ArticlePDF Available

A Reflection on Sustainability of Dollarization in Zimbabwe

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Joyce Chigome It is widely acknowledged that hyperinflation in Zimbabwe led to the abandonment of the local currency and the subsequent adoption of the multicurrency regime. Although literature has articulated on the benefits and disadvantages of dollarization in Zimbabwe, this paper rather tends to focus on the sustainability of dollarization. This is motivated by the notion that in the midst of evolving signs of the limitations of dollarization, research has tended to prescribe alternatives to dollarization seemingly discounting that its implementation came with huge costs which cannot be easily overlooked. For this reason, this paper advocates that policymakers need to explicitly embrace dollarization and avoid abrupt abandonment of the monetary regime as previously done with the Zimbabwean dollar. Therefore the purpose of this paper is to provide an insight into the factors that need to be considered for the sustainability of dollarization since its adoption was aimed at economic recovery and stabilization. The method employed here entails the use of an evaluative research approach and the findings show that there are some factors that enable sustainability of dollarization that are not out of reach but rather require a comprehensive systematic framework of macroeconomic reform adjusted for a dollarized economy.
Content may be subject to copyright.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
306
Journal homepage: http://www.journalijar.com INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL
OF ADVANCED RESEARCH
RESEARCH ARTICLE
A Reflection on Sustainability of Dollarization in Zimbabwe
Joyce Chigome
(Economics Department, Midlands State University, Zimbabwe)
Manuscript Info Abstract
Manuscript History:
Received: 15 May 2015
Final Accepted: 22 June 2015
Published Online: July 2015
Key words:
Sustainable, dollarization,
Zimbabwe
*Corresponding Author
Joyce Chigome
It is widely acknowledged that hyperinflation in Zimbabwe led to the
abandonment of the local currency and the subsequent adoption of the
multicurrency regime. Although literature has articulated on the benefits and
disadvantages of dollarization in Zimbabwe, this paper rather tends to focus
on the sustainability of dollarization. This is motivated by the notion that in
the midst of evolving signs of the limitations of dollarization, research has
tended to prescribe alternatives to dollarization seemingly discounting that its
implementation came with huge costs which cannot be easily overlooked.
For this reason, this paper advocates that policymakers need to explicitly
embrace dollarization and avoid abrupt abandonment of the monetary regime
as previously done with the Zimbabwean dollar. Therefore the purpose of
this paper is to provide an insight into the factors that need to be considered
for the sustainability of dollarization since its adoption was aimed at
economic recovery and stabilization. The method employed here entails the
use of an evaluative research approach and the findings show that there are
some factors that enable sustainability of dollarization that are not out of
reach but rather require a comprehensive systematic framework of
macroeconomic reform adjusted for a dollarized economy.
Copy Right, IJAR, 2015,. All rights reserved
INTRODUCTION
It is highly acknowledged that the chief cause of the radical changes in Zimbabwe’s monetary policy was a response
to aggravated price instability. The country faced a decade of severe economic meltdown and had hyperinflation of
over 231 million percent by July 2008. (CSO, 2008). According to rankings of the world’s hyperinflation (Bernhole,
2003), Zimbabwe would come after Serbia which had 390 million percent, showing the severity of the country’s
crisis. This led to the abandonment of the local currency in March 2009 and the adoption of the multiple currency
regime as a way of stabilizing the economy, improving business confidence and promoting economic growth. Whilst
it is generally conceived that dollarization is an intervention aimed at supporting economies with poor economic
policies, it may be asserted that the appreciation of the consequences of this suggested reality is somewhat lacking.
Despite the abundance of theoretical and empirical evidence on advantages and disadvantages of dollarization, it
may be suggested that the dollarization issue in Zimbabwe has not been meticulously tended to from a practical
approach.
This paper acknowledges that although the issues of dollarization cannot be generalized, theoretical prescriptions
and lessons from the experiences of other countries still remain indispensable. There is vast literature dwelling on
dollarization and with particular reference to Zimbabwe some of the studies include: Hanke (2008), Kairiza (2009 )
,Makochekanwa (2009), Chagonda (2010), Kramarenko et al (2010), Coomer and Gstraunthaler (2011), Noko
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
307
(2011) Makoto (2012), Mutengezanwa et al (2012), Pindiriri (2012), Richardson (2013), Sikwila (2013), Bonga and
Dhoro (2014) and Bonga et al (2014). Some of the concepts arising from these studies converge at establishing the
pros and cons of dollarization in Zimbabwe, the impact it has had on the economy thus far and others are more
concerned with what is appropriate after dollarization. Makoto (2012) suggests the introduction of bond coins into
circulation (this was implemented in December 2014 and March 2015) and Bonga et al (2014) provide an enquiry
into the effects of such action. Nonetheless, their findings barely suffice to the provision of a resolution whether or
not to pursue de-dollarization any further. Essentially, even after integrating some of the ideas from these
independent works there lay a challenge in forming a systematic view towards a pragmatic approach to sustainable
dollarization. This is based on the notion that the difficulty of reversing this process magnifies the need to consider
dollarization in a much larger sphere than usual evaluations of isolated aspects of the economy. (Berg and
Borensztein, 2000)
It is crucial to understand that the decision to move to dollarization is not only a monumental historical event but
rather a difficult one as it requires resources, time, and even threatens government legitimacy. Sikwila (2013, pp
403) provides a list of 25 African countries with past and present experience of dollarization, however, there is
insufficient empirical evidence of sustainability to learn from and thus making the dollarization experiment even
more difficult. Furthermore, it would be preposterous to presume that monetary and fiscal authorities are assertively
cognizant of what lies ahead and hence both policy makers and the society should be adequately knowledgeable
about some of the ways in which sustainable dollarization may be achieved. However, this paper discerns the
inadequacy of propagation of what should work to enable the sustainability of dollarization. By June 2010, Cabinet
had tasked the Minister of Finance to develop a paper on the course a currency regime for Zimbabwe’s future.
Notably, no conclusive emphatic conviction has been made to this call and considering the time that has lapsed, it
may not be prejudicial to assert the existence of inadequacies of the possible alternatives. In other instances,
sentiments from fiscal and monetary authorities reemphasize unwillingness to move from status quo and hence, this
paper affirms the possibility of an “intellectual gap” between theory and actual practice of policies that government
has instituted in a bid to sustain economic recovery. To this end, whilst it has been largely contended that the recent
economic slowdown is a product of poor policies alone, emphasis should also consider the possibility of
sucretization - early warning signs of the limitations of dollarization. Despite these setbacks, this paper concurs with
Sikwila (2013) that Zimbabwe should not abandon the current regime without having fulfilled the motives that led to
its adoption.
Although, the country showed some slight economic recovery at the onset of dollarization, literature foundations
suggest the basis for sustainability of dollarization relates to the establishment and sustenance of significant changes
in the functioning of an economy. It is expected that in the short-run dollarized economies experience some growth
and improved price stability. However, the medium and long term would require the growth of productive activities
to be channeled to the foreign sector because the domestic sector would still be facing the effects of depression from
previous economic instability. Furthermore, speculative activities are discouraged with calls being made to advance
towards productivity and efficiency to be able to be competitive in the foreign market. Nevertheless, Zimbabwe is
currently compounded with a wide range of problems which have seriously threatened fiscal sustainability and
overall economic performance. Some of the challenges include: business closure, relatively lower wages,
unemployment, low foreign investment and liquidity shortages. These may be the result of the inadequacies in the
management of the initial boom experienced just after the inception of dollarization.
It is important to note that prior to dollarization, Zimbabwe barely prepared for it by means of assembling the
required base upon which the regime could be incorporated into the economy. Whilst it may be viewed as
unrealistic to plan such a process in the midst of severe economic meltdown, some of the expected outcomes from
bypassing the process are evident. In this regard, the major contribution setting this work apart from many others is
that it acknowledges the no-existence of the best currency regime but rather emphasizes that the relevant resolution
is to embrace the multicurrency regime as the most appropriate at this given time, given the constraints faced by the
country.
Roubini (2001), Rojas-Suarez (2003) and Lupupa (2003) provide some theoretical and empirical foundation on
issues pertinent to the examination of sustainability. Although some of the ground work is set from previous
literature on Zimbabwe, this paper closely follows the approach in Rojas-Suarez (2003) guiding principles for a
sustainable regime, Roubini (2001) and Lupupa (2003) to identify some of the factors constraining the sustainability
of dollarization in Zimbabwe and to suggest possible directions for policy reform aimed at reducing or eliminating
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
308
the limitations of dollarization. This is critical to avoid abrupt and unruly desertion of the multicurrency regime. As
such this paper serves as a primary guide to policy makers and practitioners on sustaining dollarization. However,
the modalities to the formulation of a systematic and comprehensive reform package are left for further research.
This paper is split into five sections: Section One presents the introduction; Section Two focuses on the
characterization of sustainability of dollarization; Section Three discusses the methodology; Section Four focuses on
the identification of some key macroeconomic indicators and key structural reforms that may be required for the
sustainability of dollarization in Zimbabwe and Section Five provides the conclusion. .
2. CHARACTERIZATION OF SUSTAINABILITY OF DOLLARIZATION
This section dwells on describing some of the key institutional and operational issues pertaining to sustainability of
dollarization. The issue under consideration is the assurance of dollarization to receive ample support from the
public even after several years from its inception. This is expected if inflation declines, growth and employment
increase reasonably, interest rates decline, wide availability of credit and longer term and the vitality of export
activities. However, this necessitates the need for supplementary policies to guarantee success and the full
exploitation of the virtuous reform circle. (Hausmann and Powell, 1999)
According to Berg and Borensztein (2000) the absence of historical experiences to draw lessons from poses greater
difficulty in dealing with this issue. Moreover, the circumstances in which dollarized countries find themselves in
are contextualized that what may work in one country may have adverse effects on another. For instance Panama
has had some success with dollarization and has very close political, historical and economic ties with the United
States; however this may not be apparent for any other dollarized country. Mazzaferro (2002) suggested that
sustained cases of dollarization/euroisation highlight three essential characteristics which include; real integration
through development of tourism, financial integration through offshore finances and large fiscal transfers from
anchor countries. However, it is commended that caution should be exercised with regards to viewing the features as
desirable for sustainable dollarization .In a study on Turkey, Metin-Ozcan and Us (2007) observe that the economy
signaled dedollarization in 2001 with unfavourable macroeconomic conditions being evident and whilst the
economy contained its inertia. However, by 2006 dedollarization had become defunct. Leaval et al (2003)
investigated the impact of dollarization on the tourism industry in Ecuador and suggests that it did not follow
through the predictions of theory and such concluded that it was better to get rid of it before it destroyed the
economy. It is asserted that there were inadequacies fiscal sustainability, well-functioning labour markets,
appropriate legislation, and the enforcement of laws. Therefore, dollarization in Ecuador could lead to a financial
crisis similar to that of Argentina and would have to create a new currency and financial system. According to
Leavall et al (2003) Ecuador was ill-suited for dollarization. These cases highlight the complexity of identifying
factors that may be of practical significance in actually sustaining dollarization in different countries.
Winkler (2005) suggests that the bipolar view of sustainable exchange rate regimes and optimal theory of currency
area allude to credibility of monetary commitment as being fundamental to sustain dollarization. Furthermore, it is
suggested that there is need for an independent monetary policy as an adjustment mechanism in the emergence of
systematic socks. However, Calvo and Reinhart (2001) criticizes the standard theory of optimal currency by
asserting that in the light of recent global financial crises some other factors become more pertinent, for instance, the
existence of partial dollarization, imperfect credibility and weak financial systems. In this regard, for small
economies dollarization would be very attractive even in the face of loss of control of monetary policy. Moreover,
the challenge of Lender of last resort would not necessarily be a major drawback as long as there could be access to
foreign funds. According to Trejos (2003) the global trend towards openness makes it undesirable and unfeasible
for small economies to maintain a central bank with currency independence. It is expected that as countries move
into international trade, substantial volumes of money should start flowing. Schuler and Stein (2000) suggest that
financial integration would then become critical. These differences are largely attributed to the dynamics of the
global economy and hence theory predictions may require constant re-evaluation. However, it is vital to note that
country experiences differ. Calvo (2002) highlights that although both Ecuador and El Salvador decided to dollarize,
their motivations were different. In the former, there was economic and banking crisis although the conditions were
fairly stable in the latter. After dollarization, Ecuador experienced exchange rate misalignment, deflation and
problems concerning price risk of assets and liabilities in the financial sector. It is suggested that public sector and
fiscal policy reforms could address these problems. Comparatively, both Ecuador and El Salvador saw
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
309
improvements in banking sector performance and competitiveness although the magnitudes differed because
enhanced competitiveness in El Salvador which had adhered to international accounting standards. Bradbury and
Vernengo (2008) suggest that in Ecuador, the source of external funds was reliance on remittances however quizzed
its influence on the potential of sustainable the sustenance of the economy. The situation was quite different from
Argentina who had substantial international capital flows. Nonetheless, Quispe-Agnoli and Whisler (2003) suggest
that the time frame was too little to make an assessment of sustainability of dollarization in these economies.
Starr (2001) focused on the political and economic variables believed to influence the variability of sustaining
dollarization. The contribution of the work was premised on departing from the convention of pursuing a theoretical
approach and focus on practical issues which would reflect on policy relevancy. Some of the suggested political
factors include the presence of cushioning institutions where it is reiterated that society must be willing and able to
contain the costs of adjustments. On the other hand, it is suggested that the degree of conflict in the society is crucial
in order to minimize divisions and competing interest that poses threats to sustainability of dollarization. Finally,
Starr (2001) alludes to the essence of government capacity as reflected by governments’ ability to induce society to
absorb costs of adjustment and willingness of society losers to absorb the costs of adjustment as well. It is suggested
that government capacity may thrive better in the face of strong political parties and well-functioning democracy.
According to Nelms (2012), long-term sustainability of dollarization may also be threatened by extensive public
investment and expansionary fiscal policy funded from loans from other countries.
Gruben et al (2003) asserts that prior to implementing dollarization certain requirements need to be satisfied to
ensure long-term sustainability of the monetary regime. Similarly, Eichengreen (2002) identifies some pre-
conditions for dollarization and suggests that debate surrounding the issue was centered on two views. In the first, it
is affirmed that dollarization should take place upon the completion of complementary reforms and the other view
asserts that dollarization would yield the necessary changes required for smooth operation of the new currency
regime. In view of the first notion some of the basics involved labour market reform, fiscal reform, and financial
sector reform. According to Jácome and Lönnberg (2010), trade reform is also essential. Gruben et al (2003) also
alludes to the importance of a referendum in which the majority must agree to the implementation of dollarization.
Although it may appear as a waste of time, bypassing it may lead to opposition by competing society interests citing
the flows of dollarization as inadequacy of democracy and possibly threatening government. Based on the results of
Mutengezanwa et al (2012) indications are that many people consider the multicurrency regime better than any
option and hence abrupt changes to this situation may prompt lack of cooperation. Notably, Mutengezanwa et al
(2012) show that from their sample 78% were against the return of the Zimbabwean dollar and hence conclude that
the country is not ready. To this end, it reinforces the notions by Gruben et al (2003) and hence, this study affirms
that this highlights the need to fully embrace dollarization and find ways of making it sustainable. According to
Kairiza (2009) dedollarization should be an endogenous outcome of a policy of macroeconomic stabilization which
this paper posits as being possible only if the multicurrency regime is sustained to bring about that condition. This is
contradictory to those who have advocated for dedollarization (Makoto, 2012) in the country’s present
environmental state. Kairiza (2009) concludes that dedollarization would only succeed in the face of market reforms.
According to Roubini (2001) there are pre-conditions to be satisfied if a country is to achieve success of
dollarization. Although the guide was desirable for countries considering the implementation of dollarization, this
paper posits that some of the underlying concepts of success remain predominantly the same even. Lupupa (2003)
examined long-term sustainability of dollarization as a policy decision and uses the pre-conditions of dollarization to
shed light on examining sustainability. The paper focused on Ecuador and Bolivia who used different strategies to
exchange rate and inflation management.
3. METHODOLOGY
This paper is largely influenced by the method laid out by Hofstee (2006; pp 126) and therefore employs an
analytical qualitative approach which involve aspects of evaluative research. Reference is made to the different
criterion used to assess sustainability of dollarization and data from monthly and annual publications from IMF,
RBZ, World Bank, Zimstat and Ministry of Finance. Although a quantitative analysis could have been carried out,
the time frame since the inception of the multicurrency regime to limited to provide data suitable for such an
assessment. However, the method employed here seeks to reach a conclusion by reviewing the factors that need to
be considered for the sustainability of dollarization in Zimbabwe. The evaluative approach taken here is adopted
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
310
from a study done by Roubini (2001) and Lupupa (2003) as they provide a comprehensive identification of some
factors upon which the analysis of this study is based on. The appraisal is combined with theoretical explanations
describing why the selected factors should be of prime importance to Zimbabwe.
4. MACROECONOMIC INDICATORS AND IMPLICATIONS FOR STRUCTURAL REFORM
This section is devoted to the analysis of the performance of some macroeconomic indicators and subsequent
structural reforms to be made where necessary.
4.1 Policy credibility and inflation experience
Policy credibility may be defined as the belief that responsible authorizes are able to execute policies in ways that
will ultimately lead to the achievement of expected goals. The wavering of this belief is the advent of loss of policy
credibility and can be measured some factors like: history inflation, exchange rate instability and the country’s fiscal
record. Lupupa (2003) suggests that dollarization itself represents the ability of a country to assume the credibility of
monetary policy of countries with stable currencies and eliminates currency risk thereby reducing speculative
activities. Fig. 1 shows that Zimbabwe has a strong history of monetary instability as indicated by the inflation rate
of over 231 million percent by July 2008. On the basis of using inflation history as a criterion to assess policy
credibility, there is solemn need for commitment to strict monetary rules to enable longterm policy credibility.
Recent figures since the inception of dollarization show controlled inflation however, it is suggested that the country
is operating in a near deflation environment as indicated in the country’s national budget statement for 2015. Figure
2 shows the inflation profile for the period 2013-2014 (Ministry of Finance, 2015) and indicates a slowdown in
inflation and subsequently the figures for April 2015, month-on-month inflation was at -0.89% and year-on-year
inflation was at -2.65%. (ZimStat, 2015). Amid lack of consensus on what this means, others argue that there is
disinflation, others assert it to be deflation and some have dismissed any potential threat by citing it as an indication
of price correction. Chief among them are the responsible monetary authorities as alluded to by RBZ (2015).
Nonetheless, according to literature on price stability, inflation is asserted to be better than deflation and thus if there
exists a threat in reality, the sustainability of dollarization is largely at risk. This may thus require urgent inquiry to
the existence of the risk of deflation in Zimbabwe. Experiences of deflation cases are significant in countries like
Japan and global concerns have risen in the Eurozone but there is a very little background to work with if the case is
assumed for dollarized countries. It is widely accepted that a healthy benchmark for inflation should be 2%. It
implies that in order to regain credibility, monetary authorities should work against deflation although the common
trend has been inflation control. Evidently, Zimbabwe has no experience with successfully dealing with deflation
because there is no record of it in the greater part of the country’s macroeconomic turbulence. This is likely to
further constrain the success of dollarization if the threat of deflation becomes apparent in the near or far future.
4.2 Reserve coverage of monetary base and capacity to run lender of last resort functions
Calvo (1999) argues against critics of dollarization that the function of lender of last resort is not only linked to the
ability to print money. As long as there are alternatives to providing bank liquidity then it is possible to sustain
dollarization. The view that is largely opposed by Calvo (1999) is quite evident in Zimbabwe as some have called
for the return of the local currency based on the notion that the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe is being limited.
According to Roubini (2001) it is essential that the foreign exchange reserves of a dollarized country should at least
cover the monetary base or the currency in circulation unless there is provision to borrow the necessary reserves
from private creditors. An extension to this would be to further require coverage of the central banks liabilities.
However, rising foreign currency liabilities of the central bank may undermine the credibility of the dollarization.
On the other hand, this criterion may be used to assess whether a central bank has the ability to provide the functions
of lender of last resort. Alternative ways to achieve this function include: borrowing from the private sector or
international financial institutions, alterations in the reserve requirement ratios may provide further liquidity to a
banking system and seigniorage revenue-sharing arrangements.
By January 2008, the foreign assets were about 0.1% of monetary base (Hanke, 2008) and according to the World
Bank Global Economic indicator (2015) show that the average foreign exchange reserves for the period March 2014
to February 2015 is about 484.41 and the net change is -0.39%.. In 2009, net foreign assets amounted to -$845
million and -$680 million in 2010. Projections from IMF (2012) show that net foreign assets were -$485 million in
2013 and -$401 million in 2014 and as such figures to 2017 indicate an increase in net foreign assets to -$151.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
311
Nonetheless, monetary base figures for 2009 and 2010 were $125 million and $256 million respectively. In 2013,
monetary base rose to $468 million, $553 million in 2014 and $802 million by 2017. According to Besada (2011)
the amount of reserves after dollarization has been inadequate in terms of covering the country’s monetary base and
this trend still persists as explained by periodic reviews by the central bank. This largely compromises the ability to
execute the function of lender of last resort.
According to Roubini (2001) solvency is critical for any central bank operating in a dollarized economy and
becomes more essential if seigniorage is not shared with the anchor country. It is therefore suggested that the central
bank solvency problem may be abated by making implicit seigniorage from non-remunerated reserve requirements
of the banking system, explicit seigniorage revenue sharing with the anchor country used to recapitalize the central
bank and any other or possible ways of recapitalization. This highlights the importance of the creation of a strong
financial sector with a significant foreign bank presence as receiving countries can take advantage on the lender of
last resort, liquidity access, supervision and regulation that its foreign banks receive from home bank authorities and
head offices. However, it still remains essential to have the central bank operating if its functions are not offered by
the central bank of the anchor country. (Roubini, 2001). Likewise, there is need for sound, competitive, well-
supervised and well-regulated banking system to avoid fiscal costs and economic angst. In Zimbabwe government
cannot afford to bear the fiscal costs to bail out the banking sector given the already limited lender of last resort
resources.
4.3 State of public finances
The smaller is the budget deficit and the stock of public debt, the smaller is the risk that dollarization might fail. In
fact, unsustainable fiscal conditions may eventually tempt policy makers to reverse dollarization and return to a
domestic currency enabling printing presses so as to regain access to the inflation tax. Severe fiscal problems may
also undermine the confidence of the public in the fiscal authorities and lead to a foreign debt-related financial crisis.
Zhou (2012) acknowledges that debt distress is apparent in Zimbabwe and Mupunga and Le Roux (2014) suggest
that issuing debt and increases its vulnerability of the country to further risk of debt distress. In such a critical time
when sustainability of dollarization is at stake, there is need to review the chief causes of this persistent behaviour if
serious reform is to be undertaken.
4.4 External debt and financing requirements
According to Lupupa (2003), countries with large external debts and structural weaknesses in tax systems limit the
scope of fiscal policy in dollarized economy. Notwithstanding the reduced usefulness of monetary policy, fiscal
policy remains as major tool at the country’s disposal. According to Roubini (2001), the stock of the external debt of
a dollarizing country and its external debt servicing requirements will affect the success of dollarization. This factor
becomes crucial amid the possibility of the emergence of financial crises associated with excessive external debt.
However, if a country pragmatically pursues disciplined fiscal policies this may aid in reducing the severity of
adverse effects that may undermine the success of dollarization. Nonetheless, as long as external debt accumulation
is excessive and public debt poorly managed the prospect of financial crises looming is high. The issue of debt
management is very crucial because of its limitations on access to development funds from international financial
institutions. Chikova (2013) reflects on the debt management problem in Zimbabwe and attempts to shed light on
why the country is failing to sustain its external debt stock despite having a constitutional framework to address the
problem. In 2009, external debt was 118% of GDP and approximately US $10 billion by 2013 and considered highly
unsustainable. (Ministry of Finance, 2013). On the other hand, Saungweme and Mufandaedza (2013) assert that the
serious debt overhang in Zimbabwe emanates from the growth of external debt stock and lack of debt servicing.
Government adopted the Zimbabwe Accelerated Arrears Clearance, Debt and Development Strategy (ZAADDS) in
April 2011 and aimed at working on the removal of sanctions and clearance arrears, new financing and full debt
relief; and securitization in pursuit of debt relief and development. Nonetheless, these efforts barely sufficed to
reducing the country’s debt. According to IMF (2013), by the end of 2012, external debt overhang was 88 % and
attributed to subdued economic growth and placed limitations on acquisition of finance. Although government
formulated a comprehensive macroeconomic reform agenda, the average of the external debt to GDP ratio computed
from statistics in RBZ (2015) for the period 2009 to 2014 remained relatively high at 69.23%. Taking cognisance of
these factors, it is evident that Zimbabwe’s external debt and financing pose a huge challenge to the sustainability of
the dollarization. Possible reforms would have to be well informed on why the country continues to suffer this
predicament despite the substantial work and effort that has been directed to debt management. Only then can
reform resolutions be formulated in accordance with the constraints faced.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
312
4.5 Ability to effectively pursue counter-cyclical monetary policy
It is essential to determine whether monetary policy may be able provide counter-cyclical output stabilization in
order to evaluate the possibility of dollarization undermining the ability to even output fluctuations. The
determination of counter-cyclical monetary policy depends on factors like policy credibility and the extent of
indexation of wages. From the discussion of policy credibility, the resolution lies in cross evaluation of monetary
policy and fiscal policy to institute measures undermining price stability. Nevertheless, as alluded to by Lupupa
(2003), the absence of an exchange rate policy leaves employment and output as potential stabilizers from external
shocks. It raises concerns over the creation or extension of the ability of monetary policy to be able to influence
output fluctuations as they in turn affect the ability to absorb external shock. This situation presents an ultimate
paradox. In one hand, theory predicts that it is good for countries like Zimbabwe to be under dollarization due to
lack of credibility of monetary policy. On the other hand, theory suggests that the need to pursue counter-cyclical
monetary policy. In this regard, this paper advocates for a systematic framework that incorporates economy wide
aspects of the benefits and limitations of dollarization in order to craft policy reform to balance the trade-offs.
4.6 Correlation with the US business cycle and Trade integration
Correlation depends on the magnitude of trade integration and similarities in production structures. According to
RBZ (2009), the US dollar is predominantly used for transactions by both government and the private sector.
However, Mundell (1961) prescribes that a precondition for dollarization is the existence of close trade links with an
anchor country if the situation is to be sustainable in the long-run. Table 2 shows the distribution of Zimbabwe’s
averages of exports and imports during 2000 to 2008. According to ZimStat (2015), exports to the US from
Zimbabwe were at $9, 46million in 2009 and rose to $29, 16 million in 2010 and began to fall in 2011 to $16, 26
million by 2012. For the same period, in 2009, imports were $274, 98 million and rose to $744, 47 million in 2010
and declined in 2011 to $558, 08 million by 2012. Nonetheless, trade with the US is classified as being far from that
of a major trading partner. During the period 2000-2008, average imports and exports between Zimbabwe and the
US were 3% and 4% respectively. After the adoption of the multicurrency regime, Zimbabwe predominantly uses
the US dollar for both public and private sector transactions although the South African Rand is termed the reference
currency. Nonetheless, exports to the US constitute about 4, 5% of trade. South Africa was Zimbabwe’s major
trading partner whilst trade with the US was below 5% for both components. After the inception of the
multicurrency regime, South Africa still remains Zimbabwe’s major trading partner however, there is no evidence of
significant improved trade integration with the US. The level of significance prescribed here is defined by levels of
trade that would relate to theory predictions. Mundell (1961) and McKinnon (1963) assert that high integration of
commodity trade tends to lead to natural correlations in the fluctuations of private sector activities and hence there
would be no need for monetary policy independence. However, Zimbabwe’s business cycle is far from that of the
US and Berg et al (2003) suggests that in the face of differences in the level of development, high integration is
insufficient to bring the benefits to trade as postulated by theory. In principle it means that, the benefits of assuming
the monetary policy of the US would be more apparent only if business cycles are correlated. And to get there, it
requires that production structures should be relatively similar to the US and hence reform affecting production or
private sector activities should seek to emulate this. McKinnon (1963) quizzes whether there would be need to try to
make monetary policy effective in the face of asymmetric shocks and unsynchronized business cycles and hence
suggests evaluating the effectiveness of other adjustment mechanisms and the level of economic integration.
According to McKinnon (1963) and Mundell (1961), these instruments may include: wage flexibility, mobility of
factors of production, fiscal and political integration with the anchor country, production diversity and openness to
trade financial integration. Roubini (2003) suggests that the vulnerability to terms of trade is apparent if a country is
small and a price taker in the foreign market for its export and import goods and as such the gains from dollarization
are significant. However, although terms of trade shocks are suggested to be correlated to fiscal revenues this kind
of fiscal adjustment vanished the moment Zimbabwe dollarized.
4.7 Non-sticky wages, degree of labour migration and flexibility of labour markets
Mundell (1961) alludes to the necessity making adjustments in areas where monetary policy and exchange rate
policies are restricted by dollarization. Reference is made to the use of non-sticky wages, control of labour migration
and flexibility of labour markets as possible adjustment instruments to influence output and employment. According
to Lupupa (2003), dollarized economies can correct imbalances from external shocks not by using exchange rates or
monetary policy but through adjustments in employment and output. As such nominal sticky wages, high labour
migration and labour immobility would cause reductions in employment and output. Although it may be presumed
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
313
as a loss in welfare, the suggestion to reduce wages in instances of fiscal stress emphasize the notions postulated
before that, sometimes for dollarization to work, society must be willing and able to bear the costs of necessary
adjustments because in as much as pros exist ,so do cons. These suggested areas to be considered in place of
monetary and exchange rate policies pave way to possible areas of reform that may be undertaken in view of their
possible effect on the economy as a systematic system.
4.8 Political factors
Sustained dollarization needs substantial public support and it is generally conceived that there is reduced risk of
political influences in a dollarized economy. According to Mutengezanwa (2012) there is acknowledgement that
dollarization came with significant improvements in the economy of Zimbabwe. The findings of the paper showed
that 78 % of the interviewees were not ready for the introduction of Zimbabwean dollar. This provides some rough
popularity or preference of dollarization over the use of the local currency and thus illuminating the importance of
public acceptance. In the same vein, the Zimbabwean dollar is associated with economic turmoil whilst dollarization
is perceived to be the liberator of such economic difficulties. In this regard, failing to sustain the dollarization
experiment may lead to abrupt abandonment of the multi-currency regime in the same manner in which the
sovereign local currency was abandoned. However, such decisions have political, social and economic
consequences. For instance, from a political view, this may be regarded as rewarding opposition with ammunition
that may be grossly taken advantage of in swaying public perception and hence public support. This heightens the
need to sustain dollarization as it is also pertinent to long term political sustainability.
5. CONCLUSION
Zimbabwe adopted the multicurrency regime following severe economic hardships imposed by a hyperinflationary
environment. As predicted by theory, the country experienced an initial boom in economic activity, however the
inadequacies in the current environment threatens the sustainability of dollarization. Notably, the country abruptly
dollarized without satisfying the basic conditions as prescribed by literature and this paper asserts that what has
commonly been criticised as poor economic policy may at large be sucretization. This implies that although
economic activity may be sound, the environment of dollarization may abate the usefulness of the policies. This
paper highlights that they is need to embrace dollarization and make it work rather than opt out when difficulties are
faced. This may have dire economic, political and social problems. The availability of options to sustain the
dollarization experiment provides hope for policy making to focus on making the situation work rather than
constantly seeking alterations in the advent of facing limitation. The paper recommends the adoption of an economy
wide framework which views dollarization as the new environment in which various economic facets work in and as
such, isolated analysis of policies within such an environment may tend to be rancorous than a systematic view.
Nonetheless, further research may probe into the redesign or evaluation of current policies regarding their suitability
towards sustainable dollarization.
6. REFERENCES
Berg, A., & Borensztein, E. (2000). The pros and cons of full dollarization (No. 2000-2050). International
Monetary Fund.
Berg, A., Borensztein, E., & Mauro, P. (2003). Monetary regime options for Latin America. Finance and
Development, 40(3), 24-27.
Bernholz, P. (2003). Monetary Regimes and Inflation, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar
Besada, H. (Ed.). (2011). Zimbabwe: picking up the pieces. Palgrave Macmillan.
Bonga, W. G., & Dhoro, N. L. (2014). Currency Substitution, Dollarization and Possibility of De-Dollarization in
Zimbabwe. Dollarization and Possibility of De-Dollarization in Zimbabwe (June 8, 2014).
Bonga, W. G., Chira, F., Chemina, J., & Strient, M. V. (2014). World De-Dollarization: Economic Implication of
De-Dollarization in Zimbabwe (Introduction of Special Coins). Available at SSRN 2534972.
Bradbury, M., & Vernengo, M. (2008). The limits to dollarization in Ecuador: Lessons from Argentina (No. 2008-
12). Working Paper, University of Utah, Department of Economics.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
314
Calvo, G. A. (1999). Testimony on full dollarization.
Calvo, G. A. (2002). On dollarization. Economics of Transition, 10(2), 393-403.
Calvo, G., & Reinhart, C. M. (2001). Reflections on dollarization. Currency Unions, 39-47.
Central Statistical Office (2008), National Accounts 1990-2008
Chagonda, T. (2010, December). Dollarization of the Zimbabwean economy: Cure or curse? The case of the
teaching and banking sectors. In Coterie Conference on the Renaissance of African Economies. Dar Es Salam,
Tanzania (pp. 20-21).
Coomer, J., & Gstraunthaler, T. (2011). The hyperinflation in Zimbabwe. Quarterly journal of Austrian
economics, 14(3), 311-346.
Eichengreen, B. (2000). When to Dollarize? Paper presented at a conference on dollarization hosted by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, 6-7 March
Gruben, W. C., Wynne, M. A., & Zarazaga, C. E. (2003). Implementation Guidelines for Dollarization and
Monetary Unions. Dollarization: Debates and Policy Alternatives. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Hanke, S. H. (2008). Zimbabwe: Hyperinflation to growth. New Zanj Publishing.
Hausmann, R., & Powell, A. (1999). Dollarization: issues of implementation.IADB, March.
Hofstee, E. (2006). Constructing a good dissertation. Johannesburg: EPE.
IMF (2009). IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics
IMF Country Report, (2012). Zimbabwe Article IV Consultation Staff Report
International Monetary Fund. (2015, June). Zimbabwe country tables. Retrieved from International Financial
Statistics Online database
Jácome, L. I., & Lönnberg, Å. (2010). Implementing official dollarization. IMF Working Papers, 1-31.
Kairiza, T. (2009). Unbundling Zimbabwe’s journey to hyperinflation and official dollarization. Natl. Grad. Inst.
Policy Stud. GRIPS, 09-12.
Kramarenko, V., Engstrom, L., Verdier, G., Fernandez, G., Oppers, S. E., Hughes, R., McHugh, J., & Coats,
W. (2010). Zimbabwe: challenges and policy options after hyperinflation. Washington (District of Columbia):
International Monetary Fund.
Leavell, H., Hart, S., & Alan, C. (2003). The Dollarization of Argentina and Ecuador. Journal of International
Business Research, 2(1).
Lupupa, J. (2003). Dollarization and sustainability in emerging markets.
Makochekanwa, A. (2009). Zimbabwe’s Currency Crisis: Which Currency to Adopt in the Aftermath of the Multi-
Currency Regime?
Makoto, R. (2012). Dollarization and the way forward in Zimbabwe. Journal of Strategic Studies: A Journal of the
Southern Bureau of Strategic Studies Trust: Joint Research Programme of the Ministry of Finance, the Zimbabwe
Economic Policy and Research Unit and the University of Zimbabwe, 3(1), 51-67.
Mazzaferro, F., Thiemann, C., & Winkler, A. (2003). On the Sustainability of Euroisation/Dollarization Regimes:
How Important are Fiscal Transfers, Offshore Finance and Tourism Receipts quest. Comparative Economic
Studies, 45(3), 421-436.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
315
McKinnon, R. I. (1963). Optimum currency areas. The American Economic Review, 717-725.
Metin-Özcan, K., & Us, V. (2007). Dedollarization in Turkey after decades of dollarization: A myth or
reality? Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 385(1), 292-306.
Ministry of Finance and Economic Development, (2014). National Budget statement for year ended 19
December, 2013.
Ministry of Finance and Economic Development, (2015). National Budget statement for year ended 27
November, 2014.
Mundell (1961) in McKinnon, R. I. (2004). Optimum currency areas and key currencies: Mundell I versus
Mundell II. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies, 42(4), 689-715.
Mundell, R. A. (1961). A theory of optimum currency areas. The American Economic Review, 657-665.
Mupunga N., & Le Roux P. (2014). Analyzing the Theoretical and Empirical Foundations of Public Debt
Dynamics in Zimbabwe (No. 409). Economic Research Southern Africa.
Mutengezanwa, M., Mauchi, F. N., Njanike, K., Matanga, J., & Gopo, R. N. (2012). The possibility of
reintroducing the Zimbabwean dollar. Australian Journal of Business and Management Research, 2(6), 01-08.
Nelms, T. (2012, August). Una moneda de confianza (a trustworthy currency): Dollarization, debt, and everyday
economic organization in Ecuador. In The Second ISA Forum of Sociology (August 1-4, 2012). Isaconf.
Noko, J. (2011). Dollarization: the case of Zimbabwe. Cato Journal, 31(2).
Pindiriri, C. (2012). Monetary Reforms and Inflation Dynamics in Zimbabwe. International Research Journal of
Finance and Economics, (90), 207-222.
Quispe-Agnoli, M., & Whisler, E. (2006). Official dollarization and the banking system in Ecuador and El
Salvador. Economic Review, (Q 3), 55-71.
RBZ, (2008). First Half Monetary Policy Review Statement, 23-28.
Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe, (2009). Monetary Policy Statement. Retrieved from www.rbz.co.zw
Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe, (2015). Monetary Policy Statement. Retrieved from www.rbz.com
Richardson, C. J. (2013). Zimbabwe: Why is One of the World's Least-Free Economies Growing so Fast? Cato
Institute Policy Analysis, (722)
Rojas-Suarez, L. (2003). Monetary policy and exchange rates: Guiding principles for a sustainable regime. After
the Washington Consensus: Restarting Growth and Reform in Latin America. Washington, DC: Institute for
International Economics.
Roubini, N. (2001). Factors to be considered in assessing a Country’s Readiness for Dollarization. Stern School of
Business, New York University, November. (Http: //pages. stern. nyn. edu/~ nroubini/dollarization. pdf).
Schuler, K., & Stein, R. (2000, March). The Mack dollarization plan: An analysis. In Conference “Dollarization:
A Common Currency for the Americas,” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Sikwila, M. N. (2013). Dollarization and the Zimbabwe’s Economy. J. Econ. Behavioural. Studies, 5.
Starr, P. K. (2001). The Political-Economy of. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 21(1), 81.
Trejos, A. (2003). International currencies and dollarization. Evolution and Procedures in Central Banking, 147.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
316
Winkler, A. (2005). 7. Lessons from sustained cases of official dollarization/euroisation. European Economic
Integration and South-East Europe: Challenges and Prospects, 77.
World Bank. (2015). Statistics retrieved from World Development Indicators database.
Zhou, G. (2012). Three Decades of Public Expenditure Management in Zimbabwe. Journal of Public
Administration and Governance, 2(3), Pages-33.
ZimStat (2015). Statistics retrieved from ZimStat online database.
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
317
Appendix 1: Tables
Source: Hanke and Kwok (2009)
Table 2: Distribution of Zimbabwe’s exports and import averages (2000-2008)
Exports (%)
Imports (%)
Rest of the World
13
16
European Union
20
9
Rest of Africa
17
21
APEC (excluding US)
22
7
United States of America
4
3
South Africa
24
44
Source: Direction of Trade Statistics
Table 1: Zimbabwe’s Hyperinflation 2007-2008
Date Month-on-month inflation (%) Year-on-year inflation (%)
March 2007 50.54 2,200.20
April 2007 100.70 3,713.90
May 2007 55.40 4,530.00
June 2007 86.20 7,251.10
July 2007 31.60 7,634.80
August 2007 11.80 6,592.80
September 2007 38.70 7,982.10
October 2007 135.62 14,840.65
November 2007 131.42 26,470.78
December 2007 240.06 66,212.30
January 2008 120.83 100,580.16
February 2008 125.86 164,900.29
March 2008 281.29 417,823.13
April 2008 212.54 650,599.00
May 2008 433.40 2,233,713.43
June 2008 839.30 11,268,758.90
July 2008 2,600.24 231,150,888.87
August 2008 3,190.00 9,690,000,000.00
September 2008 12,400.00 471,000,000,000.00
October 2008 690,000,000.00 3,840,000,000,000,000,000.00
November 2008 79,600,000,000.00 89,700,000,000,000,000,000,000.00
Source: Hanke and Kwok (2009)
ISSN 2320-5407 International Journal of Advanced Research (2015), Volume 3, Issue 7, 306-318
318
Appendix 2: Figures
Figure 2: Inflation profile 2013-2014
Source: Ministry of Finance (2015)
... The adoption of dollarization helped Zimbabwe arrest the hyperinflation experienced in the period 2006-2008, among other notable benefits. However dollarization of the economy has also brought about some challenges in the economy that include stunned growth, de-industrialization, and serious liquidity challenges among others (Chigome, 2015). The concept of dollarization refers to a situation when the United States dollar is used in addition to or instead of the domestic currency of a given country as legal tender or Ephraim Matanda, Master of Science Degree in Finance and Investment, Senior Lecturer, Department of Banking and Finance, Great Zimbabwe University, Masvingo, Zimbabwe. ...
... Many countries have moved their economic roads to full dollarization. However, dollarization comes with huge costs (Chigome, 2015). Zimbabwe abandoned the Zimbabwean dollar as an official currency in 2009 (Kramarenko et al., 2010). ...
Article
Full-text available
The Zimbabwean financial sector has been retrogressive, constrained, and unpredictable since the year 2000, serving for the multiple currency periods (2009-2013) after the demonetization of the domestic dollar. The sector since then has seen a number of commercial banks fail to meet RBZ (Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe) minimum capital requirements, put under curatorship, delisted or liquidated because of a myriad of operational and financial challenges. The objective of this study is to make an assessment of whether or not the introduction of bond notes has been a curse or blessing. The study drew raw data from bank account holders, academics, general public, corporate world and commercial banks in Masvingo for analysis and interpretation. The study established that the majority of people, corporate world and commercial banks were sceptical to embrace the surrogate bond notes because of the uncertainties, operational and financial risks that they paused on the domestic financial markets. It was also discovered that most banks were quick to pay clients' withdrawals in bond notes, deduct US dollar equivalences from their accounts, and distinguish bond notes from US dollars at the point of making deposits and foreign business transactions. It was also realized that there was market indiscipline and trading in bigger US dollar notes in the informal sector and serious shortage of the same notes in the formal sector. The study concluded that the introduction of bond notes to trade parallel to the US dollar brought a serious shortage of cash on formal markets and increases in the general price level of goods and services. The study therefore recommends that the RBZ should completely withdraw the bond notes from the market to accord the US dollar its world market value and restore confidence and discipline in the Zimbabwean financial sector. The study also recommends another option of the adoption of the South African Rand as an interventionist way of solving Zimbabwe's liquidity crises.
... A good example is in the economy of Japan, which is a very low-inflation economy and the Japanese yen is a very divisible unit of currency. This allows businesses to set optimum prices for goods and services right to the smallest possible margin (Chigome, 2015). This aspect benefits both consumers and business people as customers get exactly what they want and pay exactly what it is worth, rather than a rounded off figure (Chagonda, 2010). ...
Article
Full-text available
Many African countries have experienced an expansion of the informal economy and Zimbabwe is amongst the highest affected. The growth of the informal sector (IS) has largely been viewed in two contexts. Firstly as a survival net for the poor and secondly as an escape from regulation and deliberate intention to avoid paying taxes and these views have been generalised to the detriment of realistic tax policy formulation. Countries in the region have devised various strategies to tax the IS, with the intention to broaden the tax base. Zimbabwe adopted a presumptive tax system for various IS categories, to generate the desperately needed revenue for the fiscus. The minimal tax revenue contribution by this sector which is incommensurate with its alarming growth and weighty contribution to GDP informs this research. The meagre attention associated with studies concentrating on taxation, its administration as well as revenue mobilisation capabilities in general and IS taxation in particular in the African continent also motivates this study. This study was carried out in Bulawayo to evaluate the strategies and challenges to IS taxation in Zimbabwe. The perspective of IS players from the different categories and those of the Zimbabwe Revenue Authority (ZIMRA) through its officers were sought by means of a sequential mixed method approach using questionnaires and interviews. The major findings were that: the key motives towards the IS taxation were not clearly outlined and there was inadequate appreciation of the drivers of the growth of the IS. However a precursory understanding of the magnitude of the IS, its genesis and continued swelling remains crucial in the crafting of a legitimate, logical and practical IS tax framework. It was also evident that ZIMRA was not adequately equipped to tackle the large IS which is inherently hard to pinpoint, trace and adequately tax. The IS was ignorant of the presumptive taxes in place and the few who were privy could not comply because of the purportedly high tax rates. The conclusion reached was that the ZIMRA was not ready to enforce any tax laws on the IS. Preliminary studies and IS inclusion in the crafting of IS tax policy were critical for understanding the nature of informal activities in Zimbabwe and all this hinged on the government commitment to support the endeavour as well clarity of intentions and objectives with regards to IS taxation.
Article
Full-text available
This paper examines the economic impact of the inception of the full dollarization 1 in Zimbabwe's economy after the effects of hyperinflation and an unprecedented depreciation of an exchange rate between 2000 and 2008. Dollarization is a generic word implying the use of any foreign currency as legal tender instead of the domestic currency. An analytical qualitative approach was adopted for this study. The analysis of the benefits and costs of dollarization to Zimbabwe's economy revealed how dollarization has impacted on the stabilization of Zimbabwe's economy. This article also highlights the fact that Zimbabwe is not the only country in Africa that has had to resort to adopting foreign currency as legal tender in an effort to remedy macroeconomic imbalances. To our knowledge, there is scant literature on dollarization in Africa and this is the reason why we have chosen to examine the impact of dollarization on Zimbabwe's economy. In addition, we add to Kurt Schuler's work (2005) by indicating the other African countries that had adopted dollarization over the years. Furthermore, the study offers support to recent literature that asserts that economic stabilization in these countries resulted from the impact of dollarization. The results of the study revealed that dollarization positively impacts on the country's economy. In particular, this study is important to policymakers in that it sheds some insight into the importance of a strong currency and stable exchange rate for the stabilization of economies that experienced hyperinflation.
Article
Full-text available
This paper provides an analysis of the theoretical and empirical foundations of public debt dynamics in Zimbabwe. The analysis was undertaken by applying the debt dynamics equation that enables estimating the required primary balance, building on the government inter-temporal budget constraint to infer the factors that influence public debt, as well as to ascertain specific policy issues required to ensure a sustainable public debt structure. The results show that debt dynamics in Zimbabwe are largely composed of huge stock flow adjustments to finance social and political related expenditures. Results also indicate that the output gap had a significant influence on public debt dynamics in Zimbabwe. As such, the results underscore the need for prudent debt management to guard against unexpected changes in public debt, which are not explained by fundamentals. The major policy implication from the study is the need to minimize the interest rate growth differential and to implement growth enhancing fiscal policies to ensure a sustainable long term public debt position.
Article
Full-text available
Dollarisation can be a path to economic stability and growth if managed properly. Governments which end up dollarising only do so as a last resort.This paper used both explanatory and empirical approach to explore the nature of currency substitution and dollarisation in Zimbabwe. The paper also discuss the possibility and the requirements for de-dollarisation to take place. The process of dollarization in Zimbabwe was peculiar in that it was not backed by international reserves as is normally the case with countries that have dollarized. The only foreign currency that the government had was from taxation after full dollarisation. Currency substitution isan important phenomenon in countries with high inflation rates, complicating forecasts of money demand and making monetary policy more difficult to conduct. The most important incentive for currency substitution has been change in the domestic inflation rate, though there have been episodes of currency substitution arising for other reasons. Adequate reforms have been emphasized before de-dollarisation.
Article
Full-text available
Dollarisation can be a path to economic stability and growth if managed properly. Governments which end up dollarising only do so as a last resort. This paper used both explanatory and empirical approach to explore the nature of currency substitution and dollarisation in Zimbabwe. The paper also discuss the possibility and the requirements for de-dollarisation to take place. The process of dollarization in Zimbabwe was peculiar in that it was not backed by international reserves as is normally the case with countries that have dollarized. The only foreign currency that the government had was from taxation after full dollarisation. Currency substitution is an important phenomenon in countries with high inflation rates, complicating forecasts of money demand and making monetary policy more difficult to conduct. The most important incentive for currency substitution has been change in the domestic inflation rate, though there have been episodes of currency substitution arising for other reasons. Adequate reforms have been emphasized before de-dollarisation.
Article
Full-text available
The study examines and assesses the causes of inflation in the post-dollarized Zimbabwe. It employs time series econometric methodology based on monthly data to examine the probable factors influencing inflation in the post-dollarized Zimbabwe. The influence on inflation of factors such imports, consumer expectation about future inflation, exchange rate, interest rates, output growth and money supply, among others is investigated. Although interest rate has been found to be one of the major determinants of inflation in Zimbabwe by studies done during the pre-dollarization period, this study finds statistical evidence of an insignificant relationship between interest rate and inflation in dollarized Zimbabwe. The study however finds evidence that consumer expectations about future inflation, money supply, current exchange rate, and import value are the major factors influencing post-dollarization inflation.
Article
The research was conducted to assess the possibility of reintroducing the Zimbabwean dollar. A descriptive research design was used in which data was collected from a sample of 183 respondents using questionnaires and interviews. This research found out that the current multicurrency regime has proved effective in that it has stabilized macroeconomic conditions, reduced inflation significantly and has provided a foundation for the resumption of economic growth. It was concluded that Zimbabwe was not yet ready to reintroduce the Zimbabwean dollar as there was need for commitment by the monetary authorities to maintain price stability, stem hyperinflation as well as guarantee the independence of monetary authorities.
Article
Zimbabwe's economic crisis originates from its struggle for independence in the 1970s. Military adventures and reckless spending led to exploding budget deficits, and the forced seizure of commercial farms almost brought the agricultural production to a halt. Zimbabwe entered into a state of hyperinflation, which culminated in a de facto dollarization of the Zimbabwean economy, made official in early 2009 by the Minister of Finance. Given all the hyperinflations of the past, the question to ask is whether the Zimbabwean experience is an isolated economic novelty; or is rather a repetition of the economic and political follies that have plagued some of the fiat governments of the modern world. This paper provides a detailed historical account of the economic crisis, which we will subsequently compare to other past hyperinflations, first and foremost to Mises's account of the Hyperinflation in Germany of 1920-1923.
Article
Sound public expenditure management forms the bedrock of public administration. It facilitates producence, efficiency, transparency and accountability in expenditure processes at various levels of government. This serves as a long term barricade aginst debt trap. This article responds to these fundamental concerns by examining the nature, processes and challenges of public expenditure management in Zimbabwe. Reviews of expenditure management systems in Zimbabwe show general consistence with those in Anglophone Africa. Ministries of finance, working closely with spending ministries, Accounting Officers, Public Accounts Committees of Parliament, Auditor Generals and internal auditors-constitute key players in the public expenditure management process. Notwithstanding this, overall expenditure over the decades remained sticky downwards due to inflationary pressures, unbudgeted expenditures and weak expenditure management systems. Robust mesaures should be put in place to institutionalise a culture of compliance with extant expenditure management frameworks at both the macro and micro levels of government.
Conference Paper
The official adoption of the U.S. dollar in Ecuador represented as profound a transformation in the everyday lives, shared social experience, and cultural memory of Ecuadorians as in national monetary and fiscal policy. Replacing the very yardstick by which Ecuadorians measured, stored, and transacted the value of the world around them with a foreign currency with unfamiliar dimensions and denominations, dollarization changed the way Ecuadorians live day to day, as well as how Ecuadorians were and are able to understand those changes. Ten years later, Ecuadorians widely support dollarization—primarily because the dollar is said to be “de confianza,” a trustworthy currency. Some suggest, however, that the long-term sustainability of dollarization is threatened by the extensive public investments and expansionary fiscal policy, funded in large part by loans from the Chinese government and high oil prices, of President Rafael Correa’s administration. This paper will examine the discourse of confianza that surrounds the dollar and its uses among middle-class Ecuadorians who have organized informal, family-based savings and credit cooperatives. Specifically, this paper will investigate how “confidence” or “trust” plays into the everyday economic practices of these Ecuadorians and their co-ops, while reflecting on the diversity of practices of debt and indebtedness in public and private budgeting. It will suggest that one of dollarization’s social effects includes the generation of a “popular monetarism,” through which the dollar is widely understood to provide a stable store of value over time. It will also suggest a parallel between this “popular monetarism” in Ecuador and academic approaches to money-as-debt, which risk eliding the diverse functions and uses of both money and debt.