ThesisPDF Available

Understanding the Block-Level Price Elasticity of On-Street Parking Demand: A Case Study of San Francisco's SFpark Project

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper explores the the determinants of on-street parking demand in an effort to provide a robust empirical model for estimating block-level demand sensitivity. The SFpark Project in San Francisco, which has implemented performance-based parking pricing since Aug. 2011, provides a unique setting in which to study these factors. First-order panel vector autoregression, i.e. pVAR(1), is implemented with controls for unobserved heterogeneity and serial correlation. Despite few structural specifications, no clear statistically significant relationships between parking occupancy and price emerge. The paper supports the conclusion that block-level price elasticities vary too widely to be reliably estimated using econometric modeling.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Shriver
1
Vanderbilt University
College of Arts & Science
Understanding the Block-Level Price Elasticity of On-Street Parking Demand:
A Case Study of San Francisco’s SFpark Project
Adam Shriver
Advised by Professor Malcolm Getz
shriver.adam.j@gmail.com
I greatly appreciate the guidance and thoughtful revisions of Professor Malcolm Getz through
every stage of the development of this project. I also thank Professor Joel Rodrigue for
numerous stimulating discussions and insightful comments.
1 May 2016
Shriver
2
Abstract
This paper explores the the determinants of on-street parking demand in an effort to
provide a robust empirical model for estimating block-level demand sensitivity. The SFpark
Project in San Francisco, which has implemented performance-based parking pricing since Aug.
2011, provides a unique setting in which to study these factors. First-order panel vector
autoregression, i.e. pVAR(1), is implemented with controls for unobserved heterogeneity and
serial correlation. Despite few structural specifications, no clear statistically significant
relationships between parking occupancy and price emerge. The paper supports the conclusion
that block-level price elasticities vary too widely to be reliably estimated using econometric
modeling.
I. Introduction
Parking plays a pivotal role in a city, shaping its spatial layout, facilitating (or hindering)
economic growth, and directly impacting the welfare of its residents (Shoup 1997, 2006).
Despite its importance, many of the fundamentals of the market for urban parking are little
understood by urban planners and transportation economists. In particular, what variables are
most influential in determining the demand for on-street parking? These important factors may
include location, time of day, day of the week, month of the year, availability of public transit
and off-street parking nearby, and land use in the surrounding area. This paper explores which,
if any, of these variables impact parking demand with the goal of providing urban planners more
reliable information regarding how parking prices should be set to maximize social welfare.
Unlike traditional competitive markets, the market for on-street parking does not have an
“invisible hand” to find the price that balances demand and supply. On-street parking is
Shriver
3
typically owned and controlled by the local government; however, there are instances where
local governments contract parking management out to private businesses. In particular,
Chicago controversially leased its parking meter system to a private group of investors in 2008
(Preston 2010). Some transportation economists discuss the plausibility of a monopolistically
competitive market for on-street parking with many private owners (Anderson and de Palma
2004).
Despite these alternative parking market structures, local government ownership of
parking systems prevails in the United States. Private monopoly, as in Chicago, leads to
overpriced and under-utilized parking systems due to the profit motive of the owner, which
diverges from policymakers’ goal of maximizing social welfare. Another approach would be for
the city to franchise parking to many small vendors, thus creating a monopolistically competitive
market. However, monopolistic competition with many small vendors would be difficult to
implement and sustain due to the spatial monopolies generated. If parking were franchised at too
high of a level, such as the city’s entire downtown financial district, there would be little
competition in that particular area due to the resulting spatial monopoly. For competition to
work, each parking district or neighborhood must have more parking vendors than would likely
be able to collude, which may require an unreasonable number of vendors. Moreover, the small
private vendors are unable to take advantage of the economies of scale associated with
maintaining parking systems. These economies of scale arise from investment in new pricing
software and technology, as well as employing parking patrol officers and keeping up with meter
and other technological maintenance. Consequently, this paper specifically studies city-owned
parking systems to better understand how urban planners should determine parking prices in
order to achieve socially optimal outcomes.
Shriver
4
Today, many cities use rigid hourly parking rates. These rates often do not vary by the
time of the day, day of the week, or even the location of a given parking space. For example, as
of December 2015 the City of Boston charges $1.25 per hour for any on-street parking space
between 8 a.m. and 8 p.m., Monday through Saturday, with no charge on Sunday (“Parking
Meters”). Frequently, meters stop operating after a specific time, often around 6 p.m., which is a
tradition retained from when most stores closed near that time and when meters had one or two
hour limits to promote turnover (Pierce and Shoup 2013). As a result, when there is a surge of
shoppers on a Friday evening, for example, the increased demand causes parking to be
underpriced since prices do not adjust to reflect the change in market conditions.
When the price of parking does not adequately reflect demand, externalities result that
negatively affect societal welfare. First consider the case where the price of parking is below the
market-clearing price (i.e. parking is underpriced). This may occur if there is a special event,
such as a concert or sporting event, that involves many drivers seeking parking spaces within a
narrow time interval within a relatively small area. Or, if the parking rate is flat all day, the mid-
afternoon may see a surge in demand due to an influx of people going out for lunch or to shop on
their lunch breaks. When most spaces are filled, drivers must “cruise” to find an open parking
space. Shoup (2006) found that out of 16 studies in large cities, the average percent of traffic
cruising for parking was 30 percent and the average time spent cruising was 8.1 minutes.
However, the standard deviation of these studies’ estimates is large, and Arnott and Inci (2006)
point out that the methods used in the individual studies were rudimentary and that the studies
are likely biased since researchers looked for cruising in locations where they expected to find
cruising. Despite these potential flaws, the studies strongly suggest that cruising is a major
consequence of underpriced parking.
Shriver
5
Cruising wastes individual drivers’ time and resources, adds to congestion, harms the
environment, and puts pedestrian and driver safety at risk. In a dense urban area, the cost of
cruising for each individual driver in terms of his or her time and money spent on fuel is
relatively insignificant. But aggregating this cost over all drivers in that area can give surprising
results. In a manner similar to Shoup (2006), consider a situation where the average time spent
cruising is 4 minutes. If 10 cars park in a particular space in a given day and there are 10 spaces
on a block, then that block generates 400 minutes of cruising per day. Now, if the average speed
while cruising is 10 mph, then over a year that block generates about 2,433 hours of cruising and
24,333 additional Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT). Arnott and Inci (2006) argue that a car
cruising for parking adds more to congestion than a car in transit. A cruising car is typically
moving slower than the throughput traffic, and the interaction between slow- and relatively fast-
moving cars causes more congestion than if all cars were travelling at the same speed (Verhoef,
Rouwendal, and Rietveld 1999). This affects not just automobile drivers, but also users of public
transit who are negatively impacted by slow-moving traffic. Besides adding to congestion, the
additional VMT increase emissions, resulting in lower air-quality and other potentially negative
long-term environmental effects. Finally, a little studied topic is cruising’s effect on pedestrian
and driver safety. Drivers cruising for parking are often distracted while looking for an open
space, which puts both pedestrians and drivers at risk of collisions. The SFpark Pilot Project
Evaluation (2014) cites safety improvement as one of the parking Project’s secondary benefits,
working through the mechanism that fewer distracted drivers cruising for parking reduces
collisions.
The other case of mispriced parking to consider is overpriced parking. Overpriced
parking occurs when rigid prices do not adjust downwards in order to compensate for periods of
Shriver
6
low demand. Pierce and Shoup (2013) argue that overpriced parking causes fewer drivers to
demand parking services than the socially desirable quantity. The consequence is detrimental to
the economic vitality of the surrounding area, since nearby businesses lose customers and hire
fewer employees. Moreover, the local government loses the opportunity to collect revenue on
those empty spaces.
An intriguing question arises regarding overpriced parking: would it ever be socially
desirable for parking to be overpriced? Suppose that the local government has the primary
objective of reducing traffic and that the implementation of roadway congestion pricing (i.e.
tolls) is not feasible. Since raising the price of parking can discourage automobile travel, the
local government may choose to raise parking prices beyond the equilibrium price in order to
reduce the number of automobile trips and consequently the amount of traffic in a particular area.
Compared with road pricing, parking pricing is comparatively easy to put into effect from an
administrative standpoint (parking pricing has fewer privacy concerns and does not require
additional legislation) and relatively inexpensive to implement since most cities have some type
of parking pricing infrastructure in place (Litman 2015). However, raising parking prices
beyond their equilibrium level to reduce traffic is still a second-best strategy for traffic control to
road pricing because it affects individual behavior indirectly and therefore does not affect
through traffic.
Given the presence of these externalities associated with the parking market, it is
desirable for the urban planner to set the price of parking such that marginal social benefits are
equated with marginal social costs (Arnott and Inci 2006). This is a basic problem from
microeconomics, but the solution is difficult to find and implement in practice. While supply is
easy to measure (simply count the number of spaces) in the short-run, what should the long-run
Shriver
7
socially optimal number of parking spaces be? This is a tricky question, since this quantity
should, to some extent, depend on the level of societal demand for parking. However, parking
demand is extremely difficult to measure directly for practical considerations (Shoup 1995). In
particular, for a particular price the quantity demanded of on-street parking on a given block
reflects how many vehicles would park on that block if there were sufficient supply (Ottosson et
al. 2013). But the “sufficient supply” assumption is often not met in practice when blocks are
full. This raises the following question: how can economists and urban planners determine if a
particular driver cruising for parking would actually park on a fully occupied block if there were
open spaces at the quoted price? This issue is layered on top of the practical difficulty of
distinguishing between throughput traffic and cars cruising for parking. Given these difficulties,
urban planners sometimes even make policy decisions (in particular, set minimum parking
requirements) by assuming that all parking is free and then roughly estimating demand based on
land use (Shoup 1995).
Another problem with estimating demand accurately is that the demand for on-street
parking is stochastic. Unpredictable random variables, such as the weather, may impact how
many drivers are seeking parking at a given point in time. On the other hand, urban planners can
try to forecast how many people will attend a non-random special event, such as a concert or a
sporting event, but their forecasts are simply estimates since the number of additional vehicles
seeking parking cannot be known with certainty ahead of time. Moreover, in the case of a
special event, there may be a “crowding out” effect on other vehicle trips; for example, if a
person wants to go downtown to shop on a Sunday afternoon but there is an NFL football game
that night taking place downtown, that person may choose to delay his or her trip to another day.
This means that the effect of a special event on parking demand is not purely additive. The
Shriver
8
extent of this crowding out is uncertain and cannot be perfectly predicted beforehand. As a
result, the randomness associated with parking demand adds another layer of difficulty for
determining prices.
In light of this uncertainty in demand measurement, transportation economists have
advocated “performance-based pricing,” also known as “demand-responsive pricing” (Ottosson
et al. 2013; Pierce and Shoup 2013). First define the occupancy rate of a block to be the percent
of parking spaces on that block that are occupied at a given point in time. An average occupancy
rate over an interval of time can easily be computed from a set of time-specific occupancy rates.
Typically, the target occupancy range is around 60 to 80 percent, as is the case in San Francisco,
so that there should always be one or two spaces open on every block. Other cities have also
implemented performance-based pricing using cutoffs near this range, such as Seattle, Los
Angeles, and Washington D.C. Some economists advocate a target occupancy of 85 percent
(Weinberger, Kaehny, and Rufo 2010). Under the performance-based pricing régime, urban
planners choose a target occupancy rate per block (typically a range of rates) and adjust prices up
or down until the target occupancy is reached. Ottosson et al. (2013) justify the use of
occupancy rates to adjust prices by arguing that occupancy rates are highly related to parking
demand and that occupancy rates can be used as an estimator of parking demand. Performance-
based pricing is appealing to planners because it renders directly estimating parking demand
unnecessary since occupancy rates are used to adjust prices.
Determining the optimal target occupancy range is difficult. If the range were 90 to 95
percent occupancy, blocks would often be completely full during peak periods of demand. In
addition, small stochastic fluctuations in demand would cause blocks to become entirely
occupied, such as a small surge in demand caused by a large party having dinner at a restaurant.
Shriver
9
On the other hand, the range should not be set too low (say at 30 to 50 percent) because nearby
businesses would lose customer traffic and some cruising would simply be shifted to surrounding
areas. The key to determining the appropriate target occupancy or occupancy range is to balance
the aforementioned tradeoffs between having overcrowded blocks with high targets and under-
occupied blocks with low targets. This is why the target range is typically near 60 to 80 percent,
ensuring that one or two spaces are always open on each block.
However, several additional issues regarding the implementation have yet to be
considered. These include how often prices should be changed, as well as at what increments
prices should be changed in order to reach the target occupancy range. Pierce and Shoup (2013)
posit that narrower intervals improve efficiency and ensure that target occupancy rates are met
more frequently. However, in order to answer the latter question regarding price adjustment
magnitudes, it is essential to be able to predict how occupancy rates will change in response to a
given change in price. For a given percentage change in price, what is the corresponding
percentage change in average occupancy rates? In economics terminology, it is necessary to
understand the price elasticity of on-street parking demand. If this measure is known, urban
planners can use it to adjust prices more accurately and, consequently, find the “right” price of
parking quicker (Ottosson et al. 2013).
There is strong empirical evidence that the price elasticity of parking demand varies
widely at the block level (Ottosson et al. 2013; Pierce and Shoup 2013). Key potential
determinants of the price elasticity of parking demand for a particular block include the time of
the day, day of the week, month of the year, location relative to driver’s destination, land use in
surrounding neighborhood, and availability of public transit and off-street parking. In order to
understand how the demand sensitivity to price varies by block, this paper presents and tests a
Shriver
10
model based on some of these variables using data from the SFpark Project. The particular
variable of interest in this paper is the location relative to the driver’s destination. To my
knowledge, this paper represents the first attempt to systematically model how distance between
a block and drivers’ destinations within a neighborhood affects the price elasticity of demand.
The SFpark Project is a cutting-edge project that has utilized performance-based pricing
to implement multiple block-level price changes since August 2011. The primary objective of
the Project is to improve parking availability, making it easier for drivers to find parking spaces
at all times of the day during each day of the week on any given block (SFMTA 2014). The San
Francisco Municipal Transportation Agency also cites reduction of cruising-related externalities
as secondary benefits of the Project (SFMTA 2014). Seven parking management districts
(PMD), i.e. neighborhoods, with varying characteristics are included in the Project, as well as
over a dozen city-managed parking garages. The Project utilizes new technologies to facilitate
highly accurate data collection on occupancy rates, overcoming the need to impute occupancy
from payment data. These data are made publically available online in an effort to promote
transparency and stimulate research. This is an ideal setting for decomposing the price elasticity
of parking demand by its principle determinants and, in particular, modeling the spatial variation
of demand sensitivity to price.
II. Literature Review
As noted previously, the economics of urban parking literature is thin. There have been
several empirical studies of how employer parking-pricing policies affect commuter mode choice
in the United States (Shoup 1997; Washbrook, Haider, and Jaccard 2006; Hamre and Buehler
2014; Ommeren and Russo 2014). An increase in the price of parking is an increase in the cost
Shriver
11
of individual automobile travel. Essentially, these studies are therefore estimating how
substitutable commuters find single-occupancy automobile vehicle travel and carpooling, public
transit, biking, or walking to work. Another notable study by Donald Shoup (1999) studies
minimum parking requirements and analyzes their effects on land use, congestion, and the
environment.
Several theoretical modeling attempts have been made to understand various aspects of
the parking market. Arnott and Inci (2006) model the interaction between cars cruising for
parking and cars in transit. Arnott and Rowse (2009) present an expanded model that
incorporates the availability of off-street parking, concluding that local governments should raise
on-street parking rates in order to effect efficiency gains and raise revenue. There have also been
modeling exercises that capture stochastic variation in parking demand (Arnott and Rowse 1999;
Qian and Rajagopal 2014). Anderson and de Palma (2004) consider a long, narrow city with
parallel access roads, and Anderson and de Palma (2007) use a monocentric model with discrete
zones based on the distance from the center. Both of these attempts incorporate distance from
the center of the city as a key variable in the analysis.
However, these theoretical studies often run into problems due to lack of reliable
empirical information regarding key parameters in their models. For example, Arnott and Inci
(2006) take for granted -0.2 as an estimate for the price elasticity of travel demand during peak
periods. This parameter value is then used in the remainder of the numerical analysis without the
authors justifying its use beyond positing that it is a “standard estimate” (without reference).
Anderson and de Palma (2004) do not mention the price elasticity of demand for parking, nor its
potential spatial variation. However, these authors’ assumptions regarding price elasticities of
Shriver
12
parking are not a sign of a lack of rigor; instead, they indicate the dire need for additional
empirical evidence regarding the determinants of parking demand sensitivity.
There is a limited body of existing literature on price elasticities of parking demand,
although relatively recent technological advancements have spurred transportation economists to
begin to more closely study this topic. Even within the last decade, researchers have used meter
payment data to estimate how many cars parked in each space during a day, but since not all
drivers comply to payment requirements, this simply gives an estimate of occupancy. Now, in-
ground parking sensors can be used to precisely determine how many hours of the day any given
parking space is occupied. Moreover, “smart meters” facilitate payment and ease of use for
drivers, consequently increasing payment compliance rates. When compliance rates are higher,
pricing strategies are more effective. If a driver is going to park in a space but not pay regardless
of the price, no pricing structure will influence that driver’s behavior. These new technologies
aid parking meter enforcement, reducing the cost of hiring Parking Control Officers (SFMTA
2014). Finally, the real-time data provided by these instruments is time and location specific,
which enables urban planners and transportation economists to perform rigorous analysis and
make data-driven decisions (SFMTA 2014).
Outside the United States, Kelly and Clinch (2009) study the block-level price elasticity
of demand of on-street parking in the central district of Dublin, Ireland, and derive an average
estimate of -0.29. The same study also suggests temporal variation in price elasticities, with
demand being more sensitive in the morning and less sensitive in the afternoon and at night.
However, a shortcoming of this study is that it does not report standard errors for its price
elasticity of demand estimates, which are computed using the arc elasticity formula and adjusted
Shriver
13
for changes in average income over time. The lack of reported standard errors hides potentially
large block-level variability in elasticities.
To my knowledge, the first block-level study of the price elasticity of demand of on-
street parking in the United States was conducted by Ottosson et al. (2013) using data from a
single, neighborhood-level price adjustment near Downtown Seattle. Each neighborhood
contained multiple blocks. The price adjustment was determined using a combination of the
neighborhoods’ previous peak period occupancy and average occupancy rates, with target
occupancy between 71 and 86 percent. Block elasticities varied based on the time of day, with
demand being most elastic in the morning and most inelastic mid-day. The study finds also that
as a block’s distance increases from the core of the Central Business District (CBD), parking
demand becomes more sensitive. In neighborhoods with price increases, public transit
availability had a significant negative effect on occupancy rates. Surprisingly, the price of off-
street parking did not have a significant effect on occupancy rates.
Several problems arise in the Ottosson et al. (2013) analysis. In particular, only one price
change was studied. All analysis, as a result, was conditioned on whether a particular block had
a price increase, decrease, or no change. This prevents direct, reliable comparison (without
additional assumptions) between a block that had a price increase and another that had a
decrease. Moreover, occupancy rates were estimated based on meter payment data. This carries
the implicit assumption that payment compliance is uniform over space. If a certain block is
more heavily patrolled by Payment Compliance Officers, then compliance should be higher on
that block. This would cause the price change to have a larger effect on the high-compliance
block than a similar price change on a low-compliance block. If payment compliance varies in
some systematic way, especially if it is correlated with distance from the center of the CBD
Shriver
14
(which is a likely possibility), then the analysis cannot definitively attribute price elasticity
variation to distance from the urban core.
In the same year as Ottosson et al. (2013), Pierce and Shoup utilized data from the
SFpark Project to study the block-level price elasticities of on-street parking demand. The
SFpark dataset has a distinct advantage over the Seattle data used in Ottosson et al.: SFpark
tracks many performance-based price changes, occurring approximately every two to three
months, as well as the corresponding changes in block-level occupancy. Additionally, SFpark
uses in-ground sensors to directly observe occupancy rates, rather than imputing occupancy rates
based on meter payment (SFMTA 2014). The study found that price elasticities varied by
neighborhood, time of day, day of the week, initial price, magnitude of price change, and date of
price change. As a result of this observation, Pierce and Shoup conclude that “planners will
never be able to develop a robust theoretical model to predict the correct prices needed to
achieve the target occupancy for every block” (2013). However, a considerable factor
undermining this conclusion is the study’s lack of analytical rigor. Pierce and Shoup simply
observe that elasticities vary greatly and are related to many variables, and they jump to the
conclusion that there is not a systematic way to model how these variables interact to determine
price elasticities. Furthermore, they do not address the availability of public transit or off-street
parking prices, as well as location of blocks relative to likely driver destinations (i.e. block
distance from center of neighborhood).
The above commentary reveals a discrepancy in the existing literature. Ottosson et al.
(2013) maintain that transportation economists can rigorously model parking demand sensitivity
to predict future occupancy rates based on price changes, while Pierce and Shoup (2013) claim
that this prediction process is not possible since block-level elasticities vary so greatly. Instead,
Shriver
15
Pierce and Shoup advocate a trial-and-error process for determining prices that achieve
occupancy goals. This paper seeks to address this disagreement in the literature.
III. Methodology
Study Setting
The City of San Francisco has experienced considerable growth moving out of the Great
Recession in terms of population and economic viability. From 2011 to 2013, San Francisco’s
citywide population grew an average of 1% per year with average growth in real metropolitan
GDP of 2% per year (author’s calculation) during the same time period (SFMTA 2014; BEA
2015). Growth in real metropolitan GDP skyrocketed in 2014, reaching 5.2% and more than
doubling the national average of 2.3% (BEA 2015).
These demographic and economic changes in San Francisco have had interesting
influences on transportation demand. As of 2014, San Francisco-Oakland is ranked by
researchers from The Texas A&M Transport Institute and INRIX, Inc. to be the third most
congested metropolitan area in the United States, most notably ahead of New York, Boston, and
Chicago (Schrank et al. 2014). Vehicle miles traveled to and from San Francisco decreased by
approximately 5% per year from 2011 to 2013; weekday BART ridership (the heavy-rail system
servicing the San Francisco Bay Area) to and from San Francisco increased by 7% per year over
the same time period (SFMTA 2014). These data suggest that commuters from outside San
Francisco have shifted away from driving automobiles to work in favor of utilizing public transit.
However, it is surprising that automobile ownership in San Francisco increased one-to-one with
citywide population from 2011 to 2013, adding 16,000 cars to the city (SFMTA 2014).
Shriver
16
A possible explanation of this phenomenon is that wealthier individuals, who are able to
afford the extraordinarily expensive housing in the heart of San Francisco, moved into the city
during this time period, bringing their cars with them. Then, the increased congestion and
demand for parking within San Francisco may have discouraged workers from outside the city
from commuting by car, thus shifting their demand to public transit systems. This becomes a
plausible story when one considers the growth of the technology industry in Silicon Valley.
Many of the recent employees at growing tech companies, such as Facebook, are young and
mobile, choosing to live outside the city limits in order to avoid monumental housing costs
within the city. These young, reasonably wealthy commuters often utilize public transit services,
such as BART, rather than owning cars in order to avoid the headaches of traffic and parking in
the city. High traffic and parking costs have induced some large tech companies to offer their
workers subsidies to relocate closer to the city. Notably, Facebook has begun to offer a $10,000
or more subsidy to workers who relocate near the Facebook headquarters in South San Francisco
(Lam 2015).
As discussed in the Introduction, cruising is a major problem associated with mispriced
urban parking. When parking access is not readily available, drivers waste time and money
searching for open spaces. This increases congestion, harms the environment, and poses safety
risks to drivers and pedestrians. In response to worsening traffic conditions and decreasing
parking availability in recent years, the San Francisco Municipal Transportation Agency
(SFMTA) launched the SFpark Project in August 2011. Under this unique project, the SFMTA
implemented performance-based pricing for on-street parking in 7 Parking Management Districts
(PMDs), i.e. neighborhoods, and for off-street parking in 14 garages (SFMTA 2014). The
SFMTA operates San Francisco’s public transit system, roads, on-street parking, and a
Shriver
17
significant amount of its off-street parking. The primary goal of this project was to improve
parking availability, with secondary benefits being reduced cruising and its associated
externalities (SFMTA 2014).
As a part of the project, the SFMTA developed and tested cutting-edge technologies.
StreetSmart Technologies, now known as Fybr, installed and maintained in-ground sensors
starting in September 2010 (SFMTA 2014). These parking sensors provide real-time occupancy
data on individual spaces by detecting the presence of a parked car regardless of whether or not
the meter is paid. This overcomes one of the major difficulties in the Ottosson et al. (2013) study
that relied on meter payment data to estimate occupancy. New “smart” parking meters were also
installed for the Project from July 2011 to January 2012 in an effort to facilitate payment and
increase payment compliance, as well as enable wireless communications and updates that
allowed for programmed price changes according to occupancy rates (SFMTA 2014). These
meters accept credit cards, as opposed to traditional coin- and cash-only meters. The wireless
communication of these new technologies also laid the groundwork for the creation of an SFpark
mobile app. The app uses real-time data to inform drivers seeking parking where there are open
spaces and what the hourly rates are at those spaces. It has become widely-used, with 73,500
downloads from iPhone and Android users as of July 2013 (SFMTA 2014). The data collected
by these technologies is available on the SFpark.org website for public use, as well as the source
code for their software. This is part of an organized effort to promote data-driven parking
management decisions and encourage novel research to inform policy.
The SFpark Project is an ideal setting for evaluating performance-based pricing. Parking
prices vary at the block level by time of day and weekday/weekend. Each day is segmented into
three time bands: morning (open to 12 p.m., where opening time varies by PMD and is usually
Shriver
18
around 9 p.m.), afternoon (12 p.m. to 3 p.m.), and evening (3 p.m. to close, where closing time
varies by PMD and is usually around 6 p.m.). Parking is free overnight, i.e. from closing to
opening time. As of January 2016, there are two classes of days: weekdays (Monday through
Friday) and weekend days (Saturday and Sunday).
Prices are updated approximately every two months in response to observed average
occupancy rates during the previous two-month period. The target occupancy range is 60 to 80
percent. Average occupancy over 80 percent indicates a $0.25 hourly increase; between 60 and
80 percent, no change; between 30 and 60 percent, $0.25 hourly decrease; and less than 30
percent, $0.50 hourly decrease. During the day, rates cannot fall below $0.25 or exceed $6.00
per hour.
To illustrate this pricing system, consider Beach Street 500 in Fisherman’s Wharf from
12:00 to 3:00 p.m. on the weekend. From October 2011 to December 2011, the price of parking
on this street was $3.25 and the average occupancy was 84%. This indicates a $0.25 hourly price
increase on this street from 12:00 to 3:00 p.m. on weekends, resulting in a new price of $3.50 per
hour. During the next period, from December 2011 to February 2012, the occupancy declined
slightly to 83%. This indicates another incremental increase of $0.25 per hour, giving a new
price of $3.75 per hour. This trial-and-error process is designed so that prices adjust according to
observed occupancy during the previous period until target occupancy goals are reached.
Ideally, prices will be adjusted such that target occupancy will eventually be met every day, in
every time band, and on every block.
To perform a qualitative review of the effectiveness of the performance-based pricing
system, the SFMTA conducted a pilot project of SFpark from late 2011 to mid-2013, making a
total of ten price adjustments. Performance-based pricing as outlined above was instituted in
Shriver
19
seven “pilot” Parking Management Districts with varying characteristics and geographic
locations. During this time period, two control Parking Management Districts with no price
changes were tracked. These control PMDs were added in order to mitigate the influence of
possible confounding factors, such as city growth, increased transportation demand, and other
demographic shifts. Before undergoing the pilot project, payment compliance was measured on
each block by comparing in-ground sensor data with meter payment data. Assuming payment
compliance remains constant over time, these data can be used to analyze the relative efficacy of
price changes in high payment versus low payment neighborhoods. A high payment block, or
“HP block”, is one in which 85 percent or more of the hours parked on that block were paid for
(SFMTA 2014).
As expected, qualitative analysis has shown that the performance-based pricing was
highly effective over that time period. First let a “full” block be a block with, on average, 90 to
100 percent of spaces occupied. Pilot HP blocks were full 45 percent less often than before the
project began, and other pilot blocks were full 16 percent less often. In contrast, control blocks
were full 51 percent more often (SFMTA 2014). This statistic also suggests that the pricing
régime was more effective in high payment blocks. The pilot blocks performed better than
control blocks on a number of categories, such as average time spent cruising, greenhouse gas
emissions, number of citations, congestion, and traffic volume and speed. Pilot HP blocks also
experienced greater improvements than other pilot blocks in percent of time meeting target
occupancy goals and percent of time at full occupancy (SFMTA 2014).
The above qualitative considerations strongly suggest that SFpark was effective during
the pilot project. This has led the SFMTA to continue the SFpark Project, which continues to be
in effect as of January 2016. Nevertheless, several aspects of SFpark require improvement.
Shriver
20
Pierce and Shoup (2013) argue that SFpark should refine its time periods and take a proactive
approach in predicting future occupancy rather than implementing price changes based solely on
the previous period’s occupancy. Narrower time bands, as well as later meter hours, would
improve the amount of time that target occupancy is met. Furthermore, seasonal effects should
be considered when adjusting prices. Just because occupancy rates are high in December due to
the holiday and shopping season does not indicate that parking prices should be raised in
January. In general, a more thorough understanding of the determinants of parking demand
would allow planners to estimate future demand by means other than simply relying on past
occupancy rates.
In order to accomplish the shift from reaction to prediction, a more developed
investigation of the price elasticity of on-street parking demand is necessary. If planners do not
understand how sensitive parking demand is to price, how can they possibly predict the hourly
price required to reach the desired target occupancy?
Data Set
The data set is arranged as panel time-series (longitudinal) data. Each city block in
SFpark constitutes a panel, and each price change corresponds to a time period. There are
N=256 blocks in the SFpark data set, and there have been T=17 price changes as of January
2016. I refer to an “observation” as all data measures associated with block i at time t. SFpark
contributes 12 measurements per observation: price per hour during the period in the morning,
afternoon, and evening, as well as average occupancy during the period in the morning,
afternoon, and evening. These measures are supplied for both weekdays (Monday through
Friday) and weekends (Saturday and Sunday). I use the term “morning” to designate opening
time to noon, “afternoon” to indicate noon to 3 p.m., and “evening” to denote 3 p.m. to 6 p.m.
Shriver
21
Some blocks have a fourth “night” time period that runs from 6 p.m. to close, but I exclude these
night periods from the sample due to the relatively small number of measurements that fall into
this category (254 out of 4,353). Observations begin in August 2011 and end in December 2015.
Note that weekend observations before 2013 only represent Saturday price and occupancy data
because San Francisco only began to charge parking fees for Sunday parking during the first
weekend of January 2013 (Baker 2013).
While each time period on average lasts approximately three months, there is
considerable variation in the length of time between price changes. The shortest period lasted
only one month, while the longest period lasted almost a full year (10 months). In stark contrast
to the transparent, rule-oriented pricing rules, the rules about when price changes are
implemented are unclear. This creates a potential source of endogeneity for the econometrician:
are prices changed when urban planners begin to account for potential future demand influences?
For example, suppose BART needs major repairs, and construction will begin in six months and
last for up to a year. Such an occurrence may reduce the accessibility of public transit, thus
shifting mode choice toward automobile travel and increasing the demand for parking.
Expecting this change in transportation demand, urban planners may decide to implement a price
change just as construction begins and just after the increased surge in demand, say in 6 months
and 7 months from today, respectively. The first price change “resets” the average occupancy
measurement so that the increased occupancy during the 6 to 7-month time frame is not diluted
by lower average occupancy rates before the construction. Therefore, the average occupancy
rate over the 6 to 7-month period fully reflects the increased demand for parking induced by the
construction. This example serves to illustrate that the choice of time periods is likely not
random in the SFpark Project, and as a result, each price change not only reflects the previous
Shriver
22
period’s average occupancy but also planners’ expectations of future parking demand. Despite
this observation, the remainder of this paper will treat the time periods as having been imposed
deterministically, without regard to expectations of future conditions. Without further
information about how time periods are selected, this assumption is necessary for data analysis.
The results will be interpreted with caution given this underlying assumption. It is appropriate to
point out that the average time period length without the 10-month outlier is still 3 months.
In addition to the data provided by the SFMTA, I have gathered additional data
pertaining to distance in order to perform analysis. I estimated the physical center of each of the
7 PMDs as they are laid out in the “SFpark: Pilot Project Evaluation” but with two key
exceptions: the bordering Downtown and South Embarcadero districts. I reallocated the blocks
in the southern portion of the Downtown district to the South Embarcadero district to force land
usage, distance, and parking district to better coincide. The center of the modified Downtown
district is determined based on borders that more closely resemble the Financial District
displayed on Google Maps, and the center of the modified South Embarcadero district is actually
closer to many of the reallocated blocks than the center of the modified Downtown district is.
The original and modified Downtown and South Embarcadero districts are depicted in Figure 1.
Shriver
23
Figure 1. Modified Districts: Downtown and South Embarcadero
Notes: The red and green dashed lines encompass the unmodified financial district and South
Embarcadero (SE) district, respectively. The black and blue lines encompass the modified
financial district and SE district, respectively, with their estimated centers denoted by stars.
The “center” of each PMD was determined as the centroid of the physical area
encompassed by the blocks in the neighborhood. Suppose each block is a point of mass (each
with uniform density) in the two-dimensional plane. Averaging the horizontal and vertical
measurements gives the coordinate of the centroid of the neighborhood. Determining the center
of each PMD allows for the measurement of the network grid distance from the midpoint of each
block to the center of the PMD. These distances were measured using Google Maps, and the
distance was recorded as the shortest walking distance in kilometers. One distance measurement
was taken for each of the 256 blocks. All distances are greater than zero.
Public transit is not included in this data set. Visual inspection of the PMDs using
Google Maps suggests that public transit stops are (reasonably) uniformly spread over space
within the districts. Many of the blocks have well over 20 public transit stops within a 500m
radius. Due to the lack of variation in public transit accessibility points, this variable is assumed
Shriver
24
to have a uniform effect on all blocks. Additionally, the price of off-street parking is not
included in the analysis since Ottosson et al. find it to have no effect on on-street occupancy
rates. If these assumptions do not hold and the number of transit accessibility stops or the price
or availability of off-street parking are correlated with distance from the center, then the results
of the regression analysis will be biased due to omitted variables. Potential bias is further
addressed in the Discussion.
Model
With many panels and relatively few time periods, the data are most readily analyzed
with micro-panel techniques (“Panel time-series modeling”). Specifically, I utilize a first-order
panel vector auto-regression model, i.e. pVAR(1), implemented with Stata programs created by
Abrigo and Love (2015). The first-order model was selected based on model-fit criteria
proposed by Andrews and Lu (2001). Appendix B.1 describes the selection process of the lag-
order of the pVAR model in detail. The model can be represented as
!"#$ % &!"#$'( ) *+,"#$ ) -") ."#$
(1)
where !"#$ is a 6x1 vector of the natural logarithm of average occupancy rates (expressed as
percentages, all of which are greater than 0 and less than or equal to 100) at different times of the
day on weekdays and weekends on block i during time period t. & is a 6x6 matrix of time-
invariant parameters that are estimated, and !"#$'( is a 6x1 vector of the natural logarithm of
lagged average occupancy rates; -" is a 6x1 vector of dependent variable-specific fixed-effects
errors; and ."#$ is a 6x1 vector of idiosyncratic error terms.
,"#$ is a time-variant column vector of exogenous variables that can be expanded as
follows
Shriver
25
/
0$
1 23"#$
450/"+3"#$
1(#" 674 +3"#$
8
19#" 674 +3"#$
(2)
where / is a linear time trend and 0$ is a 4x1 vector representing the “weighted-average season.”
The linear time trend controls for linear changes in on-street parking demand over time that
impact all blocks. Since the time periods are irregular, controlling for seasonal effects is not a
straight-forward task. To deal with this issue, I let March through May be spring months; June
through August be summer months; September through November be fall months; and
December through February be winter months. If a time period spans multiple seasons, then I
count the number of months of the period that fall in each season to allocate the time period
across the season (by proportion). The sum of the seasonal terms must therefore equal 1.
Next, 3"#$ is a 6x1 vector of the natural logarithm of the hourly price of parking at
different times of the day on weekdays and weekends on block i during time period t. 1 23"#$
is a 6x1 vector of dummy variables defined as follows
1
:23"#$ % + ;# 3"#$ < 3"#$'( = >
># 3"#$ < 3"#$'( % > ++++++? % ;#…,6
(3)
In plain words, 1
:23"#$ represents whether or not there was a change in price from t-1 to t on
block i and is calculated for each time zone (i.e. time of day, day of week). Following Ottosson
et al. (2013), the inclusion of this term establishes a control group—a group of blocks with
constant price between over the time interval—against which blocks with price changes can be
compared.
Shriver
26
450/"+3"#$ is simply the distance of block i from the center of its associated PMD (in km)
multiplied by the price vector, 3"#$ . The estimated coefficient on 450/"+3"#$ represents the change
in price elasticity associated with a 1 kilometer increase in distance from the center of the PMD.
1@#" 674 equals 1 if block i belongs to PMD k and is 0 otherwise, where k=1,…,5.
1@#" 674 +3"#$ represents the interaction between PMD and the price vector. The estimated
coefficient on 1@#" 674 +3"#$ represents the price elasticity of on-street parking demand for PMD
k if 450/"=0.
Here I note that k=1,…,5 since the preferred model excludes the Marina and Mission
PMDs due to numerical considerations. The omission of these two PMDs leaves 5 remaining
PMDs for estimation, which have a total of 209 blocks. The decision to exclude these
neighborhoods does not have a significant impact on any of the main results, but the elasticity
estimates break down for these particular neighborhoods due to large estimates (in magnitude)
and large standard deviations on their 1@#" 674 +3"#$ slope coefficients. This issue and potential
causes will be further addressed in the Model Results subsection.
An assumption in the analysis is that 450/" is a time-invariant scalar. A case in which this
assumption may not hold is if new commercial developments are implemented asymmetrically
on one edge of a PMD over time during the SFpark Project. If the SFMTA installs additional
meters near the development, then the regression analysis could be performed before and after
the natural experiment with an updated center utilized after the change. This paper does not take
this approach since to my knowledge, no such information regarding meters installed due to
commercial development is available. If asymmetric development occurs but the SFMTA does
not install additional meters, then the “real” center of the neighborhood may shift despite the
observed center (based on SFpark block inclusion data) not moving. However, this fundamental
Shriver
27
alteration in the system would not be reflected in the data. This would lead to biased parameter
estimates and would obscure the role of distance in the system.
It is important to notice that the model does not include interactions between distance and
PMD. In other words, I assume that the effect of distance is constant across neighborhoods.
This assumption is imposed for practical purposes. Initial regressions were performed including
this interaction, but the number of parameters in the model was so large that reliable parameter
estimates were not attainable. As more data from SFpark become available, this may be a
fruitful relationship to further explore.
In the absence of readily available natural experiments, such as some supply shock or
some other externally induced change to the environment, including the lagged dependent
variable as a regressor is often the best approach to dealing with the possible joint determination
of price and quantity that often presents a barrier to this type of regression analysis. Under the
assumptions that price changes are entirely determined by the previous period’s occupancy and
that their timing is independent of expectations of future market conditions, it is valid to include
the price vector 3"#$ as exogenous regressors after “conditioning” on lagged occupancies !"#$'(.
Ottosson et al. (2013) approaches this issue in a similar way, using a first-order autoregressive,
i.e. AR(1), model to account for possible endogeneity. They posit that the inclusion of lagged
occupancy as a regressor ensures that “any measured influence of the interest … price elasticity
in our case … is conditioned on this history and represents the effect of the new information
(price change)” (Ottosson et al. 2013).
While the inclusion of lagged dependent terms on the right-hand side of System 1 reduces
concerns of joint-determination of occupancy and price, it presents the need for sophisticated
econometric tools to mitigate bias in estimating system parameters. It has been shown that
Shriver
28
significant bias still remains when using an equation-by-equation OLS approach to estimating a
system of equations with lagged dependent variables used as regressors, even with large N
(Nickell 1981) or T as large as 30 (Judson and Owen 1999). Due to this consideration, I jointly
estimate System (1) using the pVAR package of programs in Stata in order to avoid bias in my
results (Abrigo and Love 2015).
Dependent variable-specific fixed effects errors, -", are removed using forward
orthogonal deviations (FOD). Under this method, the mean of all future observations in the
block is subtracted from the observation at time t (Baum 2013). I utilize this method in order to
preserve as large of a sample size as possible with the goal of improving estimation reliability.
The data set is unbalanced (contains gaps), so a method such as taking first differences (FD)
magnifies the gaps in the data and further reduces the sample size. Utilizing forward orthogonal
deviations dramatically reduces this loss of data while effectively controlling for unobserved
heterogeneity at the block level and eliminating the omitted-variable bias associated with -".
Sensitivity analysis shows that parameter estimates are sensitive to choice of FOD or FD. The
preferred model utilizes FOD for the reasons cited above.
The first four lags of the dependent variables are used as moment conditions in estimating
the pVAR(1) model (see Appendix B.1 for details on the selection of moment conditions). Since
the panels are unbalanced, I replace missing observations with zero, as recommended by Holtz-
Eakin, Newey, and Rosen (1988). This substitution is valid under the standard assumption that
the instruments are uncorrelated with the error terms (Abrigo and Love 2015). The econometric
gain from the substitution is an increase in the number of observations and panels that can be
utilized for model estimation.
Shriver
29
Under panel vector auto-regression, idiosyncratic error terms are assumed to be serially
uncorrelated with mean zero, and the contemporaneous covariance matrix is assumed to be
positive semi-definite (Abrigo and Love 2015). Model estimation is robust to heteroskedasticity.
In the analysis, I relax the assumption that idiosyncratic error terms are serially uncorrelated
within blocks by clustering ."#$ at the block level. That is, errors may be dependent within blocks
but not across blocks. Kézdi (2004) shows that N>50 is sufficient to use cluster-robust standard
error (CRSE) estimation at little to no cost, even in the absence of error clustering. Since the
number of blocks under study is much greater than 50, I confidently use CRSE estimation.
Moreover, blocks are assumed to be independent. This is a strong assumption for this
study, since it is likely that there is spatial correlation between blocks. However, the distance
term interacted with price will control for this spatial relationship between the blocks. An
alternative approach would be to substitute the distance-price term with a weighted matrix that
controls for the distance between each block (Ottosson et al. 2013; “Panel time-series
modeling”).
Descriptive Statistics
Table 1 contains descriptive statistics of the data set. A graphical representation of the
occupancy statistics for each time period, not just the first and most recent periods, can be found
in Appendix A.1 for each combination of time of day and day of week.
Shriver
30
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Occupancy and Price
Weekdays
Weekends
Morning
Afternoon
Evening
Morning
Afternoon
Evening
Variable:
Mean
S.D.
Mean
S.D.
Mean
S.D.
Mean
S.D.
Mean
S.D.
Mean
S.D.
Avg. Occupancy Aug. 2011 (%)
61.52
19.39
72.59
16.60
69.38
16.67
51.58
23.48
66.63
22.51
67.70
20.19
Avg. Occupancy Dec. 2015 (%)
63.68
12.84
67.96
12.43
67.62
11.71
58.20
13.89
68.41
15.02
68.39
14.03
Avg. Occupancy Change (%)
2.16
-
-4.63
-
-1.76
-
6.62
-
1.78
-
0.69
-
Price Aug. 2011 ($/hr)
2.87
0.61
2.87
0.61
2.87
0.61
2.87
0.61
2.87
0.61
2.87
0.61
Price Dec. 2015 ($/hr)
1.90
1.46
3.23
1.43
2.82
1.54
1.16
1.28
2.78
1.88
2.70
1.95
Price Change ($/hr)
-0.97
-
0.36
-
-0.05
-
-1.71
-
-0.09
-
-0.17
-
Notes: Based on the prices and average occupancy rates by time of day and day of week of 205 blocks.
Shriver
31
There are several striking features of Table 1. First, average occupancy rates vary widely
by time of day and day of the week. In Aug. 2011, occupancy was lowest on weekend mornings
and highest on weekday afternoons. After 17 price changes, by Dec. 2015 occupancy was still
lowest on weekend mornings but had increased by over 6 percentage points, moving it closer to
the target range of 60 to 80 percent. Also, weekday afternoon occupancy had decreased by more
than 4 percentage points, narrowing the gap between its average occupancy and the other time
periods’ average occupancies.
Even more striking is the decrease in the standard deviation of average occupancy rates
across blocks from Aug. 2011 to Dec. 2015 for all times and days. The price changes appear to
have squeezed more neighborhoods into the target occupancy range, reducing the number of
outliers (i.e. blocks with very high or very low occupancy rates) and, more generally, the number
of blocks not meeting occupancy goals. This finding does not mean that the occupancy rate on
any particular block is more stable; it means that overall variability in average occupancy rates
across blocks decreases through performance-based price changes. Ottosson et al. (2013) also
report decreased standard deviations after the performance-based price change in Seattle, but
since their study was conducted over the course of just one year and based on a single price
change, the change in standard deviation is small enough (less than 2% in all cases) that the
researchers did not mention the reduced standard deviation in their analysis. This is a novel
result from this paper: performance-based pricing appears to decrease the variability in average
occupancy rates across blocks through time and subsequent price changes.
The average hourly price of parking was $2.87 for all times and days in Aug. 2011 before
the first price change. The reason for this is that the price on each block did not change by time
of day; in other words, prices were completely rigid at the block level. Variation did occur
Shriver
32
across blocks, resulting in non-zero standard deviation in each time zone. To achieve the
average weekend morning occupancy increase of 6.62 percentage points, prices were lowered an
average of $1.71, which is about a 60 percent decrease from their original level. Similarly, the
price was raised $0.36 on average to reduce average weekday afternoon occupancy rates by 4.63
percentage points.
Unlike the decrease in standard deviation over time of occupancy rates, the standard
deviation of prices rose with time. Blocks started out at a few predetermined, rigid rates, and
subsequent incremental adjustments caused their distribution to spread out. In Dec. 2015, the
standard deviation in price ranges from $1.28 during the weekend mornings to $1.95 weekend
evenings. Price distribution histograms by time of day and day of week can be found in
Appendix A.2.
Both occupancy and price show more variability on the weekends than on the weekdays
both in Aug. 2011 and Dec. 2015. A possible explanation for this phenomenon is that some
shops are closed on the weekends, especially weekend mornings. This may lead to reduced
parking demand on blocks near such closed shops, but nearby blocks with fewer or no closings
do not experience this drop in demand. On the other hand, shops are likely more consistently
open during the weekdays, reducing this effect on the weekdays. As a result, occupancy rates
are more likely to show greater variability on weekends than on weekdays. Since price
adjustments are based on observed occupancy, it is not surprising then that the larger variability
in occupancy rates across blocks during the weekends forces the prices to spread out more over
time relative to weekday prices.
Finally, if the SFpark Project is successfully moving individual blocks towards the
“right” price through incremental price changes, then one would expect more and more blocks to
Shriver
33
fall in the target occupancy range over time. An alternative way to look at this is that fewer
blocks would be expected to required price changes during each subsequent time period. Indeed,
this is generally what has happened in SFpark, as shown in Figure 2 below.
Figure 2. Number of Price Changes Over Time
After the first 6 price changes, the general trend in number of price changes appears to be
downwards, which supports the efficacy of SFpark’s pricing strategy.
Shriver
34
Model Results
Table 2. Parameter Estimation of Auto-Regressive Component (Matrix A in Sys. 1)
Natural Logarithm of Lagged Occupancy at Time t - 1
Weekdays
Weekends
Morning
Afternoon
Evening
Morning
Afternoon
Evening
Natural Logarithm of Occupancy
at Time t
Weekdays
Morning
0.519***
(0.114)
0.272*
(0.144)
-0.062
(0.112)
-0.013
(0.045)
-0.023
(0.053)
0.003
(0.060)
Afternoon
0.092
(0.085)
0.542***
(0.133)
-0.019
(0.090)
-0.010
(0.040)
0.028
(0.040)
0.028
(0.048)
Evening
-0.020
(0.109)
0.227
(0.171)
0.428***
(0.115)
0.023
(0.039)
-0.017
(0.053)
0.025
(0.061)
Weekends
Morning
-0.028
(0.252)
-0.008
(0.375)
0.244
(0.274)
0.145*
(0.088)
-0.226***
(0.084)
0.115
(0.119)
Afternoon
0.043
(0.264)
0.447
(0.400)
-0.289
(0.279)
0.072
(0.088)
-0.238**
(0.099)
0.143
(0.113)
Evening
0.054
(0.247)
0.319
(0.423)
-0.165
(0.353)
0.105
(0.080)
-0.355***
(0.103)
0.285**
(0.114)
Notes: Based on 2,514 observations, 205 panels, average number of T=12.263; the exogenous
variables, as well as 4 lags of the dependent variable, were used as instruments for the pVAR(1)
model; Hansen’s J-statistic for the overall model was 87.20 with 108 degrees of freedom giving a
p-value of 0.929; FOD used to control for unobserved heterogeneity; *, **, and *** indicate
significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 2 reports the estimated coefficients of Matrix A in System 1. Recall that forward
orthogonal deviations are utilized to control for unobserved heterogeneity rather than first
differences. This significantly impacts the interpretation of these results. The parameters in
Table 2 capture the extent to which lagged occupancy during time t-1 is linearly correlated with
occupancy at time t during different times of the day and days of the week after removing
dependent variable-specific fixed effects at the block level. Using FOD, a positive, statistically
significant coefficient along the main diagonal indicates that !"#$%& is positively linearly
correlated with !"#$ during the particular time of day and day of the week corresponding to the
row and column label.
In general, for autoregressive models to be stable, the estimated coefficients on lagged
terms should be less than one in absolute value. This precludes the possibility of self-
Shriver
35
perpetuating effects in the system that amplify in magnitude over time rather than diminish. For
example, if there is a large music festival that increases average occupancy rates at time t-1,
occupancy rates after the festival at time t may remain slightly elevated from their “normal”
levels, all else equal, but one would not expect occupancy to increase every period thereafter at t,
t+1, t+2, … without any other changes to the system. Eventually, average occupancy rates
should settle back down to their pre-festival rates unless there is some other change to parking
demand or supply. Glancing over Table 2, it is clear that all statistically significant coefficients
are less than one in absolute value. This supports the proposition that the model is stable. A
technical test for parameter estimation stability is presented in Appendix B.3, and the model
satisfies the stability condition.
Except for afternoon weekends, all occupancy rates are positively correlated with their
own lagged values after controlling for price, seasonality, distance, neighborhood fixed effects,
and block-level unobserved heterogeneity. Since occupancy during some time of the day and
day of the week at time t-1 is positively correlated with occupancy at t, this simple result
bolster’s SFpark’s practice of using the previous period’s average occupancy during a particular
time zone to adjust that time zone’s hourly price for the next period.
On the other hand, the lagged weekend afternoon occupancy is actually negatively
correlated with current weekend morning, afternoon, and evening occupancy. This is an unusual
result and requires further attention. A possible explanation for this is that individuals are pay
close attention to occupancy rates on the weekend afternoons when planning future automobile
trips. For example, suppose an individual goes shopping one weekend afternoon and finds that
all of the stores are overcrowded, resulting in an unpleasant shopping experience. He likely
experiences difficulty with vehicle and pedestrian traffic, as well as finding parking, in such a
Shriver
36
situation. So when subsequent weekends roll come around, the hypothetical individual is less
likely to make a trip out on the weekend, perhaps assuming that the weekends are too busy and
crowded for an enjoyable outing.
Table 3 presents the parameter estimation of the distance-price interaction in System (1).
Recall that the interpretation of these coefficients is the change in the price elasticity of demand
associated with a one kilometer move away from the center of the PMD. It is immediately
apparent that none of the coefficients are statistically significant.
Table 3. Parameter Estimation of Distance-Price Interaction in Sys. 1
Distance*Natural Logarithm of Price at Time t
Weekdays
Weekends
Morning
Afternoon
Evening
Morning
Afternoon
Evening
Natural Logarithm of Occupancy
at Time t
Weekdays
Morning
-0.635
(0.554)
0.603
(0.722)
-0.736
(0.543)
0.708
(0.416)
-0.185
(0.719)
-0.042
(0.647)
Afternoon
-0.002
(0.442)
0.454
(0.496)
-0.258
(0.345)
0.153
(0.316)
-0.476
(0.473)
0.365
(0.409)
Evening
0.204
(0.658)
0.138
(0.812)
-0.448
(0.436)
0.010
(0.506)
-0.444
(0.728)
0.492
(0.608)
Weekends
Morning
-0.525
(1.456)
-1.191
(1.423)
0.299
(1.216)
0.258
(0.998)
0.900
(1.389)
-0.868
(1.138)
Afternoon
1.701
(1.378)
-0.957
(1.361)
-0.583
(1.195)
-0.765
(0.937)
0.962
(1.364)
-0.589
(1.186)
Evening
1.737
(1.399)
-1.269
(1.551)
-0.102
(1.366)
-0.957
(1.043)
0.018
(1.265)
0.455
(1.306)
Notes: *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 4 presents (partial) parameter estimation results of the PMD-price interaction in
System 1. These coefficients can be interpreted as follows: they represent the percentage change
in occupancy during a time of the day and day of the week associated with a one percent change
in price during that same time zone in a particular PMD when '()*"=0. A full table of output
would include cross-elasticities that capture the percent change in occupancy corresponding to a
percent change in price during different time zones (i.e. a different day of the week and/or time
of day). Note that none of the coefficients in Table 3 are statistically significant. The magnitude
Shriver
37
of the coefficients and associated standards is large for Fisherman’s Wharf during weekend
afternoons and evenings. Large fluctuations in price elasticities at the block level within the
PMD during these time zones could potentially cause this phenomenon. It is also possible that
there remains some PMD-level omitted-variable bias that disproportionately impacts
Fisherman’s Wharf.
Table 4. Parameter Estimation of PMD-Price Interaction in Sys. 1
Notes: *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
The coefficient estimates from Table 3 and Table 4 can be used to predict the price
elasticity of demand on any given block i. Let + be the coefficient on the distance-price
interaction from Table 3, and let ,- be the coefficient on the PMD-price interaction from Table 4
for block k. Then the price elasticity of demand during a particular day of the week and time of
day on block i, .", can be estimated as
./0 1+'()*"2 ,-3-#" 45'
6
-7&
(4)
Note that ." is assumed to be time-invariant. The estimated ./ are presented below in
Table 5.
Parking Management District*Natural Logarithm of Price at Time t
Civic
Center
Downtown
Fillmore
Fisherman’s
Wharf
South
Embarcadero.
Natural Logarithm of Occupancy
at Time t
Weekdays
Morning
-0.111
(0.308)
-0.893
(1.370)
0.449
(0.524)
0.125
(0.276)
0.315
(0.317)
Afternoon
-0.225
(0.425)
0.710
(1.189)
-0.079
(0.581)
-0.936
(0.618)
-0.247
(0.283)
Evening
0.208
(0.267)
-1.038
(2.006)
0.114
(0.329)
-0.330
(0.406)
0.567
(0.413)
Weekends
Morning
0.077
(0.331)
-0.675
(0.641)
-0.738
(1.121)
-0.475
(0.646)
-0.158
(0.488)
Afternoon
-1.211
(0.941)
-0.921
(1.759)
-1.431
(1.258)
5.933
(6.110)
-0.767
(0.986)
Evening
0.829
(1.094)
-0.635
(1.359)
0.388
(1.449)
-4.808
(5.142)
-0.526
(0.773)
Shriver
38
Time Zone
Mean 89
S.D.
Min.
Max.
Weekday Morning
-0.233
0.389
-1.243
0.417
Weekday Afternoon
0.006
0.466
-0.913
0.959
Weekday Evening
-0.176
0.457
-1.284
0.563
Weekend Morning
-0.228
0.334
-0.725
0.307
Weekend Afternoon
0.625
2.663
-1.382
6.702
Weekend Evening
-0.603
1.955
-4.785
1.101
Table 5. 89 Summary Statistics
Notes: Based on 209 blocks
The results from Table 5 should be interpreted with caution since none of the coefficients
in Table 2 or Table 3 are statistically significant. Moreover, the large coefficient estimate on
Fisherman’s Wharf during the weekend afternoon and evening introduces considerable
variability to these two overall price elasticity estimates.
I would expect these coefficients to be less than 0; however, the weekend afternoon
estimate is much larger than 0. This is an odd result and is attributable to the influence of
Fisherman’s Wharf on this estimate. In all time zones, the standard deviation across block price
elasticities is large enough such that some block-level elasticities are positive and others are
negative.
This is not inconsistent with rough calculations using the midpoint formula to calculate
price elasticities. Table 6 gives the results obtained from calculating observed elasticities using
the midpoint formula and aggregating the results according to time zone.
Shriver
39
Time Zone
Obs.
Mean
S.D.
Min.
Max.
Weekday Morning
1,578
-0.535
2.129
-15.526
9.025
Weekday Afternoon
1,551
-0.895
2.355
-25.900
15.658
Weekday Evening
1,390
-0.908
2.589
-30.977
23.459
Weekend Morning
1,531
-0.504
2.685
-17.475
19.697
Weekend Afternoon
1,653
-0.961
3.107
-23.438
20.444
Weekend Evening
1,702
-0.780
2.831
-23.400
20.700
Table 6. Midpoint Elasticity Summary Statistics
The mean of the observed midpoint elasticities is negative in all cases, as expected.
However, the standard deviation is larger than in the predicted model, and the range of values is
much greater. A possible reason for these results is that, unlike the pVAR(1) model proposed in
this paper, using the observed occupancy and price data to compute midpoint elasticities does not
require the assumption that the price elasticity of demand be time-invariant. The implications of
this will be further addressed in the Discussion.
IV. Discussion
The model proposed in this paper makes very few structural assumptions, controls for
serially correlated error terms within blocks, and accounts for block-level unobserved
heterogeneity. Despite these advantages, the model fails to show statistically significant
relationships between occupancy and price, distance, and PMD.
In plain words, the implication of this finding is that block-level price elasticities are not
easy to predict. As the qualitative analysis by Pierce and Shoup (2013) argues, it appears to be
the case that there is simply too much variability in price sensitivity at the block level in order to
accurately predict elasticities, at least using the econometric model presented in this paper. The
Shriver
40
novel contribution of this paper to the literature is that price elasticity prediction is not difficult
because of the variability in price elasticity but rather the lack of structure of this variability. In
this sense, this paper goes one step further than Pierce and Shoup (2013), who simply observe
wide price elasticity variation and jump to the conclusion that economists cannot develop robust
econometric models to predict block-level price elasticities.
A logical question that arises is the following: why is there no apparent structure in the
variability of on-street parking demand sensitivity to price? One possible explanation is that the
price of on-street parking is relatively unimportant in determining occupancy rates. When a
person considers where to park, he takes many variables into account, both consciously and
subconsciously. His trip has a purpose, and this purpose is unobservable to economists, as well
as other factors such as his preferences regarding physical exercise, ability to parallel park, and a
number of location- and time-specific potential influences. The goal of this study was to try to
understand aggregate behavior: how average occupancy rates change in response to price
changes. Nevertheless, realizing that ultimately individual choices and preferences influence
parking decisions unlocks the door to a number of possible confounding variables.
To elaborate on one example, suppose that in 2014 a groundbreaking study was published
that definitively established a causal relationship between physical exercise and cancer mortality
rates. In response, public health campaigns may begin to encourage people to walk a certain
number of steps per day in order to reduce the risk of cancer. All of a sudden, individuals do not
try to park immediately near their destinations anymore; they seek to park further away so that
they can walk more and maintain a healthy lifestyle. Now, for many individuals the relationship
between distance between desired destination and parking spot is not primarily based on the
opportunity cost of time spent walking but rather represents a more complex tradeoff that
Shriver
41
invokes the value of health and life. Therefore, if the pre-2014 model is used to estimate post-
2014 data, the parameter estimates will suffer from omitted variable bias.
While the above scenario is clearly fabricated, the idea is generalizable. There are so
many changing conditions that may impact fundamental relationships in any proposed
econometric model of parking that reliable prediction of parameters is not feasible.
A significant limitation in my study is that I assume that the block-level price elasticity in
each time zone is constant over time. In other words, the model assumes that price elasticity is a
function of PMD and distance from the center of the PMD only, and this price elasticity is
estimated for all time zones (i.e. times of day and days of the week). In the model’s estimation,
there is no allowance for the possibility for structural changes to this relationship as time
progresses. If some other influential variables were to arise in, say, 2013, then the model’s
parameter estimates would be biased.
The calculation of observed midpoint elasticities provided an interesting exercise against
which I could compare the model results. These point estimates of the midpoint elasticities were
all negative on average but showed huge variability across individual estimates. Pierce and
Shoup (2013) conduct a similar exercise and utilize this observation as key evidence for their
claim that elasticities vary too widely to be estimated reliably. Note that the mean price
elasticity estimates are reasonably comparable between Table 5 and Table 6, but the standard
deviations are not directly comparable. I say the means are “reasonably” comparable because
the model provides exactly one estimate per block per time zone. In contrast, the midpoint
method may provide many estimates for some blocks and none for others; in other words, the
midpoint method does not ensure that the blocks are equally represented in calculating the
average elasticity during a particular time zone.
Shriver
42
My model also omits off-street parking based on the findings of Ottosson et al. (2013)
and public transportation based on lack of variation in number of accessibility points per block.
If either one of these variables did in fact turn out to be important determinants of price
elasticity, then my study would also suffer from omitted variable bias.
Ottosson et al. (2013) have statistically significant price elasticity estimates and find that
distance is an important determinant of this demand sensitivity. I suggest that their findings are
due to the single price change used in the study. Their study takes place over a single year,
which reduces the chance that time-dependent structural changes in the price-elasticity of
demand determinants occur between the beginning and end of their study. This starkly contrasts
the approximately 4-year period under study in this paper, where there is greater likelihood that
omitted variable bias becomes an issue sometime during the course of the study and thus
disproportionately affects a portion of the data.
Future research on this topic should seek to more carefully control for potential structural
changes over time in the relationship among the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.
In addition, future research may consider adding off-street parking and public transit data in
order to explore the effects of these variables further.
V. Conclusion
This study has presented a sophisticated econometric model that seeks to relate occupancy
rates and prices after controlling for endogeneity and confounding factors. The preferred model
does not show a statistically significant effect of key variables of interest, such as distance, PMD,
and price, on occupancy rates. However, there remain promising avenues for future research in
the parking literature, particularly in the context of the SFpark Project.
Shriver
43
Works Cited
Abrigo, Michael R.M. and Inessa Love. “Estimation of Panel Vector Autoregression in Stata: a
Package of Programs.” University of Hawaii, Department of Economics. Feb. 2015.
Web. 10 March 2016.
Andrews, Donald W.K. and Biao Lu. “Consistent model and moment selection procedures for
GMM estimation with application to dynamic panel models.” Journal of Econometrics
101 (2001): 123-164. Web. 13 March 2016.
Anderson, Simon P. and André de Palma. “The economics of pricing parking.” Journal of Urban
Economics 55 (2004): 1-20. ScienceDirect. Web. 26 May 2015.
---. “Parking in the city.” Papers in Regional Science 86.4 (2007): 621-632. Web. 31 July 2015.
Arnott, Richard and Eren Inci. “An integrated model of downtown parking and traffic
congestion.” Journal of Urban Economics 60 (2006): 418-442. ScienceDirect. Web. 1
Jan. 2016.
Arnott, Richard and John Rowse. “Downton parking in auto city.” Regional Science and Urban
Economics 39 (2009): 1-14. ScienceDirect. Web. 1 Sept. 2015.
---. “Modeling Parking.” Journal of Urban Economics 45 (1999): 97-124. Web. 31 Dec. 2015.
Baker, David R. “S.F. begins charging for Sunday parking.” SFGate. 6 Jan. 2013. Web. 12 Apr.
2016.
Baum, Christopher F. “Dynamic Panel Data estimators.” Boston College. Spring 2013. Web. 1
Apr. 2016.
Eberhardt, Markus. “Panel time-series modeling: New tools for analyzing xt data.” University of
Nottingham. 2011 UK Stata Users Group Meeting, Cass Business School, London. 16
Sept. 2011. Conference Presentation.
Shriver
44
“Economic Growth Widespread Across Metropolitan Areas in 2014.” Bureau of Economic
Analysis 23 Sept. 2015. Web. 1 Jan. 2015.
Hamre, Andrea and Ralph Buehler. “Commuter Mode Choice and Free Car Parking, Public
Transportation Benefits, Showers/Lockers, and Bike Parking at Work: Evidence from the
Washington, DC Region 2014.” Journal of Public Transportation 17.2 (2014): 67-91.
Web. 31 Dec. 2015.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, Whitney Newey, and Harvey S. Rosen. “Estimating Autoregressions with
Panel Data.” Econometrica 56.6 (1988): 1371-1395. JStor. Web. 21 March 2016.
Judson, Ruth A. and Ann L. Owen. “Estimating dynamic panel data models: a guide for
macroeconomists.” Economics Letters 65 (1999): 9-15. ScienceDirect. Web. 14 March
2016.
Kelly, J. Andrew and J. Peter Clinch. “Temporal variance of revealed preference on-street
parking price elasticity.” Transport Policy 16.4 (2009): 193-199. ScienceDirect. Web. 31
Dec. 2015.
Kézdi, Gábor. “Robust Standard Error Estimation in Fixed-Effects Panel Models.” Spec. issue of
Hungarian Statistical Review 9 (2004): 95-116. Web. 7 Apr. 2016.
Lam, Stephen. “Facebook offers workers $10K to cut the commute.” Al Jazeera America. Al
Jazeera America, 18 Dec. 2015. Web. 1 Jan. 2015.
Litman, Todd. “Parking Pricing Implementation Guidelines: How More Efficient Parking Pricing
Can Help Solve Parking And Traffic Problems, Increase Revenue, And Achieve Other
Planning Objectives.” Victoria Transport Policy Institute. 24 Aug. 2015. Web. 11 Apr.
2016.
Shriver
45
Nickell, Stephen. “Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects.” Econometrica 49.6 (1981):
1417-1426. JSTOR. Web. 14 March 2016.
Ommeren, Jos van and Giovanni Russo. “Time-varying parking prices.” Economics of
Transportation 3 (2014): 166-174. ScienceDirect. Web. 7 July 2015.
Ottosson, Dadi Baldur, Cynthia Chen, Tingting Wang, and Haiyun Lin. “The sensitivity of on-
street parking demand in response to price changes: A case study in Seattle, WA.”
Transport Policy 25 (2013): 222-232. ScienceDirect. Web. 7 Oct. 2015.
“Parking Meters.” City of Boston. CityofBoston.gov, n.d. Web. 20 Dec. 2015.
Pierce, Gregory and Donald Shoup. “Getting the Prices Right.” Journal of the American
Planning Association 79.1 (2013): 67-81. Web. 12 Oct. 2015.
Preston, Darrell. “Morgan Stanley Group’s $11 Billion Makes Chicago Taxpayers Cry.”
BloombergBusiness. 2010 Aug. 8. Web. 20 Dec. 2015.
Qian, Sean and Ram Rajagopal. “Optimal occupancy-driven parking pricing under demand
uncertainties and traverler heterogeneity: A stochastic control approach.Transportation
Research Part B: Methodological 67 (2014): 144-165. ScienceDirect. Web. 31 Dec.
2015.
Schrank, David, Bill Eisele, Tim Lomax, and Jim Bak. “2015 Urban Mobility Scorecard.” The
Texas A&M Transportation Institute and INRIX, Inc. Aug. 2015. Web. 1 Jan. 2015.
“SFpark: Pilot Project Evaluation.” SFMTA. SFpark.org., June 2014. Web. 26 Oct. 2015.
Shoup, Donald. “Cruising for parking.” Transport Policy 13 (2006): 479-486. Web. 24 Feb.
2015.
---. “Evaluating the effects of cashing out employer-paid parking: Eight case studies.” Transport
Policy 4.4 (1997): 201-216. Web. 31 Dec. 2015.
Shriver
46
---. “The High Cost of Free Parking.” Journal of Planning Education and Research 17 (1997): 3-
20. Web. 30 May 2015.
---. “The trouble with minimum parking requirements.” Transportation Research Part A 33
(1999): 549-574. Web. 31 Dec. 2015.
Washbrook, Kevin, Wolfgang Haider, and Mark Jaccard. “Estimating commuter mode choice: A
discrete choice analysis of the impact of road pricing and parking charges.”
Transportation 33.6 (2006): 621-639. Web. 31 Dec. 2015.
Weinberger, Rachel, John Kaehny, and Matthew Rufo. “U.S. Parking Policies: An Overview of
Management Strategies.” Institute for Transportation & Development Policy. ITDP, 23
Dec. 2010. Web. 31 Dec. 2015. Web.
Verhoef, Erik T., Jan Rouwendal, and Piet Rietveld. “Congestion Caused by Speed Differences.”
Journal of Urban Economics 45.3 (1999): 533-556. Web. 31 Dec. 2015.
Shriver
47
Appendix A
A.1 Time-Series Occupancy Summary
Shriver
48
Shriver
49
Shriver
50
A.2 Price Distribution Histograms
Shriver
51
Shriver
52
Appendix B
B.1 Lag-Order Selection
The pvarsoc program, created by Abrigo and Love (2015), was utilized to determine to
the appropriate lag-order for the panel auto-regression analysis. The dependent variables can be
represented as !"#$, which is a vector of the natural logarithm of average occupancy rates
(expressed as percentages) at different times of the day on weekdays and weekends on block i
during time period t. The goal is to find the lag-order 4 : ;<# =# > # ? @ <A such that the model
!"#$ 0 B1C!$%C
D%&
C7&
2 E1F"#$ 2 G"2 ."#$
(B.1)
provides the best fit for the data. The measures used to determine the “best fit” of the data are
the Andrews and Lu (2001) moment model selection criteria (MMSC), which are based on
Hansen’s J statistic of over-identifying restrictions, as well as the number of moment conditions,
the number of endogenous variables, and the sample size (Abrigo and Love 2015). These
include the MMSC-Bayesian Information Criterion (MBIC), MMSC-Akaike Information
Criterion (MAIC), and the MMSC-Hannan-Quinn Information Criterion (MQIC). The best-
fitting model will minimize the MMSC criteria. Additionally, pvarsoc reports the coefficient of
determination (CD) of a particular lag-order as a representation of the proportion of variation
captured by the model (Abrigo and Love 2015).
Since the time intervals are approximately three months long and therefore loosely
resemble quarterly data, I follow Ryan-Collins (2016) in using 4 lags of the dependent variables
as moment conditions. Specifying before testing that 4 lags be used as instruments prevents the
temptation to “over-fit” the data. The lagged instruments are defined to be the first to fourth lags
from the highest lag used in the pVAR model. For example, when testing a pVAR model of
order 2, the second to fifth lags are used as instruments.
Shriver
53
As a final consideration before testing, since the number of moment conditions must be
greater than the number of lags of the endogenous variables in order to calculate the J statistic,
the maximum lag order I test is 3. The lag-order selection test results are shown in Table B.1.
Table B.1. Lab-Order Selection Criteria*
Lags
CD
J
J P-Value
MBIC
MAIC
MQIC
1
0.9871842
124.8447
0.1279227
-625.7398
-91.15528
-293.919
2
0.8367188
56.40032
0!.9116846
-443.9893
-87.59968
-222.7755
3
**
6.09532
1.0000000
-244.0995
-65.90468
-133.4926
*Based on 1,043 observations, 186 panels, average number of T = 5.608
**Internal numerical error in Stata prevented calculation of CD for lag 3
The results from Table B.1 show that the MBIC, MAIC, and MQIC are minimized with
the first-order PVAR model. The CD is also maximized with the first-order model, although the
CD was not able to be computed for the third-order model due to numerical errors in Stata
(perhaps due to the small magnitude of the determinant of the unconstrained covariance matrix
of the dependent variable in this model). Hansen’s J-statistic is declines as the number of lags
increases, suggesting that model fit improves as lag order increases; however, this measure does
not account for degrees of freedom in the model like the MMSC criteria and is thus considered
less heavily in model selection (Abrigo and Love 2015). In all cases, though, the p-value of
Hansen’s J-statistic is insignificant at the 10% significance level, so for all three models I fail to
reject that the null hypothesis that the over-identifying restrictions are valid.
The above discussion leads me to choose the first-order model as the preferred model
throughout the paper.
Shriver
54
B.2 Stationarity Testing
It is important to determine whether or not the key endogenous variables are stationary in
an autoregressive model in order to understand the effect of shocks on the system and identify
spurious relationships.
The data in this study are unbalanced (i.e. some panels have missing occupancy
observations), which limits the panel root tests that may be applied. I implement the Fisher unit
root test in Stata using the xtunitroot fisher program. The Fisher unit root test performs unit root
tests on each panel individually and essentially aggregates the p-values to report a single statistic.
The null hypothesis is that the all panels contain a unit root, and the alternative hypothesis is that
at least one panel is stationary. The test performed on each panel is the Phillips-Perron test,
which I choose since it uses Newey-West standard errors to control for the possibility of serial
correlation, with a linear time trend. Before performing the test, I subtract the cross-sectional
averages from the series, as recommended by Levin, Lin, and Chu (2002), to reduce the potential
impact of cross-sectional dependence. Four lags of the dependent variables are used in the test
since the average time period is three months and thus resembles quarterly data (Ryan-Collins
2016). Finally, to test the null hypothesis specified above, Choi (2001) recommends using the Z
test for empirical applications based on simulation results supporting the Z test’s ability to
outperform alternative tests (i.e. P, L*, Pm tests) with respect to size and power considerations.
The results of the above statistical procedure are presented for the endogenous variables
!"#$ in Table A.2. The null hypothesis is rejected at the 5% level or less in all cases, so I reject
the null hypotheses that the endogenous variables are non-stationary. I conclude that each series
of ln(occupancy rates) is I(0), i.e. stationary.
Shriver
55
Table B.2. Fisher Unit Root Test Results*
Variable
Inverse Normal
Statistic (Z)
P-Value
Weekdays
Morning occupancy
-13.8998
0.0000
Afternoon occupancy
-12.1727
0.0000
Evening occupancy
-14.1685
0.0000
Weekends
Morning occupancy
-24.6148
0.0000
Afternoon occupancy
-25.5827
0.0000
Evening occupancy
-22.3086
0.0000
*Based on 205 to 209 panels, average number of T=14.97; all occupancy variables are the
natural logarithm of average occupancy rates
Shriver
56
B.3 Stability Testing
Figure B.1 shows that the stability condition of the pVAR estimates is met since all
eigenvalues of the companion matrix lie inside the unit circle, i.e. have a modulus less than one.
Figure B.1. Eigenvalues of the Companion Matrix
Shriver
57
Appendix Works Cited
Abrigo, Michael R.M. and Inessa Love. “Estimation of Panel Vector Autoregression in Stata: a
Package of Programs.” University of Hawaii, Department of Economics. Feb. 2015.
Web. 10 March 2016.
Andrews, Donald W.K. and Biao Lu. “Consistent model and moment selection procedures for
GMM estimation with application to dynamic panel models.” Journal of Econometrics
101 (2001): 123-164. ScienceDirect. Web. 13 March 2016.
Choi, In. “Unit root tests for panel data.” Journal of International Money and Finance 20 (2001):
249-272. ScienceDirect. Web. 14 March 2016.
Levin, Andrew, Chien-Fu Lin, and Chia-Shang James Chu. “Unit root tests in panel data:
asymptotic and finite-sample properties.” Journal of Econometrics 108 (2002): 1-24.
ScienceDirect. Web. 14 March 2016.
Ryan-Collins, Joshua Jacob. “Credit creation, monetary policy and the macroeconomy: three
empirical studies.” University of Southampton, School of Business. Feb. 2016. Web. 13
March 2016.
!
... • Papers with strong endogeneity in prices (Kimley-Horn and Associates, 2011; Ottosson et al., 2013;Pierce and Shoup, 2013;Shriver, 2016;Pu et al., 2017). 7 ...
Article
Full-text available
The effect of parking fees on parking demand has been investigated in many different contexts, applying a wide variety of study designs. Research that brings together the knowledge derived in these studies systematically, however, is scarce. We conduct a meta-analysis of parking price elasticities based on 50 studies. Using seemingly unrelated regression models we account for the interdependence between the price elasticity of occupancy (EPO), dwell time (EPD), and volume (EPV). We show that estimates of parking elasticities based on stated preference (SP) data lead to different managerial and policy insights than estimates based on revealed preference (RP) data. Given a large amount of reported and unreported variation between the existing studies on parking price elasticities, we provide concrete recommendations for future studies that should warrant a higher degree of comparability and coherence in research design, conduction, and reporting.
... Since its implementation, a study in March 2014 shows that drivers cruising looking for parking spots have been down by 50% (Millard-Ball et al., 2014). In another economic study on the SF-Park implementation (Shriver, 2016), it provides positive feedback from the dissemination of parking spaces around the city. Supported by the demand-based pricing model, the distribution of spaces have provided a wider variance in the spaces available in each sector of the city and also has managed to suppress drivers from cruising around looking for a spot. ...
Article
Full-text available
Municipalities and employers in the U.S. attempt to reduce commuting by automobile through commuter benefits for riding public transportation, walking, or cycling. Many employers provide a combination of benefits, often including free car parking alongside benefits for public transportation, walking, and cycling. This study evaluates the relationship between commuter benefits and mode choice for the commute to work using revealed preference data on 4,630 regular commuters, including information about free car parking, public transportation benefits, showers/lockers, and bike parking at work in the Washington, DC region. Multinomial logistic regression results show that free car parking at work is related to more driving. Commuters offered either public transportation benefits, showers/lockers, or bike parking, but no free car parking, are more likely to either ride public transportation, walk, or cycle to work. The joint provision of benefits for public transportation, walking, and cycling is related to an increased likelihood to commute by all three of these modes and a decreased likelihood of driving. However, the inclusion of free car parking in benefit packages alongside benefits for public transportation, walking, and cycling, seems tooffset the effect of these incentives. Benefits for public transportation, walking, and cycling, seem to work best when car parking is not free.
Article
Full-text available
Problem, research strategy, and findings: Underpriced and overcrowded curb parking creates problems for everyone except a few lucky drivers who find a cheap space; all the other drivers who cruise to find an open space waste time and fuel, congest traffic, and pollute the air. Overpriced and underoccupied parking also creates problems; when curb spaces remain empty, merchants lose potential customers, workers lose jobs, and cities lose tax revenue. To address these problems, San Francisco has established SFpark, a program that adjusts prices to achieve availability of one or two open spaces per block. To measure how prices affected on-street occupancy, we calculated the price elasticity of demand revealed by over 5,000 price and occupancy changes during the program's first year. Price elasticity has an average value of -0.4, but varies greatly by time of day, location, and several other factors. The average meter price fell 1% during the first year, so SFpark adjusted prices without increasing them overall. This study is the first to use measured occupancy to estimate the elasticity of demand for on-street parking. It also offers the first evaluation of pricing that varies by time of day and location to manage curb parking. Takeaway for practice: San Francisco can improve its program by making drivers more aware of the variable prices, reducing the disabled placard abuse, and introducing seasonal price adjustments. Other cities can incorporate performance parking as a form of congestion pricing.
Article
Full-text available
Suppose curb parking is free but all the spaces are occupied, and off-street parking is expensive but immediately available. In this case, you can cruise to find a curb space being vacated by a departing motorist, or pay for off-street parking right away. This paper presents a model of how drivers choose whether to cruise or to pay, and it predicts several results: you are more likely to cruise if curb parking is cheap, off-street parking is expensive, fuel is cheap, you want to park for a long time, you are alone in the car, and you place a low value on saving time. The model also predicts that charging the market price for curb parking—at least equal to the price of adjacent off-street parking—will eliminate cruising. Because the government sets curb parking prices, planners and elected officials strongly influence drivers’ decisions to cruise. The failure to charge market rates for curb parking congests traffic, pollutes the air, wastes fuel, and causes accidents. Between 1927 and 2001, studies of cruising in congested downtowns have found that it took between 3.5 and 14 min to find a curb space, and that between 8 and 74 percent of the traffic was cruising for parking.
Article
Full-text available
This paper develops unit root tests for panel data. These tests are devised under more general assumptions than the tests previously proposed. First, the number of groups in the panel data is assumed to be either finite or infinite. Second, each group is assumed to have different types of nonstochastic and stochastic components. Third, the time series spans for the groups are assumed to be all different. Fourth, the alternative where some groups have a unit root and others do not can be dealt with by the tests. The tests can also be used for the null of stationarity and for cointegration, once relevant changes are made in the model, hypotheses, assumptions and underlying tests. The main idea for our unit root tests is to combine p-values from a unit root test applied to each group in the panel data. Combining p-values to formulate tests is a common practice in meta-analysis. This paper also reports the finite sample performance of our combination unit root tests and Im et al.'s [Mimeo (1995)] t-bar test. The results show that most of the combination tests are more powerful than the t-bar test in finite samples. Application of the combination unit root tests to the post-Bretton Woods US real exchange rate data provides some evidence in favor of the PPP hypothesis.
Article
Panel vector autoregression (VAR) models have been increasingly used in applied research. While programs specifically designed to fit time-series VAR models are often included as standard features in most statistical packages, panel VAR model estimation and inference are often implemented with general-use routines that require some programming dexterity. In this article, we briefly discuss model selection, estimation, and inference of homogeneous panel VAR models in a generalized method of moments framework, and we present a set of programs to conveniently execute them. We illustrate the pvar package of programs by using standard Stata datasets.
Thesis
This thesis is composed of three empirical studies examining the relationship between credit creation, monetary policy and macroeconomic activity. It is motivated by the neglect of credit in mainstream macroeconomic theory and empirical work prior to the financial crisis of 2007-08. The first study investigates the relationship between monetary policy and nominal GDP in the United Kingdom over 50 years using a new quarterly dataset. Different theories of the monetary transmission mechanism are tested using the ‘General-to-Specific’ (GETS) method. A long-run cointegrating relationship is found between a real economy credit growth variable and nominal output growth. Changes to short-term interest-rates and broad money growth fall out of the parsimonious model. Vector error correction and vector auto-regression (VAR) analysis finds one- way Granger causality from credit growth to nominal-GDP growth. The second study examines evidence of a ‘credit cycle’ by analyzing the dynamic interlinkages between credit, house prices, monetary policy, and economic activity in nine advanced economies. Credit is decomposed in to ‘productive credit’ (bank lending to non-financial firms and for consumption) and ‘asset market credit’ (lending for domestic mortgages or financial assets). Country-level and panel VAR analysis finds: 1) a secular growth in asset market credit relative to productive credit; 2) productive credit growth has a stronger impact on real-GDP growth than asset-market credit although there is cross-country heterogeneity; (3) property prices strongly influence both credit growth aggregates and the macroeconomy; and (4) interest rates are more weakly linked to the other variables. The third study considers the monetary financing of government expenditure by central- banks as a monetary policy tool. This is pertinent today given historically high private and public debt-to-GDP levels. A literature review finds little support for the standard claim that such activity leads to damaging inflation. A counter-example is presented via an institutional case study of the central bank of Canada during the period 1935-1975 when it monetised on average 25% of government debt to support fiscal expansion and economic growth. Econometric analysis also finds no evidence for a relationship between monetary financing and inflation. The policy implications of the thesis are that: 1) credit growth plays a central role in the monetary policy transmission mechanism; 2) there is evidence of a credit cycle strongly related to house prices in advanced economies which may be strengthening over time; and 3) monetary financing of government deficits should be considered as a policy tool given high private debt levels and private banks’ turn towards asset market credit creation.
Article
A novel parking pricing strategy dependent on real-time sensing is proposed to manage the parking demand. Parking pricing and information provision jointly serve as a dynamic stabilized controller to minimize the total travel time (TTT) of the system. Parking prices are adjusted in real time according to the real-time occupancy collected by parking sensors. All the parking information along with parking prices, is then provided for travelers to make real-time parking choices. We model the optimal parking pricing in the preferred (closer) parking cluster as a stochastic control problem. We take into account two types of randomness, demand uncertainties and user heterogeneity in Value of Time (VOT), both of which can be learned by taking real-time measurements. The optimal parking pricing policies are solved using the dynamic programming approach. There exists a critical occupancy for each time period, and the parking prices should be set effective (by diverting travelers to the farther parking lot) when the up-to-date occupancy is above the critical occupancy. From the numerical experiments, we find that the optimal parking policies based on stochastic control models are promising. They can deal with different demand levels (high, low or unstable) and generally outperform the deterministic pricing schemes. It can approach the minimum TTT in most of the cases as if we know the traffic demand in advance of the commuting time. Providing real-time occupancy information alone without setting proper parking prices, seems useful, but marginal, in reducing the parking congestion.
Article
Arnott and Inci [Arnott, R. and Inci, E., 2006. An integrated model of downtown parking and traffic congestion. Journal of Urban Economics 60, 418–442] developed an integrated model of curbside parking and traffic congestion in a downtown area. Curbside parking is exogenously priced below its social opportunity cost, and the stock of cars cruising for parking, which contributes to traffic congestion, adjusts to clear the market for curbside parking spaces. Denser downtown areas have garage as well as curbside parking. Because of economies of scale in garage construction, garages are discretely spaced. The friction of space confers market power on parking garages. Spatial competition between parking garages, as modeled in Arnott [Arnott, R., 2006. Spatial competition between downtown parking garages and downtown parking policy. Transport Policy 13, 458–469], determines the equilibrium garage parking fee and spacing between parking garages. Also, the stock of cars cruising for parking adjusts to equalize the full prices of curbside and garage parking. This paper combines the ingredients of these two models, hence presenting an integrated model of curbside parking, garage parking, and traffic congestion, and examines curbside parking policy in this context through a numerical example with parameters representative of a medium-sized US city. The central result is that raising the curbside parking fee appears to be a very attractive policy since it generates efficiency gains that may be several times as large as the increased revenue raised.