Conference PaperPDF Available

Innovation Ecosystems vs. Innovation Systems in Terms of Collaboration and Co-creation of Value

Authors:

Abstract

In this paper, we explore the relevance of the term “innovation ecosystem” to describe dynamic collaborative networks of people and organizations formed around projects with an innovation objective. We present a survey of literature reviews on ecosystems studies to clarify typical features and interpretations of innovation ecosystems, and we highlight differences in terms of collaboration and value co-creation. We explore ecosystem thinking and illustrate patterns of innovation ecosystems by describing the structure of regional clusters, global value chains and platforms. We offer policy insights on the role of governments in stimulating innovation ecosystems and innovation-conducive environments
Innovation Ecosystems vs. Innovation Systems in Terms of Collaboration and
Co-creation of Value
Nataliya Smorodinskaya
Inst of Economics, RAS
smorodinskaya@gmail.com
Martha G. Russell
Stanford University
MarthaR@stanford.edu
Daniel Katukov
Inst of Economics, RAS
dkatukov@gmail.com
Kaisa Still
VTT of Finland
kaisa.still@vtt.fi
Abstract
In this paper, we explore the relevance of the term
“innovation ecosystem” to describe dynamic
collaborative networks of people and organizations
formed around projects with an innovation objective. We
present a survey of literature reviews on ecosystems
studies to clarify typical features and interpretations of
innovation ecosystems, and we highlight differences in
terms of collaboration and value co-creation. We
explore ecosystem thinking and illustrate patterns of
innovation ecosystems by describing the structure of
regional clusters, global value chains and platforms. We
offer policy insights on the role of governments in
stimulating innovation ecosystems and innovation-
conducive environments.
1. Introduction
The concept of innovation ecosystems has emerged
in early 2000s to meet the demands of emerging
knowledge-based economies, in which the production of
innovations and the associated development processes
are increasingly non-linear and network-based [1]. This
concept has remarkably enriched the idea of innovation
systems, coined in the industrial era in the research
streams of Freeman, Lundvall, Nelson, and their
followers [26]. In the 1990s, national or regional
innovation systems were seen as static structures
regulated by government bodies, with successful
performance depending on a critical mass of involved
actors and intentional infrastructure [1]. As a departure,
innovation ecosystems of the 2000s are considered
dynamic and agile collaborative structures that enjoy
self-governance as a necessary prerequisite for
interactive innovation [7, 8]. This approach is now
applied in innovation policies of many developed and
developing nations [9].
Meanwhile, some scholars and experts still seriously
doubt whether the introduction of the term ‘ecosystem’,
adding “eco- to “system”, is justified. In particular,
some papers argue that though writers on “innovation
ecosystems” have added some valuable ideas to the
innovation discussion, appending “eco- to “innovation
systems” adds nothing of substance. Rather, “innovation
ecosystem” is a faulty analogy to natural ecosystems
[10]. A discussion on this problem of a better
terminology opened in the literature quite recently.
Against this background our paper is an attempt to
make a contribution to such discussion. With the updated
thinking of innovation (for example by the World
Economic Forum) [1], we conduct a review of literature
published from 2005 to 2016 on ecosystems,
concentrating on innovation ecosystems and
acknowledging the related terms of business ecosystem,
software ecosystem, industrial ecosystem, digital
business ecosystem, entrepreneurship ecosystem, and
knowledge ecosystem. We aim to clarify typical features
of innovation ecosystems as compared to systems and to
highlight the advantages of an ecosystemic mode of
producing innovations, while picking up interpretations
and definitions both from economic and business
literature.
2. On the definition and the variety of
ecosystems in literature
In the updated version of the Global
Competitiveness index (GCI), the World Economic
Forum draws from findings in the literature, and argues
in GCI that innovation now means not only
technological innovation but, in a broader notion, an
“ecosystem” (environment) conducive to the generation
of ideas and their implementation in the form of new
products, services, and processes in the global
marketplace [1]. This approach can be further described
with three important details: the wider-scope of
innovation, the innovation-conducive environment, and
various studies on ecosystems.
Firstly, regarding the scope of innovation, new ideas
can be generated by formal scientific R&D; they can
also result from non-R&D activities that do not require
fixed research costs yet increase the efficiency with
which a good or service is produced (such as
innovations in managerial and organizational
5245
Proceedings of the 50th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences | 2017
URI: http://hdl.handle.net/10125/41798
ISBN: 978-0-9981331-0-2
CC-BY-NC-ND
techniques, personnel, accounting, work practices, etc.)
The implementation of such ideas may be commercial
and non-commercial (the latter often treated as “softer”
innovation.)
Table 1. Literature reviews on the variety of ecosystems, 2005-2016
Review
Review source
Review result
(Peltoniemi, 2005) [11]
Literature review and conceptual
analysis of business ecosystem as
an organizational population model
Dynamics of conscious choice and limited
knowledge of an individual organization and
from the interconnected-ness and feedback
loops of an organization’s population;
differences in cluster and value networks
(Peltoniemi, 2006) [12]
(Manikas & Hansen, 2013)
[13]
90 papers relevant to software
ecosystem(s)
The software industry is moving towards
software ecosystems with platforms like
Google Android and Apple iOS
(Pilinkienė & Mačiulis,
2014) [14]
Literature review of ecosystem
analogies: industrial ecosystem,
innovation ecosystem, business
ecosystem, digital business
ecosystem, entrepreneurship
ecosystem
Ecosystem analogies have various scopes
and objectives having an impact on micro-
level, associated with actions of internal
actors; (eco)system can be a significant
determinant of sustainable economic
development
(Gawer, 2014) [15]
Review of management research on
technological platforms: industrial
economics and engineering design
Platforms operate along an organizational
continuum, including firms, supply chains,
and industry ecosystems
(Gawer & Cusumano,
2014) [16]
Platform-based ecosystem
innovation; review of research on
internal and external platforms
A critical issue for managers is to learn to
manage the evolution of their industry
platforms and accompanying ecosystems
and make interrelated technological and
business decisions
(Thomas, Autio, & Gann,
2014) [17]
183 publications of platforms in
management context
Four streams of platform research identified:
organizational capability, product family,
market intermediary and technology system
(Kortelainen & Järvi,
2014) [18]
72 empirical articles on ecosystems
in a business context
Research on ecosystems is still a long way
from the stage of theory testing (i.e., using
multivariate statistical methods) or of
replication studies across ecosystems
(Valkokari, 2015) [19]
Review of types of business,
innovation and knowledge
ecosystems and the relationships
between them
In order to survive and thrive in an
ecosystem, a variety of forms of interaction
are required; the interaction between various
types of ecosystems is an unexplored area
(Suominen, Seppänen, &
Dedehayir, 2016) [20]
4681 publications to look at
innovation systems literature, 427
ecosystem research articles
The literature on national, regional and
technological innovation systems, as well as
literature on corporate competitiveness and
the ecosystem approach, has both shared and
divergent intellectual roots
(Aarikka-Stenroos, Peltola,
Rikkiev, & Saari, 2016)
[21]
Systematic content analysis of 157
articles of innovation and business
ecosystems
Multidisciplinary perspectives exist on
ecosystem phenomenon; research gaps exist,
including a gap in policy-making; the
business ecosystem stream is dominant
Source: Authors’ elaboration
Secondly, an innovation-conducive environment,
comprised of ecosystems and networks, can increase
the likelihood that “softer” innovation takes place.
This environment encourages collaboration,
connectivity, critical and creative thinking, diversity,
and confrontation across different visions and angles.
By bringing new products and services to market,
5246
such ecosystems and networks foster productivity
though embedded technology, with efficiency gains.
Thirdly, to achieve a complete picture of an
innovation-conducive environment one needs to
consider both economic literature (which focuses
more on system incentives to spur idea generation at
the aggregate level) and business literature (which
identifies important factors that generate innovative
companies and/or motivate them to innovate).
To this end, and particularly to explore the
contemporary perception of innovation ecosystems,
we examined relevant scholarly literature in the field
of management and economics. We found eleven
(11) literature reviews, identified through previous
literature reviews themselves. For example,
Kortelainen and Järvi [18] acknowledge seven
primary reviews, while Valkokari [19] draws from
the review by Thomas, Autio and Gann [17]. In
addition, participation in scientific conferences
allowed us to include other very recent reviews. The
range of primary sources covered by reviews during
the 2005 to 2016 period is diverse, as some are based
on tens of scholarly articles, others are based on 100+
articles, and one even considers close to 5000
publications, as shown in Table 1.
Our overarching survey has highlighted a broad
variety of related terms, used simultaneously in
literature to describe organizational continua or
network interactions. Particularly, there are business
ecosystems, software ecosystems, platforms,
industrial ecosystems, digital business ecosystems,
entrepreneurship ecosystems and knowledge
ecosystems; in addition, start-up ecosystem is
mentioned [21]. Overall, these entities are seen as
vital in sustainable economic development [14].
Our findings confirm that the ecosystem idea is
often applied without clear definitions [19] and that
there is increased conceptual ambiguity of the
terminology [20]. Terms denoting different types of
ecosystems are often used interchangeably [21],
although some differences between biological and
business ecosystems are articulated [11, 12, 14]. It
has been noted that research on ecosystems is still a
long way from the stage of theory testing [18].
3. Synthesis for interpreting innovation
ecosystems
In previous writings, we viewed innovation
ecosystems as networks of sustainable linkages
between individuals and organizations, which emerge
from a shared vision of desired transformations and
provide an economic context (milieu) to catalyze
innovation and growth [22]. As applied to the variety
of inter-firm or inter-organizational networks, this
definition implies innovation ecosystems are oriented
either to the direct co-creation of innovations or to
the formation of innovation-supportive milieu [23].
As our literature review shows, innovation
ecosystems may be treated both as business networks
and as communities meant for innovation. They may
assume different scale and design, functioning as
regional innovation hubs, nation-wide innovation
communities, local inter-firm networks, very small
network-based ad-hoc groups of individuals, or
global wide networks [7].
However, neither geography nor industry sector
expose the essence of innovation ecosystems as
compared to systems. Noticeably, in management
studies, one of the primary motivations for
addressing the ecosystem concept has been the desire
to explore self-organizing properties of natural
ecosystems [24]. In studies on innovation dealing
with generation and implementation of new ideas,
ecosystems are usually considered a means for co-
creation and market introduction of inventions [1].
Literature on economic competitiveness incorporates
the idea of ecosystems in the context of the broad
impact of digital technologies (IT, ICT) on the
changing nature of innovation process, especially
regarding implications of non-linear innovation for
alternative organizational designs. Such thinking is
reflected in modern production systems at all levels
(firms, clusters, regions, national economies, global
economy).
Summarizing the relevant points in literature, as
they highlight the origin and properties of innovation
ecosystems, we come to the following conclusion. In
the age of non-linear innovation and digital
technologies, innovation can be better nurtured
within a special, innovation-conducive environment.
Such an environment may be seen as an ecosystem
meant for co-creation of value through collaboration.
The concept of value co-creation is basically
associated with a business strategy focusing on
interactive relationships between producers and
consumers (the latter are becoming productive
workers, or prosumers, who are granted authority by
companies to articulate their specific requirements
and at times contribute to design considerations).
Initially elaborated by the business and market
literature, this concept started to gain momentum in
the post-2000 period, expanding further in its two
dimensions, as both the idea of value co-production
and the idea of value-in-use [25].
According to an updated definition, as introduced
in management studies, particularly by LSE
Enterprise [26], co-creation of value is an active,
creative and social process, based on collaboration
5247
between producers and users, which is initiated by
the firm to generate value for customers and compete
to pass others in the category (i.e., the Nike approach
constitutes a full spectrum of customer involvement
and competition). While consumers benefit from
greater personalization and value, companies build
competitive advantage by turning just-in-time
knowledge from customers into just-in-time learning
for their organizations. Relationships for co-creation
may also be established between and among
businesses and service organizations. Such
collaboration might include global introduction,
competitive analytics and tolerance for inefficiency.
The co-creation concept highlights not only the
frequency of interaction, but also the quality of
relationships between companies and their customers,
or among companies, to determine how knowledge is
created, shared and transferred [27]. In terms of
modern economics literature, this concept can be
applied to the architecture of the innovation-led
economy based on customized products. In this
sense, the co-creation process may imply the
possibility of collaboration between different types of
actors across the economy, enabling them to co-
produce new goods and values, i.e., innovations.
In turn, collaboration, taken in a broad sense,
denotes various forms of interactive communication
between networked actors. For example, some
experts argue [27] that collaboration is important for
both R&D and non-R&D innovation but each type
uses different networks. In a more exact definition,
collaboration is seen as the most developed form of
interactive cooperation. It implies that in order to co-
create innovations, networked actors must rely on a
common vision, strategy, common identity, and joint
obligations [28].
To further explain the term of innovation
ecosystems and its implications, we have developed
additional perspectives.
3.1 ‘Innovation ecosystem’ as a metaphor
for collaborative innovation networks
Ecosystems can’t be deliberately established as
system-like organizations. Rather they emerge as
innovation-conducive environments in the course of
collaboration among networked actors. Meanwhile,
collaborative networks themselves, tailored to co-
creation of value in various forms and ways, can and
should be treated as modern agile organizations
typical of the 21st century. One of the first
descriptions of such dynamic and innovative entities
appeared in early 1990s in the “New Society of
Organizations” by P. Drucker [29], in which he
underlined the ability of such organizations for
continual “creative destruction” and predicted their
future global domination.
Later, a more exact term of ‘collaborative
innovation networks’ appeared in literature to denote
typical organizational forms of production in the age
of digital technologies. This term was popularized by
Gloor in 2006 [30] and further explored conceptually
[31] and empirically [32] by other authors. Such
networks may be local, national, transnational or
global; they may have different configuration and
patterns of collaboration [31]. Their growing
proliferation implies that in the 21st century,
innovative goods, technologies and values will be
typically co-created through collaborations of
networked entities that form relatively sustainable
ecosystems of actors, linkages and assets [33].
Since innovativeness of networks can be revealed
only through their collaboration activities, we can
consider them innovation ecosystems and use this
term as a metaphor for denoting their specific
organizational and functional features, as compared
to systems. Ecosystems are tailored to interactive co-
creation of values, while systems are not.
Taken as a metaphor of collaborative networks,
the term ‘innovation ecosystem’ provides a highly
useful image to draw a difference between the rigid
hierarchical design of economic systems in the age of
linear development and their dynamic network-based
architecture in the 21st century. Hence, this term helps
to highlight the newly emerging economic milieu, in
which innovative goods and values are created at the
level of networks capable of shaping an effective
ecosystem. “Eco” stands to emphasize the non-linear
nature of innovation and the crucial role of
collaboration in producing innovations to achieve
sustainable development in non-linear environments.
The ability of collaborative networks to adapt
themselves to a non-linear environment implies they
assume certain features of complex adaptive systems -
agility, self-organization, self-governance, and
synergy effects [34]. When it comes to such
ecosystems as innovation clusters, cluster literature
(originated by Porter and followers) directly
interprets them as complex dynamic systems, noting
their unique synergy effects [3537].
Also important, collaborative networks that form
an ecosystem of actors and linkages to co-create
innovations are designed as temporary projects,
around a common project idea. For this reason, the
emanating network economy is also called a project
economy [38], as an alternative to a traditional
economy, in which interactions are not necessarily
collaborative and long-term systems are intended.
Collaborative networks and their ecosystems are
distinguished by different design, functional purpose
5248
and pattern of collaboration. These differences can be
easily seen when comparing regional innovation
clusters, global value chains and digital platforms.
3.1.1. Innovation clusters as formalized
innovation ecosystems. Innovation clusters are
geographically localized agglomerations of
collaborating firms and organizations, which enjoy a
highly developed pattern of collaboration, associated
with a triple-helix model, i.e. an interactive pairwise
collaboration between three types of networked
institutional actors, namely companies, research
centers and authorities [39]. As follows from cluster
literature [37], innovation clusters constitute a special
variety of innovation ecosystems, in which triple-
helix interactions enable unique economic effects of
innovation synergy, or co-creation of innovative
goods and services on a continual basis. According
to this literature, among the various kinds of
collaborative networks only innovation clusters can
provide a sustainable rise in productivity based on a
continual innovation [40]. Initial systemic findings
[41] confirm that successful innovation clusters can
function as poles of growth for a given region.
Open innovation clusters are considered the
most convenient ecosystem model both for
continuous co-creation of innovations and for
disseminating them across an economy. These
ecosystems are shaped by collaborative partners of
various profiles, who are free to join and leave the
open cluster network [40]. According to observations
[4244], mature clusters have a sophisticated
ecosystem of functional linkages, formed both by
deeply embedded actors and by flagship firms that
have already expanded beyond the cluster’s bounds
and are reinvesting money in their business projects
By virtue of the coordinating work of cluster
organizations, a co-located group of companies is
able to transform itself into a self-governed and self-
sustainable network that can achieve innovation
synergy. Due to their relationships developed as
ecosystems, entities in agile innovation clusters can
combine and rapidly recombine their shared assets in
varied and novel configurations and, in this way, can
flexibly start new venture business projects to meet
the rapidly changing market demands. Their “design”
is evolved through a combination of market forces,
organizational efforts of triple helix actors [45], and
value transactions [46].
3.1.2. Global value chains as innovation
ecosystems of cross-cluster collaboration. Regional
innovation clusters are seeking to develop their
specializations in ways that enable them to become
geographically localized network nodes of global
value chains (GVCs). The latter are the result of
globalization, when traded goods and services are no
longer produced or consumed within a single country
but instead, through dispersion of the production
processes and marketing, across several countries.
GVCs are now horizontally crossing countries and
territories, with value added flows circulating
between their cluster nodes. Meanwhile, GVCs
themselves constitute a special kind of collaborative
networks, and therefore, a kind of ecosystem to co-
create value.
GVCs emerged in the late industrial era due to
outsourcing business practices. Initially, they were
governed by hierarchic multinationals that were
building vertical systems of actors under their
control, while looking for expansion in size at local,
not yet globalized markets. Nowadays, multinationals
tend to become more horizontally dispersed and
network-based [47].
One can see a GVC as a horizontally dispersed
ecosystem for value co-creation, formed by a
network of legally independent and functionally
interdependent actors that are collaborating across
countries and territories within a common project.
The participating actors create initial and
intermediary products (knowledge, technologies,
goods, services) that move along the chain in an
upstream way, generating flows of a consecutively
added value, until the final product is co-created and
delivered to external customers, embedding
productivity into a dynamic cluster ecosystem.
3.1.3. Platforms as ecosystems for value co-
creation. Digital platforms are oftentimes regarded
as technological systems, as a technical artifact, “as
the extensible code-based system that provides core
functionality shaped by the modules that interoperate
with it, and the interfaces through which they
interoperate” [48, p. 677]. Increasingly they are also
seen as management and economic concepts, creating
value by providing products and services that enable
two or more different types of customers to find each
other and exchange value [49]. Importantly, the
overall value of platform requires players, such as
developers who build tools, to operationalize the
exchange [50]. Conceptualization of platforms has
been developed separately by two streams of
academic literature industrial economics and
engineering design.
The industrial economics perspective associates
platforms with a new, network type of markets (two-
sided or multi-sided), focusing on how platforms
create value by coordinating transactions between
two or more groups of consumers who would not
have been able to connect without the platform. This
5249
literature highlights that platforms generate a virtuous
cycle of indirect, or cross-group network effects (the
value that consumers and the platform owner can
capture increases with increasing customer bases),
which dynamically reinforces incumbents’ early-
gained advantages.
The engineering design perspective views
platforms as purposefully designed modular
architectures organized around a ‘core’ (the platform
leader) and a ‘periphery of users’ (which complement
the platform leader), providing a respective
technological interface between these two sides. This
literature posits that platforms can network and
coordinate users not just in the role of consumers but
first of all in the role of suppliers and innovators, thus
helping firms to achieve the economy of scope
effects and facilitate innovation [51].
The literature on platforms distinguishes three
broad types of platforms, namely platforms within
firms (like Sony Walkman’s platform servicing
constituent sub-units of one firm in consumer
electronics), platforms across supply chains,
including GVCs (like Boeing’s platform for the GVC
in aerospace manufacturing, or Renault-Nissan’s
platform for the GVC in automotive manufacturing),
and industry-wide platforms (like Facebook’s
platform across the sector of social networking) [52].
Industry-wide platforms are considered as generators
of the most open ecosystems. They are defined as
technological building blocks (technologies,
products, or services), which act as a foundation for
organized array of interdependent firms (sometimes
called an industry ‘‘ecosystem’’) to develop a set of
inter-related products, technologies and services [15].
On top of this, there exists a special class of
platforms for joint action, tailored to overcome
coordination problems and to directly support
collaboration in the process of the project realization
[52]. These platforms enable cluster participants to
better exploit potential linkages among existing
capabilities and to make better decisions on investing
into new capabilities, taking into account the
externalities of such actions across the cluster [53].
These platforms aim to provide innovation synergy
effects that lead to individual and aggregate
‘competitiveness upgrading’ across the cluster [37].
Insights from different research streams move us
closer to understanding platforms from the
perspective of value co-creation. Platforms can form
or promote the emergence of ecosystems enabling the
co-production of innovations [25]. Much of this
ability concerns the value-in-use dimension of the
value co-creation concept, i.e., using and transferring
value. Cluster platforms for joint action enable
networked actors (producers, suppliers, customers) to
exchange their knowledge, transfer value and
reshuffle their resources for the purpose of direct co-
production of innovations [45].
Overall, digital platforms are redesigning
traditional industrial landscapes towards ecosystemic
perspective. Literatures on platforms and ecosystems
have started to merge and have introduced the term
‘platform ecosystem’ (for example Basole & Karla
54). Scholars are examining platform roles in
ecosystems that generate large populations of
networked users, who carry different functions and
interact in a wide variety of ways to co-create value.
This makes it reasonable to associate platforms with
innovation ecosystems rather than with technological
systems. And as studies on platforms suggest
(McKinsey Global Institute, 2015 55), the digital
sector provides several widely recognized examples
of platforms and their associated platform leaders,
such as Apple, Facebook, or Google (which became
Alphabet) with each of these leaders playing an
orchestrating role within a network of firms and
individual innovators that have come to be
collectively referred to as the platform’s “innovation
ecosystem” [56].
3.2 Transition of economies to ecosystem
organizational design
Although the word ‘ecosystem’ derives
linguistically from biological ecology, the use of this
term in the context of innovation is not about
connotations with Darwin’s natural order. Rather it
reflects the growing organizational complexity of
economic systems, which denotes the formation of a
new, more sophisticated social order, based on
network coordination [27].
The shift of the technological paradigm [57]
associated with non-linear innovation and
proliferation of digital technologies is occurring hand
in hand with a concomitant shift in the paradigm of
social interactions. While industrial economies of
mass production rested on a combination of market
and hierarchic patterns of coordination, the emerging
innovation-intensive economies (also called post-
industrial systems, or knowledge-based economies)
rely on a more sophisticated, network pattern of
social coordination, constituting a functional hybrid
between rigid hierarchies and atomistic markets [58,
59]. As applied to these changes, the term
‘innovation ecosystem’ can be used to denote the
ongoing organizational transformation of economies
into network-based production systems. This change
is accompanied by a deconstruction of hierarchies
both at micro- and macro-levels of social activity. In
a growing number of countries private firms and
5250
public bodies are meeting the challenge of
restructuring, transforming themselves from
vertically built entities into more flexible and
horizontally oriented [47, 60].
The newly emerging design of economies can be
called ecosystemic, to emphasize the crucial role of
networking and dynamic connectivity between actors
(including interpersonal linkages) to work within the
dispersed non-linear space. As a result, an
innovation-conducive context is emerging. This
context implies an inclusive institutional environment
in the terms of Acemoglu and Robinson [61], or the
idea of building ‘commons’ in terms of Ostrom [62],
or simpler, the culture of win-win games in economic
and political markets to meet challenges of the global
competition.
As rigid vertical hierarchies, typical of the
industrial era, are being replaced by agile horizontal
networks, the traditional patterns of governance are
giving way to collective decision-making, in which
investment priorities, lines of business activity and
conventions are defined through interactive
consensus-building among networked actors. This
non-hierarchic model of governance, associated with
proliferation of platform-based communication, is
often called collaborative governance [63].
Collaborative governance in its various patterns
is now emerging for region-wide or national-wide
innovation ecosystems that are gradually evolving
within countries and territories under government
support. Collaboratively governed ecosystems
provide an alternative to the former, “linear”
innovation systems of regional or national scale,
which governments have tried to develop not through
promoting collaboration and connectivity but through
initiatives that concentrated on the individual roles of
actors, or the establishment of innovative
infrastructure or structures as such [64].
3.3 The new mission of governments in the
age of ecosystems. Policy implications.
The global trend in the transformation of the
hierarchical systems of the past into network-based
and self-supportive ecosystems of the post-industrial
era doesn’t mean that the governments are becoming
less active. On the contrary, governments’ best
interests require being even more proactive now than
in the late industrial epoch, associated with
liberalization of markets. However, the functional
purpose and the manner of government interventions
into markets are drastically changing.
In the industrial age, various national
governments, especially in developing economies,
took the upper hand in defining strategic priorities for
the private sector, which was associated with a
classical model of industrial policy. During times
when modernization in many developing economies
had been driven by their market-oriented transition,
direct state interventions into industrial structures
have been replaced by mild indirect initiatives aimed
at building a better institutional environment.
The situation has changed in recent years, when
all types of economies (developed, developing and
those in transition) have been faced with a common
need to accelerate their transition to knowledge-based
systems and adapt themselves to the non-linear
world. At the organizational level, this challenge is
concerned with promotion of a network-based and
ecosystem-oriented transformation. As a result, since
2010s, a new model of industrial policy has emerged
in many developed and developing countries, one
which seeks to upgrade their industrial structure and
enhance competitiveness through a collaborative
organizational environment for a continual
innovation [65].
The new industrial policy is not limited to
manufacturing or to material goods. Rather it's about
acceleration of the ecosystem-oriented restructuring
in the whole industrial (economic) landscape,
implying that under this new design the market forces
will self-discover the most innovative business
projects and re-direct resources into those projects
and industries [66]. Under this policy, national
governments don't seek to build specialized
innovation clusters in "priority" industries, but
instead help localities create platforms and
infrastructures for networking and collaboration.
Though modern industrial policy is aimed at
generating macro-level structural shifts, it is based on
removing barriers at the micro-level, in order to
cultivate organizational and social transformations
through inter-firm and inter-organizational
networking. The ecosystem approach implies that
network linkages interconnect the micro- and macro
levels of economies, corresponding to the core idea
of Porter’s Diamond model of competitiveness [40].
4. Concluding findings
The term “innovation ecosystem” symbolizes the
newly emerging, network mode of arranging business
activity and economic governance, which enables
companies and territories to master innovation-led
growth and benefit from rapid technological changes.
This mode requires horizontal and inclusive
economic thinking, as well as enabling certain
organizational continua, relevant for interactive
innovation and dispersed patterns of production.
5251
Innovation ecosystems can’t be referred to as
subjects of decision and action. Rather they are
special organizational spaces, tailored to co-creation
of values through collaboration. More exactly, they
constitute a sophisticated milieu of actors, assets and
linkages, generated by collaborative activities of
networks. Such networks of various forms, sizes and
profiles can play the role of modern-type
organizations meant for a collective decision-making
and collective action, and innovation ecosystems
should be seen as the native environment of such
networks. However, since collaborative networks and
their ecosystems are functionally inseparable (in
terms of interactive co-creation of value), both terms
may be perceived and used interchangeably. This
admission corresponds to findings in literature on
complexity, viewing collaborative networks as
complex adaptive systems that are inseparable from
their changing environment by definition [66].
A multifaceted variety of ecosystem models,
meant for various functional purposes, is now
emerging and developing. Irrespective of their
dispersed titles in different research streams, most of
them can be referred to the class of innovation
ecosystems, since the modern non-linear pattern of
economic activity and economic growth is inherently
connected with innovation. Our exploration of this
variety through comparison of three different cases
(platforms, clusters and value chains) suggests that
all ecosystem models are complementary and
predetermine each other in terms of design, pattern of
collaboration and functionality.
Digital platforms, while coordinating broad
groups of networked actors that interact in different
functional combinations (consumers-consumers,
consumers-producers, producers-producers), can be
easily seen as universal tools to generate various
kinds of ecosystems at various levels of social and
economic activity. Platform-generated or platform-
enhanced ecosystems have their own platforms
tailored either to co-usage or to co-production of
innovations, or both. Regional clusters of triple-helix
design can form advanced and convenient
ecosystems to co-create innovations continuously,
allowing clusters to serve as multi-faceted tools for
upgrading industrial structures of modern economies.
Meanwhile, collaboration between clusters of
different geographical locations leads to the
evolvement of GVCs and global production networks
that can shape more powerful ecosystems, able to co-
create innovations continuously across the world.
Collaborative networks and hence innovation
ecosystems may evolve and proliferate in the future
across all sectors and levels of modern economies, be
they region-wide, country-wide, or global-wide.
Plainly speaking, networks and their ecosystems
shape the modern mode of production, making
economies both more cohesive to meet the challenges
of high uncertainty, and more innovative to become
globally competitive and self-sustainable. Overall,
innovation ecosystems concern the social,
organizational and cultural shifts that facilitate the
formation of the knowledge-based economy.
Social and economic ecosystems are surely not
the same as natural ones. But both types are
populations able to self-organize and self-develop in
a similar, agile manner of complex adaptive systems,
associated with inter-relationship of elements, as well
as with the ability to adapt in and evolve with a
changing environment [66], with mutual respect. In
particular, the ecosystems can obtain new sources for
growth and achieve dynamic sustainability through
internal, self-correcting structural changes rather
than through top-down intervention of any
centralized bodies, or from an external intervention,
as typical for traditional systems.
All this supports the rationale for using the term
‘ecosystem’ far beyond a mere metaphor to systems,
to highlight both the network-based organizational
design and the collaborative organizational culture
of the emerging innovation-led economies. Because
of its relevance for the contemporary reality, it is no
surprise that this term is widely popular in
management studies and economics communities, as
shown in our literature review.
Nevertheless, returning to publications that argue
in favor of the classical term 'innovation systems', we
admit that this option may still be regarded as a
problem of academic taste in introducing
contemporary realities. Some researchers may find it
convenient to consider ecosystems as a new
generation of systems and may respond by describing
their growing complexity and ever changing features
in the era of non-linear innovation. Others may prefer
to call them ecosystems from the outset and underline
the key role of collaborative interactions and value
co-creation, including the historically new enabling
role of government interventions.
In our view, the idea of ecosystems provides a
much better image for effective policymaking across
countries. It offers instructive insights on the framing
and implementation of further research on
innovation. Additionally, it acquires an especially
important practical notion for the post-Soviet and
other transition economies (in contrast to the situation
in US and other technologically advanced nations), in
which innovation systems are often perceived as
special infrastructure projects realized by
governments, and not as the result of networking and
collaborative dialogue developed across the society.
5252
5. References
[1] World Economic Forum, The Global Competitiveness
Report 20152016, World Economic Forum, Geneva,
2015.
[2] Lundvall, B.-Å., ed., National Systems of Innovation:
Toward a Theory of Innovation and Interactive
Learning, Pinter, London, 1992.
[3] Nelson, R.R., ed., National Innovation Systems: A
Comparative Analysis, Oxford University Press, New
York, NY, 1993.
[4] Edquist, C., ed., Systems of Innovation: Technologies,
Institutions and Organizations, Pinter, London, 1997.
[5] Braczyk, H.-J., P. Cooke, and M. Heidenreich, eds.,
Regional Innovation Systems: The Role of
Governances in a Globalized World, UCL Press,
London, 1998.
[6] Malerba, F., ed., Sectoral Systems of Innovation:
Concepts, Issues and Analyses of Six Major Sectors in
Europe, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2004.
[7] Bramwell, A., N. Hepburn, and D.A. Wolfe, Growing
Innovation Ecosystems: University-Industry
Knowledge Transfer and Regional Economic
Development in Canada. Final Report to the Social
Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada,
2012.
[8] Townsend, A., A.S.-K. Pang, and R. Weddle, Future
Knowledge Ecosystems: The Next Twenty Years of
Technology-Led Economic Development, IFTF
Reports(SR-1236), 2009.
[9] Council on Competitiveness, Innovate America:
Thriving in a World of Challenge and Change, Council
on Competitiveness, Washington, DC, 2005.
[10] Oh, D.-S., F. Phillips, S. Park, and E. Lee,Innovation
Ecosystems: A Critical Examination, Technovation,
2016.
[11] Peltoniemi, M., Business Ecosystem: A Conceptual
Model of an Organisation Population from the
Perspectives of Complexity and Evolution, Tampere
University of Technology, Tampere, 2005.
[12] Peltoniemi, M., Preliminary Theoretical Framework
for the Study of Business Ecosystems, Emergence:
Complexity and Organization, 8(1), 2006, pp. 1019.
[13] Manikas, K. and K.M. Hansen, Software ecosystems
A systematic literature review, Journal of Systems
and Software, 86(5), 2013, pp. 12941306.
[14] Pilinkienė, V. and P. Mačiulis, Comparison of
Different Ecosystem Analogies: The Main Economic
Determinants and Levels of Impact, Procedia - Social
and Behavioral Sciences, 156, 2014, pp. 365370.
[15] Gawer, A., Platform Dynamics and Strategies: From
Products to Services, in Platforms, Markets and
Innovation, A. Gawer, Editor. 2009. Edward Elgar:
Cheltenham.
[16] Gawer, A. and M.A. Cusumano, Industry Platforms
and Ecosystem Innovation, Journal of Product
Innovation Management, 31(3), 2014, pp. 417433.
[17] Thomas, L.D.W., E. Autio, and D.M. Gann,
Architectural Leverage: Putting Platforms in
Context, Academy of Management Perspectives,
28(2), 2014, pp. 198219.
[18] Kortelainen, S. and K. Järvi, Ecosystems: Systematic
Literature Review and Framework Development. XXV
ISPIM Innovation Conference. Dublin, Ireland, 9-11
June 2014.
[19] Valkokari, K., Business, Innovation, and Knowledge
Ecosystems: How They Differ and How to Survive
and Thrive within Them, Technology Innovation
Management Review, 5(8), 2015.
[20] Suominen, A., M. Seppänen, and O. Dedehayir,
Innovation Systems and Ecosystems: A Review and
Synthesis. XXVII ISPIM Innovation Conference.
Porto, Portugal, 19-22 June 2016.
[21] Aarikka-Stenroos, L., T. Peltola, A. Rikkiev, and U.
Saari, Multiple Facets of Innovation and Business
Ecosystem Research: The Foci, Methods and Future
Agenda. XXVII ISPIM Innovation Conference. Porto,
Portugal, 19-22 June 2016.
[22] Russell, M.G., J. Huhtamäki, K. Still, N. Rubens, and
R.C. Basole, Relational Capital for Shared Vision in
Innovation Ecosystems, Triple Helix, 2(1), 2015,
p. 1-36.
[23] Wessner, C.W., Entrepreneurship and the Innovation
Ecosystem Policy Lessons from the United States, in
Local Heroes in the Global Village: Globalization and
the New Entrepreneurship Policies, D.B. Audretsch,
H. Grimm, and C.W. Wessner, Editors. 2005.
Springer: New York, NY.
[24] European Commission, Digital Business Ecosystems,
Office for Official Publications of the European
Communities, Luxembourg, 2007.
[25] Ranjan, K.R. and S. Read, Value Co-creation:
Concept and Measurement, Journal of the Academy
of Marketing Science, 44(3), 2016, pp. 290315.
[26] Roser, T., A. Samson, P. Humphreys, and E. Cruz-
Valdivieso, Co-creation: New pathways to Value, LSE
Enterprise Promise Corporation, London, 2009.
[27] MacGregor, S.P. and T. Carleton, eds., Sustaining
Innovation: Collaboration Models for a Complex
World, Springer, New York, NY, 2012.
[28] Camarinha-Matos, L.M. and H. Afsarmanesh,
Concept of Collaboration, in Encyclopedia of
Networked and Virtual Organizations, G.D. Putnik and
M.M. Cruz-Cunha, Editors. 2008. IGI Global:
Hershey, PA.
[29] Drucker, P.F., Post-Capitalist Society, Butterworth-
Heinemann, Oxford, 1993.
[30] Gloor, P.A., Swarm Creativity: Competitive
Advantage Through Collaborative Innovation
Networks, Oxford University Press, New York, NY,
2006.
[31] Camarinha-Matos, L.M. and H. Afsarmanesh, Classes
of Collaborative Networks, in Encyclopedia of
Networked and Virtual Organizations, G.D. Putnik and
M.M. Cruz-Cunha, Editors. 2008. IGI Global:
Hershey, PA.
[32] Nieto, M.J. and L. Santamaría, The Importance of
Diverse Collaborative Networks for the Novelty of
Product Innovation, Technovation, 27(6-7), 2007,
pp. 367377.
[33] Russell, M.G., K. Still, J. Huhtamäki, C. Yu, and N.
Rubens, Transforming Innovation Ecosystems through
5253
Shared Vision and Network Orchestration. Triple
Helix IX International Conference. Stanford, CA,
USA, 1114 July 2011.
[34] Jucevičius, G. and K. Grumadaitė, Smart
Development of Innovation Ecosystem, Procedia
Social and Behavioral Sciences, 156, 2014, pp. 125
129.
[35] Martin, R. and P. Sunley, Complexity thinking and
evolutionary economic geography, Journal of
Economic Geography, 7(5), 2007, pp. 573601.
[36] Martin, R. and P. Sunley, Conceptualizing Cluster
Evolution: Beyond the Life Cycle Model?, Regional
Studies, 45(10), 2011, pp. 12991318.
[37] Porter, M.E. and C.H.M. Ketels, Clusters and
Industrial Districts: Common Roots, Different
Perspectives, in A Handbook of Industrial Districts,
G. Becattini, M. Bellandi, and L. De Propis, Editors.
2009. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.
[38] van Winden, W., L. van den Berg, L. Carvalho, and E.
van Tuijl, Manufacturing in the New Urban Economy,
Routledge, Abingdon, 2011.
[39] Etzkowitz, H. and L. Leydesdorff, The Dynamics of
Innovation: From National Systems and “Mode 2” to a
Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government
Relations, Research Policy, 29(2), 2000, pp. 109123.
[40] Porter, M.E., The Competitive Advantage of Nations,
Free Press, New York, NY, 1990.
[41] Delgado, M., M.E. Porter, and S. Stern, Clusters,
Convergence, and Economic Performance, Research
Policy, 43(10), 2014, pp. 17851799.
[42] Ffowcs-Williams, I., Cluster Development The Go-
To Handbook: Building Competitiveness through
Smart Specialisation, Cluster Navigators, Nelson,
2012.
[43] Lindqvist, G., C.H.M. Ketels, and Ö. Sölvell, The
Cluster Initiative Greenbook 2.0, Ivory Tower,
Stockholm, 2013.
[44] Napier, G. and S. Kethelz, The Welfare Technological
Ecosystem in the Region of Southern Denmark, REG
X The Danish Cluster Academy, Copenhagen, 2014.
[45] Sölvell, Ö., Clusters Balancing Evolutionary and
Constructive Forces, 2nd edn., Ivory Tower,
Stockholm, 2009.
[46] Huhtamäki, J., M.G. Russell, K. Still, and N. Rubens,
A Network-Centric Snapshot of Value Co-Creation in
Finnish Innovation Financing, Open Source Business
Resource, March 2011.
[47] Sölvell, Ö., The Multi-Home-Based Corporation:
Solving an Insider-Outsider Dilemma, in Innovation
and Institutional Embeddedness of Multinational
Companies, M. Heidenreich, Editor. 2012. Edward
Elgar: Cheltenham.
[48] Tiwana, A., B. Konsynski, and A.A. Bush, Research
Commentary Platform Evolution: Coevolution of
Platform Architecture, Governance, and
Environmental Dynamics, Information Systems
Research, 21(4), 2010, pp. 675687.
[49] Evans, D.S., Platform Economics: Essays on Multi-
Sided Businesses, Competition Policy International,
London, 2011.
[50] Parker, G.G., M.W. van Alstyne, and S.P. Choudary,
Platform Revolution: How Networked Markets Are
Transforming the Economy And How to Make Them
Work for You, W.W. Norton & Co., New York, NY,
2016.
[51] Gawer, A., Bridging Differing Perspectives on
Technological Platforms: Toward an Integrative
Framework, Research Policy, 43(7), 2014, pp. 1239
1249.
[52] Sölvell, Ö., G. Lindqvist, and C.H.M. Ketels, The
Cluster Initiative Greenbook, Ivory Tower, Stockholm,
2003.
[53] Ketels, C.H.M., Clusters, Cluster Policy, and Swedish
Competitiveness in the Global Economy, Expert
Reports to Swedens Globalisation Council (30), 2009.
[54] Basole, R.C. and J. Karla, On the Evolution of Mobile
Platform Ecosystem Structure and Strategy, Business
& Information Systems Engineering, 3(5), 2011,
pp. 313322.
[55] McKinsey Global Institute, Digital America: A Tale of
the Haves and Have-Mores, McKinsey & Company,
New York, NY, 2015.
[56] Gawer, A., The Organization of Technological
Platforms, in Technology and Organization: Essays in
Honour of Joan Woodward, N. Phillips, G. Sewell, and
D. Griffiths, Editors. 2010. Emerald Group Publishing.
[57] Ivanova, I.A. and L. Leydesdorff, Rotational
Symmetry and the Transformation of Innovation
Systems in a Triple Helix of UniversityIndustry
Government Relations, Technological Forecasting
and Social Change, 86, 2014, pp. 143156.
[58] Powell, W.W. and S. Grodal, Networks of
Innovators, in The Oxford Handbook of Innovation,
J. Fagerberg, D.C. Mowery, and R.R. Nelson, Editors.
2005. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
[59] Williamson, O.E., The Economics of Governance,
American Economic Review, 95(2), 2005, pp. 1–18.
[60] Smith-Doerr, L. and W.W. Powell, Networks and
Economic Life, in The Handbook of Economic
Sociology, N.J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, Editors.
2005. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.
[61] Acemoglu, D. and J.A. Robinson, Why Nations Fail:
The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, Profile
Books, London, 2012.
[62] Ostrom, E., Governing the Commons: The Evolution
of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, 1990.
[63] Ansell, C.K. and A. Gash, Collaborative Governance
in Theory and Practice, Journal of Public
Administration Research and Theory, 18(4), 2007,
pp. 543571.
[64] European Commission, Smart Guide to Cluster Policy,
European Commission, Brussels, 2016.
[65] Warwick, K., Beyond Industrial Policy: Emerging
Issues and New Trends, OECD Science, Technology
and Industry Policy Papers (2), 2013.
[66] Chan, S., Complex Adaptive Systems. ESD.83
Research Seminar in Engineering Systems. 31 October
/ 6 November, 2001.
5254
... In the light of the pragmatic views of the recent researchers (Guijarro-Garc ıa et al., 2019; Guimarães et al., 2023;Gutmann et al., 2020;Smorodinskaya et al., 2017;Yablonsky, 2018), startup projects can be defined as a brief idea with a scalable future to disrupt the future market. Shedding light on the ontological and epistemological paradigms of startup projects in comparison to regular business models, startup projects are generated, nurtured and grown with certain basic characteristics (Adner and Kapoor, 2010;Pellinen et al., 2012;Ritala et al., 2013). ...
... Recent researchers on entrepreneurial and digital ecosystems are very keen to analyze formation, execution and success of different startup projects, for instance, Google, Uber, different social media platforms, etc. (Cheah et al., 2016;Morgan-Thomas et al., 2020;Purbasari et al., 2021;Ritala et al., 2013;Song, 2019). However, for the sustainability of ecosystem startup projects, it is essential to address, explore and understand structural dynamics, stakeholders and their association in the supply chain (Longva, 2021;Oppong et al., 2020;Ritala et al., 2013;Smorodinskaya et al., 2017;Yablonsky, 2018). However, this essential issue is not extensively explored by the researchers (Dutta and Hora, 2017;Gutmann et al., 2020;Schwartz, 2013;Wagner, 2021). ...
... To establish an entrepreneurial ecosystem, stakeholders of the supply chain of any startup projects have an enormous potential role to play (Guijarro-Garc ıa et al., 2019; Gutmann et al., 2020). Different stakeholders, who must participate to establish a balanced ecosystem for startups, are mutually responsible to form and direct a RSC to minimize all sorts of risks and to withstand possible disruptions (Smorodinskaya et al., 2017;Wagner, 2021;Yablonsky, 2018). Shedding light on the principle of rules of the game (North, 1991;Trussler, 1998), it is quite evident that in an uncertain environment where an entrepreneurial ecosystem of startup projects develops, based on the complex characteristics of the organizations, players, i.e. stakeholders, will be selected to advance the institution. ...
Article
Purpose This study has conducted exploratory research to understand who should comprise the members of a resilient supply chain for promoting an entrepreneurial ecosystem of a startup project and to determine the mechanisms for the balanced coexistence of all stakeholders. This is necessary to ensure mutual benefits for all stakeholders, each of whom has multidimensional interests. Additionally, this supply chain must be able to withstand any potential disruption risks. Design/methodology/approach This research has employed a mixed-design approach. In this context, the study conducted an extensive qualitative and quantitative investigation, including 30 interviews and a survey involving 180 potential stakeholders in this supply network, respectively in the capital city of Bangladesh, Dhaka. The analysis of the interviews utilized principles of matrix thinking, while structural equation modeling (SEM) through LISREL was employed to understand cause-and-effect relationships. Findings Network, platform and governance—these three independent constructs have the potential to contribute to the dependent construct, a resilient supply chain, aimed at promoting an entrepreneurial ecosystem for startup projects. It has been revealed that the management of such projects depends on the rules and regulations within the ecosystem. An excellent governance mechanism is essential for this purpose. To facilitate coexistence, the establishment of a platform is crucial, where cooperation among all members is mandatory. Practical implications For practitioners, three distinctive but closely interdependent issues are explored and resolved in this philanthropic study. It has unfolded the elements of any startup project with essential settings. Originality/value The identification of the structural dynamics of potential stakeholders within the entrepreneurial ecosystem of startups is largely absent in existing literature. Therefore, there is a need to comprehensively investigate the entire network, including their roles, responsibilities and associations. This study makes a significant and novel contribution to the existing literature. Academics and practitioners alike have ample opportunities to learn from this new aspect of relationships across three distinct areas: the entrepreneurial ecosystem, startup projects and the development of a resilient supply chain.
... La innovación desde una perspectiva sistémica, ha abarcado el término de sistemas para comprender las relaciones de diferentes actores que interactúan en los procesos de innovación. Sin embargo, este concepto puede quedase corto para identificar estrategias exitosas de política pública local, cultural, entornos naturales y conocimientos tácitos que conduzcan hacia la innovación situada, más allá de sus propias fronteras (Smorodinskaya et al., 2017) , además de comprender el rol de la colaboración y la co-creación de valor. En este sentido, el término de ecosistema de innovación combina perspectivas de la innovación abierta, el crowdsourcing, digitalización, roles diferenciales o nichos, la gestión estratégica, la co-evolución, la El término ecosistema tiene su origen en la ciencia de la ecología. ...
... De este modo, el trabajo de Adner y Kapoor (2010) , es una transición entre el constructo ecosistemas de negocios y el de ecosistemas de innovación. Así, el constructo de ecosistemas de innovación se ha posicionado en la literatura de manera cada vez más amplia, donde la discusión en la co-creación de valor es central, más allá de su captura (Smorodinskaya et al., 2017;Gomes et al., 2018) . ...
Article
Full-text available
Resumen La colaboración a nivel conceptual y metodológico se ha incorporado en una narrativa académica, laboral y profesional. En especial, en la literatura de los estudios de innovación, la colaboración y la co-creación han sido de mucho interés a nivel de gestión, redes y de experiencias. No obstante, existe aún una brecha en términos teóricos y analíticos para comprender este proceso. El objetivo del presente texto es proveer un análisis teórico de la colaboración y en particular, sugerir el marco de los ecosistemas de innovación de base comunitaria como un escenario de co-producción socio-técnica. De este modo, se problematiza esta dinámica de interacción e interdependencia entre organizaciones, lo cual, es base para analizar los sistemas y ecosistemas de innovación a través de la perspectiva relacional. Se presenta un modelo de ecosistema colaborativo de innovación se destacan las cinco dimensiones base de este fenómeno. Finalmente, se presentan las consideraciones finales, centradas en sus principales elementos alrededor de la teoría de la
... At the same time, the reach goes beyond single projects, formal relations and industry boundaries (Ketonen-Oksi & Valkokari, 2019). Consequently, the innovation ecosystem perspective promotes co-creation and enables value to be created beyond what a single firm could achieve on its own (Smorodinskaya et al., 2017). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
Circularity has become a central approach to making the infrastructure sector more future proof. As such, circularity is positioned as a transformative mission. However, the socio-technical transition required to achieve this mission is steeped in complexity, uncertainty, and contestation, making its governance a tricky exercise. This PhD dissertation delves into the systemic barriers to the mission-oriented transition and offers various ways to deal with those on a sectoral, organizational, and inter-organizational level. By doing so, this dissertation aims to equip scholars and practitioners with the tools to effectively steer and support the transition towards a circular infrastructure sector. The first study identifies three causal cycles that act as systemic barriers to the transition: one regarding the contestation of the circularity concept, one regarding learning and upscaling, and a final cycle on rigid procurement approaches that hamper radical innovations. The first cycle, regarding the contestation of circularity, is examined in more detail in the second study as it forms the most deeply-rooted barrier. The third study presents a governance approach to steer mission-oriented transitions, acknowledging their inherently complex, uncertain, and contested nature. How organizations deal with the external pressures caused by the circularity mission is investigated in the fourth study within the Dutch infrastructure system. Finally, the fifth study explores how the innovation ecosystem approach can help the circularity transition by introducing long-term oriented forms of collaboration to support innovation beyond single infrastructure projects. The dissertation concludes with a discussion of the implications for both practice and theory, extending beyond the individual studies to offer actionable perspectives for various domains and actor types in academia and practice.
... There is no "one-size-fits-all" definition of an innovation ecosystem in the mainstream literature. Generally, the innovation ecosystem is described as the co-creation of value (Gomes et al., 2018;Smorodinskaya et al., 2017). The main difference between a business ecosystem and an innovation ecosystem is mainly linked to the ecological aspect of the innovation ecosystem that encompasses the collaborative effort of actors towards co-creation along with the dimension of sustainability development (Cai, 2017). ...
Chapter
The innovation ecosystem in higher education has attracted much public and scholarly attention. In this sense, universities are now demanded to be part of the innovation ecosystems as they commercialize their outcomes of research, create knowledge-based enterprises, and converge with the captains of industry and commerce. Unfortunately, the innovation ecosystem in higher education towards sustainable development in Africa is under-researched. Hence, this chapter aims to establish the benefits of innovation ecosystems in higher education towards sustainable development focused on Africa. The results from the thematic analysis showed various benefits of innovation ecosystems in higher education towards sustainable development in general and more specifically for Africa, namely encouraging interdisciplinary collaboration, enhancing research and development, producing enterprising graduates, inculcating entrepreneurial culture, promoting economic growth, and enhancing the reputation of the institution.
... Conforme Schumpeter (1934), a inovação é toda mudança que introduz novas formas de pensar, agir e produzir; é a aplicação de tecnologia, processos e conhecimentos para desenvolver soluções criativas e eficazes para os problemas atuais. Nesse contexto, surge o ecossistema de inovação, que conecta pessoas, empresas e governos de diferentes setores e cria um ambiente propício para o desenvolvimento de novas soluções (DODDS, 2008;SMORODINSKAYA, 2017, FENG et al., 2020. ...
Article
Full-text available
Este artigo aborda a extensão universitária e sua significativa contribuição para promover a inovação social no terceiro setor, que consiste em um conjunto de recursos naturais e capacidades humanas voltadas para solucionar questões sociais prementes. As instituições de ensino superior desempenham um papel estratégico na transformação dos Ecossistemas de Inovação Social, ao investigar minuciosamente os fatores que impactam seu desenvolvimento. Destaca-se a importância da extensão universitária como um veículo crucial para a interação e compartilhamento de conhecimento entre a comunidade acadêmica e a sociedade em geral. Este trabalho tem como objetivo principal apresentar as iniciativas de extensão realizadas por estudantes e professores em colaboração com organizações do terceiro setor. O enfoque principal dessas iniciativas é melhorar a aprendizagem significativa e a formação acadêmica dos estudantes. Os resultados das ações de extensão destacam não apenas o impacto positivo dessas iniciativas na sociedade, mas também ressaltam a necessidade de uma abordagem cuidadosa e responsável em sua execução. Essas ações de extensão têm o potencial de enriquecer a formação dos estudantes, tornando-a mais alinhada com a realidade em que a universidade está inserida. Além disso, elas promovem um olhar mais atento e uma responsabilidade social corporativa nas organizações do terceiro setor, que também se beneficiam dessas iniciativas de extensão.
... In addition to direct support measures, government involvement can influence firm competitiveness by fostering a conducive innovation ecosystem (Smorodinskaya et al., 2017). This includes investing in public R&D infrastructure, promoting industry-academia collaboration, and facilitating access to knowledge and resources (Lundvall, 1992;Zhou and Wang, 2023). ...
Article
Full-text available
This study delves into the dynamics of green product innovation, artificial intelligence (AI) adaption, and intellectual capital, investigating their impact on the competitiveness of firms in Oman. It emphasizes the crucial role of government intervention and R&D investments in this process. Based on the responses of 214 top managers in Oman, the research employs structural equation modeling to analyze the intricate relationships between these factors. The findings underscore a significant positive correlation between green innovation, AI implementation, and intellectual capital, with government involvement and R&D investments as vital moderators. This study provides a novel perspective on the synergy of technology, innovation, and intellectual capital in developing economies. It offers essential insights for business leaders, policymakers, and scholars, highlighting the necessity of integrating advanced technologies and sustainable practices in business strategies to achieve competitive advantage. The research adds to the existing body of knowledge on innovation and competitiveness. It offers practical implications for enhancing firm performance in Oman and similar emerging markets.
Article
Full-text available
Continuous technological development, digitalization, Industry 4.0, robotization, virtualization, and related investments in new types of physical assets are imposing increasing financial and intellectual demands on micro, small, and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs). While fast technological development and rapid societal change make maintenance of a successful competitive edge ever more challenging, they also offer considerable potential for differentiation. In the area of networking and outside resources, MSMEs can utilize external resources and cooperate and collaborate with higher educational institutions (HEI) to boost their innovations pipeline and develop new technologies and processes to generate commercial products/services and improve their service offering. This research explores existing highly effective university–industry collaboration (UIC) models and seeks explanations for their success by examining the literature from the point of view of establishing successful relationships, emphasizing the importance of critical drivers for success. Our work synthesizes current knowledge of best practices based on a comparative analysis of practical collaboration. In the work, we identify eight popular and successful collaboration models: research and development partnerships, internships and co-op programs, knowledge transfer programs, entrepreneurship, and incubation programs, sponsored projects and grants, joint ventures and licensing agreements, executive education, professional and student career development. Based on analysis of globally reviewed successful models, a concept for robust, productive, and extended collaboration between companies and universities is produced suitable for the Finnish context. Several practical experiences are given for robust collaboration in the current post-COVID transition and energy crisis.
Chapter
The emergence of digital multi-sided platforms has disrupted day-to-day business in many industries. Nowadays, many small businesses participate in digital platform (DP) ecosystems and act as value creators or complementors. Investigating the small business perspective does not have a rich tradition in platform research yet. In response, this paper presents a systematic literature review (SLR) analyzing the thematic points of focus and highlighting new avenues for information systems and small business research. We find that objectives related to digital transformation, digital strategy- and business model-development, and DP adoption are fundamental topics in the conjunction of small business and DP ecosystems. Based on the findings, an agenda for future research is developed, including propositions for practice-oriented and human-centered approaches fostering sustilience, innovation capabilities and digital leadership competencies in small businesses facing DP ecosystem participation.
Article
Full-text available
In management studies, the ecosystem metaphor is often utilized without clear definition and, thereby, several partially overlapping concepts such as industrial, business, service, innovation, and knowledge ecosystems have been introduced. The purpose of this conceptual article is to go beyond the confusion to define what is meant by different concepts regarding an ecosystem and especially describe the relationships between the three different ecosystem types: business, innovation, and knowledge ecosystems. The article contributes to the literature by describing how the ecosystem types differ in terms of their outcomes, interactions, logic of action, and actor roles. The results show that the three ecosystem types are interconnected from the viewpoint of the ecosystem actor. For practitioners, the article sheds more light on how the rules of the game (i.e., the logic of action) differ in the different types of ecosystems and demonstrates that different models are needed in order to operate in different ecosystems. Link. http://timreview.ca/article/919
Chapter
Full-text available
A collaborative network (CN) is an alliance constituted by a variety of entities (e.g., organizations and people) that are largely autonomous, geographically distributed, and heterogeneous in terms of their operating environment, culture, social capital, and goals but that collaborate to better achieve common or compatible goals, and whose interactions are supported by computer network. Some authors see the roots of this paradigm in early works of economists like Oliver Williamson in the 1970s. Along his vast work, Williamson established the study of transaction cost economics (Williamson, 1975) and defended that manufacturing firms should make much greater use of externally purchased goods and services, rather than those internally supplied. These ideas had a more evident impact with the booming of the “outsourcing” wave in the 1980s. Outsourcing became very attractive when managers had to reduce the organization overheads and eliminate the internal inefficient services, the so called lean organization, as it transfers the problem to the outside, namely to other efficient service providers. In this line of developments, the idea of virtual enterprise/virtual organization was not “invented” by a single researcher but rather it is a concept that has matured through a long evolution process. Some of the early references first introducing the terms like virtual company, virtual enterprise, or virtual corporation go back to the early 1990s, including the work of Jan Hopland, Nagel and Dove, and Davidow and Malone (Davidow & Malone, 1992; Introna, More, & Cushman, 1999; Walton & Whicker, 1996). Since then, a large but disjoint body of literature has been produced mainly in two communities: the information and communications technology (ICT) community and the management community.
Article
Full-text available
The chapter outlines key elements of the cluster framework and contrasts it with the framework of industrial districts. It argues that industrial districts describe a specific type of cluster, and focus more on the socio-economic aspects of agglomeration and networks than the cluster research.
Book
In many ways, the process of innovation is a constant social dance, where the best dancers thrive by adapting new steps with multiple partners. The systematic and continuous generation of value in any innovation system relies on collaboration between different groups, who must overcome multiple, often competing agendas and needs to work together fruitfully over the long term. Featuring contributions from leading researchers, business leaders, and policymakers representing North America, Europe, India, Africa, and Australasia, this volume investigates different combinations of collaborative arrangements among innovation actors, many of which are changing conventional expectations of institutional relationships. Collectively, the authors demonstrate that no particular combination has emerged as the most dominant, or even resilient, model of innovation. Several authors expand on our understanding of the triple helix model, with both academics and practitioners looking to the quadruple helix (encompassing business, academic, government, and civil society) as the new standard. Other authors address aspects of open innovation, co-creation, and user-centered design—all testaments to the rapidly shifting landscape. At the same time, many businesses, academics, and governments, not to mention non-profit organizations, foundations, and society at large, are active in conversations about how to pursue a more sustainable model of innovation. The pursuit of this holy grail of innovation is both facilitated and complicated by an ever-accelerating technological environment in which social networking and mobile tools are emerging as new dance arenas.
Technical Report
The objective of this study is to construct a conceptual model of the behaviour and development of an organisation population of which knowledge-intensive service firms form an important part. Attention is directed towards the assumptions, on which the behaviour of organisations and populations that constitute of them is based. In addition, the importance and value of knowledge in business, and especially in knowledge-intensive service organisations, is taken into account. This research is conducted in an explorative manner as a literature review and conceptual analysis. The material for this study - books, journal articles and conference papers - has been gathered through library databases and by attending some international conferences. The research problem “How can the behaviour and development of an organisation population, of which knowledge intensive service firms form a part, be modelled at the conceptual level?” has been approached in an interdisciplinary way from the fields of complexity, evolutionary economics and business ecosystem. In addition, some assumptions of neoclassical economics, and their implications to the modelling problem at hand, are reviewed. The conceptual model constructed in this research emphasises the dynamics that follow on the one hand from conscious choice and limited knowledge of an individual organisation and on the other hand from the interconnectedness and feedback loops of an organisation population. Conscious choice is an important observation since it differentiates economic evolution from biological evolution. Limited and local knowledge is assumed since no organisation can be perfectly aware of the present state, not to mention the future. This leads to profit motivated striving and not to optimisation as neoclassical economics would suggest. An organisation population is interconnected through competition and cooperation that can be present simultaneously. This results in feedback loops that carry triggers that can induce change in the behaviour of the organisations. Thus, a change in the behaviour of an organisation can induce another organisation to change its behaviour which in turn will encourage the initial organisation to change its behaviour again. These triggers consist essentially of knowledge. Conscious choice, limited knowledge, interconnectedness and feedback loops result in a nondeterministic, nonlinear and unpredictable future constructed by the organisations.
Book
Innovation and technological change follow markedly different pathways depending on the sector in which they take place. Contributions from eighteen experts in their fields consider the framework of sectoral systems of innovation to analyze the innovation process, factors affecting innovation, the relationship between innovation and industry dynamics, changing boundaries and transformation of sectors, and the determinants of the innovation performance of firms and countries in different sectors. © Cambridge University Press, 2004 and Cambridge University Press, 2009.