Chapter

Economic nationalism and income distribution in late industrializing countries

Authors:
To read the full-text of this research, you can request a copy directly from the authors.

Abstract

Economic nationalism has evaded the economist's modeling skills. This is not surprising given that nationalism has generally escaped clear theoretical exposition. When economic nationalism has been analyzed by historians, it has typically been defined in terms of militarism and self-sufficiency. With ample justification, it is conventionally regarded in the West as being negative. Nevertheless, in " the rest" - countries outside modem Europe, North America and Japan that started from behind but industrialized at break-neck speed since W odd War II - economic nationalism has taken on a different meaning. 1 In the context of late industrialization, with only weak military power, economic nationalism has referred to ownership. Public resources have been concentrated on nationally owned and controlled business enterprises to substitute for multinational firms. These national enterprises - which have typically taken the form of diversified business groups - have raised welfare by investing in people's skills and research and development. The breadth and depth of their investments in technological capabilities have tended to exceed those of the overseas branches of international firms. We define economic nationalism below in terms of national ownership (not necessarily by the state) of business organizations and investments in skill formation , rather than by reference to trade orientation or military posture. The more countries invest in their own technological capabilities, the more nationalist they are, where the "make" as opposed to "buy" technology decision is a necessary condition for the emergence of nationally owned and controlled firms that rise to prominence in global oligopolistic markets on the basis of firm-specific , proprietary skills. For our purposes, the more state policies in the form of industrial licensing and subsidy allocation "target" national leaders in industry, the more nationalistic a latecomer government is considered to be. Apart from historical circumstance (the early source of a country's manufacturing experience) , the single most important factor to facilitate or frustrate economic nationalism is income distribution. Taking the nation as an organic whole, an absence of national divisions by class, race, religion, ethnicity and region provides the most fertile soil for economic nationalism to grow. Paradoxically, equality and homogeneity leave policy makers relatively free to create inequality - To concentrate resources on priming "targeted" firms. Restricting licenses and allocating subsidies to a limited number of firms , assumed to be a necessary condition for the emergence of a national leader in most targeted industries, creates a greater concentration of resources. The more equal the income distribution is at the start of development, the more government policy can ignore distribution issues and pursue nationalist goals with respect to fi= fo=ation. In addition, income inequality influences the emergence of national champions through the alternative investment opportunities it harbors outside manufacturing. Above-normal rates of return to the exploitation of quasimonopolies in scarce natural resources may be expected to occur if a concentration in the ownership of such resources creates monopoly pricing (P > MC).2 That is, the concentration of the highest quality resources in a few producers results in their relatively high rates of return. The higher the rate of return to investments outside manufacturing is, the less incentive for firms to invest in manufacturing. Consequently, the more unequal income is distributed in " agriculture," broadly defined to include mining and ranching, the lower the probability that countries will foster national firms with a core competency in manufacturing, the epicenter of modem economic growth, the incubus of knowledge-based assets, and the generator of high wages. By way of the evidence discussed below, the incidence of national leaders in "the rest" was greatest in countries with prewar colonial manufacturing experience and relatively equal income distributions: China, India, Korea and Taiwan, in contradistinction to Argentina, Brazil and Mexico. In this chapter, we focus primarily on the post-war experience of Korea and Taiwan, on the one side, and Brazil and Argentina on the other, supplemented by reference to the experience of other states, especially India. © 2006 by Hong Kong University Press, HKU. All rights reserved.

No full-text available

Request Full-text Paper PDF

To read the full-text of this research,
you can request a copy directly from the authors.

... (2.) Amsden and Hikino (2006) emphasize the importance of local firms and national champions as part of economic nationalism. They also suggest that initial favorable distribution of income allows the state to create national champions (Amsden and Hikino 2006: 190). ...
Article
Full-text available
This chapter introduces the rationale for the persistence of economic nationalism in Asia, its forms, how it differs from past practice, and its implications for the functioning of the world economy. It theoretically captures the changes in the world economy from an era of economic nationalism of the orthodox kind, when infant-industry protection was intellectually justified and routinely practiced, to an era of deep international integration. Rather than see states retreating from the economy, the chapter underscores the significance of states in coping with the new opportunities and challenges offered by the world economy. The chapter argues that states are active in promoting national capitalist development and hence cannot be expected to withdraw from intervening from the economy even if the climate for intervention is not receptive. The remaining chapters in the book are introduced.
Article
Full-text available
This paper seeks to identify the theoretical and empirical development of the research field of industrial competitiveness on the concept of technological capabilities proposed by Sanjaya Lall in the framework of firms. A methodology consisting of the systematic review of literature during the period between 1987 and 2019 is proposed. As the main finding, the study clearly identified three future research lines on technological capabilities dynamics, structure incentives and the analysis of macro-fundamental variables, which allows to conclude that there is an emerging field of study in relation to the interactions between technological capabilities, from its economic perspective, and resources and capabilities from the strategic and administrative literature. So, this study contributes significantly to the theoretical reflection on the relationship between technological capabilities and management, the metrics of the firm's resources, and the scenarios, environments and learning processes at firm's individual, collective, organizational and interorganizational level.
Article
Privatizations in developing countries were an important element underlying the rapid increase in foreign direct investment to these countries in recent years. Especially Latin America, East Asia, and countries in Eastern Europe managed to attract substantial amounts of foreign investment through the sale of state-owned enterprises to foreign buyers. However, countries with strong privatization programs also witnessed a growth in foreign direct investment inflows that went beyond the direct impact of foreign participation in these sales. The privatization of infrastructure services, in particular, seems to have had a strong effect on the decision making process by foreign investors, advertizing a country as a more attractive investment location. -Author