ArticlePDF Available

Modeling complex Megaregion systems: Horizontal and vertical integration for a Megaregion Model

Authors:
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015), pp.69-90
http://dx.doi.org/10.14257/ijt.2015.3.1.06
ISSN: 2287-7940 IJT
Copyright 2015 SERSC
Modeling complex Megaregion systems: Horizontal and Vertical
Integration for a Megaregion Model
Rolf Moeckel1, Sabyasachee Mishra2, Fred Ducca3 and Tara Weidner4
1National Center for Smart Growth, University of Maryland
2Department of Civil Engineering, University of Memphis
3National Center for Smart Growth, University of Maryland
4Oregon Department of Transportation (ODOT)
1rolf.moeckel@udo.edu, 2smishra3@memphis.edu, 3fducca@umd.edu,
4tara.j.weidner@odot.state.or.us
Abstract
Megaregions are considered to be the new geography that may become the nation’s
operative regions, according to the March 2010 U.S. Federal Highway Administration
(FHWA) Strategic Plan. Such regions need analysis tools to evaluate scenarios and their
regional impacts. These tools have to cover areas larger than covered by the typical
Metropolitan Planning Organization (MPO) or State Department of Transportation
(DOT) models. In addition, such tools need to integrate systems beyond transportation,
such as economic, land-use or environmental modules. This paper reviews a megaregion
case study, funded by the Federal Highway Administration’s Exploratory Advanced
Research Program, using an analysis framework to address the impact of high energy
prices in the Chesapeake Bay Megaregion around Washington D.C., USA. The paper
describes the model, focusing on horizontal and vertical integration issues of various
modules. A high-energy price scenario is analyzed showing the need for action at the
megaregional scale.
Keywords: Multi-scale modeling, megaregion modeling, transportation/land use
integration
1. Introduction
Megaregions across the Unites States have been analyzed for decades. The Boston-
Washington corridor, the Chicago Metropolitan Region and the Los Angeles Basin are
prime examples of frequently studied megaregions [1]. In Europe, one early megaregional
concept, the Blue Banana, covers an arc stretching from Manchester in Northern England
to Milan in Northern Italy. The Blue Banana was later rejected as being too simplistic (as
it also covered the highly rural Alps) and the European Grape was proposed as an
alternative [2], where every single grape abstracted a different European megaregion.
Formal megaregional arrangements are rare, despite the fact that political borders do
not confine regional interactions and associated impacts. One notable quasi-megaregional
agreement in the U.S. is the I-95 Corridor coalition, a group of transportation agencies
and toll authorities along the U.S. East Cost from Maine to Florida. Being a volunteer and
consensus-driven organization, however, the coalition is limited to actions that support the
interests of each player involved. Megaregional organizations with executive power do
not exist in the U.S. to date.
On the other hand, Megaregions comprise the economic engine of the U.S., forecasted
to contain half the nation's population growth and perhaps up to two-thirds of its
economic growth by 2050 [3]. Supporting the megaregions’ economic competiveness
domestically and abroad is a key concern given increasing global competition and
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
70 Copyright 2015 SERSC
international trade. A primary justification for addressing policy issues at a megaregional
scale as opposed to the metropolitan scale is that regional economic activities are
increasingly linked. Economic shocks to one metropolitan area result in spillovers, both
positive and negative, to adjacent metropolitan areas. As a consequence, the resulting
environmental and social impacts associated with such activities similarly spill across
metropolitan areas. Furthermore, as pointed out by Christaller [4], Lösch [5], and Ross
and Woo [6], individual cities are part of larger systems that are linked by inter-city trade
hierarchies.
Policy issues exhibiting the following characteristics are most appropriate for a
megaregional governance framework.
Investments involving large-scale economies, which are exhausted at the
megaregional scale.
Issues for which public sector demand is relatively homogeneous at the scale of the
megaregion.
Issues that involve a redistribution of resources across metropolitan areas or states
but which benefit from local (megaregional) knowledge regarding the nature of the
redistribution.
Issues that can be addressed with low administrative costs at the megaregional
scale. If there are economies of scale for administration, megaregional governance
would be preferred to local governance arrangements.
Megaregional frameworks are most relevant for issues involving large spillovers that
extend beyond existing local, regional, and state governance arrangements but not to the
scale of the entire nation. Even if the spatial extent is contained within one state,
megaregional governance arrangements are beneficial to address the externalities.
Many planning issues in the domains of environment, transportation, society and
economic development meet these criteria and deserve megaregional attention. There are
three methods to predict megaregional development. Behavior can be observed (observed
preference) or people can be asked (revealed preference), and this behavior can be
extrapolated into the future, or a mathematical model can be implemented. Out of these
three alternatives, a model is the only option that allows studying the megaregional
development under different scenarios. Given the geographic extend of megaregions,
observing or interviewing is particularly challenging. A model allows capturing the most
relevant interactions to analyze megaregional development under different scenarios. In
addition, a model can also capture interactions between the megaregion and national and
world economies, which would be very difficult to capture through surveys.
This paper provides a review of the literature (Section 2) and introduces the
Chesapeake Bay Megaregion (CBM) around Washington D.C. (Section 3). Following, the
framework for a megaregional model is described (Section 4), paying special attention at
the multi-dimensional integration of modules and geographies (Section 5). The CBM
model is described as an implementation of this megaregion modeling framework.
Simulation results of a high-energy price scenario are presented (Section 6), and finally,
implications for megaregions are discussed (Section 7).
2. Literature Review
Megaregions are defined in multiple ways in the literature. In the early 1960s,
Gottmann [7] wrote a seminal book of the Northeastern Seaboard reaching from
Washington to New York City, the largest urban conglomeration in the world at that time.
An update was published by Gottmann and Harper [8], in which the megaregion remained
mostly defined by population densities. A more common approach, adopted by the U.S.
Census Bureau and Bureau of Economic Analysis, is to define regions in terms of labor
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 71
market commuting sheds, where the majority of workers commute to locations within the
region for employment purposes. This approach is consistent with Hoover and
Giarrantani’s [9] conception of a “nodal” region and Fox and Kumar’s [10] “functional
economic areas,” where regional activities are oriented towards an internal nodal
commercial business district, and there is a presumption of dominance of the node over
the surrounding peripheral area [11]. Richardson [12] extends this concept to allow for
polycentric regions with several nodes and several peripheries, a concept that is embodied
in the U.S. Census Bureau’s current definition of a Combined Statistical Area (CSA).
The definitions proposed by recent authors differ in terms of the units of analysis that
make up the underlying regions and how they are connected. The Regional Plan
Association [13] along with urban planning graduate students at the University of
Pennsylvania identified ten megaregions in the U.S., defined as those regions that are
interconnected along at least one of the following dimensions: (1) environmental systems
and topography, (2) infrastructure systems, (3) economic linkages, (4) settlement patterns
and land use, and (5) shared culture and history. Hagler [14] proposes quantitative criteria
to establish these linkages. An index was created with points assigned to counties
according to whether the county was part of a core-based statistical area, had a population
density exceeding 200 persons per square mile, and had increases in population,
employment, or population densities exceeding certain thresholds. Ross et al., [15]
proposed the following procedure to identify megaregions: (1) identify the core areas, (2)
identify the boundaries of the areas of influence, (3) apply local characteristics, and (4)
finalize the boundaries.
While there is a substantial body of literature on analyzing megaregions, little research
has been conducted to modeling megaregions. The few applications published tend to
focus on one aspect only, rather than integrating transportation, land use, demographic,
economic and environmental models. For example, the Netherlands National Model
System (NMS), often referred to by its Dutch name Landelijk Model Systeem (LMS),
models travel demand for the entire Netherlands [26, 27], but only focuses on
transportation. Another pure transportation model at the megaregional scale has been
described by Zhang et al. [29]. They developed an impressive microscopic assignment
model for a megaregion, but stopped short of integrating this model with land-use,
economic or environmental components. A pure land use model for the evolving
megaregion Dar es Salaam, Tanzania was developed by Lindner and Hill [30], but this
model lacked the integration with a transportation model. The SASI (Spatial and Socio-
economic Impacts of Transport Investments and Transport System Improvements) model
is a notable exception as it models interactions of the economy with the transportation
system for the entire European Union [28]. However, infrastructure benefits are only
represented through accessibilities, they do not capture actual congestion on the
transportation network. This paper fills this gap by developing a model for a megaregion
that fully integrates economic, land-use, transportation and environmental modules.
3. Chesapeake Bay Megaregion
The Chesapeake Bay Megaregion (CBM) spans the area from the Southern border of
Pennsylvania through Maryland and eastern Virginia to Norfolk and Virginia Beach. It
includes all or part of six states: Pennsylvania, Maryland, Virginia, Delaware, West
Virginia and the District of Columbia. The megaregion includes major cities such as
Wilmington, Baltimore, Washington, Richmond, and the Norfolk area plus smaller areas
such as Salisbury MD and Fredericksburg, VA. The CBM is defined by its primary
environmental resource, the Chesapeake Bay. This Bay is the largest brackish water
estuary in the U.S. and an important ecosystem for the region. The megaregion also
consists of an advanced system of rail, ports, and highways that link labor markets and
facilitate commodity flows, as well as linked labor markets that depend heavily on the
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
72 Copyright 2015 SERSC
transportation and government sectors. Figure 1 provides a map of the CBM along with
major surface transportation infrastructure.
Figure 1. The Chesapeake Bay Megaregion
3.1 Transportation
The Chesapeake Bay Megaregion is a major transportation hub, and the transportation
system not only connects it to the rest of the country but also helps to unite the
megaregion. Interstate highways I-70 and I-270 connect the region to the west while I-81
and I-95 connect it to the north and south. In addition, Washington D.C., located near the
center of the region, is a major rail hub with the Norfolk Southern, Chessie System and
the AMTRAK Northeast corridor all passing through Union Station. The Ports of
Baltimore and Norfolk-Hampton Roads connect to the land transportation network and
the megaregion to the rest of world.
3.2. Economy
Economic factors define the size and character of the Chesapeake Bay Megaregion.
According to Lang and Nelson’s [16] definition of megapolitan areas, this area is defined
by the anchor metropolitan areas of Baltimore, Washington, Richmond, and Norfolk.
Ross [17] defines a similar geography using cluster analysis. She finds that interactions
within the Buffalo-Boston-New York-Philadelphia region and the Washington DC-
Virginia region are stronger than between these two regions. This smaller geography also
makes policy implementation more feasible, given that collaborative policy solutions
require cooperation among a smaller number of states and local governments.
Strong economic linkages are demonstrated using a database based on IMPLAN
1
input-output trade relationships. Figure 2 presents the dollar value of freight flows
between subareas of the megaregion. As can be seen, freight flows among the major cities
1
The data base consists of the dollar value of economic flows, disaggregated by 440 NAICS
codes, between every county within the Chesapeake Bay Megaregion. This figure was constructed
by taking the total dollar value of flows among all economic sectors and separating flows related to
freight movements.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 73
link the megaregion together. Not only are there strong economic ties along the I-95
corridor from Wilmington through Richmond, there are also major connections to Norfolk
as well as connections to areas on the Eastern Shore of the Chesapeake Bay and to
Western Maryland.
Figure 2. Dollar Values of Freight Flows Between Megaregion Subareas in
2007
The Chesapeake Bay acts as a major economic engine for the megaregion. The Bay
supports outdoor recreation including sailing, swimming, boating and tourism. It is also a
major food source, with oysters and crabs from the Bay shipped nationwide. The Bay is
home to two major ports, Norfolk-Hampton Roads and Baltimore. These ports are well
positioned to grow in importance as the Panama Canal is widened and the east coast
develops more direct shipping linkages with Asia.
3.3. Political Linkages
Political linkages also help to define the Chesapeake Bay Megaregion. The region is a
key part of the I-95 corridor coalition, a group of states from Maine to Florida concerned
with traffic on the Interstate Highway I-95. Furthermore, the Chesapeake Bay
Commission composed of the states Pennsylvania, Maryland and Virginia is a body set up
to manage water and land resources within the Chesapeake Bay watershed. All areas
within the megaregion are particularly concerned with the overall health of the Bay.
3.4 Policy Issues
By 2030, the Chesapeake Bay Megaregion is projected to be the fastest growing among
all other subregions within the Northeast Corridor with 40.2 percent [16], giving rise to a
range of growth-related policy challenges including traffic congestion and environmental
pollution. Within Maryland and the Northern Virginia, land use and Smart Growth
policies are of concern. The widening of the Panama Canal stands to redirect a portion of
international freight flows to the CBM’s major ports of Baltimore and Norfolk. As a
result, watershed protection, megaregional growth management, congestion pricing, land
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
74 Copyright 2015 SERSC
use and port expansions are all issues that will likely rise in importance over the next
several decades.
4. Modules
Given the geographic extend of a megaregion, a single scale model is insufficient to
capture relevant activities, travel behavior and their impacts. Instead, a two-layer
approach was chosen that distinguishes a megaregional layer represented in more detail
and a national layer capturing relevant activities and flows outside of the main study area.
Given the interactions between different megaregions nationally, and to some respect
even globally, the two-layer approach facilitates to represent the study area with sufficient
detail yet acknowledges that megaregions cannot be treated as monolithic islands.
Figure 3 visualizes the organization of the megaregion framework implemented for
the Chesapeake Bay area. A series of economic models predict the growth and decline of
different economic sectors based on assumptions of changes in the global economy. The
economic models cover both the megaregional layer and the national layer to account for
a global economy that affects growth and decline in the megaregion. This economic
forecast is used to constrain both the land-use model and the transport model. The land-
use model simulates changes in population and employment, including
demographic/firmographic changes and household/employment relocation.
Figure 3. Concept of the Integrated Megaregion Model
The locations of population and employment are used in the travel demand model to
simulate both person travel and freight flows. While the travel model has more detail in
the megaregional layer, the national layer is relevant to cover long-distance traffic flows
that may go into or through the megaregion study area. Accessibilities are fed back into
the land-use model to influence land-use changes in the following simulation period,
allowing land use to evolve over time. Finally, both traffic flows and the output of the
land-use model are used in a series of indicator models to analyze the model results. The
following sections describe the different modules in more detail.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 75
4.1. Economic Model
To address the larger economic interest of a potential megaregion authority, the
analysis framework emphasizes links with the economy, both nationally and locally. The
megaregion model chain is driven by a national economic forecast component that
predicts economic activity for large regions covering North America. This is used to drive
long-distance freight flows, as well as provide control totals for employment and
population to be allocated within the study area by the land use model. The national
Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) economic forecasting model built by the
INFORUM group at the University of Maryland is applied [18, 19]. The model employs
inter-industry-macroeconomic general equilibrium models to examine past employment
trends and to forecast future employment across 65 sectors of the economy. The primary
model, LIFT (Long-term Inter-industry Forecasting Tool), uses econometric equations to
predict final demand and output at the national level, based on inter-industry input-output
relationships and value-added behavioral equations. The second component STEMS
(State Employment Modeling System) allocates the national forecast to states, considering
the industry’s mix of basic and non-basic employment and personal income. Basic
employment is driven by LIFT national industry trends, while non-basic employment is
driven by state-specific personal income forecasts. The land use model further allocates
these state control totals to model zones.
To account for local transport impacts on the regional economy beyond the national
economic drivers that have little knowledge of local conditions, an economic post-
processor was developed. The post-processor combines knowledge of county-to-county
goods movement by industry and its sensitivity to travel impedance (generalized cost
including time, distance, and travel cost per mile) to determine the impact on an industry
based on the local transport influence on their supply chain relationships (up and
downstream). To do so, the following steps were completed:
An empirically based supply chain dataset at the county level with full input-output
relationships provided data on county-to-county financial flows for 2007 by
industry (IMPLAN data). These data were aggregated into industry groups and
isolated to sectors that ship products likely to travel by highway (by examining the
purchased transportation inputs by mode, and the nature of the products shipped).
The financial flows in dollars were converted to highway tonnage flows using
ancillary data and mode split relationships
2
. This resulted in truck tonnage as a
function of county-pair characteristics, while retaining the industry connection.
The travel model provided estimates of base and future years generalized
impedances between county pairs, while the national economic model and land use
model provided employment estimates for each county by industry category for
base and future years.
Based on the change in activity and travel impedance, estimates of the change in
county-to-county tonnage flows were developed by industry group.
The above provides an economic post processor that allows identifying that under a
given scenario Industry X will trade Y% more/less tonnage in counties A, B and C due to
change in transport cost. This provides an industry and spatially explicit indicator of the
impact of the scenario on the economy going beyond the top down economic
assumptions. Ideally these impacts would influence the size and location of the region’s
economic activity (feedback to an earlier stage in the model chain), which may be
considered in a future upgrade. However, by stopping at this point before full feedback,
2
Freight Mode Choice model HaulChoice, (c) ECONorthwest 2010 based on IMPLAN
Software v.3 (c) MIG, Inc. 2011, and county-level data provided by MIG, Inc.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
76 Copyright 2015 SERSC
the indicated economic impacts assume the industry and its suppliers do not relocate or
change technologies to accommodate the transport costs. As such, it provides information
for the megaregion to proactively plan to avoid such adverse industry impacts. The
megaregion governing authority learns, which links/portions of the transportation network
need to be strengthened in order to keep the megaregion economically viable. The result
is, in effect, a worst case bookend because (a) the highway network representation is not
made a function of the expected economic growth (or decline) of the region, and (b) the
base-year focus of industrial activity is held fixed, albeit scaled by the national economic
forecast model. Although footloose industries may in fact relocate as highway facilities
congest over time, astute improvements to the network afford the opportunity to mitigate
this effect. Thus, the findings can better inform long-term planning and economic
development.
4.2. Land Use Model
The framework for the economic/land use model is presented in Figure 4. The three
stages are: (a) national level, (b) regional level and (c) local level. The first component
was already described in Section 4.1 and provides control totals for the latter two, which
operate only within the megaregional model layer.
Regional Model: The disaggregation process at the county level begins with the
input of historic employment data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics’ (BLS)
Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages [20]. Employment data at the county
level are used to calculate the share of employment of each county in the baseline
years 2000, 2005 and 2009. The ratio of employment for each county is then
extrapolated for five-year periods beginning in 2010 and ending in 2030 using an
exponential smoothing method. Employment data from 101 BLS sub-sectors for
the same period are then reconciled with 65 STEMS industries disaggregated to
match the BLS sub-sectors. This process simply employs a straight average of the
two employment ratios. The purpose of this method is to allocate future STEMS
projections based on the historic difference in BLS data and STEMS projections.
Based on these previous ratios from 2000, 2005 and 2009, the projection for the
ratios until 2030 is extrapolated using OLS regression. The final disaggregation
process takes the aggregate STEMS total employment number for each five-year
projection cycle and allocates it by county and sub-sector based on the ratios
developed in the previous steps.
Figure 4. Multi-layer Land Use Model
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 77
Local Model: The local model results in land use outputs at the megaregional
modeling zones (MMZ
3
) level. The initial allocations are made based on
transportation costs and the basic employment distribution. At the local level a
Lowry model based allocation [21] is used to allocate households and employment
by five income categories from counties to MMZs. The input data of the model
consist of (1) Friction factors by household income group, (2) Household and
employment control totals at county level, and (3) Basic employment at MMZ
level. The output includes (1) Households by five income categories, (2)
Employment by four categories, (3) Error check files and plots. The model follows
the Lowry approach in five steps:
o Step 1: Determine the shortest path travel times and calibrate the friction
factors for base year by household type and income category.
o Step 2: Determine the household by income category from the county
control total and the proportions derived from the travel impedances of
basic employment (industrial).
o Step 3: Determine a specific type of non-basic employment using the
county control total and the proportions derived from travel impedances of
households of income category.
o Step 4: Go to step-2 and obtain a new set of households, repeat step-3 to
obtain new set of employment.
o Step 5: Repeat step-2 through step-4 till convergence is achieved.
The model steps are repeated every five years until the horizon year 2030 is reached.
The location of basic employment provides inertia in the local model’s allocation over
time. To develop a functional megaregion model, a Lowry model was employed to obtain
land use input in a timely matter. Since the megaregion size is a combination of states,
obtaining detailed data to develop a land use model is a challenging task. In contrast, a
Lowry model required less details of input but provides reasonable land use results
efficiently and within computationally acceptable runtimes. However, to increase scenario
sensitivities, more advanced and theoretically robust land use models should be
considered in the future.
4.3 Travel Demand Model
In line with the land use model, the travel demand model works at two geographic
layers (a megaregional with 2,075 zones and the national layer with 126 zones). While the
local travel demand model is closer to a traditional Metropolitan Planning Organization
Model, the national models are built from nationwide surveys for both person travel and
truck long-distance travel. Travel demand of the two layers is combined in the traffic
assignment process that assigns short- and long-distance traffic flows simultaneously in a
multi-class assignment.
The megaregional travel demand model is built as a five-step aggregate model that
includes trip generation, destination choice, mode split, time-of-day split and assignment.
The original modeling concept was borrowed from the Baltimore Metropolitan Council
model [22], refined and applied for short-distance trips of 50 miles or less to the entire
CBM study area. Trip generation rates were derived from a 2007 Household Travel
Survey for the Baltimore and Washington D.C. metropolitan areas, as well as travel times,
mode split and time-of-day split to fully calibrate the model to the core area of the CBM
3
MMZs are the polygon structures used in the megaregional model similar to TAZs in
metropolitan transportation planning. MMZs in the megaregional model are equivalent to TAZs in
high-density areas, and TAZs are nested in MMZs in low-density areas.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
78 Copyright 2015 SERSC
study area. Household Travel Surveys tend to have a sample size that is too small to fully
calibrate mode choice options. Two on-board surveys that were conducted for planned
transit expansions in the Baltimore and Washington regions were used to enrich data to
calibrate mode choice.
This model includes a three-step local truck model based on the Quick Response
Freight Manual (QRFM) published by the Federal Highway Administration [23], which
was applied for local trips under 50 miles within the CBM study area. The comparison
against VMT estimates revealed that the QRFM method, which is based on a 1992 truck
trip survey from Phoenix, generates too many truck trips for the Chesapeake Bay study
area. Therefore, parameters were scaled down to resemble local VMT truck estimates and
truck count data. This model distinguishes three truck types, namely light (such as pick-up
trucks or vans), medium (or single-unit) and heavy (or multi-unit) trucks.
At the national layer, the National Estimate of Long-Distance Travel (NELDT) has
been implemented to simulate long-distance person travel greater than 50 miles [24]. The
long-distance element of the National Household Travel Survey (NHTS) 2002, the most
recent survey that covered explicitly long-distance trips in the U.S., provided data for
long-distance travel behavior. To expand the survey to cover all long-distance travel in
the U.S., air travel data from the Bureau of Transportation Statistics, which covers ten
percent of all ticketed air travel passengers, was used as a control total for long-distance
trips by air. Comparing the BTS data with the NHTS air travel records revealed that every
25,319th air passenger was included in the NHTS. Assuming that the NHTS is
representative across all travel modes, this expansion factor was used to scale up the
NHTS to represent the entire long-distance travel in the U.S. Auto trips were added to the
multi-class assignment in conjunction with local traffic. Given the limitations of the
sample size of the NHTS, some scaling was necessary to match count data at external
entry points to the CBM study area.
For freight long-distance travel, commodity flows from the Freight Analysis
Framework FAF3 were used for truck trips of 50 miles or more. FAF3 data are provided
by 123 domestic FAF zones. Though these zones reflect centers of economic activity, the
resolution is too coarse to model truck trips on a network with much more detail.
Therefore, flows between FAF zones were first disaggregated to flows between counties
and then further disaggregated to flows between model zones. To disaggregate
commodity flows, make/use coefficients and employment by type were used to allocate
flows to the most likely producers and consumers of every commodity.
Commodity flows between zones are converted into trucks trips using average payload
factors provided by FAF. These factors describe how many tons of a given commodity are
carried by a truck on average. To account for empty truck trips, an empty-truck trips rate
is added globally to all truck trips. The model distinguishes two truck types, single-unit
and multi-unit trucks. The truck type depends on the traveled distance. While single-unit
trucks cover most of the short distance truck trips, multi-unit trucks dominate long-
distance travel.
4.4. Environmental Model
Multiple indicator models are included that cover the environment, fiscal, and social
impacts. The indicator models are used to estimate specific impacts from various policies
using outputs from the transportation, land-use and economic models. The results of the
indicator models are typically not fed back to the other model components but may be
used to identify additional scenarios to test, such as economic, land use, or transportation
actions necessary to keep below targeted indicator values.
Indicator Model for Gaseous Emissions. This model captures estimates of air
emissions using the EPA Motor Vehicle Emission Simulator (MOVES) model [25]. The
MOVES model uses VMT and link-level volumes and speed data output by the travel
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 79
model to estimate GHG and other mobile emissions. The model thus responds to changes
in travel demand, vehicle fuel efficiency, VMT and/or speeds, reporting regional
quantities of various emissions with each model run.
Indicator Model for Water Quality. This model captures the impact of alternative
policies on water quality. A nutrient-loading model covers the portion of the megaregion
draining into the Chesapeake Bay (although not the entire watershed). It forecasts the
annual loads of nitrogen, phosphorus and sediments on the watershed. The model uses
detailed land cover changes from a parcel-based land use model to identify changes in
nutrient runoff experienced in each watershed. The model contains detailed data on
ground classification for urban and agricultural land sub-classified into specific land cover
categories. The model responds to changes in land cover, and thus any economic,
transport, or land use policy.
Indicator Model for Infrastructure Costs. This model estimates state and local
governments’ costs to provide public infrastructure in support of new development (e.g.,
roads, sewer, water). Established relationships between the current development and the
provision of infrastructure are applied to project future improvements needed to satisfy
additional activity. Data includes residential development classified by housing type,
existing water and road infrastructure, property value trends and tax rates, among others.
An infrastructure cost model uses relationships between urban/rural development and the
provisions of infrastructure to forecast needs. The fiscal indicator model has been
developed to reflect conditions and costs in Maryland. The model responds to economic,
land use or transportation policies which impact land use.
5. Module Integration
Section 4 described four different groups of models that cover economic, land-use,
travel and environmental aspects of the megaregion. These different modules have been
tightly integrated to work in sync and pass information from one module to the next. The
economic model sets the stage for the entire framework by defining growth or decline of
population and employment as well as the amount of travel that is required to support this
economy without exceeding the budgets set by the economy. The land-use model
allocates households and employment to zones, which then are fed into the travel demand
model to generate traffic. Traffic flows are used in the environment modules to estimate
greenhouse gas emissions and other environmental impacts. And these flows of
information happen at two different geographic layers, the megaregional and the national
layer.
Therefore, this integration has two dimensions as shown in Figure 5. First, models of
otherwise comparable phenomena may work at different geographical levels, such as
integrating a travel model of the CBM area with a long-distance travel model
(geographical integration). At a minimum, the output of the two models need to be
combined, and often output from a model at one geographic layer directly influences the
model behavior at another geographic layer.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
80 Copyright 2015 SERSC
Figure 5. Two Dimensions of Model Integration
Secondly, modules with the same geography but different modeling tasks need to be
integrated horizontally, such as a transportation model and a land use model covering the
same study area (component integration). The two modules are likely to improve by
exchanging information. Each level is discussed separately in the following sections.
5.1. Vertical Integration Across Geographies
The CBM model is built as a geographic multi-layer approach integrating a national
with a megaregional model. This two-layer approach requires close integration of
modules to exchange data while avoiding double counting of modeled aspects. Interfaces
were needed that facilitate the integration even under extreme scenarios. This integration
needs to be bidirectional, with megaregion models utilizing information from national
models and megaregion models providing information to national models. Megaregion
models by their scope are most valuable to assess strategic region-wide policy actions,
and should not try to replicate the urban-level forecasts that commonly are better
represented by urban models.
Building modules that work at different geographies allows simulating similar tasks
(such as person trips) with different modeling approaches catered to each geographic
level. Every module may be designed differently, and the spatial resolution of different
modules may differ to fit each model's purpose. While a destination choice model works
well to distribute person trips at the local level, this module becomes difficult to apply
simultaneously with both short-distance and long-distance trips. Thus, the same task of a
person trip may be simulated with different methods at the megaregional and the national
level. The spatial resolution is likely to be finer at the local level and much coarser at the
national level. For a trip that stays within the study area, the detailed locations of origin
and destination are of interest. For a trip that leaves the study area to a destination
hundreds of miles away, the precise location of that destination most likely is irrelevant.
In the CBM model, Washington D.C. is subdivided at the local level into 85 zones (called
MMZ or megaregional model zones). At the national level, the finest resolution used is
counties, with Washington D.C. being one jurisdiction at the county level. While a
geographic distinction in different model layers is less relevant for urban models, this
distinction is helpful when modeling larger study areas, particularly for megaregions.
The predecessor of the CBM model, the Maryland Statewide Transportation Model
(MSTM), is integrated with the two urban models for Baltimore and Washington. This
integration works in two dimensions. On the one hand, aggregated results of MSTM are
compared with MPO model results to ensure consistency across geographies. Compared
are number of trips generated, average trip length, mode split, and VMT by county. If the
two layers agree across these dimensions, confidence of both the statewide and the MPO
models is raised. In the interesting case that the two layers do not agree, seaking to
understand the reasons for different model results may lead to intriguing conclusions on
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 81
which modeling approach works best for certain tasks. For example, the MSTM did not
agree with the MPO models in terms of trip generation. After some research the team
found that these models were using different household travel surveys, and the impact of
using different surveys could be traced down from trip generation to the assignment.
For the integration in the other direction, model volumes from the MSTM are fed into
some of the MPO models as traffic at external stations. In contrast to simple traffic
counts, which only provide the total number of vehicles entering the MPO are at a certain
location in the base year, the MSTM volumes specify how many of these external trips
are through trips (providing the entry and exit point to and from the MPO area), and how
many trips are internal-to-external/external-to-internal trips. For scenarios that may affect
the travel behavior of long-distance travel, such as widening the capital beltway by adding
more lanes, the MSTM provides updated external volumes under a given scenario.
Figure 6 shows this integration geographically for the CBM model. Further integration
of the CBM model with MPO models in the region is anticipated.
Figure 6. Three Geographic Layers of the CBM Modeling Framework
If trips are simulated at several geographic layers, special attention has to be paid to
minimize inconsistencies at the boundaries between the layers. If the megaregional model
had very small zones and the national model had very large zones, unrealistic behavior
may be generated at the border. While outside the megaregion the model may only
generate trips between zonal centroids that are fairly far apart, the model finds centroids
that are close together inside the megaregion. This may lead to different trip length
frequency distributions caused by the different resolutions in the zone system inside and
outside the megaregion. The CBM model overcomes this inconsistency by applying
different models to the more detailed megaregional zone system and to the coarser zone
system at the national level. This way, both models can be calibrated to their respective
zonal resolution, creating a more consistent trip length frequency distribution.
5.2. Horizontal Integration Across Modules
Within a geographic layer, a series of model components need to be integrated
horizontally, including an economic model, a land use model, a person-travel demand
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
82 Copyright 2015 SERSC
model, a truck model, and several environmental impact models. Every model is likely to
benefit from (if not require) the integration with some or all other models. Figure 7
shows graphically the integration designed for CBM.
Figure 7. Horizontal Integration of Modules for the CBM
The economic model provides population and employment for the land-use model
based on exogenously given growth. At this point, the economic model provides these
data at the state level, and the land-use model allocates population and employment to the
zonal level within these statewide constraints. At a future point, the economic model may
be redesigned to provide the socio-economic control totals for the entire study are of the
CBM model, allowing the land-use model to distribute population and employment
entirely based on utilities of different locations, unconstrained by artificial state borders.
The economic model also sets the stage for the transportation model, as it defines growth
in long-distance person travel, long-distance truck travel and auto-operating costs based
on exogenously given gas prices. The transportation model returns accessibilities to both
the economic model and the land-use model. Accessibilities are considered to be one
variable in predicting economic growth as well as the attractiveness of locations for
households and firms to locate.
To calculate environmental impacts, the transportation model provides traffic volumes
by vehicle type, time of day and speed at the link level. The land-use model provides land
cover to the environmental impacts module, as different land cover types have different
impacts on run-off water, fixed-source emissions and infrastructure costs. Conceptually
envisioned, though not implemented yet, the environmental model will provide feedback
to the land-use model on environmental quality. Environmental quality is a relevant
location factor, as households enjoy living close to the shore of the Bay, close to parks,
and away from highways and other sources of noise or pollution.
5.3. Module Interaction
At the outset, every module is calibrated independently. For example, the travel model
was calibrated to match observed traffic flows in the base year, and sensitivities for
policies in future years were tested. Similarly, the economic model was calibrated to
observed employment numbers in the base year, and sensitivities to various economic
scenarios were tested. After each module has been calibrated individually, they are
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 83
connected in one modeling framework as shown in Figure 7. After integration, no
further calibration was necessary as the output of each module closely resembled base
year conditions. Naturally, this connection leads to a certain disequilibrium over time.
Congestion may change, and households may experience longer commute times. Some
households may decide to relocate the following simulation period. But not all households
that could improve their housing utility move at once, as the transactions costs are too
high. Total convergence is not intended in such integrated models. The land use model
will adjust location choices of households and employment based on changing
accessibilities, and therefore, the modeling system is leaning towards an equilibrium. But
land use and transportation will never reach a full equilibrium. Rather, some households
relocate in one year, accessibilities change, and further households decide to relocate the
following year based on updated accessibilities. In other words, every module moves
towards equilibrium, but a true equilibrium is never reached because other modules
changed in the meantime.
This continuous disequilibrium is assumed to better represent real-world development.
Households are reluctant to relocate if accessibilities change, because moving is
expensive. The only module that is assumed to be in true equilibrium is the traffic
assignment, which iterates several dozen times to find an equilibrium. Drivers are
assumed to adjust their routing choice almost immediately to changing traffic conditions,
leading to a near-perfect equilibrium of traffic flows on the average day that is modeled.
All other modules move towards an equilibrium but by design have built in a certain time
lag to reach equilibrium.
5.4. Tightness of Model Integration
There is a wide range of tightness when integrating models. Models may share the
same modules that are fed with different data to work at different geographies. Or, models
may share some data that are reconciled to ensure consistency across each model. There
are also different levels of how closely different modules may be integrated technically
(Figure 8) [31, 32]. The most common is Integration Level 1. Every model runs
independently. After a model has started, it reads the output data of several other models,
completes its own calculations, writes new output data, and is closed. After one model has
finished another model can start. Building one single piece of modular software
(Integration Level 2) that contains all modules may be advantageous. Having all modules
in one piece of software saves runtime because a large amount of data can be kept in
working memory, saving read and write time. The integration into one piece of software
that is likely to improve the runtime requires, on the other hand, a very close interaction
between developers of all modules. The third level of integration runs all modules
simultaneously. Events of each module are executed in random order, such as a person
makes a trip to work, another household moves, a truck delivers groceries, a child is born,
a person goes to the cinema, etc. This very close integration resembles how events happen
in reality. So far, however, this level of integration rarely has been achieved in operational
models.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
84 Copyright 2015 SERSC
Figure 8. Three Levels of Model Integration
The CBM model uses a combination of level 1 and level 2 integrations. While the
economic and the land use model are stand-alone modules that are run consecutively, the
long-distance person model, the long-distance truck model and the short-distance truck
model are built as one single module that runs efficiently without time-consuming reading
and writing of intermediate results.
6. Application
The CBM model was used to analyze the impacts of three scenarios: a base scenario
for the year 2007 for validation purposes, a 2030 business-as-usual scenario (BAU), and a
2030 high-energy-price scenario (HEP). The single difference between the BAU scenario
and the HEP scenario is the assumed price for gasoline. In the BAU scenario, a gas price
of $2.90/gal is assumed, resulting in auto-operating costs of 12 cents per mile. The HEP
scenario analyzes the impact of a gas price of $14.00/gal, which results in auto-operating
costs of 42.2 cents per mile. The price of gas was set at a rather high level to test the
resilience of the megaregion’s transportation and land use system response under an
extreme scenario. The value of 42.2 cents/mile (in 2000$) was set at just over 3 times the
INFORUM high-energy scenario fuel price and assumed a “shock” in prices, such that the
population had only limited time to adjust the vehicle fleet. Still, average fuel efficiency
in miles per gallon (mpg) was assumed to increase from 24.4 mpg in 2010 to 41.8 mpg in
2030.
The HEP scenario assumes energy prices rise suddenly to this higher price due to
depletion of resources or market disruptions. No changes in land use are assumed, as the
sudden price increase has not yet triggered long-term location decisions. The comparisons
of these scenarios are presented for number of trips generated, the average trip length, the
modes chosen and vehicle-miles traveled. This scenario section intends to show that the
model provides reasonable responses to policy analyses. Since no considerable changes in
land-use or economic data were observed in this sudden increase in energy costs, the
analysis of this scenario focuses on impacts on the transportation system.
A Delphi Panel of experts in travel demand modeling was interviewed to develop
elasticities in trip generation. The resulting sensitivities for trip generation range from -
0.4% per 10% increase in gasoline prices for home-based work trips (least sensitivity) to -
1.5% for home-based other trips (largest sensitivity). Additionally, long-distance person
travel was assumed to be limited to a constant travel budget. Thus, increased travel costs
led to a smaller number of trips and shorter distances for long-distance person travel.
Figure 9 compares the travel demand for the three scenarios by several trip purposes.
Collectively, the number of trips in the 2030 BAU scenario is larger than the number of
trips in the 2007 base year, largely due to population growth. Home-based work and non-
home-based work trips show the least sensitivity to increased auto-operating costs under
the 2030 HEP scenario. Home-based other trips as well as long-distance trips show a
Integration level 1
Integration level 2
Integration level 3
Every module is run consecutively
Single events of all
modules are simulated
in random order
Separate pieces of
software, data transfer
by files
One piece of software keeps data in memory
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 85
larger sensitivity, as many of these trips are discretionary trips. Long-distance truck trips
were assumed to have almost no sensitivity to high gasoline prices, as options to reduce
trips are limited and a large share of increased transportation costs are passed on to the
consumer.
Figure 9. Trip Generation by Trip Purpose
Figure 10 compares the average trip length in miles for the three scenarios analyzed.
Trip lengths increased slightly from 2007 to 2030 in the BAU scenario, which is mostly
due to employment and population growth resulting in job/housing imbalances throughout
the region. The 2030 HEP scenario shows trip lengths that are notable smaller. Auto-
operating costs are part of the generalized-cost function used to simulate destination
choice. With higher gas prices, travelers seek destinations that are closer, and therefore,
reduce the expenses for traveling.
Figure 10. Average Trip Length by Purpose
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
86 Copyright 2015 SERSC
To understand the impact on mode choice, the transit share in the three scenarios is
shown in Figure 11. As expected, home-based work and non-home-based work have the
highest transit shares, mainly due to the transit-friendly location of many workplaces in
downtown Baltimore and downtown Washington D.C. The BAU 2030 scenario shows a
slightly lower transit share, as the region has grown in less transit accessible areas. In the
HEP 2030 scenario, the transit share has approximately doubled in comparison to the
BAU 2030 scenario, as higher gasoline prices make it more attractive to switch to transit
where it is available.
Figure 11. Transit Share by Purpose
Vehicle-miles traveled (VMT) are a common way to assess the total travel on the
highway network. Figure 12 compares VMT in the three scenarios by State, including
Washington D.C. Note that these VMT numbers only include travel on the network
covered by the megaregional model. Though the national layer of the model generates
long-distance trips with trip ends outside of the megaregion, no short-distance trips are
generated outside of the megaregion. In other words, total VMT in Pennsylvania is larger
than shown in Figure 12, as only the part of Pennsylvania covered by the CBM study
area is shown.
Between 2007 and 2030, VMT within the CBM region grew by 41%. This is due to a
combination of growth in less transit-friendly areas and a general increase in population
and income. The HEP scenario generates 19% less VMT than the BAU scenario. While
higher gas prices will be a serious burden on many households and businesses, a positive
side effect would be a relief in congestion and reduced transportation-related emissions.
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 87
Figure 12. Vehicle-miles Traveled by State, Including Washington D.C.
The scenarios show that transportation is significantly affected by changes in auto-
operating cost. Effects include reduction in number of trips, shorter trip lengths and,
where available, modal shifts from auto to transit.
7. Conclusions
The scenario results could only be achieved by integrating modules (horizontal
integration) and geographies (vertical integration) into one megaregional model. Given
the size of a megaregion, it is relevant to distinguish short-distance and long-distance
travel. Even though every model gains from horizontal and vertical integration, a
megaregional model benefits particularly due to the number of interactions and the
geographic size. Integrating modules allows simulating complex interactions as found in
the real world.
The model further allows analyzing the implications of scenarios on sub-regions and
urban areas. By isolating those communities, population segments (e.g., by income,
transit-accessible) and industries vulnerable to higher energy prices, the megaregion can
use this analysis to identify policies to shore up these areas. This may help planning for a
megaregion that is most resilient for economically competing under a high-energy price
future.
The scenarios show a significant reduction in number of trips, trip length, auto share
and vehicle miles traveled under the high-energy scenario. This would result in less
congestion, fewer vehicle-hours of delay and a reduction of transportation-related
emissions. However, such high surge in transportation costs will be a significant burden
for many businesses and households, particularly those with lower incomes. In addition,
air travel, which has not been modeled in this context, is expected to be affected severely
by such high prices for gasoline. Though the exact impact is beyond this research, parts of
the economy are likely to endure serious pressure under such a scenario as well.
Each module has been calibrated to match base year data for 2007, which included
traffic counts for the transportation model, zonal households and employment for the land
use model, and state employment and commodity flows for the economic model. The
validation shows that the model is able to replicate base year conditions, even though the
validation does not necessarily proof reasonable model sensitivities. Each module went
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
88 Copyright 2015 SERSC
through a series of sensitivity tests to assess reasonable responsiveness heuristically. A
more thorough analysis, however, would have been a back-casting study. In such
analyses, the base year is set to a year in the past, such as 2000, and model results are
compared to the most recent available current data, such as 2012. If the model back-casts
changes from 2000 to 2012 reasonably, it would provide additional confidence that the
model is capable of generating reasonable forecasts as well. Unfortunately, moving a
model year is difficult as it requires collecting socio-economic data at the zonal level,
updating highway networks, collecting traffic performance data (vehicle counts and VMT
estimates), and gathering transit schedules and routings for a new model year. Given the
size of the study area, data collection requires merging and reconciling datasets from
various states, making it even more challenging to move the model year. As this research
focused on the integration of various models, more effort was spent on developing
methods of model integration, rather than spending too much time on data collection,
back-casting and model validation.
Nevertheless, given the limited availability of natural resources and the global increase
of demand for oil, a reduction in oil supply is inevitable in the future. Political unrest in
some oil-producing regions further contributes to the increase of oil prices. The point of
time by which the price for gasoline will rise to levels simulated in the HEP scenario is
unknown. Regardless of whether it takes another ten years or fifty years, it is almost
certain that the price for gasoline will rise to this level and beyond given the limitedness
of resources and a worldwide growing demand. Though the impact will be severe both on
the economy and on travel behavior, preparing a region for a high-energy price future
may help mitigating negative impacts. Regions that are prepared are likely to cope more
easily with the impacts of high gas prices. Changing land-use policies or redesigning the
transportation system takes decades to show effects. The comparatively small price spike
in 2008 happened within a matter of a few months, moving at a much faster speed than
changes to land-use or to the transportation system may be implemented. Preparing a
region before a steep price increase hits gives a region a competitive advantage in a high-
energy price future.
Though some policies, such as environmental regulation or taxation, are most effective
at the national or even global level, the megaregion is the appropriate entity to address
many policies helping to prepare a region for increasing gas prices. If a single city limited
urban sprawl, some households would move to a neighboring city without regulations, as
housing prices might be lower. In contrast, if a megaregion defines land-use policies, the
entire region will develop consistently. To a large extent the transportation system serves
to connect urban regions. The megaregion is the most efficient level to implement region-
wide transportation policies and to develop an integrated transportation infrastructure
system that prepares the region for future challenges.
References
[1] R. Florida, T. Gulden and C. Mellander, The rise of the megaregion”, Cambridge Journal of Regions,
Economy and Society, vol. 1, pp. 459-476.
[2] K. R. Kunzmann, La "Banane blue" est morte! Vive la "Grappe européenne"! In: 13 Conseil General
des Ponts et Chaussées, Bureau de la Communication (Eds.) Les Cahier 14 Du Conseil. Espace
Europeen & Politique Française des Transports, (2001) February, pp. 38-41.
[3] A. A. Amekudzi, L. Thomas-Mobley and C. Ross, Transportation Planning and Infrastructure Delivery
in Major Cities and Megacities”, Transportation Research Record, vol. 1997 / 2007, (2007), pp. 17-23.
[4] W. Christaller, Central places in southern Germany”, Trans. Charlisle W. Baskin. Prentice Hall:
London, (1966 [1933]).
[5] A. Lösch, The economics of location”, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, (1954).
[6] C. L. Ross and M. Woo, Identifying megaregions in the United States: Implications for infrastructure
investment”, Ross, Catherine L. (Ed.) Megaregions: Planning for global competitiveness, Island Press:
Washington, DC, (2009).
[7] J. Gottmann, Megalopolis. The Urbanized Northeastern Seaboard of the United States”, The Twentieth
Century Fund: New York, (1961).
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
Copyright 2015 SERSC 89
[8] J. Gottmann and R. A. Harper, Since Megalopolis”, The Urban Writings of Jean Gottmann. The Johns
Hopkins University Press: Baltimore and London, (1990).
[9] E. M. Hoover and F. Giarrantani, Introduction to regional economics, 3rd ed. Knopf: New York, NY,
(1995).
[10] K. A. Fox and T. Krishna Kumar, The functional economic area: Delineation and implications for
economic analysis and policy”, In Urban-regional economics, social system accounts, and eco-
behavioral science: Selected writings of Karl A. Fox. James R. Prescott, Paul van Moeskeke, and Jati K.
Sengupta, eds. Iowa State University Press: Ames, (1994).
[11] C. J. Dawkins, Regional Development Theory: Conceptual Foundations, Classic Works, and Recent
Developments”, Journal of Planning Literature. CPL Bibliography 370 18, 2, (2003), pp. 131-172.
[12] H. W. Richardson, Regional economics”, University of Illinois Press: Urbana, IL, (1978).
[13] Regional Plan Association, America 2050: A Prospectus. New York, NY, (2006).
[14] Y. Hagler, Defining U.S. megaregions”, America 2050: New York, NY, (2009).
[15] C. L. Ross, M. Woo, J. Barringer, H. West and J. Lynn Harbour Doyle, Identifying megaregions in the
U.S.: Implications for infrastructure investment, Center for Quality Growth and Regional
Development: Atlanta, GA, (2008).
[16] R. E. Lang and A. C. Nelson, The rise of the megapolitans, Planning, (2007) January, pp. 7-12.
[17] C. L. Ross, Megaregions: Literature review of the implications for U.S. infrastructure investment and
transportation planning”, U.S. Department of Transportation Federal, (2008).
[18] B. M. McCarthy, “LIFT: INFORUM’s model for the U.S. Economy”, Economics Systems Research, vol.
3, no. 1, (1991), pp. 15-36.
[19] INFORUM (2010) STEMS and LIFT Model. Online resource:
http://www.inforum.umd.edu/services/models/ stems.html, accessed October 2010.
[20] BLS (2013) Overview of BLS Statistics on Employment. Online resource:
http://www.bls.gov/bls/employment.htm
[21] I. S. Lowry, A Model of Metropolis. Memorandum RM-4035-RC. Santa Monica, Rand Corporation,
(1964).
[22] BMC (2007). Baltimore Region Travel Demand Model. Version 3.3. 2000 Validation. Baltimore,
Baltimore Metropolitan Council.
[23] D. Beagan, M. Fischer and A. Kuppam, Quick Response Freight Manual II”, Washington, FHWA: 296,
(2007).
[24] R. Moeckel and R. Donnelly, Nationwide Estimate of Long-Distance Travel (NELDT)”, Generating
External Trips for Local Travel Demand Models. Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research
Forum, Long Beach, CA, (2011).
[25] EPA (2011) MOVES (Motor Vehicle Emission Simulator). Online resource:
http://www.epa.gov/otaq/models/moves/index.htm, accessed November 2011.
[26] H. Gunn, The Netherlands National Model: a Review of Seven Years of Application”, International
Transactions in Operational Research, vol. 1, no. 2, (1994), pp. 125-133.
[27] J. Fox, A. Daly and H. Gunn, “Review of RAND Europe’s Transport Demand Model Systems”, Report
prepared by RAND Europe for TRL Limited, (2003).
[28] M. Wegener, SASI Model Description”, Working Paper 08/01.Spiekermann& Wegener, Urban and
Regional Research. Dortmund, (2008) August. Online Resource: http://spiekermann-
wegener.de/mod/pdf/AP_0801.pdf. Accessed on May 22, 2013, .
[29] Z. Zhang, K. Spansel and B. Wolshon, Megaregion Network Simulation for Evacuation Analysis”,
Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, vol. 2397, (2013), pp.
161-170.
[30] C. Lindner and A. Hill, Simulating informal urban growth in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania A CA-based
land-use simulation model supporting strategic urban planning, Koch, A.; Mandl, P. (Eds.): Modeling
and simulating urban processes, Lit Verlag, Wien, Münster, S., (2011), pp. 77-97.
[31] R. Donnelly, G. D. Erhard, R. Moeckel and W. A. Davidson, Advanced Practices in Travel
Forecasting. Transportation Research Board, National Cooperative Highway Research Program. Report
406. Washington, D.C. Online Resource: http://onlinepubs.trb.org/onlinepubs/nchrp/nchrp_syn_406.pdf.
Accessed May 22, 2013, (2010).
[32] J. E. Brandmeyer and H. A. Karimi, Coupling methodologies for environmental models”,
Environmental Modelling & Software, vol. 15, (2000), pp. 479-488.
Authors
Rolf Moeckel, Dr.-Ing., works as a Faculty Research Assistant at the National
Center for Smart Growth Research and Education at the University of Maryland. His
main interest is to understand how computer modeling may support urban and
regional planning. He has worked extensively on integrating land-use with
transportation modeling. He has developed and implemented three land-use models
International Journal of Transportation
Vol.3, No.1 (2015)
90 Copyright 2015 SERSC
and continues researching how to integrate such models with travel demand models.
To support regional and statewide planning, statewide or even megaregional travel
demand models help decision makers prioritizing projects and policies. Dr. Moeckel
has worked on nine statewide models across the U.S. Within these models, he has
designed and implemented long-distance travel demand models for both person
travel and freight travel. Prior to joining the National Center for Smart Growth, he
worked with the Parsons Brinckerhoff as a Principal Professional Associate where
he developed a wide range of models, including activity-based, mode choice, land
use and freight models. He is a member of the TRB committee Travel Forecasting
Resource (ADB45) and holds a doctorate in Spatial Planning from the University of
Dortmund in Germany.
Sabyasachee (Sabya) Mishra, Ph.D., is an Assistant Professor with the Department of
Civil Engineering at the University of Memphis. He is also affiliated faculty of the
Intermodal Freight Transportation Institute at University of Memphis. His areas of
expertise include Travel Demand Modeling, Transportation Planning and Policy,
Econometric Modeling, Transportation Economics and Finance. Over the last few years,
he has been involved in the development of statewide transportation models for various
states as these models cater to short term and long term decision making of multimodal
transportation system. He is a member of Transportation Economics (ABE20), and
Freight Transportation Economics and Regulations (AT010) committees of the
Transportation Research Board (TRB).
Fred Ducca, Ph.D., is Director of the Transportation Policy Research Group for the
National Center for Smart Growth, research and Education at the University of Maryland.
He has 27 years of experience in research, development, deployment and training in travel
forecasting methods and procedures, including extensive experience providing technical
assistance to state and local governments on travel forecasting issues. While with the
Federal Highway Administration he managed the Travel Model Improvement Program
(TMIP). This program advanced both the state of the art and state of the practice in travel
forecasting. Dr. Ducca has a B.S. in mathematics from St. Peter’s College, an MBA from
the University of Pennsylvania and a Ph.D. in City Planning, also from the University of
Pennsylvania.
Tara Weidner, PE, is an Integrated Transportation Analysis Engineer in ODOT’s
Transportation Planning Analysis Unit (TPAU). She has over 20 years of experience in
modeling and analysis of multi-modal transportation systems. Her recent work has
focused on quantifying the complex interactions of transportation, land use, and the
environment. She joined TPAU about a year ago after working as a Senior Planner for
Parsons Brinkerhoff (PB), where she led the consultant team partnering with the
University of Maryland that worked on the FHWA Mega-regions project. This project
included a case study using an expanded Maryland Statewide Model to look at the effect
of high gas prices on the resilience of the Chesapeake Bay Mega-Region. Tara has played
a key role in the integrated land use-transport models for Maryland as well as for the
states of Oregon, Washington, and Ohio.
Article
The integrated Transport Land-use and Energy (iTLE) model is combined with traffic and emission simulators to examine the effects of electric vehicle (EV) adoption on traffic networks and greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions reduction. The research uses data from the 2022 Halifax Travel Activity (HaliTRAC) survey to develop an EV type choice model within iTLE, while traffic and emission simulators are created on PTV VISUM and MOVES3.0 platforms. Along with the base case scenario (2022), two more scenarios are considered at five-year intervals: 2027 (scenario-1), and 2032 (scenario-2). The traffic assignment model is calibrated and validated for the base year (2022) considering traffic volume data of fifty (50) different intersections of Halifax Regional Municipality (HRM). The findings reveal that the younger generation, higher-income households, and full-time workers are more inclined to adopt EVs in the future. The estimated EV adoption rate for 2027 is 16.3% from the base year (2022), increasing to 31% by 2032. Regarding GHG emissions, the morning peak period in 2027 witnessed a notable 18.5% decrease compared to the base year of 2022, and in 2032, this reduction became even more substantial at 31.8% compared to 2027. Similarly, the evening peak period also experienced significant declines, with a 22.4% decrease in 2027 and a more remarkable 32.9% reduction in 2032. The outcomes of this research will be valuable for urban planners, engineers, and government officials when implementing climate action plans as they devise effective policy measures related to vehicles.
Article
The megaregion is viewed as a platform from which to address a variety of issues. Despite agreement that a megaregion is a large, globally connected urban agglomeration, there is no consensus as to how to delineate its boundaries and how it differs from other urban forms. The scholarly literature is dominated by three distinct analytic approaches: interdependent systems, nodal linkages, and satellite data. We assess the utility of each approach in delineating the boundaries of four megaregions – BosWash, Greater Tokyo, the Amsterdam-Brussels-Antwerp region, and a Global South megaregion – and conclude by proposing a sequence of steps to guide future research. • Highlights • Delineating megaregion boundaries; differentiation with other urban agglomerations. • Dominant approaches: interdependent systems, nodal linkages, and satellite data. • Megaregion vignettes: BosWash, Tokyo, Amsterdam-Brussels-Antwerp, and Global South. • Comparative analysis requires a clear, broadly accepted definition of megaregion. • Combine dominant approaches to clearly define megaregion and delineate boundaries.
Technical Report
Full-text available
NCFRP Research Report 38 provides a guidebook for conducting benefit-cost analyses of proposed infrastructure investments on multimodal, multijurisdictional freight corridors for public and private decision makers and other stakeholders at local, state, regional, and national levels in order to arrive at more informed investment decisions. http://nap.edu/24680
Article
The essentials of regional development forecasting are freely addressed in existing multidimensional approaches. Nowadays, despite the convenience of high-quality data, enhanced tools, and equipment that provide a good degree of realism in forecasting, the doors are open to confusion primarily because of the difficulty in appreciating such a large number of concepts, models, and experimental details. Based on this issue and practical examples, this paper presents common essentials in a demand-supply allocation model for regional development forecasting.
Article
It is an expensive and time-consuming task to develop a new model. Furthermore, a single model often cannot provide answers required for complex decision making based on multiple criteria. Coupling models are often applied to make use of existing models and analyze complex policy questions. This paper provides an overview of possible model integration approaches, briefly explains the modules that were integrated in a particular application, and focuses on the integration methods applied in this research. While the initial attempt was to integrate all models as tightly as possible, the authors developed a much more agile integration approach that allows adding and replacing individual modules easily. Python wrappers were developed to loosely couple land use, land cover, transportation, and emission models developed in different environments. ArcGIS Model Builder was used to provide a graphical user interface and to present the models’ workflow. The suggested approach is especially efficient when the models are developed in different programming languages, their source codes are not available, or the licensing restrictions make other coupling approaches impractical.
Article
By 2040, the US is ready to add another 100M residents which will be located in super regions that combines at least two, and often several, metropolitan areas, known as "megapolitan areas" or "megas" for short. Currently, regions with multiple cities, like Phoenix and Tucson, Tampa and Orlando, and San Antonio and Austin, are exhibiting the same pattern, where Dallas and Fort Worth converged in the 1960s, but on a more massive scale. The megapolitan concept was developed to depict where the next 100 million Americans will live. It is found 20 emerging megapolitan areas that are based on the US Census Bureau's definition of a combined statistical area (CSA). The main criterion for a census-defined CSA is economic interdependence, as evidenced by overlapping commuting patterns. Today, organizations like the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and the New York-based Regional Plan Association are also developing strategies in managing future metropolitan expansion.
Article
This paper describes a project to develop a microlevel traffic simulation for a megaregion. To accomplish that goal, a mass evacuation event was modeled with a traffic demand generation process that created a spatial and temporal distribution of departure times, origins, and destinations based on past hurricane scenarios. A megaregion-scale simulation was required to assess this event, because only at this level could traffic from multiple cities, over several days, with route assignments in multiple and overlapping directions be analyzed. One finding of the research was that it was possible to scale up and adapt existing models to reflect a simultaneous multicity evacuation covering a megaregion. The movements generated by the demand and operational models were logical and meaningful, and they were able to capture the key elements of the system, including the traffic progression over vast spaces and long time durations. They were also adequate to demonstrate the benefits of proactive traffic management strategies and the effect of increased and decreased advance warning times. The project also revealed numerous limitations of the existing modeling and computational processing capabilities. The knowledge and results gained from this research can be adapted and can be transferable for the evaluation of other locations with different road networks, populations, transportation resources, and hazard threats. Models such as this can also be modified to represent future anticipated growth and development in other large regions and can be used to evaluate the performance, varying conditions, and interrelationships between behavioral response and regional transportation management strategies.