarded in support of this Article, and to Judge Jim Holderman of the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of Illinois for his encouragement to take this article further. Many thanks also to Susanna Bagdasarova and her team at the Penn State Law Review, including Beth Robinson, Alexandra Cumings and Emma Snyder, for their outstanding work in bringing this Article to print. All errors and omissions remain my own.
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the relationship between product market competition (PMC) and innovation. A growth model is developed in which competition may increase the incremental profit from innovating; on the other hand, competition may also reduce innovation incentives for laggards. There are four key predictions. First, the relationship between product market competition (PMC) and innovation is an inverted U-shape. Second, the equilibrium degree of technological neck-and-neckness' among firms should decrease with PMC. Third, the higher the average degree of neck-and-neckness' in an industry, the steeper the inverted-U relationship. Fourth, firms may innovate more if subject to higher debt-pressure, especially at lower levels of PMC. We confront these predictions with data on UK firms' patenting activity at the US patenting office. They are found to accord well with observed behavior.
Some scholars argue that royalty rates should be based on the end-user product; seePortfolio Licensing at the End-User Device Level: Analyzing Refusals to License FRAND-Assured Standard-Essential Patents at the Component Level' (2016) available at <https://ssrn
  • W Koren
  • Jorge Wong-Ervin
  • Padilla
Some scholars argue that royalty rates should be based on the end-user product; see, Koren W. Wong-Ervin and Jorge Padilla, 'Portfolio Licensing at the End-User Device Level: Analyzing Refusals to License FRAND-Assured Standard-Essential Patents at the Component Level' (2016) available at <https://ssrn.com/abstract=2806688 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2806688> accessed 23 April 2017; J.
The Proper Royalty Base for Patent Damages Journal of Competition Law & Economics 989-1037; but see Roberto Grasso, 'Standard Essential Patents: Royalty Determination in the Supply Chain
  • Gregory Sidak
Gregory Sidak, 'The Proper Royalty Base for Patent Damages' (2014) 10(4) Journal of Competition Law & Economics 989-1037; but see Roberto Grasso, 'Standard Essential Patents: Royalty Determination in the Supply Chain' (2016) Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 1. 39
]; Case No. 76 of 2013 [Intex Technologies (India) Limited v
Case No. 50 of 2013 [Micromax Informatics Limited v. Telefonaktiebolaget LM Ericsson (Publ.)]; Case No. 76 of 2013 [Intex Technologies (India) Limited v. Telefonaktiebolaget LM Ericsson (Publ.)]; Case No. 04 of 2015 [M/s Best IT World (India) Private Limited (iBall) v. Telefonaktiebolaget LM Ericsson (Publ.)]. 40
Licensing Terms of Standard Essential Patents: A Comprehensive Analysis of Cases
  • Chryssoula See
  • Pentheroudakis
  • Justus
  • Baron
See Chryssoula Pentheroudakis and Justus A Baron (European Commission), 'Licensing Terms of Standard Essential Patents: A Comprehensive Analysis of Cases' (2017) at 96-99 and 147-150.
) at [7] and [17], where the CCI stated that Ericsson's refusal to share its commercial terms and royalty payments with other licensees was "strongly suggestive of the fact that different royalty rates/commercial terms were being offered to the potential licensees belonging to the same category" and
See e.g. Intex Technologies (India) Ltd v Telefonaktiebolaget LM Ericsson, Case No. 76 of 2013, Competition Commission of India (16 January 2014) at [7] and [17], where the CCI stated that Ericsson's refusal to share its commercial terms and royalty payments with other licensees was "strongly suggestive of the fact that different royalty rates/commercial terms were being offered to the potential licensees belonging to the same category" and "fortifie[d] the accusations of [Intex], regarding alleged discriminatory commercial terms imposed by [Ericsson]".
Intellectual Property Rights Policy', cl 6.1. On FRAND licensing, see Chryssoula Pentheroudakis and Justus A Baron (European Commission), 'Licensing Terms of Standard Essential Patents: A Comprehensive Analysis of Cases
  • E G Etsi
E.g. ETSI, 'Intellectual Property Rights Policy', cl 6.1. On FRAND licensing, see Chryssoula Pentheroudakis and Justus A Baron (European Commission), 'Licensing Terms of Standard Essential Patents: A Comprehensive Analysis of Cases' (2017).
Standard Essential Patents, Trolls, and the Smartphone Wars: Triangulating the End Game' (2014) 119(1) Penn State Law Review
  • Daryl Lim
Daryl Lim, 'Standard Essential Patents, Trolls, and the Smartphone Wars: Triangulating the End Game' (2014) 119(1) Penn State Law Review 1 at 4 and 10-11.
Portfolio Licensing at the End-User Device Level: Analyzing Refusals to License FRAND-Assured Standard-Essential Patents at the Component Level
  • W Koren
  • Jorge Wong-Ervin
  • Padilla
FRAND obligations turn property rights into pseudo liability rules. SSOs are private and agreements to Some scholars argue that royalty rates should be based on the end-user product; see, Koren W. Wong-Ervin and Jorge Padilla, 'Portfolio Licensing at the End-User Device Level: Analyzing Refusals to License FRAND-Assured Standard-Essential Patents at the Component Level' (2016) available at <https://ssrn.com/abstract=2806688 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2806688> accessed 23 April 2017; J.