ChapterPDF Available

Microfinance and Financial Inclusion

Authors:

Abstract

Microfinance is currently considered one of the most important tools for international development and poverty alleviation. Despite numerous empirical inquiries, however, the actual effects of microfinance on economic and gender variables relative to poverty remain unclear, and a number of critiques have challenged the efficacy of microfinance at promoting women's empowerment and alleviating poverty. Moreover, since the 1970s, microfinance has grown and transformed into a largely commercial financial sector that connects capital investors with poor borrowers at a significant scale. Nonetheless, through its business success, microfinance has also engendered a series of overindebtedness crises, most notably the one in India in 2010. These crises, as well as the strong critiques levied against microfinance, have prompted the sector to search for new methods and a new mission as well as new markets to conquer. // RECOMMENDED CITATION: Mader, Philip (2016). ‘Microfinance and Financial Inclusion’. In: Brady, David/Linda M. Burton (eds.): The Oxford Handbook of the Social Science of Poverty. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Pp. 843-865
1
Microfinance and Financial Inclusion
Philip Mader*
(Forthcoming Chapter 37 in Brady, David and Linda Burton (eds.): The Oxford
Handbook on the Social Science of Poverty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.)
Abstract
Microfinance is currently considered one of the most important tools for international
development and poverty alleviation. Despite numerous empirical inquiries, however, the actual
effects of microfinance on economic and gender variables relative to poverty remain unclear, and
a number of critiques have challenged the efficacy of microfinance at promoting women’s
empowerment and alleviating poverty. Moreover, since the 1970s, microfinance has grown and
transformed into a largely commercial financial sector that connects capital investors with poor
borrowers at a significant scale. Nonetheless, through its business success, microfinance has also
engendered a series of overindebtedness crises, most notably the one in India in 2010. These crises,
as well as the strong critiques levied against microfinance, have prompted the sector to search for
new methods and a new mission as well as new markets to conquer.

* Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom.
Pre-edited version.
2
Introduction
[E]ven though she worked hard to grow her tiny businesses, Rukia was never able to put aside
any savings and her dreams remained out of reach. Then, Rukia applied for and received a
microloan. . . . Gradually her profits have increased and she has since been able to move her
business to a permanent stall on the busy main street outside the market where she attracts even
more customers. Thanks to her perseverance and [the microfinance organisation’s] loans,
Rukia’s goal of constructing a house is finally within grasp. “We’ve already made the
foundation and purchased some of the bricks,” Rukia states proudly.1
Countless success stories like this one are told about microfinance. Summarily, they form
a globally recognized narrative about the power of financial services to transform lives in
positive ways. Microfinance refers to the provision of financial services to poor and low-
income populations, usually in the global South. Microfinance appears as a financial
market solution to the social problem of poverty, promising poverty alleviation in a market-
friendly and cost-efficient way, and is regarded by many today as a key tool in the portfolio
of international development policies. Proponents hope that the financial inclusion of poor
and low-income population segments will help them cope better with multifaceted
problems of poverty, in particular their uncertain and low incomes.
The activities of the global microfinance sector today directly impact nearly 200 million
clients worldwide. Total loans in 2012 amounted to $100.7 billion, equal to roughly two-
thirds of global aid, a part of which went to funding microfinance projects.2 However, for
a poverty-alleviation tool of its extraordinary scope and reputation, there is remarkably
little consensus about its practical impacts. As a systematic review assessing the entire
domain of microfinance-impact studies concluded, until today “it remains unclear under
what circumstances, and for whom, microfinance has been and could be of real, rather than
imagined, benefit to poor people” (Duvendack et al. 2011:75). This chapter therefore offers
a concise examination of the microfinance sector and its practices, explaining its historical
origins and rise, discussing and interpreting the results of impact studies, relating the
critical debates waged over microfinance, and taking stock of three sets of recent
developments: a spate of crises, a new mission, and a growing scope of activity.
3
Overview of Microfinance
Under the heading “What Is Microfinance?” the World Bank’s in-house microfinance
agency Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP) explains:
“Microfinance” is often defined as financial services for poor and low-income clients offered by
different types of service providers. In practice, the term is often used more narrowly to refer to
loans and other services from providers that identify themselves as “microfinance institutions”
(MFIs). . . . More broadly, microfinance refers to a movement that envisions a world in which
low-income households have permanent access to a range of high quality and affordable financial
services offered by a range of retail providers to finance income-producing activities, build
assets, stabilize consumption, and protect against risks. These services include savings, credit,
insurance, remittances, and payments, and others. (CGAP 2012; emphasis added)
While merely one possible description, it comes from a key organization linked to the
World Bank, which aspires to represent the “consensus” in the microfinance field and
reveals several things. First, microfinance can be understood as services for certain
populations and services from certain providers. Second, it is neither so clear-cut who the
clients are—poor or “low income”—nor exactly who the providers are.3 Third, the focus
is on lending, although other services also matter. Fourth, the vision behind microfinance
has been adopted by a broader social movement dedicated to promoting it.
The microfinance sector is an amorphous field, constituted by a diverse set of actors at the
intersection of the state with the market and civic society. They include the following:
Microfinance institutions (MFIs), directly working with the clients; some are NGOs
or cooperatives, others are strictly for-profit banks, many are in-between.
International financial institutions (such as the World Bank or Asian Development
Bank); they are funders, standardizers, and political promoters of MFIs.
Governmental development agencies and multilateral development bodies (like
USAID or the International Fund for Agricultural Development) that fund and
promote MFIs;
Foundations and philanthropic organizations (such the Gates Foundation or Oxfam)
that fund and operate MFIs.
4
Specialized for-profit microfinance investment vehicles (MIVs) and investment
funds, which are often linked to major banks.
Transnational private funding and advocacy organizations (such as Accion,
Oikocredit, or Kiva).
Private, wealthy individuals funding and publicly promoting microfinance.
A broader social movement, including small-scale middle-class investors and active
enthusiasts.
The sector rose to global recognition with small loans for entrepreneurship—
microcredit—but since at least the mid-2000s the term microfinance has dominated. This
rephrasing denotes more than a mere semantic change since microfinance also
encompasses savings, insurance, and money transfers. At the same time, the justification
for offering microfinancial services has shifted: the core mission previously was
exclusively to help small enterprises with credit, but today financial services more
generally are expected to alleviate poverty through popular participation in the financial
sector. The new mission of “financial inclusion” emphasizes savings, sending money, and
insurance services but also suggests that poor people’s ubiquitous financial needs (such as
housing, water, or consumption) should be served with credit. (Mader and Sabrow 2015)
Credit still stands out as the core activity of the microfinance sector. For example, although
the global scope of microinsurance remains very small (Kiviat 2009; Binswanger-Mkhize
2012) a major, if not predominant, part of it is credit default or life insurance which is often
obligatorily sold with loans, not a loan-independent service like health or crop insurance
(Wipf, Kelly, and McChord 2012). Microsavings, meanwhile, are also far less important
than often made out to be. Although in total they came to $86.5 billion globally (compared
to outstanding loan balances of $100.7 billion), of these savings nearly half were held at
two large institutions, Harbin Bank (China) and Bank Rakyat Indonesia—hardly typical
microfinance institutions.4 Practically all MFIs worldwide—even those ostensibly
focusing on savings like SafeSave in Bangladesh and MicroSave in India—make loans.
Out of 1,263 MFIs reporting to the database MIX, 579 MFIs reported no client savings at
all (another 255 had less than $1 million), while 1,255 reported issuing loans (and 978 had
5
lent more than $1 million). Only at 172 MFIs worldwide did clients hold greater savings
than the loans they owed.5
The focus in microfinance is clearly on credit. Although poor people evidently have fairly
little to save (and many of the savings held at MFIs are not from very poor people), MFIs
focus on loans for an even simpler reason: lending is more profitable than their other
activities. When MFIs do take savings, this service is often tied to credit, such that clients
are only allowed to save if they take a loan—worse yet, some parts of what appears as
savings are actually forced savings (cf. CGAP 2003; Sinclair 2012).6 Furthermore, the
commercialization of microfinance dissuades MFIs from taking savings because it eases
MFIs’ access to other capital sources; among those MFIs in which commercial MIVs have
invested, the share of savings has decreased (Symbiotics 2013).7 The effort and cost of
administering small savings accounts is high, so MFIs often prefer to borrow their capital
from larger banks or seek investors; many can even borrow capital without interest from
“p2p” funders, like Kiva, or obtain grants from donors.
Economic and Gender Impacts of Microfinance
From the outset, MFIs and other key organizations have argued that poverty alleviation
and women’s empowerment are the main objectives of microfinance. For instance CGAP
(1995:2) explains: “Finance and enterprise systems that serve the majority can be the
pivotal links and the levers, enabling the poor to share in economic growth and giving poor
people the means to use social services.” The idea behind microfinance is that poor people
above all lack the financial tools with which to help themselves out of poverty; with hard
work and some borrowed capital as their substrate, they should be able to grow.
Muhammad Yunus likened microcredit clients to “bonsai people” in his 2006 Nobel
lecture:
To me poor people are like bonsai trees. . . . There is nothing wrong in their seeds. Simply,
society never gave them the base to grow on. All it needs to get the poor people out of
poverty [is] for us to create an enabling environment for them. Once the poor can unleash
their energy and creativity, poverty will disappear very quickly.8
6
The notion of microfinance as a poverty-alleviating instrument was (and still often is)
underpinned by stories of poor individuals investing in their small businesses and gaining
material wealth—as with Rukia’s story, above. By the 1990s, however, many donors and
academics sought more systematic evidence of impact. The most supportive evidence came
from studies conducted with World Bank support in Bangladesh, studying “the impact of
participation, by gender, in . . . three group-based credit programs on women’s and men’s
labor supply, boys’ and girls’ schooling, expenditure, and assets” (Pitt and Khandker
1998:960). Pitt and Khandker concluded that “participation in these credit programs, as
measured by quantity of cumulative borrowing, is a significant determinant of many of
these outcomes. Furthermore, credit provided to women was more likely to influence these
behaviors than credit provided to men.” They estimated that for every 100 Taka lent to a
woman, her household’s consumption expenditure—the main poverty indicator used—
increased by 18 Taka (11 Taka for men) relative to households who did not borrow.
Practitioners broadly welcomed these results as proof of microfinance’s success; but the
results in fact were far less clear than they first appeared. For instance, when Morduch
(1998) and later Roodman and Morduch (2009) adjusted certain parameters, ensuring
among other things that the characteristics of borrower households matched those of
comparison households, or accounting for women generally receiving much smaller loans,
their analysis suggested a slightly negative overall impact from microcredit. Mosley and
Hulme’s (1998) research found that the poorer the client, the more likely they were to fall
deeper into poverty, and only comparatively better-off households stood to benefit from
borrowing. Anthropologists in particular meanwhile questioned whether women really
gained empowerment through loans, especially because men often appropriated their
wives’ loans and rising levels of domestic tension and violence were found (Rahman
1999:74).9
Pitt and Khandker’s contested studies triggered a still-ongoing academic debate over
appropriate statistical methods for measuring poverty impact (cf. Duvendack and Palmer
Jones 2012), fuelling an enterprise of further studies aiming to resolve the shortcomings of
earlier ones. The earlier phase of impact research may be distinguished from a later phase
since the mid-2000s which has been dominated by studies using increasingly sophisticated,
randomized sampling methodologies (cf. Banerjee and Duflo 2011). The recent spell of
7
randomized controlled trials (RCTs) has drawn upon methods adopted from medical testing
in order to eliminate the sources of upward bias, which critics and skeptics asserted
accounted for alleged improvements in poverty indicators, for instance self-selection bias
(more success-prone households likelier to apply for loans) and program-placement bias
(MFIs lending in settings more conducive to success). By randomizing membership in
“treatment” and “control” groups, akin to clinical trials, it was to be ensured that any
differences in poverty outcome were actually caused by the intervention itself. RCTs in the
social sciences, however, only incompletely reproduce the clinical situation; for instance,
since “patients” and “doctors” are not double-blinded (both know who received a loan), no
“placebo” is administered (to the control group), and therapeutic equivalence is not tested
(no comparison of the tested “treatment”, microfinance, against another established one)
(Mader 2013b).
Instead of clearly demonstrating impact, however, the microfinance RCTs so far have
shown very few significant positive differences between the “treatment” and “control”
groups; the results of the first two studies were released in 2009. The Indian RCT,
conducted in Hyderabad, had partnered with an MFI, agreeing to randomly open branches
only in half of certain slum districts where it planned to open new offices (Banerjee et al.
2009). The researchers found no net change in the expenditures of households living in
these “treatment” slums relative to “control” slums, indicating that loan availability did not
make the areas less poor on aggregate. Also, no impacts on women’s empowerment and
other “social” outcomes were found. The researchers, however, noted that MFI lending
made people living here marginally more likely to start a business and increase their overall
spending on business purposes, although this did not raise their incomes or assets. They
also found that spending on so-called temptation goods (Banerjee et al. 2009:28) decreased,
which they interpreted as a successful outcome.10 In the Philippines RCT, an MFI in Manila
randomly gave loans to some marginally creditworthy applicants and denied loans to others
(Karlan and Zinman 2009). This research turned up puzzling results: for instance, “treated”
businesses shrank and laid off workers. Borrowers’ children were more likely to attend
school, but only if the borrower was a man. Microcredit did not measurably change
households’ incomes or consumption levels, yet “self-reported wellbeing, based on
responses to standard batteries of questions on optimism, calmness, (lack of) worry, life
8
satisfaction, work satisfaction, job stress, decision making power, and socioeconomic
status” worsened significantly (Karlan and Zinman 2009:17).11 More recent RCTs (such as
Augsburg et al. 2012; Crépon et al. 2014) have painted similarly unclear pictures, finding
a mixed bag of correlations between certain variables and access to credit but never
demonstrating clear-cut poverty-alleviating effects.
In 2011, the British Department for International Development (DFID) published a
systematic review summarizing the findings of all available studies on microfinance
impact. After considering a total of 2,643 publications, the reviewers short-listed a sample
of 58 studies of sufficient quality (in terms of research design and method of analysis) to
be reviewed in depth. These studies covered all types of microfinance programs and a
variety of different tested outcomes, including gender and economic empowerment. The
DFID reviewers concluded that all the studies commonly cited in favor of microfinance
were too flimsy to credibly demonstrate positive impact, since,
. . . almost all impact evaluations of microfinance suffer from weak methodologies and
inadequate data, thus adversely affecting the reliability of impact estimates. Nevertheless
authors often draw strong policy conclusions generally supportive of microfinance. This may
have lead [sic] to misconceptions about the actual effects of programmes, thereby diverting
attention from the search for perhaps more pro-poor interventions and more robust evaluations.
(Duvendack et al. 2011a:2)
The DFID team argued it had to “come down on the side of ‘there is no good evidence for’
rather than ‘there is no good evidence against the beneficent impact of microfinance’”
(Duvendack et al. 2011b:72). Others, like mathematician and microfinance expert David
Roodman (2012), have also clarified that “today the best estimate of the impact of
microcredit on poverty is zero.”
It is worth asking then, given these findings (or lack thereof), exactly why the positive
impacts expected by CGAP and Yunus are not materializing, or why microcredit for
microenterprise (the key activity of microfinance) may perhaps even generate negative
impacts. The problems noted in the literature lie in the micro-, meso- and macrolevels.12
The issues at the microlevel can be summarized as three interrelated problems:
displacement, saturation, and fallacy of composition. Displacement (or spillover) refers to
how a borrower’s microenterprise impinges on other people’s microenterprises: a borrower
9
using her loan, for instance, to sell vegetables on a local street usually enters a market with
few or no barriers to entry in which others already compete. If this borrower financially
succeeds, she likely does so by displacing a (nonborrowing) competitor, and thus the
microloan leaves the net local economic situation unchanged. Or, one enterprise does not
displace another, but instead both collectively saturate the local market, producing a new
distribution, but no growth, that is, saturation occurs.13 Given displacement and saturation
effects, the impact of microfinance may appear exaggeratedly positive when the out-
competed nonborrowers are the comparison group. Fallacy of composition occurs when an
observer (MFI employees, researchers, policymakers) falsely take their individual
observations of positive impact among the clients as representative of the entire local
economy, which may be stagnant or in decline; a handful of prosperous MFI-financed
microenterprises does not equate local economic development.
These issues connect with larger meso-level problems: demand and returns to scale.
Microfinance increases the supply of goods and services locally offered by
microenterprises, but demand generally only rises if overall wealth in the area increases;
an issue which microfinance does not address.14 To make matters worse, microenterprises
typically offer products and services whose demand is income inelastic, such that even
rising local incomes would create relatively few opportunities for microenterprise
expansion. The demand for local farm produce, rickshaw rides, hand-sewn clothes, or
haircuts is most likely to remain static while demand for processed foods, motorcycles,
urban fashion, or high-tech products (produced by large industry elsewhere) rises. The
converse, supply-side issue is that informal microenterprises show low returns to scale;
that is, they are inherently hard to grow since there are few feasible means for raising their
productivity. For instance, a $100 loan can make the difference between doing nothing and
setting up a roadside vegetable stand or buying a sewing machine. The next $100, however,
makes comparatively less difference; the vegetable seller could buy at bulk rates or
advertise, the tailor could buy a newer machine, but their business remains essentially
unchanged, unlike larger industrial enterprises, where additional investments (for instance
in machinery) can increase output by a significant factor.
10
Resting on these issues, finally, are larger problems of economic transformation: industrial
policy and entrepreneurship. Viewed macroeconomically, microfinance spreads credit
broadly among many users. However, as scholars like Ha-Joon Chang (2002) argue,
successful national economic development hinges on industrial policy—deliberately
targeting key industries and channeling finance to them (as for instance, historically,
happened in South Korea and Taiwan). Milford Bateman (2011) argues that microfinance
even actively undermines sustainable development by directing scarce capital to tiny
uninnovative, low-productivity undertakings that cannot generate growth. Moreover,
microfinance idolizes and misunderstands entrepreneurship by supporting practically any
autonomous income-generating activity. The ideology behind microfinance suggests
everyone is—or should be—an entrepreneur.15 But, following Schumpeter (1962), it is only
select individuals with vision and creativity who create the capitalist dynamic of “creative
destruction” that drives economies forward, and while some microfinance clients may be
such characters, most probably are not. Most borrowers would likely prefer a decent job,
given the choice (Karnani 2007). Worse yet, the tiny loan sizes doled out by MFIs force
even the most gifted entrepreneurs into pursuing minimalistic, emulative, noncreative
microenterprise activities.
The positive impact which microfinance is supposed to have on women specifically also
turns out to be far less clear than commonly assumed. Proponents often cite as evidence
for women empowerment the high percentage of female borrowers (over three-quarters are
female) and highlight the sheer fact that microloans place significant amounts of cash in
many women’s hands for the first time. But feminist and anthropological scholars doubt
that such borrowing brings empowerment. Microfinance may have a disempowering effect
on women since “[w]hen women are constructed as responsible clients,” as Katharine
Rankin (2001:29) argues, “the onus for development falls squarely on their shoulders.”
Critics like Nancy Fraser (2013) argue that microfinance politically replaces welfare state
paternalism with new, neoliberal forms of oppression. Empowering the female
entrepreneur as a new a catalyst for development may appear progressive, but “in
traditional patriarchal fashion, women, idealized for their responsibility, are rewarded by
being made responsible for more and more labor activities” (Isserles 2003:48).
11
In practice, instead of MFIs focusing on women as more promising entrepreneurs or better
stewards of family money (the “public transcript of microfinance”), Rahman (1999) found
it is often the case that MFIs target women because they are weaker. Women’s “positional
vulnerability” in Bangladesh’s rural social hierarchy makes them more pliant borrowers
for majority-male MFI staff to manage, and MFIs actively draw on and reinforce these
local gendered inequalities through their lending practices. As Karim (2011:84) argues, far
from being anathema to microfinance, existing patriarchal structures that suppress women
are actually useful ingredients in MFIs’ business model:
Loan recovery technologies deployed by NGOs used public shaming as a form of social
control. . . . Women who were unable to pay their loans on time were often publicly
humiliated, or the fear of a public humiliation hung over their heads, acting as a form of
discipline in their lives. Moreover, women were treated effectively as a tool, in that NGOs
shamed rural men by shaming their wives. (Karim 2011:86)
Moreover, Kabeer (2000:64) found that in Bangladesh a majority of borrowing women
practically “exercised little or no control over their loan,” and husbands or other male
relatives often decided how they should use it. Some women simply had to hand over the
loaned money while still bearing the burden of repayment.
History and Prehistory
The roots of microfinance are often traced back to the lending experiment begun in 1976
in Bangladesh by Muhammad Yunus, who founded the Grameen (Village) Bank in 1983.16
Yunus and the Grameen Bank won the Nobel Prize for Peace in 2006 and became the
public face of microfinance globally. However, Yunus’s story is hardly as unique, and
microfinance not quite as new, as the commonplace story suggests. Very similar lending
experiments were going on in different parts of the world around the same time, particularly
in South Asia, where credit as a form of social policy had an institutional lineage dating
back to the British colonial administration.17
Cooperative credit societies were brought to South Asia by the colonial administration in
the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries as a “transplant of a German idea, with
12
English characteristics, slightly modified to suit conditions in British India” (Turnell
2005:16). Aided with state money, while simultaneously avowing free-market principles
and insisting on freedom from state interference,18 the cooperatives grew to 4 million
members by 1930. At the beginning of the twentieth century, prominent cooperatives
promoter Henry W. Wolff (1910:520–21) conducted a global survey of cooperatives and
specifically lauded the British Indian credit societies for their independence and firmly
capitalist ethos, which apparently made them vastly superior to their European
counterparts. But ironically, unlike the more solidarity-oriented European cooperatives
(many of which survive until today), the British Indian system went into decline around
1925 and wholly collapsed in parts of the subcontinent. The reasons included social
imbalances, poor governance, and various departures from the original German model
(Turnell 2005). The South Asian co-ops particularly failed in their mission of ousting the
moneylender, and instead were often run by landlords, moneylenders, and other elites who
used them as sources of patronage and influence (Shah, Rao, and Shankar 2007). After
independence, despite these shortcomings, the new South Asian nations drew on the
colonial lineage of credit as a social policy and continued to encourage cooperative credit
particularly for farmers and artisans. India, especially, operated large, state-driven rural-
lending programs. The effect was that the total share of informal credit from moneylenders,
traders, and landlords fell by more than half during the 1970s, while households’ debt share
to formal lenders doubled (Shah et al. 2007).
The Bangladeshi war of independence in 1971, from which a weak and autocratic state
emerged, proved a crucial event in the development of modern microfinance. After the
war, a catastrophic famine followed in 1973–1974, and throughout the young country
newly founded civil society organizations sought to fill the void left by the incapable state,
particularly in supporting marginal and recently displaced communities (Zohir 2004). But
most of these nascent NGOs lacked funding for large transformative projects, and some
discovered short-term loans were one cost-effective way of working with the poor. Thus,
a number of nongovernmental relief organizations, such as the Bangladesh Rural
Advancement Committee (BRAC), started in 1972, pioneered microfinance before
Grameen Bank. It was in this environment that Muhammad Yunus, the son of a jeweler
from Chittagong and professor of economics educated at Vanderbilt University, returned
13
from the United States and began experimenting with small rural loans. After initial
success, through personal connections, Yunus was able to secure funding from the national
Bangladesh Bank and commercial banks. In 1983 the project officially became a
government-regulated bank, thanks to a unique ordinance passed by the government of
dictator Hussain Muhammad Ershad (Hulme 2009:165).
This new approach to poverty alleviation, with private organizations disbursing small loans
for rural entrepreneurship, was also championed by organizations such as Accion and
FINCA in Latin America around the same time. It coincided with a series of paradigm
shifts in the field of global development. In the 1970s and 1980s, state-driven policies of
import-substituting industrial development fell out of favor, while the importance of the
informal sector and women’s role in development were noted and emphasized; poor
women in particular were “discovered” as productive members of society. Also, the “basic
needs approach” advocated by the International Labor Organization (targeting the poorest
and their most urgent needs first) and the budding NGO sector were recognized as being
closer to the lives of poor people than the state and its massive industrial development
policies. The new, exciting idea of microcredit matched these new imperatives as a
nonstate, women-oriented, grassroots-level intervention that promised to release the
productive energies of poor people. It was also a response to the critique of subsidized
credit launched by a group of economists who became known as the “Ohio School,”19
which strongly influenced World Bank policy in the 1980s. Subsidized credit discouraged
savings, they argued, actually leading to “redistribution in reverse” (Gonzalez-Vega 1982);
therefore, to benefit the poor, credit markets needed to be made competitive and follow
market forces (Adams, Douglas, and von Pischke 1984).
Microcredit began to garner serious recognition from the international policy community
and economic observers in the 1980s when it began to be used in implementing structural
adjustment programs (SAPs). In the context of SAPs orchestrated by multilateral
organizations, microcredit played a strategic role in facilitating economic and financial
liberalization as a financially steered poverty-alleviation program. The World Bank and
the IMF (directly as well as through subsidiaries such as CGAP) employed microcredit to
impose an “enabling environment” for financial services, integrated with their
14
development agendas (Weber 2002). In the course of Bolivia’s New Economic Program,
for instance, from 1986 onward, microloans were deployed in order to assuage resistance
to the worst effects of austerity and facilitate the transition of formerly government- or
formal-sector employed workers into informal self-employment. Political mainstreaming
coincided with the commercial mainstreaming of microfinance. Following the first MFI
transformations in the 1980s, in the 1990s a growing number of economically successful
microfinance NGOs transformed into for-profit companies. The private for-profit approach
to microlending was picked up by the World Bank as a model for the sector, which founded
a suborganization, CGAP, to promote and standardize the template for commercial
microfinance (Bateman 2010:16–17).
CGAP, over time, also proposed a broader range of financial activities for MFIs, beyond
their traditional focus on entrepreneurship lending. MFIs should aim for a general
“provision of credit, savings, and financial services to very poor people” since providing
“these services to very poor households creates opportunities for the poor to create, own,
and accumulate assets and to smooth consumption” (CGAP 1998:1). The focus of policy
actors increasingly shifted in the 1990s from directly supporting MFIs to promoting an
appropriate financial system for the growth of microfinance providers, primarily through
enticing private investors to enter the market. This effort at commercializing microfinance
fell onto politically and economically fertile ground in an era of general enthusiasm about
financial development paired with an abundance of investment capital. A number of high-
profile events finally anchored microfinance in the public imaginary, adding widespread
social credence to the increasingly clear business case for microfinance. The Microcredit
Summit in 1997 (organized by NGOs, MFIs, and lobby groups), the United Nations’ Year
of Microcredit in 2005, and particularly the Nobel Prize for Peace awarded to Muhammad
Yunus and Grameen Bank in 2006 all raised microfinance’s profile among alternative
policies in the global development and poverty alleviation toolkit.
15
Table 1: Growth of the microfinance industry
Under the new approach that encouraged the entry of private capital (often via subsidies
designed specifically to entice commercial investments) the global microfinance sector has
grown rapidly since the 1990s (see Table 1). While public sector funding for microfinance
has continued, and has even grown, major institutional investors have also taken a growing
interest particularly since the turn of the millennium (MicroRate 2013). The
commercialization of the microfinance sector is ongoing, but today already in many
countries the leading MFIs are private companies primarily funded by private capital. The
enthusiasm of private, profit-seeking financial investors was further encouraged by a
number of stock market share issues by MFIs since the mid-2000s and the emergence of
more sophisticated investment tools such as debt collateralization, which improve the
liquidity of microfinance investments (Lieberman et al. 2009). Although still fairly small
compared to other parts of global finance, with $100.7 billion in loans (in 2012) the
microfinance sector is no longer wholly negligible. The Microcredit Summit Campaign, an
advocacy organization, counted 195 million clients served by 3,652 MFIs as of December
2011, and more than three-quarters of the clients were women (Maes and Reed 2012:3).
However, the vast majority of MFIs are small or very small, and the industry is highly
concentrated: of the 1,262 MFIs reporting their 2012 loans to the Microfinance Information
Exchange (MIX, a CGAP brainchild), only 50 large MFIs accounted for more than two-
thirds of lending worldwide.
1995 2005 2011/12
No. of MFIs ca. 735* 1,228ˆ 1,263ˆ
No. of loans or borrowers (million) 12.2* 48.8ˆ 195†
Size of loan portfolio (US$ billion) 5.0* 18. 100.7ˆ
Sources: *World Bank (2001), †Maes/Reed (2011); ˆMIX (2013)
16
Recent Developments
Three recent developments in microfinance are worth interpreting in light of the ongoing
commercialization and concentration of the microfinance sector. First, a number of crises
and collapses have shaken the microfinance field, exposing the tendency of commercial
microfinance to push clients into overindebtedness traps; the transformation of some
national MFI sectors has come with all the trappings of financial markets. Second, the
uncertainty about the impacts of microfinance has fostered the search for a new mission
and meaning, such that microfinance is now justified as an integral element of a global
push for “financial inclusion,” instead of the older, simpler idea of lending for
microenterprise. Third, because of its recent expansion beyond its traditional spheres of
activity, microfinance is increasingly proposed as useful for addressing a whole range of
social problems and is also making headway in the Global North.
Overindebtedness and Collapse
The ongoing transformation and maturation of microfinance into a financial market has
brought a series of collapses; the widely reported crisis in India 2010 was only the most
recent and severe case.20 Each collapse appears to have taken the sector by surprise, and
industry spokespeople have generally placed the blame on political actors. But the
commonalities of the crises suggest they are caused by more fundamental factors inherent
to the microfinance business itself. In spite of their geographic dispersion—from Bolivia
in 2000 via the crises in Bosnia-Herzegovina, Morocco and Nicaragua in 2007 and 2008,
to the huge collapse in the south Indian state of Andhra Pradesh in 2010—the microfinance
collapses have shown four common factors: commercialization and growth; competition
and overindebtedness; an unsound political economy; and a triggering event.
A first notable feature of the countries that experienced microfinance collapses is that these
were fast-growing markets where commercial MFIs dominated. They were leading,
exemplary microfinance markets, not backwaters. During the 1980s and 1990s, Bolivia
was the global paragon of commercial microfinance, India was the same in the late 2000s,
and Morocco was home to several globally renowned MFIs.21 The underlying problem is
that commercialization requires MFIs to seek growth and efficiency (which are supposed
to benefit clients via higher outreach and lower cost), but this striving for growth and
17
efficiency often leads MFIs to cut corners and overreach. For instance, among India’s
leading MFIs before the collapse it was not uncommon for one loan officer to supervise
more than 400 clients. Rapid growth also, incidentally, can hide the consequences of bad
lending, giving MFIs a false semblance of health, since older, nonperforming loans are
numerically eclipsed by new loans that are being repaid on time.
A second feature of these markets was the high level of competition, which amplified the
pressure on MFIs to grow and exacerbated the side-effects of growth. The Ohio School
economists had suggested competitive credit markets to enhance efficiency and ensure
optimal capital allocation, but in practice competition often leads to very poor lending
decisions. Since commercial MFIs depend on securing finance from capital markets, they
compete in signaling to investors a high likelihood of generating exceptional returns. The
most effective means for signaling this is to expand their market share by growing the client
base and making larger loans. Competition thereby encourages (or even requires) MFIs to
act in ways that in the short term and for each MFI make sense but in the long term and
collectively can be disastrous. To illustrate: in a market with several MFIs targeting the
same client, each MFI knows that if it does not lend, another will gain the fees and interest
payments. Given strong enough competition, even if the client’s creditworthiness is
doubtful, at least one MFI (and perhaps all) will lend. Perversely, however, if the borrower
ever finds herself in repayment trouble—even just temporary trouble—all MFIs will
competitively squeeze her for repayments. Competition also extends beyond the other
MFIs. In Bolivia and Bosnia-Herzegovina, MFIs and commercial consumer lenders
competed for the same clientele. In Nicaragua, MFIs competed against a large state
program, and in India they competed against the state-supported “self-help group” model
of linking poor borrower groups to commercial banks. Furthermore, ubiquitously there
remains the traditional moneylender as a competitor.
Third, the political economies of these locales were conducive to both the growth and
subsequent collapse of the microfinance system. In different but comparable ways,
desperation rather than opportunity drove many borrowers to take loans. In all locales, a
reduction of economic security for low-income populations drove people into debt,
generating the high demand for microcredit that attracted MFIs and their investors. In the
18
1990s, Bolivia’s economic reforms thrust multitudes of previously formally employed or
transfer-dependent people into the labor market, leaving many with no other option than to
self-employ through microenterprise to survive in the country’s stagnant economy. For
Nicaragua, the 2000s were a period of slow growth and historically relatively low coffee
prices. Bosnia-Herzegovina faced not only postwar rebuilding after 1999 but also the
construction of a capitalist economy, which European and international donors sought to
achieve through microfinance; but their strategy succeeded only in creating a
deindustrialized and “infantilized” market economy (Bateman 2007). In India, post-1994
liberalization saw the discontinuation or reduction of various social programs, farmer
subsidies, and state lending, which squeezed the livelihoods of the rural poor. Given the
lack of economic security and opportunity, it was only a matter of time until many clients
became caught in debt traps, which were deepened by the competitive supply of credit.
Fourth, the collapses were all to some extent triggered or accompanied by an external
(political or economic) event on which microfinance industry representatives placed the
blame. In Bolivia, in 2000, debtor protests arose in the context of successful nationwide
campaigning against neoliberal reforms (Marconi and Mosley 2005). In part, they were
organized by well-known political activists, and some protestors resorted to desperate
means including hunger strikes and building occupations; MFIs mostly blamed the political
activists for the crisis (Rhyne 2001). In Nicaragua, in 2008, after six borrowers in a small
town were arrested for not repaying; protests ensued and rapidly spread throughout the
north of the country, turning violent. This protest movement “No Pago” (“I’m Not Paying”)
was publicly endorsed by President Daniel Ortega, who accused the MFIs of committing
“usury”. Again, politics (only the proximate trigger) was blamed for the crisis. The
collapses of Bosnia-Herzegovina and Morocco in 2008, meanwhile, were blamed on the
global economic downturn (Chen et al. 2010). An explanation that makes the most sense
when considering how that credit crunch deprived MFIs of the funds necessary to continue
raising the loan balances of their already-overindebted clients.
To understand the interplay of these four factors, it is worth examining the Indian crisis,
the deepest and most dramatic one to date. In India, microfinance began expanding in the
late 1990s, building on the legacies of colonial cooperative credit and state-lending
19
programs. Indian MFIs were generally founded as NGOs using state and donor money, but
within under 10 years many had transformed into private “nonbank financial companies”
successfully chasing commercial funding and aiming for share listing on the stock market.
Focusing solely on the business of credit, India’s hyperefficient MFIs achieved unheard-of
growth rates and were well-capitalized by Indian banks and investors from abroad.
Showing default rates as low as 0.14 percent in 2008 (nationwide) and posting
extraordinary profits, Indian MFIs exemplified the commercial microfinance model’s
success at generating efficiency, outreach and profitability.22 Behind the scenes, however,
extreme forms of social coercion and multiple borrowing upheld the microfinance miracle;
debtors were often driven to take extra loans (including from moneylenders) to survive
each successive loan cycle. The boom centered on Andhra Pradesh, a leading neoliberal
reform state, where MFIs found many people well-experienced in the management of debt
and handily preorganized into borrower groups thanks to the Self-Help Group (SHG)
system (the MFIs “poached” these groups) who often also faced extreme and worsening
hardships. An ecological crisis (including depleting common resources, unsustainable
agricultural change, and climate change) intertwined with the retrenchment of social
spending and farmer subsidies to push rural populations to use credit for handling income
losses and insecurity or for migrating to cities. By the end of the boom, 84 percent of
households in Andhra Pradesh held two or more loans (from different sources) and 58
percent had four or more; the median household had three. In late 2010, after two years of
droughts and floods afflicted parts of the state, a wave of violence and suicides swept
through the ranks of Andhra borrowers, exposing widespread overindebtedness and
unleashing a media storm that induced the government of Andhra Pradesh to temporarily
halt all microlending and loan collection.23 Although the halting effect of the emergency
ordinance lasted only five days, widespread repayment defiance took hold, and the MFIs
lost an estimated fifth of their nationwide loan portfolio (over $1 billion), for which they
blamed the Andhra government.
New Methods and Mission
Rather than retreating from microfinance, or critically reconsidering the suitability of
finance-driven approaches to poverty alleviation altogether, since the 2000s the
20
microfinance industry and its funders have reacted to the collapses and deepening questions
about impact broadly in three ways. The first is the construction of a new market
infrastructure in many countries, particularly those which already experienced collapses.
Debt counseling is now supposed to help clients manage and reduce their debts, but its
effectiveness is doubtful. For instance, in Bosnia, widespread debt counseling began in
2009, but a 2013 survey still found 69 percent of borrowers “vulnerable” to, “exposed” to,
or “concerned” about overindebtedness (Goronja 2014). Credit registries, on the other side,
aim to prevent clients from becoming indebted to more than one MFI (cf. McIntosh,
Sadoulet, and de Janvry 2006). However, under conditions of intense competition (as
described earlier) they may not succeed and might even help one MFI poach another’s
client. Finally, financial education programs—often supported by large, corporate donors
(e.g.cf. MasterCard Foundation 2011)—aim to educate (prospective) clients about the
benefits and risks of different financial products, but it is unclear to what extent they
actually succeed at improving clients’ ability to calculate and plan ahead in practice.
Furthermore, there is a risk of “education” merging with marketing and promotion.
A second reaction has been the launching of initiatives for “socially responsible”
microfinance—coming together in a “Global Appeal for Responsible Microfinance”24
by investor groups and thought leadership organizations. The “Smart Campaign” (initiated
by global investor network Accion), “Social Performance Task Force” (spearheaded by
CGAP), and “Truelift” (a multistakeholder initiative which, for a fee, assigns a “Pro-Poor
Seal of Excellence”) are the most prominent in a flurry of new global standards and action
plans for responsible, transparent and client-centered microfinance. What unites the
initiatives is their emphasis on voluntary participation, an absence of restrictive rules (such
as interest rate limits above which lending is considered irresponsible), no measurement of
client poverty alleviation, and a lack of mechanisms for sanctioning or exposing
transgressors. Citing the example of the Mexican MFI CompartamosBanco, infamous for
charging up to 195 percent interest, gaining the Smart Campaign’s “Client Protection
Certification,” critics have argued that the initiatives lack substance and merely serve to
deflect criticism from the sector (Sinclair 2014).
21
Third, and most fundamentally: microfinance has progressively gained a new mission.25
Earlier, the mission of microfinance was to provide finance for microenterprise (with an
explicit focus on credit), but lately the goals have broadened and become more diffuse
under the mission of financial inclusion.” The new mission asserts access to financial
services as a fundamental, ubiquitous need. An early and important marker in this mission
shift was CGAP’s 2002 annual report, which explained why financial services should be
seen as universally applicable and universally necessary tools:
Like everyone else, poor people need and use financial services all the time. They need
financial services to take advantage of business opportunities, invest in home repairs and
improvements, and meet seasonal expenses like school fees and holiday celebrations. They
need financial services to prepare for life-cycle events like the wedding of a daughter or the
death of a grandmother. They need financial services to cope with emergencies like the sudden
death of a wage-earner or a monsoon that wreaks havoc on their village. (CGAP 2001:5,
emphasis added)
Unlike microenterprise finance, the financial inclusion mission explicitly endorses credit
for survival and consumption, proposing “consumption smoothing” as an important goal
in itself: poor people’s problem is less that their incomes are low, and more that they are
uncertain and volatile, and here microfinance can help. Using finance for income
generation is therefore but one financial need the poor have, and MFIs should help them
manage their money in whichever way they themselves deem suitable to handle their
uncertain lives. Financial inclusion thereby officially inscribes and legitimates practices
that were already widespread yet unacknowledged, such as credit for nonproductive
purposes. In contrast to the earlier microenterprise mission, it is no longer assumed that
poor people need to generate the money for loan repayment via entrepreneurial ventures.
Here, they already have it, as past or future incomes: “Financial services allow people to
reallocate expenditure across time . . . if you don’t have the ability to pay for things now,
out of current income, you can pay for them out of past income or future income, or some
combination of both” (CGAP 2000b:2). Taking this logic to the extreme, proponents of the
new mission argue, “Not having enough money is bad enough. Not being able to manage
whatever money you have is worse” (Collins et al. 2009:184). In this way, with financial
inclusion, the goal posts for microfinance have shifted from raising incomes and assets to
22
the more attainable goals of consumption smoothing and financial access for all, such that
the troubling issue of (measurable) poverty alleviation disappears from discussion.
Expansion of Scope
In part thanks to the new mission, the hype about microfinance has continued and the
sector’s scope of activities is still growing. Microlending has gelled with other market-
based poverty-alleviation initiatives from the hubristic idea of “social business” serving
“humanity’s most urgent needs,” promoted by Muhammad Yunus (2011), to the idea of a
“fortune” for corporations to earn at the “bottom of the pyramid” (Prahalad 2004). In many
places, microlending increasingly is directly linked to the sale of products and services
from multinational corporations that are marketed and sold on credit, such as chemically
enriched foods, home solar systems, mobile phones, or seeds and farming services.26
Among the most consequential outgrowths is the expansion of microfinance into goods
and services traditionally governed politically as public goods, such as electricity,
education, water, and sanitation. Microfinance proponents suggest that poor people should
use credit to privately buy access to these goods, rendering public, redistributive solutions
obsolete. However, models using microfinance for such goods in practice often go against
social values, precipitate local political conflicts, enhance existing inequities, and do not
succeed in circumventing the underlying problems related to public sector incapacity
(Mader 2011).
Geographically, the scope of microfinance has expanded to the Global North. Grameen
America, based in New York and launched with a media buzz in 2008, is only one of
numerous microfinance programs now operating in the United States. Muhammad Yunus’s
new brainchild involves applying to North American poverty the Bangladeshi
microfinance model of targeting women (primarily among minority groups) who engage
in small, simple, often home-based, income-earning activities. In practice—much as in the
Global South—the activities supported in the United States often involve poor people
selling goods and services to other poor people.27 The European Union, meanwhile, funds
a growing number of microfinance programs, complementing a plethora of national and
subnational schemes, which aim to get the unemployed—particularly youths and ethnic
minorities—into self-employment. According to former Italian Minister of Foreign Affairs
23
Giulio Terzi di Sant’Agata (in an uncommonly candid endorsement analysis) microfinance
is useful as an instrument for keeping volatile populations occupied, “safeguarding the
quality of democracies” by preventing “material distress from encouraging populist
deviation and citizen regression” (Foreign Ministry of Italy 2013). Through helping uphold
consumption and facilitating self-employment while saddling the poor themselves with
social risk, microfinance in Europe serves as a device for austerity facilitation. In Terzi’s
words: microfinance could “help contain public spending by contributing to the reduction
of social buffers, the cost of which rises in times of recession.” A 2012 European
Investment Fund report, meanwhile, argued that more European public funding should be
used to catalyze “the entry of private capital in order to create a self-sustainable market in
the long run” (Bruhn-Leon, Eriksson, and Kraemer-Eis 2012:14). Just as previously in the
Global South, under conditions of fiscal austerity, taxpayer money may be redirected into
microfinance to build and prepare the market for private investors.
Conclusion
Microfinance still enjoys popular appeal and growing success as a business and is recently
expanding in scope. These factors may obscure the state of crisis which microfinance is in—
a crisis that has less to do with symbolic events like Muhammad Yunus’s ousting from office
as head of Grameen Bank in 2011 (after a spat with the Bangladeshi government), and more
with the doubtfulness of it achieving positive social aims. The lack of demonstrable impact
(beyond the individual success stories, which are true albeit misleading exceptions), the
diverse critiques which highlight its economic and gender-political flaws, and the collapses
of major markets all draw into question the idea of microfinance serving as a just and cost-
effective poverty-alleviation policy. Certainly, even if public and philanthropic backers were
to withdraw, for instance in the wake of even larger and more dramatic collapses than the
prior cases, parts of the microfinance sector (which in 2012 earned more than $21 billion in
surplus payments from the borrowers28) may be able to survive thanks to private, speculative
funders seeking high returns. However, in an era increasingly skeptical of financial market
solutions to social problems, it is unclear how much longer the sector can retain the public
legitimacy on which it has banked so far.
24
References
Accion. 2004. Accion Ventures: Newsletter of Accion International. Boston: Accion
International.
Adams, Dale W., Douglas H. Graham, and J. D. Von Pischke. 1984. Undermining Rural
Development with Cheap Credit. London: Westview Press.
Augsburg, Britta, Ralph De Haas, Heike Harmgart, and Costas Meghir. 2012.
“Microfinance at the Margin: Experimental Evidence from Bosnia and Herzegovina.”
EBRD Working Paper No. 146. London: EBRD.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster, and Cynthia Kinnan. 2009. “The
Miracle of Microfinance? Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation.” Unpublished
paper, May 30 2009. Cambridge: MIT.
Banerjee, Abhijit and Esther Dufo. 2011. Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the
Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York: Public Affairs.
Bateman, Milford. 2007. “De-industrialization and Social Disintegration in Bosnia.” Pp.
207–23 in What’s Wrong with Microfinance?, edited by Thomas Dichter and Malcolm
Harper. Bourton on Dunsmore, United Kingdom: Practical Action.
Bateman, Milford. 2010. Why Doesn’t Microfinance Work? London: Zed Books.
Bateman, Milford, ed. 2011: Confronting Microfinance: Undermining Sustainable
Development. Sterling, VA: Kumarian Press.
Binswanger-Mkhize, Hans P. 2012. Is There Too Much Hype about Index-Based
Agricultural Insurance? Journal of Development Studies 48:187–200.
Bruhn-Leon, Birthe, Per-Erik Eriksson, and Helmut Kraemer-Eis. 2012. “Progress for
Microfinance in Europe.” EIF Research & Market Analysis Working Paper 2012/13.
Luxembourg: European Investment Fund.
CGAP. 1995. “The Missing Links: Financial Systems That Work for the Majority.” Focus
No. 3. Washington, DC.
CGAP. 1998. “The Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest: A Microfinance Program.”
Focus No. 1 (1998 rev. ed.). Washington, DC.
CGAP. 2000. “Focus: Raising the Curtain on the ‘Microfinancial Services Era.’”
Washington DC.
CGAP. 2001. CGAP Annual Report: July 1, 2001–June 30, 2002. Washington DC.
CGAP. 2003. Microfinance Consensus Guidelines: Developing Deposit Services for the
Poor (2nd ed., October 2003). Washington, DC.
CGAP. 2012. “What Is Microfinance?” Washington, DC. Retrieved May 18, 2012
(http://www.microfinancegateway.org/p/site/m/template.rc/1.26.12263/).
CGAP and MIX. 2013. “2013 Survey on Cross-Border Funding for Financial Inclusion”
European Microfinance Week 2013, November, 13. Washington, DC. Retrieved
December 12, 2014 (http://www.e-
mfp.eu/sites/default/files/resources/2014/02/Estelle%20Lahaye_CGAP.pdf).
Chang, Ha-Joon. 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical
Perspective. New York: Anthem Press.
Chen, Greg, Stephen Rasmussen, and Xavier Reille. 2010. “Growth and Vulnerabilities in
Microfinance.” CGAP Focus Note 61. Washington, DC: CGAP.
25
Collins, Daryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Rutherford, and Orlanda Ruthven. 2009.
Portfolios of the Poor: How the World’s Poor Live on $2 a Day. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Counts, Alex. 2008. Small Loans, Big Dreams: How Nobel Prize Winner Muhammad
Yunus and Microfinance are Changing the World. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.
Crépon, Bruno, Florencia Devoto, Esther Duflo, and William Pariente. 2014. “Estimating
the Impact of Microcredit on Those Who Take It Up: Evidence from a Randomized
Experiment in Morocco.” Unpublished paper, May 2014. Cambridge, MA: MIT.
Dewan, Shaila. 2013. “Microcredit for Americans.” New York Times, October 28.
Dichter, Thomas and Malcolm Harper. 2007. What’s Wrong with Microfinance? Bourton
on Dunsmore: Immediate Technology.
Duvendack, Maren and Richard Palmer-Jones. 2012. “High Noon for Microfinance Impact
Evaluations: Re-investigating the Evidence from Bangladesh.” Journal of Development
Studies 48:1864–80.
Duvendack, Maren, Richard Palmer-Jones, James G. Copestake, Lee Hooper, Yoon Loke,
and Nitya Rao. 2011a: “Policy Brief: What Is the Evidence of the Impact of
Microfinance on the Well-being of Poor People?” London: EPPI-Centre, Social Science
Research Unit, Institute of Education, University of London.
Duvendack, Maren, Richard Palmer-Jones, James G. Copestake, Lee Hooper, Yoon Loke,
and Nitya Rao. 2011b. “Systematic Review: What Is the Evidence of the Impact of
Microfinance on the Well-being of Poor People?” London: EPPI-Centre, Social Science
Research Unit, Institute of Education, University of London.
Foreign Ministry of Italy. 2013. “Terzi: Micro Finance to Prevent Social Fragility, Italian
Ministry of Foreign Affairs.” February. Rome: Italian Ministry of Foreign Affairs.
Retrieved December 12, 2014
(http://www.esteri.it/MAE/EN/Sala_Stampa/ArchivioNotizie/Approfondimenti/2013/0
2/20130201_puntare_microfinanza.htm?LANG=EN).
Fraser, Nancy. 2013. “How Feminism Became Capitalism’s Handmaiden—And How to
Reclaim It.” The Guardian, October14.
Gonzalez-Vega, Claudio. 1982. “Cheap Agricultural Credit: Redistribution in Reverse.”
Colloquium on Rural Finance, Economic Development Institute Discussion Paper No.
10. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Goronja, Nataša. 2014. “IFC Experience with Responsible Microfinance in ECA.”
Presentation, Tbilisi, Georgia, January 31. Washington, DC, International Finance
Corporation. Retrieved December 12, 2014
(https://www.nbg.gov.ge/uploads/prezentacia/lending_standards/natasa_goronja.ppt).
Hartmann, Kathrin. 2014. “Social Business: Können Weltkonzerne Armut Bekämpfen?”
Pp. 193–202 in Rendite machen und Gutes tun? Mikrokredite und die Folgen
neoliberaler Entwicklungspolitik, edited by Gerhard Klas and Philip Mader. Frankfurt
am Main: Campus.
Hulme, David. 2009. “The Story of the Grameen Bank: From Subsidized Microcredit to
Market Based Microfinance.” Pp. 163–70 in Microfinance: A Reader, edited by David
Hulme and Thankom Arun. New York: Routledge.
26
Isserles, Robin G. 2003. “Microcredit: The Rhetoric of Empowerment, the Reality of
“Development as Usual.” Women’s Studies Quarterly 31:38–57.
Kabeer, Naila. 2000. “Conflicts over Credit: Re-Evaluating the Empowerment Potential of
Loans to Women in Rural Bangladesh.” World Development 29:63–84.
Karim, Lamia. 2011. Microfinance and Its Discontents: Women in Debt in Bangladesh.
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Karlan, Dean and Jonathan Zinman. 2009. “Expanding Microenterprise Credit Access:
Using Randomized Supply Decisions to Estimate the Impacts in Manila.” Yale
Economics Department Working Paper No. 68. Yale University Economic Growth
Center Discussion Paper No. 976.
Karnani, Aneel. 2007. “Employment, Not Microcredit, Is the Solution.” Ross School of
Business Paper No. 1065.
Kiviat, Barbara. 2009. “Why the World’s Poor Refuse Insurance.” Time Magazine
Business, September 21.
Lieberman, Ira, Anne Anderson, Zach Grafe, Bruce Campbell, and Daniel Kopf. 2009.
“Microfinance and Capital Markets: The Initial Listing/Public Offering of Four Leading
Institutions.” Pp. 31–80 in Moving Beyond Storytelling: Emerging Research in
Microfinance (Contemporary Studies in Economic and Financial Analysis, Vol. 92),
edited by Todd A. Watkins and Karen Hicks. Bingley: Emerald.
MacFarquhar, Neil. 2010. “Banks Making Big Profits from Tiny Loans.” New York Times,
April 13, 2010.
Mader, Philip. 2011. “Attempting the Production of Public Goods through Microfinance:
The Case of Water and Sanitation.” Journal of Infrastructure Development 3:153–70.
Mader, Philip. 2013a: “Rise and Fall of Microfinance in India: The Andhra Pradesh Crisis
in Perspective.” Strategic Change 22(1–2):47–66.
Mader, Philip. 2013b: “‘What Is the Evidence of the Impact of Microfinance . . .?’ by
Maren Duvendack et al.” Pp. 348–52 in Governance across Borders: Transnational
Fields and Transversal Themes, edited by Leonhard Dobusch, Philip Mader, and Sigrid
Quack. Berlin: epubli.
Mader, Philip. 2015. The Political Economy of Microfinance: Financialising Poverty.
London: Palgrave.
Mader, Philip and Sophia Sabrow. 2015: “All Myth and Ceremony? Examining the Causes
and Logic of the Mission Shift in Microfinance from Microenterprise Credit to Financial
Inclusion.” Forum for Social Economics (July 2015).
Maes, Jan P. and Larry R. Reed. 2012. State of the Microcredit Summit Campaign Report
2012. Washington, DC: Microcredit Summit Campaign.
Marconi, Reynaldo and Paul Mosley. 2005. “Bolivia during the Global Crisis 1998–2004:
Towards a Macroeconomics of Microfinance.” Sheffield Economic Research Paper
Series 2005007, June.
MasterCard Foundation. 2011. “Taking Stock: Financial Education Initiatives for the
Poor.” Toronto.
McIntosh, Craig, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Alain de Janvry. 2006. “Better Lending and
Better Clients: Credit Bureau Impact on Microfinance.” BASIS Brief 45: 1-6.
27
MicroRate. 2013. The State of Microfinance Investment 2013: Survey and Analysis of
MIVs.8th ed.. Arlington, VA.
MIX. 2008. “2008 MIX Global 100 Composite: Rankings of Microfinance Institutions.”
Washington, DC: Microfinance Information Exchange. Retrieved December 12, 2014
(http://www.themix.org/sites/default/files/2008%20MIX%20Global%20100%20updat
ed%20March%202009.pdf).
MIX. 2013. Basic MIX MFI Data Set. Washington, DC. Retrieved December 2, 2013
(http://www.mixmarket.org/crossmarket-analysis-report/download/).
Morduch, Jonathan. 1998. “Does Microfinance Really Help the Poor? New Evidence from
Flagship Programs in Bangladesh.” Unpublished paper, June 27, 1998. Department of
Economics and HIID, Harvard University and Hoover Institution, Stanford University.
Mosley, Paul and David Hulme. 1998. “Microenterprise Finance: Is There a Conflict
between Growth and Poverty Alleviation?” World Development 26:783–90.
OECD. 2014. “OECD StatExtracts.” (Total flows by donor (ODA+OOF+Private)
[DAC1]). Paris. Retrieved December 12, 2014 (http://stats.oecd.org).
Pitt, Mark M. and Shahidur R Khandker. 1998. “The Impact of GroupBased Credit
Programs on Poor Households in Bangladesh: Does the Gender of Participants Matter?”
Journal of Political Economy 106:958–96.
Prahalad, C. K. 2004. The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid: Eradicating Poverty
Through Profits. Philadelphia: Wharton School/Pearson.
Rahman, Aminur. 1999. “Micro-credit Initiatives for Equitable and Sustainable
Development: Who Pays?” World Development 27:67–82.
Rankin, Katharine N. 2001. “Governing Development: Neoliberalism, Microcredit, and
Rational Economic Woman.” Economy and Society 30:18–37.
Rhyne, Elisabeth. 2001. Commercialization and Crisis in Bolivian Microfinance. Bethesda,
MD: Development Alternatives.
Roodman, David and Jonathan Morduch. 2009. “The Impact of Microcredit on the Poor in
Bangladesh: Revisiting the Evidence.” Center for Global Development Working Paper
174.
Roodman, David. 2012. “Think Again: Microfinance.” Foreign Policy, February 1.
Schumpeter, Joseph. 1962. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper
Perennial.
Sinclair, Hugh. 2012. Confessions of a Microfinance Heretic: How Microlending Lost Its
Way and Betrayed the Poor. San Francisco, CA: Berrett-Koehler.
Sinclair, Hugh. 2014. “Smart or Crafty?” Confessions of a Microfinance Heretic Blog,
October 7. Retrieved December 12, 2014
(http://blog.microfinancetransparency.com/smart-or-crafty/).
Shah, Mihir, Rangu Rao, and P. S. Vijay Shankar. 2007. “Rural Credit in 20th Century
India: An Overview of History and Perspectives.” Economic and Political Weekly
42:1351–64.
Symbiotics. 2013. “2013 Symbiotics MIV Survey: Market Data & Peer Group Analysis,
Market Data & Peer Group Analysis July 2013.” Geneva. Retrieved December 12, 2014
28
(http://www.aboutmicrofinance.com/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/symbiotics-
symbiotics-2013-miv-survey-report11.pdf).
Turnell, Sean. 2005. “The Rise and Fall of Cooperative Credit in Colonial Burma.”
Macquarie University Department of Economics Research Papers 0509.
Weber, Heloise. 2002. “The Imposition of a Global Development Architecture: The
Example of Microcredit.” Review of International Studies 28:537–55.
Wipf, John, Eamon Kelly, and Michael McChord. 2012: “Improving Credit Life
Insurance.” Pp. 197–216 in Protecting the Poor. A Microinsurance Compendium. Vol.
2, edited by Craig Churchill and Michal Matul. Geneva: International Labour
Organization.
Wolff, Henry W. 1910. People’s Banks: A Record of Social and Economic Success.
London: P. S. King and Son.
World Bank. 2001. Sustainable Banking with the Poor: A Worldwide Inventory of
Microfinance Institutions. Washington, DC.
Yunus, Muhammad. 2011. Building Social Business: The New Kind of Capitalism that
Serves Humanity’s Most Pressing Needs. New York: Public Affairs.
Zohir, Sajjad. 2004. “NGO Sector in Bangladesh: An Overview.” Economic and Political
Weekly 39:4109–13.
Footnotes
1 A typical client success story, taken from Accion (2004:8).
2 Public funders accounted for US$21 billion of cross-border funding for microfinance in 2012 (CGAP and
MIX 2013. What share of this was declared as aid is unknown. Global aid (Official Development Assistance
was US$150.9 billion in 2012 (OECD 2014).
3 In most understandings, “microfinance” providers are formal lenders; as opposed to informal, private
moneylenders. Most are at least as formalized as NGOs; at most formal end of the scale, some are registered
banks.
4 A standard commercial bank and a part-privatized state development bank.
5 All data here is from 2012; source MIX (2013).
6 Forced savings are parts of loans not fully paid out by the MFI and withheld as collateral but registered as
“client savings.” These are one of the industry’s “dirty little secrets,” raising loan interest rates considerably
while appearing client-friendly (Sinclair 2012:35–36, 101–102). For instance, when Nigeria’s largest MFI,
LAPO, was criticized for its 114 percent interest loan rate, management responded by publicly announcing
a decrease. At the same time, it silently raised “compulsory” savings from 10 to 20 percent. Clients still had
to pay interest on the full loan amount, and the annual effective interest rate for some clients rose to nearly
126 percent (MacFarquhar 2010).
7 From 83 percent voluntary savers as a percentage of active borrowers in 2009 to 57 percent in 2012.
8 Nobel lecture, Oslo, December 10, 2006. Retrieved December 12, 2014,
http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/peace/ laureates/2006/yunus-lecture-en.html.
9 Practitioners and development agencies gave little attention to anthropological findings, while economic
studies were hotly discussed and new research programs created for economic impact measurement.
10 “Temptation goods” included alcohol, tobacco, betel leaves, gambling, also tea and food consumed
outside the home. The economists never wondered whether such declining consumption could adversely
affect clients’ life satisfaction or the businesses of local microenterprises selling tea or food on the street.

29

11 The authors, mystifyingly, neglected to interpret this aggregate “reduced happiness” finding in their paper
but discussed at length why shrinking businesses may be more efficient.
12 They are only briefly sketched here, drawing on Dichter and Harper (2007), Bateman (2010) and Bateman
(2011), where a deeper engagement can be found.
13 Microfinance practitioner and whistle-blower Hugh Sinclair (2012:239–49) suggests that displacement
and saturation effects therefore could combine to generate artificial demand for debt, as competitor
enterprises are forced to also borrow to remain competitive.
14 MFIs can (and do) lend for consumption, which may raise demand in the short term, but only at the price
of interest payments that depress demand even further at a later point in time.
15 Muhammad Yunus (2003:205) for instance says: “I believe that all human beings are potential
entrepreneurs. Some of us get the opportunity to express this talent, but many of us never get the chance
because we were made to imagine that an entrepreneur is someone enormously gifted and different from
ourselves.”
16 On the roots of microfinance see, for instance, Counts (2008).
17 For a more detailed version of this historical overview, see Chapter 2 of Mader (2015).
18 Much as the microfinance movement, decades later, has also avowed market principles while using
government funds.
19 Many of the economists were based at Ohio State University.
20 This part systematizes the accounts given in Mader (2013a), and Chapters 2 and 5 of Mader (2015).
21 Compare, for instance, the global MFI ranking in MIX (2008).
22 This means that less than 1 in 700 dollars was reported as not repaid; a utopian figure.
23 According to different sources, between 54 and 88 suicides in the space of one month, plus many more
attempts.
24 http://www.theglobalappeal.org; retrieved December 12, 2014.
25 As analyzed in depth (in German) in Sabrow and Mader (2014).
26 Cf. Hartmann (2014), in German.
27 The New York Times for instance reports borrowers engaged in home cooking, tailoring, street hawking,
or direct selling of cosmetics and products distributed through dubious multilevel marketing schemes (Dewan
2013).
28 For calculations, see Chapter 3 of Mader (2015).
... Credit and elements related to it, such as debt and consumption, were often at the center of controversy, and critics of the Workers' Party (PT) pointed out inconsistencies between their discourse and their practice -these critiques could be reclassified as 'expectations of action' and the 'actualization' of the left in power. To this end, authors relied on the international literature to show that the Workers' Party government worked towards what Hudson (1996) called the 'poverty industry' and what Mader (2016) and Schwittay (2014) termed 'financialization of poverty' 3 . ...
Article
Full-text available
Despite its recent growth, the academic literature on credit displays theoretical controversies and empirical differences regarding the predominant effects of consumer credit policies. At the same time, such policies have been given central importance in the historical accounts of a government that adopted them on a large scale in Brazil: the Lula government. Drawing upon theoretical debates and descriptive content, this article aims to contribute to the existing literature by examining the trajectory of Brazilian credit policies from the perspective of its main proponents. In addition, to the analysis of relevant documents, this study is based on interviews with three groups responsible for defending the payroll deducted credit policy, the most important credit policy adopted in terms of adherence and stability in the country: 01. bureaucrats from the Ministry of Finance; 02. unionists and lawmakers linked to labor unions; and 03. financial entrepreneurs, especially those organized in Febraban. We demonstrate that, for each of these groups, the payroll deducted policy carried a specific goal and context, being framed within different arrangements of public policies. Furthermore, the involvement of each group shaped the design assumed by the policy, while the overlapping of different stakeholders optimized its chances of implementation in the legislative arena.
... During the 18 th and 19 th centuries, many European countries engaged in microfinance activities in an informal manner at first (Seibel, 2005). The concept of microcredit goes as far back as the 16 th century when Jonathan Swift introduced a microcredit service to poor farmers under the Irish loan fund system, while the origin of microfinance goes back to the latter part of the 18 th century when financial cooperatives were established by Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen to provide financial support to the poor in the rural areas of Germany (Mader & Morvant-Roux, 2019;Schmidt et al., 2016;Abiola et al., 2011). In the mid-19 th century, financial cooperatives spread rapidly in Europe, North America and then all over the world. ...
Article
Full-text available
Poverty is one of the main socioeconomic issues holding back the development of economic of the underdeveloped countries. Microfinance is financial services provided to poor households of individuals who have no access to formal financial programs. It has been identified as a key mechanism to reduce world poverty in the recent past. With the revolution of the microfinance sector, it has been able to provide a wide range of services. This study aims to observe the extent to which the dimensions introduced in modern microfinance have contributed to the eradication of poverty. Data were collected using Likert scale questionnaire with total of 496 borrowers benefited under Samurdhi Micro Finance programs in Sri Lanka. Collected data analyzed confirmatory factor analysis by using AMOS 21. The factor loading of the individual measurement models were displayed that 38 items were grouped properly in to the 6 constructs which higher than 0.6
Article
Full-text available
This chapter offers a detailed analysis of microinsurance (nowadays often called “inclusive insurance”), an innovative hybrid model combining grassroots initiatives with top-down approaches to reach populations not covered by government-operated social protection systems. With half of the global population, primarily in low and middle-income countries, lacking social protection, the chapter focuses on the potential of microinsurance to address this pressing issue. The commercial microinsurance attempts, often labeled as “insurance for the poor,” have been largely insufficient. An alternative lies in the “Collaborative and Contributive” (C&C) model of microinsurance, which harnesses social forces, typically more compelling than market forces in informal settings, to stimulate demand. The chapter evaluates microinsurance’s social and economic impacts, drawing insights from 25 years of progress. It underscores the need for policymakers, international development bankers, and the reinsurance industry to recognize the potential of the C and C model in providing comprehensive insurance to marginalized populations.
Chapter
Full-text available
This chapter offers a detailed analysis of microinsurance (nowadays often called “inclusive insurance”), an innovative hybrid model combining grassroots initiatives with top-down approaches to reach populations not covered by government-operated social protection systems. With half of the global population, primarily in low and middle-income countries, lacking social protection, the chapter focuses on the potential of microinsurance to address this pressing issue. The commercial microinsurance attempts, often labeled as “insurance for the poor,” have been largely insufficient. An alternative lies in the “Collaborative and Contributive” (C&C) model of microinsurance, which harnesses social forces, typically more compelling than market forces in informal settings, to stimulate demand. The chapter evaluates microinsurance’s social and economic impacts, drawing insights from 25 years of progress. It underscores the need for policymakers, international development bankers, and the reinsurance industry to recognize the potential of the C and C model in providing comprehensive insurance to marginalized populations.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we explore the nexus between remittances and Nigeria’s economic growth over the period 1996 to 2020 from the perspective of financial inclusion (FI). The fully modified ordinary least square (FMOLS) and Granger (1969) causality methodologies were employed. The findings of the FMOLS show that the increasing flow of remittances can significantly contribute to the growth of the Nigerian economy. Also, the interaction of financial inclusion and remittances has a significant impact on the country’s development. The study concludes that the interaction of remittances with the measures of financial inclusion will lead to economic growth at a faster rate than when there is no interaction with financial inclusion. Using the Granger causality test, the study revealed that the relationship between financial inclusion and economic growth is a unidirectional one. It shows that the impact of financial inclusion on growth is conditional on remittances. Therefore, Nigeria’s authorities need to work to strengthen all existing institutional weaknesses that allow questionable transactions in financial markets and to promote a more inclusive financial sector that will reduce the number of unbanked individuals in the country.
Article
Full-text available
This article takes up recent calls to further problematize race in international political economy by focusing on money at the frontier of global finance. We draw upon the Black radical tradition’s theoretical formulations of racial capitalism, which we bring into dialogue with conceptualizations of money and finance as developed within the critique of political economy. Money is the most supreme and abstract incarnation of wealth and class power, yet it is also suffused with racial and colonial logics of differentiation. To explore this tension, we offer a relational-comparison of two sites of frontier finance, namely cross-border investment and digital financial inclusion in developing countries. We trace the mechanisms through which race affects the operations of money and finance across these two sites. We argue that racialized difference is mobilized and reproduced at three key moments in the construction of investibility at the financial frontier: (1) the re/making of a development ‘problem’; (2) the construction of racialized ideal-typical financial subjects; and (3) processes of risk valuation and the legitimation of surveillance, discipline, and extraction. This allows us to characterize the color of money at the financial frontier as a particularly potent and violent combination of the abstractive powers of race and money.
Book
Dado el estado no concluyente de resultados previos sobre el efecto de la competencia en el desempeño financiero y social de las instituciones microfinancieras (IMFs), el objetivo de esta investigación es evaluar la existencia de una relación no lineal entre la competencia y la sostenibilidad financiera y alcance social de las IMFs reguladas peruanas en el periodo 2003-2019. Consideramos tres diferentes medidas de competencia: el poder de mercado, medido con el índice de Lerner ajustado por eficiencia, la presencia geográfica en el mercado, aproximada a partir del porcentaje de agencias de cada IMF respecto del total de agencias del mercado, y el nivel de concentración del sector, medido a través del logaritmo del índice de Herfindahl-Hirschman. Aun cuando los resultados para la concentración no son significativos, los resultados para el poder de mercado evidencian una relación no lineal con la sostenibilidad financiera y la profundidad del alcance, y, una relación lineal negativa con la amplitud de alcance. Por otro lado, los resultados para la presencia geográfica evidencian una relación no lineal tanto con la sostenibilidad financiera como con el alcance. Sin embargo, pese a que la evidencia sugiere una relación en forma de U o U invertida, según sea el caso, la distribución de nuestros datos muestra solo una parte de la relación no lineal. En efecto, encontramos que el poder de mercado tiene un efecto positivo sobre las sostenibilidad financiera y negativo sobre la amplitud de alcance, mientras que, la presencia geográfica tiene un efecto negativo en la sostenibilidad financiera y positivo en ambas dimensiones del alcance. De acuerdo con estos resultados, la competencia afecta negativamente la sostenibilidad financiera y positivamente el alcance social de las IMFs peruanas.
Article
Full-text available
Islamic microfinance institutions play a major role in the provision of financial services to the poor and underprivileged through non-interest, equity-based products and services. To achieve these critical objectives, however, they need to be financially sustainable, which is threatened by the current economic and financial crisis caused by the Covid-19 pandemic. The objective of this paper is to review the determinants of financial sustainability of microfinance institutions with a view to drawing lessons for Islamic microfinance banks in Nigeria. The paper utilized the literature review methodology to synthesize research findings in the area. The review revealed that the major determinants of financial sustainability of microfinance institutions are the capital structure, asset size, and financial innovation. Others are good risk management and corporate governance frameworks. The paper thus recommended that Islamic microfinance institutions in Nigeria should maintain a robust capital structure that relies more on equity, a lean but diversified Board, and utilize more technology-based services. Most importantly, they should emphasize profit and loss sharing principles in their operations.
Article
Full-text available
Poverty is one of the main socio-economic issues holding back the development of economic of the underdeveloped countries. Microfinance is financial services provided to poor households of individuals who have no access to formal financial programs. It has been identified as a key mechanism to reduce world poverty in the recent past. With the revolution of the microfinance sector, it has been able to provide a wide range of services. This study aims to observe the extent to which the dimensions introduced in modern microfinance have contributed to the eradication of poverty. Data were collected using Likert scale questionnaire with total of 496 borrowers benefited under Samurdhi Micro Finance programs in Sri Lanka. Collected data analyzed confirmatory factor analysis by using AMOS 21. The factor loading of the individual measurement models were displayed that 38 items were grouped properly in to the 6 constructs which higher than 0.6
Book
Full-text available
This book is a collection of papers delivered at a conference in Croatia held in July 2007. It was supposed to come out sometime in 2008, but partly because it was a critique of microfinance it was accepted but later shelved by the publisher for fear of alienating a world then in thrall to the microfinance model. However, the publisher came back in 2011 out of the blue and asked if the book could be put together very quickly as they now wanted to publish it. The chapters cover mainly the Balkans, but a few other countries in order to make it a more international examination.
Book
In 2006 the Grameen Bank of Bangladesh won the Nobel Peace Prize for its innovative microfinancing operations. This study of gender, grassroots globalization, and neoliberalism in Bangladesh looks critically at the Grameen Bank and three of the leading NGOs in the country. This book offers a new perspective on the practical, and possibly detrimental, realities for poor women inducted into microfinance operations. In a series of ethnographic cases, this book shows how NGOs use social codes of honor and shame to shape the conduct of women and to further an agenda of capitalist expansion. These unwritten policies subordinate poor women to multiple levels of debt that often lead to increased violence at the household and community levels, thereby weakening women’s ability to resist the onslaught of market forces. A compelling critique of the relationship between powerful NGOs and the financially strapped women beholden to them for capital, this book cautions us to be vigilant about the social realities within which women and loans circulate—realities that often have adverse effects on the lives of the very women these operations are meant to help.
Article
The most-noted studies on the impact of microcredit on households are based on a survey fielded in Bangladesh in the 1990s. Contradictions among them have produced lasting controversy and confusion. Pitt and Khandker (PK, 1998) apply a quasi-experimental design to 1991–92 data; they conclude that microcredit raises household consumption, especially when lent to women. Khandker (2005) applies panel methods using a 1999 resurvey; he concurs and extrapolates to conclude that microcredit helps the extremely poor even more than the moderately poor. But using simpler estimators than PK, Morduch (1999) finds no impact on the level of consumption in the 1991–92 data, even as he questions PK’s identifying assumptions. He does find evidence that microcredit reduces consumption volatility. Partly because of the sophistication of PK’s Maximum Likelihood estimator, the conflicting results were never directly confronted and reconciled. We end the impasse. A replication exercise shows that all these studies’ evidence for impact is weak. As for PK’s headline results, we obtain opposite signs. But we do not conclude that lending to women does harm. Rather, all three studies appear to fail in expunging endogeneity. We conclude that for non-experimental methods to retain a place in the program evaluator’s portfolio, the quality of the claimed natural experiments must be high and demonstrated.
Article
This book helps to understand the enigmatic microfinance sector by tracing its evolution and asking how it works as a financial system. Our present capitalism is a financialized capitalism, and microfinance is its response to poverty. Microfinance has broad-ranging effects, reaching hundreds of millions of people and generating substantial revenues. Although systemic flaws have become obvious, most strikingly with the 2010 Indian crisis that was marked by overindebtedness, suicides and violence, the industry's expansion continues unabated. As Philip Mader argues, microfinance heralds less the end of poverty than new, more financialized forms of poverty. While microfinance promises to empower, it generates discipline and extracts substantial resources from the poor, producing new crises and new forms of dispossession.
Article
Most studies suggest that microcredit is beneficial but only to a limited extent. The problem lies not with microcredit but rather with microenterprises. With low skills, little capital and no scale economies, these businesses have low productivity and lead to meager earnings that cannot lift their owners out of poverty. Creating opportunities for steady employment at reasonable wages is the best way to take people out of poverty. The government is responsible for providing public services that are critical for increasing the productivity and the employability of the poor.
Article
This paper reports the results from a randomized evaluation of a microcredit program introduced in rural areas of Morocco starting in 2006 by Al Amana, the country’s largest microfinance institution. Al Amana was the only MFI operating in the study areas during the evaluation period. Thirteen percent of the households in treatment villages took a loan, and none in control villages. Among households identified as more likely to borrow based on ex-ante characteristics, microcredit access led to a significant rise in investment in assets used for self-employment activities (mainly animal husbandry and agriculture), and an increase in profit. But this increase in profit was offset by a reduction in income from casual labor, so overall there was no gain in measured income or consumption. We find suggestive evidence that these results are mainly driven by effects on borrowers, rather than by externalities on households that do not borrow. This implies that among those who chose to borrow, microcredit had large, albeit very heterogeneous, impacts on assets and profits from self-employment activities, but small impact on consumption: we can reject an increase in consumption of more than 10% among borrowers, two years after initial rollout.