ArticlePDF Available

Survival of the Fittest? Entrepreneurial Human Capital and the Persistence of Underperforming Firms Author(s)

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The model developed here explains why some firms survive while other firms with equal economic performance do not. We argue that organizational survival is not strictly a function of economic performance but also depends on a firm's own threshold of performance. We apply this threshold model to the study of new venture survival, in which the threshold is determined by the entrepreneur's human capital characteristics, such as alternative employment opportunities, psychic income from entrepreneurship, and cost of switching to other occupations. Using a sample of 1,547 entrepreneurs of new businesses in the U.S., we find strong support for the model. The findings suggest that firms with low thresholds may choose to continue or survive despite comparatively low performance.
Content may be subject to copyright.
http://www.jstor.org
Survival of the Fittest? Entrepreneurial Human Capital and the Persistence of
Underperforming Firms
Author(s): Javier Gimeno, Timothy B. Folta, Arnold C. Cooper, Carolyn Y. Woo
Source:
Administrative Science Quarterly,
Vol. 42, No. 4, (Dec., 1997), pp. 750-783
Published by: Johnson Graduate School of Management, Cornell University
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2393656
Accessed: 18/08/2008 12:10
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.
Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cjohn.
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the
scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that
promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Survival
of the Fittest?
Entrepreneurial
Human
Capital
and the
Persistence of
Underperforming
Firms
Javier Gimeno
Texas
A&M
University
Timothy B. Folta
University
of Kentucky
Arnold C. Cooper
Purdue
University
Carolyn Y. Woo
Purdue
University
? 1997 by Cornell University.
0001 -8392/97/4204-0750/$1 .00.
We thank Terry Amburgey, Joel Baum,
Parthiban David, William J. Dennis, John
Garen, Michael Hitt, Robert Hoskisson,
Nancy Johnson, David Loree, Christine
Oliver, Jing Zhou, and three ASQ anony-
mous referees for their valuable com-
ments on earlier drafts, and Tim Bates,
Josef Bruderl, Linda Leighton, and Alfred
Nucci for sharing their knowledge of
other data sources for entrepreneurship
research. We also thank Javier Fernandez
Navas and Diane Roden for their research
help. We acknowledge the help and sup-
port of the National Federation of Inde-
pendent Business. An earlier version of
this paper received the 1992 Best Empiri-
cal Paper Award from the Entrepreneur-
ship Division of the Academy of Manage-
ment.
The model developed here explains why some firms sur-
vive while other firms with equal economic performance
do not. We argue that organizational survival is not
strictly a function of economic performance but also de-
pends on a firm's own threshold of performance. We ap-
ply this threshold model to the study of new venture sur-
vival, in which the threshold is determined by the
entrepreneur's human capital characteristics, such as al-
ternative employment opportunities, psychic income
from entrepreneurship, and cost of switching to other
occupations. Using a sample of 1,547 entrepreneurs of
new businesses in the U.S., we find strong support for
the model. The findings suggest that firms with low
thresholds may choose to continue or survive despite
comparatively low performance.'
It has been frequently
argued
that, at least in the long run,
well-performing
organizations
survive
while poorly
perform-
ing ones disappear
(Alchian,
1950; Friedman,
1953; Winter,
1964; Williamson,
1991). Penrose (1952: 810) summarized
this theoretical
view as stating that "positive profits
can be
treated as the criterion
of natural
selection-the firms that
make profits
are selected or 'adopted'
by the environment,
others are rejected and disappear."
This view implies a unidi-
mensional relationship
between economic performance
(de-
fined as the economic returns
to residual
claimants)
and sur-
vival, since the firms most likely
to discontinue
are those
that perform
the worst. From
this unidimensional
model, it
follows that economic performance
and survival
should have
the same determinants
or predictors.
Interestingly,
mounting
empirical
evidence suggests that the determinants
of perfor-
mance and survival may substantially
differ
(Blau,
1984; Car-
roll
and Huo, 1986; Meyer and Zucker,
1989; Kalleberg
and
Leicht,
1991; Levinthal,
1991) and that factors other than
performance
may play a systematic role in the survival
of
organizations.
This paper proposes a theoretical
reconciliation
of apparently
conflicting
empirical
findings
about the determi-
nants of performance
and survival.
Our
framework
explains
the persistence of underperforming
firms and identifies pre-
dictors of such conditions.
We depart
from the unidimensional
model of performance
and survival
by arguing
that organizational
survival
is deter-
mined by two main dimensions: (1) the organization's
eco-
nomic performance
and (2) the organization's
threshold
of
performance.
The threshold
of performance
is the level of
performance
below which the dominant organizational
con-
stituents will act to dissolve the organization.
This implies
that survival
is not strictly
a function
of economic perfor-
mance, but performance
relative to a firm-specific
threshold.
This simple elaboration,
we believe, has profound
conse-
quences for theoretical
and empirical
research on organiza-
tional performance
and survival.
For
example, by identifying
how thresholds differ
systematically
across firms, we can
explain
why, given the same level of performance,
some
firms exit (discontinue
operations)
while others do not. We
emphasize the internal attributes
of the organization
and, in
particular,
the human
capital
attributes
of owners of new
ventures, as determinants
of thresholds. By considering
or-
ganizational
exit as a choice, our focus on organizational
mor-
750/Administrative
Science Quarterly,
42 (1997): 750-783
Survival of the Fittest?
tality
complements existing literature
in population
ecology,
where exit is seen as being forced by environmental
condi-
tions hostile to the firm.
EXIT,
PERFORMANCE,
AND THE
THRESHOLD
OF
PERFORMANCE
Our main
thesis is that organizations differ in their
thresholds
of performance,
and exit or survival is determined
by
whether economic performance
falls below or stays above
that firm-specific
threshold.
While thresholds may be shaped
by the multiple
voluntary
participants
in the organization
(Bar-
nard,
1938; Simon, 1945; Aoki, 1984), the inducements and
contributions of most participants are regulated
through a
nexus of contracts with owners. Accordingly,
it is the own-
ers' interests, as residual
claimants,
that are most closely
tied to the economic performance of the organization
(Al-
chian and Demsetz, 1972; Meyer and Zucker,
1989). The
willingness or ability
to withstand poor performance
is partly
determined by the mobility
of the assets and resources con-
trolled by the organization's
owners. When owners with a
residual
claim over these resources have alternative
uses for
these resources, they can liquidate
the firm for a reasonable
value. Consequently,
they may prefer
to dissolve the firm
when those alternatives
become more appealing
(Barnard,
1938; Caves and Porter,
1976; Porter,
1976). Exit,
however,
would not be rational at the first sign of low performance
(Bruderl
and Schussler, 1990). If
there is uncertainty
about
future payoffs, owners may be willing
to accept low levels
of performance with the hope that conditions
will improve
(Dixit and Pindyck, 1994). A firm's ability to withstand short
periods of low performance
should also be partly
determined
by buffers of accumulated
resources, such as organizational
slack (Cyert
and March,
1963) or initial
capital
endowments
and established relationships
(Bruderl
and Schussler, 1990;
Fichman and Levinthal,
1991; Levinthal,
1991). Organizations
would be able to survive
at least until their original
resources
were depleted.
Thresholds
of performance
may also be influenced when
owners have objectives other than, or in addition
to, the
maximization of economic returns to their equity. Owners
may seek "amenity potential"
from their businesses-gain-
ing utility
from being able to influence
the type of goods pro-
duced by the firm (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985: 203). For
own-
ers of professional
sports teams or media companies
(newspapers, TV) , winning
the World
Series or believing
that one is systematically
influencing public
opinion
plausibly
provides utility
even if profit
is reduced from levels other-
wise achievable. For owners of family-owned
businesses,
the firm may not only be a source of income but also a con-
text for family
activity
and embodiment of its pride
and iden-
tity (Meyer
and Zucker,
1989: 78).
Low organizational
performance also puts the interests of
owners and other organizational
constituencies (non-owners)
in direct conflict (Meyer
and Zucker,
1989). While owners
may want to terminate the business to redeploy
assets in a
more profitable
arena, non-owner
participants
(managers,
employees) who have developed firm-specific
skills may
stand to lose if the firm closes. With significant
costs of exit,
751/ASQ, December 1997
non-owners may thus exercise their voice (Hirschman,
1970)
through efforts to influence the decision-making structures
of the organization.
Thus, the threshold level of performance
would also be determined by the relative organizational
influ-
ence of non-owner
members. Firms in which non-owner
members exercise substantial organizational
influence may
remain in business at low levels of economic performance
despite a preference by owners to terminate the business
(Meyer and Zucker,
1989). In addition
to internal constituents
such as employees, external constituents (debt-holders,
cus-
tomers, suppliers,
government and community organizations)
may persuade low-performing but legitimate organizations
to
survive (as in the bailout of Lockheed
and Chrysler
by the
U.S. government)
or well-performing
but illegitimate
ones to
dissolve (such as cartels, trusts, or local businesses posing
environmental or social threats) by applying direct co-opta-
tion (Pfeffer
and Salancik, 1978) or institutional
(coercive and
normative) pressures (Meyer and Rowan, 1977; DiMaggio
and Powell, 1983). Thus, institutional embeddedness (Baum
and Oliver,
1991), legitimacy,
and co-optation by external or-
ganizations
may also keep organizations
alive despite low
performance.
Contrast with Existing Views on Organizational
Performance and Mortality
Our model of thresholds of performance
provides
a causal
link between the concepts of performance
and organizational
survival without assuming that they are unidimensional
con-
structs. Clearly,
higher
economic performance
increases the
likelihood of survival, everything
else remaining equal. Our
point is that other things are not equal, since differences in
firms' thresholds of performance
should also influence mor-
tality. Organizational
survival
is therefore influenced
by both
the determinants
of performance
and thresholds. Certain
variables
will be purely
related to economic performance,
while others may influence survival
only through
the firm's
threshold. For variables that simultaneously
influence perfor-
mance and threshold,
their survival
effect is determined by
their combined effects on both.
Our
paper
complements theories of decision making,
both at
the individual
(Kahneman
and Tversky, 1979) and the organi-
zational level (Cyert
and March,
1963; March, 1988; March
and Shapira,
1992), which posit that decision-making
choices
are determined by comparing possible outcomes relative to
some reference or aspiration
level. Viewing organizational
discontinuance as an individual
(in
the case of small ventures
run by an entrepreneur)
or organizational
choice, one may
equate reference or aspiration
levels to our threshold
con-
struct. From
that perspective, this is the first paper
we know
of that links
organizational
survival and exit to some refer-
ence level.
Our theoretical
perspective is also complementary
to a large
body of management research, mainly
in population
ecology,
that has examined the same issue we address, firm mortal-
ity (see reviews by Baum, 1996; Amburgey
and Rao, 1996).
Population
ecology studies have not been explicit,
however,
in recognizing whether firm mortality
is mediated by low per-
752/ASQ, December 1997
1
There are some important exceptions to
this generalization. Researchers studying
the liability of adolescence and honey-
moon effects (Bruderl
and SchOssler,
1990; Fichman and Levinthal, 1991;
Levinthal, 1991) have explicitly recog-
nized that the initial stock of assets
serves as a buffer between low perfor-
mance and mortality. Institutional and in-
terorganizational linkages can also serve
as a buffer and reduce mortality for high-
risk organizations (Baum and Oliver,
1991; Miner, Amburgey, and Stearns,
1990).
Survival of the Fittest?
formance or other mechanisms.' The popular
use of the
term "organizational
failure"
(Baum, 1996) seems to imply
that discontinuance
is primarily
attributable to low perfor-
mance, even though prominent
scholars in population
ecol-
ogy (Hannan
and Freeman,
1977: 940) and institutional
theory (Meyer and Rowan, 1977: 353) have explicitly re-
jected a unidimensional
interpretation of environmental
se-
lection based solely on organizational
efficiency. Meyer and
Zucker
(1989: 55) suggested that these literatures
view orga-
nizational
performance
and discontinuance as multiple
indica-
tors of an organization's
isomorphism
with its environment.
Such an approach,
unfortunately, avoids the causal link
be-
tween these constructs and has hindered
progress, since
"researchers'
understanding
of dissolution,
be it through
merger, absorption, or outright
failure,
is limited
by the
dearth
of studies that treat financial
performance
as a predic-
tor of mortality"
(Amburgey and Rao, 1996: 1274). Thus, our
theoretical
perspective complements and extends current
organizational
theories in that it explicitly
recognizes the cau-
sal effect of firm
performance
on selection processes while
also considering the selection effects of thresholds.
Exit, Performance, and Thresholds in New Ventures
While
the concept of threshold has broad
applicability,
a nar-
rower context of study can facilitate
theoretical
develop-
ment, empirical
specification,
and testing the determinants
of threshold in that specific context. This paper
investigates
performance,
thresholds, and exit in the specific context of
small entrepreneurial new ventures. Entrepreneurial
exit de-
cisions occur frequently,
with more than 800,000 businesses
discontinued in the United
States in 1992 alone (U.S. Small
Business Administration,
1994: 265). Understanding
the pro-
cesses that influence new venture survival has tremendous
implications
for the welfare of customers, suppliers,
employ-
ees, and especially for entrepreneurs.
Applying
the concept
of the threshold of performance
enables us to broaden the
current
understanding
of entrepreneurial
exit by considering
both economic performance
and nonperformance
reasons
for exit. Ronstadt
(1986) discovered that only 31 percent of
entrepreneurs
who exited did so solely because of financial
difficulties,
while 26 percent indicated that financial
reasons
played no part
in their exit decisions. Mayer
and Goldstein
(1961) found that 20 percent of all new business closures
were attributed
to nonfinancial
reasons, such as external
job
opportunities,
disappointment
with business ownership, or
unwillingness
to put up with "limited
success." At least in
some cases, dissolution is not forced upon the entrepreneur
but involves a proactive
decision to exit.
Recent studies have also found empirical
evidence suggest-
ing that factors influencing
the survival of new ventures may
be significantly
different
from those influencing
performance
(Carroll
and Huo, 1986; Kalleberg
and Leicht,
1991; Cooper,
Gimeno, and Woo, 1994). Up to now, there have been few
attempts to reconcile
theoretically
the lack of convergence
on the determinants of performance
and survival. We be-
lieve that considering
economic performance and thresholds
jointly
will shed light
on this important
topic.
The context of entrepreneurship
requires
a special consider-
ation of the determinants
of performance
and thresholds. In
753/ASQ, December 1997
small entrepreneurial firms, the entrepreneur
is likely to ex-
ert control over organizational decisions, and non-owners
therefore are less influential than in larger
or older firms,
where there is a separation of ownership and control (Meyer
and Zucker,
1989). Moreover, the organizational
contributions
of the owner to the venture are not limited
to founding capi-
tal but also include managerial and technical work and skills.
In that sense, when determining whether to continue sup-
port
for the venture, the entrepreneur will evaluate the joint
returns to both the financial and human resources contrib-
uted to the venture. Since the entrepreneur's
skills and ob-
jectives play
a dominant role in dictating
the direction of
newly founded businesses (Bruderl,
Preisenddrfer, and Zie-
gler, 1992), we focus here on how the entrepreneur's traits
and characteristics,
or human
capital,
influence the perfor-
mance threshold.
A Threshold Model of Entrepreneurial
Exit: Human
Capital Considerations
Human
capital
theory (Becker, 1975) uses economic logic to
study individual
decisions dealing
with investments in pro-
ductivity-enhancing
skills and knowledge (schooling, training,
firm-specific
knowledge investment), career choices (deci-
sion to work, switching employment, labor
mobility),
and
other work characteristics
(wages, reservation
wages, hours
of work). It is believed that individuals choose an occupation
or employment that maximizes the present value of eco-
nomic and psychic benefits over their lifetimes. Human
capi-
tal theorists have likened
the entrepreneurial
exit decision to
the more general case of an individual's decision to leave
current
employment (Evans
and Leighton,
1989; Evans and
Jovanovic, 1989; Campbell, 1995; Bates, 1995). Entrepre-
neurs can be viewed as choosing between remaining
in the
current venture or obtaining
alternative
employment. While
several studies have examined entrepreneurial
exit with hu-
man capital
theory (Bates, 1985, 1990; Preisendbrfer
and
Voss, 1990; BrOderl,
Preisend6rfer,
and Ziegler, 1992), by
assuming that the factors related to poor performance
will
be the same as those influencing exit, they have ignored
the
potential
for returns to the entrepreneur's
human
capital
in
alternative
settings. Others have theoretically
acknowledged
the importance
of alternative uses of human
capital
in entre-
preneurial
decision making (Evans
and Jovanovic, 1989;
Evans and Leighton, 1989; Bates, 1995; Campbell, 1995) but
have focused on how human
capital
influences entry, not
exit.
Expectations
for ventures are generally buoyant
in the early
start-up stage, being generally
formed under substantial un-
certainty
about market
acceptance, competitive responses,
or even the entrepreneur's
actual entrepreneurial
abilities
and satisfaction to be obtained
from the venture. As informa-
tion becomes available,
the entrepreneur
is likely
to examine
the efficacy of these expectations and reconsider
other op-
tions (Jovanovic,
1982). We would expect the entrepreneur
to terminate the business if the expected utility
of alternative
employment (UA) minus the cost inherent in switching (SC)
exceeds the revised expected utility
of remaining
in the en-
trepreneurial
venture (UE):
754/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
discontinue
venture if: UE
< (UA
- SC). (1)
UE and UA differ because of unequal economic performance
and personal enjoyment, or psychic income (Becker, 1975;
Evans and Leighton, 1989), with the two options. The eco-
nomic performance depends in part on the entrepreneur's
previous investments in education and training, which may
provide general skills or skills specific to a particular
job con-
text (Becker, 1975). The entrepreneur's economic perfor-
mance (EPE)
is a function of his or her stock of general hu-
man capital, represented by the vector x1, and of the human
capital specific to the current business, represented by the
vector x2. Meanwhile, since specific skills cannot be trans-
ferred to alternative employment, the economic returns avail-
able in alternative employment opportunities (EPA)
are a
function of the stock of general human capital (x1) and of
human capital specific to the alternative occupation (X3),
but
not of the human capital specific to the current business
(x2). The individual's psychic income associated with either
the entrepreneurial venture (PIE) or alternative employment
(PIA) is influenced by a number of factors (respectively, X4
and X5), including the individual's preference for the occupa-
tion, or personal satisfaction (Evans and Leighton, 1989).
Thus, the utilities of entrepreneurship and alternative em-
ployment can be expressed as:
UE = EPE
(X1, X2)
+ PlE (X4). (2a)
UA = EPA (X1,
X3)
+ PIA
(X5). (2b)
The cost inherent in switching (SC) includes those costs,
usually transitory, that are a function of the expected eco-
nomic cost of searching for a new alternative and the psy-
chological cost of experiencing the uncertainty of job loss.
Factors influencing the cost of switching are captured by the
vector x6. These costs should not be confounded with the
potential loss of utility experienced by switching because of
lower personal enjoyment in the new alternative or an inabil-
ity to redeploy skills specific to the venture, which are al-
ready captured in the relative magnitudes of psychic income
and specific human capital. Substituting equations (2a) and
(2b) into equation (1) and isolating EPE
on the left-hand side,
leads to:
discontinue venture if:
EPE (X1, X2)
< EPA (X1,
X3)
+ P'A (X5)
- PIE
(X4)
- SC (X6). (3)
The right-hand side of equation (3) is the threshold of eco-
nomic performance required to sustain the entrepreneur's
involvement in the current venture (TE). Thus, the threshold
(TE) is determined by the expected economic returns avail-
able in other employment alternatives (EPA),
the difference
in psychic income between alternative employment and self-
employment (PIA
- PIE),
and the cost of switching to an al-
ternative occupation (SC). The model predicts that the entre-
preneur will discontinue or stay in business according to the
following rule:
{
discontinue venture if EPE
(X1, X2)
< TE (X1, X3,
X4, X5, X6)
stay in venture
(survive)
if EPE
(X1, X2) 2 TE (X1, X3,
X4, X5, X6).
(4)
A critical insight
that follows from the above model is that
there may be situations in which entrepreneurs
do not con-
755/ASQ, December 1997
tinue their business even though, in terms of economic per-
formance, they are better off than other entrepreneurs. They
may take this action because of the opportunity costs asso-
ciated with staying in business-their level of education and
training may warrant more attractive economic returns
in al-
ternative employment opportunities. Similarly,
a poorly per-
forming venture may continue because of the entrepreneur's
lack of other attractive options, strong psychic attachment to
the venture, or high costs associated with switching into
new employment. As these cases illustrate, economic per-
formance of the venture need not exclusively determine sur-
vival. Rather,
it is economic performance relative
to the
threshold
that drives the exit decision.
Hypotheses
From the threshold model illustrated in figure 1, we develop
hypotheses that predict
how four important
dimensions of
the human
capital
of an entrepreneur-general human
capital
(x1), human capital specific to the current
venture (x2),
psy-
chic income from entrepreneurship (X4), and switching costs
(x6)-influence entrepreneurial
exit by their separate effects
on economic performance
and threshold
of performance.
We do not develop hypotheses about the effects of human
capital specific to alternative occupations (X3) or psychic in-
come from alternative
occupations (X5), since we cannot de-
termine a priori
what those alternatives
are. Alternative em-
ployment opportunities are nearly infinite and may include
wage-earning positions, other self-employment activities, or
leisure activity.
To the extent that these alternative employ-
ment opportunities cannot be fully specified ex ante, we as-
sume a generic alternative, letting
the effect of (X3) and (X5)
be included
in the error
term of the threshold
equation.
General human capital. The simple model presented in
equation (4) generates several theoretical
insights and em-
pirical predictions. General human capital (x1), as measured
by such constructs as formal
education
and the prior
work
experience of the entrepreneur, may lead to skills
that are
useful across a wide range of occupational
alternatives
(Becker, 1975). Work
experience is commonly measured as
the number
of years of experience but may also be signaled
by achievement levels in employment, such as management
or supervisory experience (Bates, 1990). While increasing
levels of education and experience are likely
to elevate eco-
nomic performance (EPE), they will also broaden the opportu-
nity set of the entrepreneurs and raise their expected in-
come from alternative
employment (EPA). Thus, while
entrepreneurs
with general skills may perform
better in self-
employment, they would also have higher performance
re-
quirements
to remain in business. How general human capi-
tal influences survival will depend on its relative
payoff in the
venture versus alternative
employment. Evans
and Leighton
(1989) found that business experience had about the same
returns
in wage work and self-employment,
while education
had greater returns
in self-employment.
A study by Fujii
and
Hawley (1991) revealed
that self-employment had slightly
lower returns associated with both experience and education
than wage work, but they did not test to see if these differ-
ences were significant.
Because there is a lack
of consensus
756/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
Figure 1. Threshold model of entrepreneurial exit: Human capital considerations.
General human capital (x1) +
K ~+
\_ / \ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~ECONOMIC
\ ~~~~~~~~~PERFORMANCE
\ ~~~~~~~~* {~~~~~~EPE)\
Human capital specific to
current venture (x2)
EXIT FROM
BUSINESS
Human capital specific to +
alternative occupations Income available in other
employment (EPA)
+~~~~~~
r \ I \+ l~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
/+
Psychic
income from \
entrepreneurship (X4)+| \ .. .._......./
entrepreneurship /x4) I I Difference in psychic I|
income between self- ' i UNOBSERVED
employment and [-p( THRESHOLD LEVEL I
Psychic income from alternative employment OF PERFORMANCE I
'
Psychic income from ' I i
(PIPEPIA) i (TE) I
alternative occupations (x5) - I [ .
g > + | [ Cost of switching -
Switching costs (x6) + occupations (SC)
<~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
} ...... .... ........ ........ .... . . . ..
...........................I
.............. ..........
... .. ... . ..... ............... .. .......... .
. . ....... .......... ... ... ....... .
....... . ...... . ........_.
on the relative payoff of work experience and education, we
hypothesize that the net effect of general human capital on
entrepreneurial exit is indeterminate a priori:
Hypothesis 1 (H1):
General
human
capital
will be positively
related
to the economic performance
of the venture and also to the entre-
preneur's
threshold
level of performance.
Hence, a priori,
general
human
capital
has an indeterminate
effect on the likelihood
of exit.
Human capital specific to the current venture. Specific
human capital results from education, training, or experience
that has a limited scope of applicability. Investments in spe-
cific human capital create value in a particular
business con-
text but do not have relevance in alternative occupations.
Therefore, while human capital specific to the venture raises
performance, it has no influence on entrepreneurs' threshold
of performance. The implication is that individuals whose
human capital is more specific to the venture would be less
mobile (Becker, 1975). A measure of specific human capital
is an entrepreneur's knowledge of customers, suppliers,
products, and services within the context of the venture (x2).
This should be directly related to the degree of similarity be-
tween the new venture and the organization where the en-
trepreneur had previously worked. This knowledge may be
critical to success, conferring a favorable asymmetry be-
tween the entrepreneurs who have been exposed to it and
those who have not (Sandberg, 1986; Cooper, Gimeno, and
Woo, 1994). In addition, similarity between the new venture
and the prior experience may mean that the entrepreneur
can build on prior relationships with relevant stakeholders
and thus minimize the "liability
of newness" (Stinchcombe,
1965; Aldrich and Auster, 1986). Yet such knowledge and
ties largely lose their value outside of their original context.
757/ASQ,
December
1997
To the extent that human capital specific to the venture
raises performance (EPE ) but has no effect on performance
in alternative occupations (EPA), and therefore on the thresh-
old (TE), it should be negatively related to entrepreneurial
exit:
Hypothesis 2 (H2): Specific human capital will be positively related
to the economic performance of the venture but should have no
influence on the entrepreneur's threshold level of performance.
As
a result, specific human
capital
should be negatively
related to the
likelihood of exit.
Hypotheses 1 and 2 assume that specific and general hu-
man capital
can be measured separately. In other contexts, it
may be easier to measure an individual's overall level of hu-
man capital
and the degree to which such overall
capital
is
general or specific, maybe as a ratio
or a subjective evalua-
tion. In those cases, we would expect lower thresholds for
entrepreneurs
with a greater ratio
of specificity in their hu-
man capital,
since general human
capital
increases thresh-
olds while specific human
capital
does not. This prediction
is
comparable
to our earlier
argument
that organizations (entre-
preneurs) with less mobile resources (human capital) should
be more willing
to withstand low performance.
Psychic income from entrepreneurship. The probability
of
exit will also be negatively related to the psychic income, or
personal satisfaction
the entrepreneur
derives from self-em-
ployment (X4). Considerable research indicates that many
entrepreneurs
are motivated,
at least in part, by noneco-
nomic goals, including
satisfaction
from the autonomy
of
self-employment
or from doing the type of work they like
(Smith and Miner, 1983; Lafuente and Salas, 1989). Entre-
preneurs may also be personally attached to entrepreneurial
activities if their parents were self-employed (Evans
and
Leighton, 1989; Bruderl, Preisend6rfer,
and Ziegler,
1992).
Since parents are seen as role models, it has been reasoned
that people growing up in such families perceive entrepre-
neurship
to be a more viable career than those without such
a family background (Shapero
and Giglierano, 1982). There-
fore, entrepreneurs
who have an intrinsic
motivation for the
activity
or who come from entrepreneurial
families are likely
to obtain a higher psychic income from entrepreneurship
(PIE) than those who do not have those backgrounds
and
motivations.
Accordingly,
the threshold level of performance
(TE)
is lower for such entrepreneurs, indicating
that they may
be willing
to accept lower economic returns
to gain personal
satisfaction
from the venture. Because a psychic attachment
to the venture lowers the threshold level of performance,
while having
no apparent
effect on the economic perfor-
mance of the venture, we expect these factors to have a
negative effect on the likelihood of exit:
Hypothesis 3 (H3): High psychic income from entrepreneurship
should have no influence on the economic performance
of the ven-
ture but should decrease the entrepreneur's
threshold
level of per-
formance.
As a result, higher
levels of psychic income from entre-
preneurship
should be negatively
related to the likelihood
of exit.
Switching costs. Finally,
the probability
of entrepreneurial
exit will be negatively
related to the costs of switching to
new employment (x6).
These costs are defined as the costs
inherent in the act of switching between two alternative
oc-
758/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
cupations and do not include the difference in returns in
those alternative occupations. This definition reflects the ef-
forts and expenses the individual
would need to undertake in
job searches and retraining, as well as the psychic costs of
not knowing whether a suitable job can be found. Older
people have less time to recoup the costs associated with
switching jobs and thus are likely to perceive lower benefits
from switching. Consistent with this view, Mincer (1974)
found a tendency for investments in training to be concen-
trated at younger ages and to continue at a diminishing rate
throughout much of a person's working life. Since employers
may need to train and develop their employees, they are
also more likely to prefer younger candidates, to maximize
the return from their investment. Evidence suggests that
older job seekers are more likely than younger ones to take
more time to find a job (Shrieves, 1995) and less likely to
find jobs eventually (Bortnick and Ports, 1993). For these rea-
sons, it is expected that older entrepreneurs will be less will-
ing to switch occupations. The existence of switching costs
should decrease the threshold level of performance (TE)
and
therefore decrease the likelihood of exit. This expectation
was supported by the in-depth case studies of Mayer and
Goldstein (1961), who found that concern about job seeking
at an older age was a major reason why older entrepreneurs
would continue their involvement with new businesses with
marginal economic performance.
By serving as a proxy for general human capital, age may
also be linked to the monetary performance of the venture
(Preisend6rfer and Voss, 1990). After controlling for general
and specific human capital levels (hypotheses 1 and 2), how-
ever, we do not expect older entrepreneurs to perform dif-
ferently from younger ones. We expect age to affect exit
only through its influence on the threshold level of perfor-
mance, not through economic performance:
Hypothesis 4 (H4):
Factors
associated with an entrepreneur's
cost
of switching
to alternative
occupations
should have no influence on
economic performance
of the venture but should decrease the en-
trepreneur's
threshold level of performance.
As a result, higher
lev-
els of switching costs should be negatively
related
to the likelihood
of exit.
Other influences. There are some important human capital
variables that may measure a combination of general human
capital, specific human capital, psychic income, or switching
costs. For example, entrepreneurs with previous venture
start-up or ownership experience may be endowed with hu-
man capital that is valuable in new venture situations be-
cause they have experience in the start-up process and in
running their own business. This experience may not be as
valuable in alternatives that include work in established
firms. At the same time, owners with prior entrepreneurial
experience may be psychologically attracted by the thrill of
start-up and thus may decide to quit and start another ven-
ture unless current performance is high.
Another important characteristic of entrepreneurs is the
number of jobs previously held. People who have been in
more job settings are likely to gain general human capital
that can be applied across a number
of alternatives.
At the
same time, however, many job changes may signal that the
759/ASQ, December 1997
Table
1
Hypothesized Impact of Independent Variables on Performance, Threshold of Performance, and Exit
Threshold of Performance
Impact on
economic Impact on
performance in psychic income Impact on Overall impact
Economic alternative from cost of on
Variable Performance employment entrepreneurship switching threshold Exit
General
human
capital
(H1)
Formal education + + 0 0 + ?
Management experience + + 0 0 + ?
Supervisory experience + + 0 0 + ?
Specific human
capital
(H2)
Similar
business + 0 0 0 0
Psychic
income (H3)
Intrinsic motivation 0 0 + 0 -
Parents owned a business 0 0 + 0
Switching
costs (H4)
Age of entrepreneur 0 0 0 +
individual
was forced out of those jobs because of poor per-
formance or low degrees of general human
capital.
Thus, a
moderate number of jobs may be the strongest indicator
of
general human
capital.
In
addition,
entrepreneurs
who have
changed jobs frequently in the past may face lower switch-
ing costs. While job switching is associated with substantial
stress (Mobley, 1977), those who have experienced it in the
past may be better able to draw on "scripted
behavior"
that
enables them to deal with the stress of job search (Lee and
Mitchell,
1994). Thus, the number of jobs previously
held by
the entrepreneur
may signal both general human capital
and
switching costs.
Our
hypotheses are summarized
in table 1, which shows the
expected effects of the variables
included
in our model.
RESEARCH
DESIGN
Testing the effect of human
capital
on thresholds of perfor-
mance in new entrepreneurial
ventures requires
finding
a
sample of new ventures in which the entrepreneurs
are
making
substantial
commitments, so that the decision to exit
is not trivial.
This suggests that the ventures should be pri-
marily
full-time,
or with the potential
to become full-time
businesses, and that there should be significant
investment
involved,
so that the decision to exit may involve a careful
consideration of the income available
from different
alterna-
tives and not merely a reaction
to immediate pressures.
The samples used in the studies noted in the literature re-
view are not adequate for testing our theory. The 1982 Char-
acteristics of Business Owners (CBO)
sample (Bates, 1990)
and the Munich
Founder
Study sample (Briderl, Preisend6r-
fer, and Ziegler,
1992) lack information
about specific human
capital
and performance,
respectively,
which are critical
vari-
ables in our study. The National
Longitudinal
Survey
of
Young Men (Evans
and Leighton,
1989) lacks information
about the business owned by the entrepreneur
and provides
a large enough sample size to study determinants
of entre-
preneurial
entry, but not exit.
76OIASQ,
December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
The sample we used includes new members of the National
Federation of Independent
Business (NFIB), the largest U.S.
small business trade association. NFIB
members tend to
have organizations
with separate business addresses, full-
time founders, and significant
investment. For
the sample,
82.2 percent of all entrepreneurs had no part-time
or full-
time jobs outside of the venture, and virtually all put in more
than 30 hours per week and grossed more than $25,000 in
the first year. The organizations
sampled at the time of the
initial
survey had a mean of 5.04 employees (median of
three employees), and only 13.2 percent had one full-time
employee or fewer (including the entrepreneur). Their me-
dian and modal investments at the time of their first sales
were between $20,000 and $50,000.
Although
sampling
from a trade association with voluntary
membership raises concerns of self-selection and represen-
tativeness of the population,
representativeness is a slippery
concept when new ventures might be defined and identified
in different
ways (Birley,
1984; Aldrich
et al., 1989). In
a pre-
liminary
comparison of our sample with other probability
samples (1982 CBO, Munich
Founder
Study data, 1985 Sta-
tistics of Income),
we found no fatal biases in the distribu-
tion of revenues, employment size, industry
membership,
and path to ownership, although
it was apparent that the
NFIB
sample included fewer part-time
entrepreneurs than
either the 1982 CBO or the Munich data. Whether the
sample is representative
of full-time
new businesses in the
United
States is difficult to discern, because there are no
comparable data on the population
of all new full-time
busi-
nesses. The fruitfulness
of this study, however, does not
depend on whether the sample is fully representative. The
aim is not to try to determine the precise mortality
rate for
all new firms but, rather,
to examine the effect and implica-
tions of firm
thresholds on organizational
survival.
We view
the current
analysis as illustrative
rather
than definitive
(Sut-
ton and Staw, 1995) and encourage further
replication
in
samples specifically
collected for this purpose.
Sample
In May 1985, we sent approximately
13,000 questionnaires
to members of the National
Federation of Independent
Busi-
ness (using the NFIB
address lists) who reported
that they
had "been in business" for eighteen months or less. We
focused on entrepreneurs
who had recently become owner-
managers, so that relevant
facts associated with start-up
would still be fresh in their minds. We had previously pre-
tested the survey instrument with 154 members of the NFIB
and altered it to improve
clarity.
We received completed sur-
veys from 4,814 entrepreneurs
(37 percent response rate),
and we sent them follow-up questionnaires
in May 1986 and
May 1987. In the three years of the study, each survey
round
involved an initial
mailing
and two follow-up
remind-
ers. For the second and third
years the response rates, cal-
culated as a percentage of those businesses not known to
have been discontinued or sold, were 47 and 39 percent,
respectively.
The 4,814 firms represent a broad range of in-
dustries and all geographic
areas of the United
States.
761/ASQ, December 1997
Determining
the status (surviving,
sold, or discontinued)
of a
firm involved
several steps. If a questionnaire
was not re-
turned in the second or third years, we sent a letter to the
business with an enclosed postcard,
asking the owner to
indicate whether the business was still in operation,
was
sold, or was discontinued. If we received no response, we
consulted the NFIB
membership records, in which the field
agents of the NFIB
report
whether businesses (whether they
continued as NFIB
members or not) had discontinued
or sur-
vived. We did not use the NFIB
records as our primary data
source, however, because the field representatives
visit
each business only once each year, so that, on the average,
the data are six months old. Finally,
if none of the above
sources indicated the status of the firm,
we noted if the
post office reported that the mail could not be delivered.
The responses to the first questionnaire
indicated that some
of the businesses were, in fact, older than the NFIB
records
indicated,
with some having
been started or acquired
in
1982 or earlier. For the 4,814 respondents, we were able to
determine the month in which they had become owner-man-
agers for 1983, 1984, and 1985 (4,103 ventures), while we
could not verify
the exact year of founding
for those organi-
zations started in "1982 or before" (711 ventures). Because
our original
sample had targeted new businesses, we elimi-
nated those older businesses that had been erroneously
sampled. We also eliminated from the sample those with
missing or nonvalid
values for the independent
variables
for
1985 (488 ventures). This left 3,615 firms with valid re-
sponses to the first questionnaire
in the sample.
A second round of sample selection was based on the data
available at the end of the third year. We maintained
in the
sample those firms that either had survived and responded
to the third-year
survey (936 observations)
or were known to
have discontinued
by that time (611 observations).
We had
to eliminate those ventures that did not return the third-year
survey and could not be identified as discontinued or sold
(1,897 firms).
We also eliminated those firms that had been
sold by the third
year (171 ventures). Thus, the final
sample
consists of 1,547 firms.
The decision to eliminate sold businesses was both theoreti-
cally grounded
and supported by substantial
sensitivity analy-
sis. Sold businesses differ from discontinued businesses in
that the owner may receive a premium
over the liquidation
value of the firm.
Thus, we believe that the choice to sell
may be different
from discontinuing
and that the two
choices should not be pooled. We conducted two statistical
tests based on a multinomial
logit specification
of the choice
problem (survived,
discontinued, sold) to determine whether
it was appropriate
either to (a) pool sold firms with those
that discontinued
or (b)
eliminate sold firms from the
sample. To examine (a),
we used a log-likelihood
ratio test to
compare whether the vector of coefficients specific to the
discontinued choice (relative
to survived)
were equal to the
vector of coefficients specific to the sold choice (relative
to
survived).
This test revealed that there was a statistically sig-
nificant difference between the vectors of coefficients
(X2
= 76.594; d.f. = 33; p < .0001) and implied
that discontin-
ued and sold firms should not be pooled. The Small and
762/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
Hsiao (1985) Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA)
test showed that the coefficients specific to the discontin-
ued and survived choices were unaffected by eliminating
sold firms (X2
= 1.7748; d.f. = 33; p <.9999). Given
the re-
sults in both tests, and to preserve consistency with our
theoretical
model, we felt justified
in eliminating sold firms
from the analysis.
We examined the possibility
of sample selection bias by
comparing our final sample (1,547 observations) with those
observations
that we eliminated
because they were sold or
did not respond to the final survey (2,068 observations). We
compared independent and control variables across these
sets of firms using tests of differences of means (t-tests) for
continuous variables and cross-tabs tests of independence
(chi-squared tests) for categorical variables. The only signifi-
cant differences between these groups were that entrepre-
neurs in the final sample had more education (p < .001), op-
erated businesses of larger scope, were more likely
to be in
professional service industries,
and were less likely
to be in
personal
service industries.
While this may indicate a slight
sample selection bias, the magnitude
of this problem
does
not seem to be great.
The period of time when the businesses in the sample were
initiated
(1983 to 1985) was characterized by a slightly
lower
index of net new business formations
in the U.S. than for
the whole decade of the 1980s (119.9 vs. 122.1, in an index
for which 1967 = 100). Net formations
hit their decade low
in 1982 and were slowly on the rebound. The period
of time
for which we recorded the exits from these businesses
(1986 and 1987) was characterized by a relatively high failure
rate (per 10,000 concerns) compared
with the whole decade
of the 1980s (111 vs. 91), with 1986 being the peak of busi-
ness failures for the decade (U.S. Bureau of the Census,
1996: 543). Thus, the study period might be characterized as
a slightly
unfavorable
period
for entrepreneurs, which, while
it may increase the baseline rate of exit in our sample,
should not affect the coefficients of the independent
vari-
ables in any systematic way.
Dependent Variables
The theoretical
model posits that the venture's economic
performance
and the entrepreneur's
threshold
jointly
deter-
mine entrepreneurial
exit. While threshold is not observable,
it can be derived
from comparisons
of two observable out-
comes: economic performance
and venture discontinuance.
When firms have equal economic performance,
the inci-
dence of exit can be attributed
to differences in thresholds.
Thus, economic performance
and exit constitute the ob-
served dependent variables in the empirical analysis.
Exit, a binary variable, represents the exit decision of firm n
(0 if the firm
continued, 1 if it was discontinued).
For those
firms that survived and returned the 1987 questionnaire,
economic performance
is represented by the amount of
money (in
the form of salaries, perquisites,
and dividends)
the entrepreneur
withdrew
from the venture during
the third
year. We lost a large number
of observations as a result of
non response to the 1987 questionnaire, and data were not
gathered on money withdrawn during either of the first two
763/ASQ, December 1997
years. For firms in the final
sample, however, money taken
out represents the overall
returns
to the entrepreneur
for
both the financial and human
capital invested in the venture
and therefore is consistent with our theoretical focus on the
economic performance for the owner. Money taken out was
reported as being within a range between predetermined
bounds (e.g., from $10,000 to $15,000).
Money taken out has the disadvantage
of not reflecting
the
extent to which an entrepreneur
may choose to accept
lower current
benefits to support greater organizational
growth. In practice,
distinguishing between economic re-
turns to investment (financial
and human
capital)
and rein-
vestment intensity is problematic
in the study of new ven-
tures because this distinction
hinges on sophisticated
accounting
concepts (accounting profits,
depreciation,
invest-
ment versus expense, retained
earnings) seldom used in
small businesses, which tend to use the cash method. It
may be that reinvestment intensities substantially
differ
by
industry,
in which case the industry
control dummies may
partial
out this effect. Below, we discuss the results in light
of this potential
weakness and conclude that the results do
not appear to be biased by it.
Independent Variables
Measures for the independent
variables
introduced
in earlier
discussions are listed in Appendix
A, while table 2 presents
descriptive statistics and correlations for the independent
and control variables in the entire sample. Because we could
only identify
the level of education (nine categories) attained
by an entrepreneur,
formal
education
was measured as the
percentage of people in the sample with lower levels of edu-
cation than the entrepreneur
in the observation.
This variable
ranges from 0 to 1 and is scaled based on the empirical
dis-
tribution
of education. While this continuous measure has
been seldom used, it may be a better metric
than "years of
education"
for several reasons. First,
the productivity
and
earnings effects of years of education are very different
for
different
stages of education. For
instance, two years of
education between high school and an associate's degree
may have different effects than two years between a bach-
elor's degree and an MBA.
Also, years of education does not
take into account that earnings
from education
are partly
de-
termined by the empirical
distribution of level of education in
the labor
supply.
While prior
research has tended to operationalize
work expe-
rience in terms of the number
of years of work experience
(Evans and Leighton, 1989; Bruderl,
Preisond6rfer,
and Zie-
gler, 1992), such a variable was not included
in our surveys.
While this could be viewed as a weakness of our study,
years of experience may not closely reflect skills and knowl-
edge developed. We used alternative
operationalizations,
meant to capture
work experience through
achievement
level attained
by the entrepreneur.
We obtained
three mea-
sures of attainment
from one question in the survey, asking
whether the highest level of management experience
achieved was "supervised managers," "supervised
others,"
"managed own business," or "supervised
no one." With
"supervised no one" as the reference group, management
764/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
Table 2
Descriptive Statistics and Pearson Correlation Coefficients*
Variable Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
1. Formal education 0.42 0.31
2. Management experience 0.13 0.33 .17
3. Supervisory experience 0.40 0.49 -.03 -.31
4. Similar
business 0.46 0.39 -.03 -.01 .02
5. Intrinsic motivation 0.01 0.99 .03 -.03 .07 -.05
6. Parents owned business 0.45 0.50 .05 -.02 -.02 -.01 .00
7. Age of entrepreneur 36.65 9.35 -.02 .13 -.14 -.09 .08 -.06
8. 1 Prior job (vs. none) 0.09 0.29 .10 .04 .01 .05 -.02 .02 -.16
9. 2 Prior jobs (vs. none) 0.17 0.37 .06 .00 -.02 .03 .04 .02 -.08 -.14
10. 3 or 4 Prior jobs (vs. none) 0.34 0.47 .03 .05 .03 -.02 -.05 -.04 -.02 -.23 -.32
11. 5+ Prior jobs (vs. none) 0.36 0.48 -.15 -.06 .00 .01 .05 .01 .22 -.24 -.33
12. Entrepreneurial experience 0.25 0.44 -.04 -.22 -.48 .09 -.07 .07 .16 -.07 .01
13. Hours worked per week 56.83 16.25 -.07 .04 -.01 .11 -.03 .01 -.05 -.07 .00
14. Outside job 0.14 0.30 -.08 -.04 .04 -.17 .00 .03 .00 .04 -.04
15. Initial capital (log) 10.04 1.21 .14 .14 -.11 -.03 -.07 .00 .12 .02 .01
16. Number of employees (log) 1.16 0.85 .11 .18 -.08 .12 -.17 -.01 .07 -.03 -.01
17. Acquired business 0.29 0.45 -.01 .01 -.04 -.11 .01 .03 .05 .00 .01
18. Inherited business 0.02 0.13 .03 -.05 .05 -.02 -.06 .11 -.08 -.03 .06
19. Radius of business sales 22.39 27.44 .05 .06 -.03 .11 -.02 .03 .09 -.06 .01
20. Months
in business (log) 2.55 0.56 .05 .05 -.01 .06 .01 .01 .04 .00 .02
21. Informational ties 0.49 0.20 -.02 .00 .03 .10 -.07 .07 -.09 .00 .03
22. Industry-construction 0.09 0.29 -.03 .01 .01 .16 -.05 .02 -.03 -.04 -.01
23. Industry-manufacturing 0.08 0.28 .00 .03 .02 .05 -.01 .01 .04 .00 -.02
24. Industry-transportation 0.02 0.15 .00 .01 .01 .03 -.03 .03 .01 .00 -.02
25. Industry-wholesale 0.05 0.21 .02 .00 -.01 .03 -.05 .00 .04 -.04 .02
26. Industry-agriculture 0.02 0.15 .11 -.01 -.03 .05 -.03 .09 -.04 .11 .01
27. Industry-financial services 0.05 0.21 .07 .01 -.03 .06 .01 .01 .03 .01 .09
28. Industry-personal services 0.17 0.38 -.13 -.02 -.03 -.04 .02 .01 -.01 -.02 -.01
29. Industry-professional services 0.07 0.26 .32 .03 .02 .10 .14 -.06 -.04 .04 .01
30. Environmental
dynamism 0.74 1.07 .04 .06 -.01 .05 -.03 .03 -.06 -.02 -.03
31. Growth
in GSP 0.08 0.11 -.06 .00 -.02 -.01 -.03 -.05 .01 -.02 -.01
32. Change
in competitors 0.51 0.92 .11 .03 .01 .02 .00 .02 .02 -.01 .00
Variable 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
11. 5+ Prior
jobs (vs. none) -.54
12. Entrepreneurial experience -.05 .10
13. Hours worked
per week -.05 .10 .07
14. Outside
job .00 .01 -.04 -.24
15. Initial
capital (log) .02 -.05 .09 .12 -.10
16. Number of employees (log) .06 -.03 .14 .17 -.12 .37
17. Acquired business -.02 .00 .03 -.01 .00 .22 .04
18. Inherited business -.01 -.04 -.03 .00 -.03 .01 .05 -.08
19. Radius
of business sales .01 .02 .08 .00 .01 .05 .19 -.11 .07
20. Months
in business (log) .02 -.03 -.01 .01 -.02 .00 .14 -.02 .01 .07
-21. Informational
ties .06 -.07 -.03 .01 -.03 .13 .12 .03 .03 .03 -.03
22. I
ndustry-construction .08 -.05 .04 .00 -.05 -.09 .15 -.09 -.01 .04 .07
23. Industry-manufacturing -.03 .06 .02 .01 .02 .06 .15 -.03 .01 .21 .01
24. Industry-transportation -.01 .02 .03 .00 .01 .04 .09 -.02 .05 .11 .01
25. Industry-wholesale .02 .01 .05 -.01 .01 .06 .04 .00 -.03 .19 .01
26. Industry-agriculture -.03 -.05 .01 .04 -.02 .07 -.02 .02 .11 .01 .02
27. Industry-financial
services -.04 -.02 -.02 .00 -.06 -.09 -.01 -.04 .02 .00 .01
28. Industry-personal
services -.04 .04 -.01 -.03 .06 -.16 -.11 -.05 .00 -.04 -.03
29. Industry-professional services .00 -.04 -.05 -.12 -.05 -.03 -.03 -.07 -.02 .02 .05
30. Environmental
dynamism .02 .02 .03 .13 -.09 .00 .11 -.04 -.01 .02 .01
31. Growth
in GSP .04 -.01 .03 .00 .00 -.02 .01 -.05 .04 -.03 -.01
32. Change
in competitors -.03 .03 .01 .01 .02 -.05 .05 -.09 -.01 .01 -.01
Variable 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31
22. Industry-construction .05
23. Industry-manufacturing -.03 -.09
24. Industry-transportation .02 -.05 -.05
25. Industry-wholesale .01 -.07 -.07 -.03
26. Industry-agriculture -.04 -.05 -.05 -.02 -.03
27. Industry-financial
services -.03 -.07 -.07 -.03 -.05 -.04
28. Industry-personal
services -.09 -.14 -.14 -.07 -.10 -.07 -.10
29. Industry-professional
services -.04 -.09 -.09 -.04 -.06 -.04 -.06 -.13
30. Environmental
dynamism .11 -.01 .00 .02 .06 .03 .11 -.05 .00
31. Growth
in GSP -.02 .06 .02 -.01 -.02 -.03 -.06 .02 -.01 .05
32. Change
in competitors .02 .03 .00 .02 -.01 -.02 .05 .04 .09 .07 .03
* N = 1,457; correlations
greater
than ?.07 are significant
at p < .01.
765/ASQ, December 1997
2
We also considered a quadratic specifica-
tion, but the nonsymmetrical distribution
of the variable, together with the fact
that most observations fall in a relatively
small number of cells (75 percent of en-
trepreneurs had five prior jobs or fewer),
led us to prefer this discrete specifica-
tion. We also ran the model with a qua-
dratic specification but preferred the dis-
crete stepwise operationalization when
we compared the results using Akaike's
Information Criterion (AIC).
experience was coded 1 if the entrepreneurs
had "super-
vised managers,"
supervisory
experience was coded 1 if the
entrepreneur
had "supervised
others," and entrepreneurial
experience was coded 1 if the entrepreneur
had "managed
own business." The survey also contained information
about
the number of prior
full-time jobs held by the entrepreneur,
which is likely
to be somewhat correlated
with years of work
experience. To account for potential
nonlinear
effects, we
segmented the variable
describing
the number of prior
jobs
into five discrete segments (0, 1, 2, 3 or 4, or 5 or more
jobs).2
Our
measure of specific human
capital
is an entrepreneur's
previous
experience with (a) customers, (b) suppliers,
and (c)
products
and services, each of which we measured individu-
ally on a 5-point
Likert scale and then combined (Cronbach
alpha
= .8723) to create the variable
similar
business (re-
coded to the 0-1 range). Intrinsic
motivation
was coded 1 if
the entrepreneur's
most important
goal in starting
a new
venture was "to let you do the kind
of work you wanted to
do" or "avoid
working
for others"; it was coded -1 if the
entrepreneur
responded "to make more money than you
would have otherwise" or "to build
a successful organiza-
tion," and 0 if the entrepreneur's
goal was "other."
Parents
owned a business is a dummy variable
that takes into ac-
count the parents' history
in an entrepreneurial
venture. Fi-
nally,
the age of the entrepreneur
is the age recorded
at the
time of the first questionnaire.
To avoid multicollinearity
be-
tween age and age2, age was operationalized as deviation
from the mean (36 years) and age2 as the square of such
deviation (Aiken
and West, 1991: 35).
Control Variables
There are well-researched
factors, unrelated
to human
capi-
tal, that may affect performance,
threshold
of performance,
or entrepreneurial
exit. These factors can be roughly
classi-
fied as characteristics
of the entrepreneur,
the firm,
and the
environment.
An important
characteristic
of the entrepreneur
is the amount of hours worked
in the venture. Entrepreneurs
working
more hours may perform
better and also expect
more from their ventures, while an entrepreneur's
desire to
readjust
work hours (Mincer,
1986) to maximize the payoff
to general human
capital,
or psychological
capital,
may lead
to exit. Entrepreneurs
who work longer hours may therefore
have a higher
threshold, being less willing
to accept a lower
level of performance.
The entrepreneur's
decision to main-
tain a full-time
or part-time
job outside the venture can also
influence
the performance
and survival
of the venture by
drawing
energy and attention
from the venture and may sig-
nal the entrepreneur's
lack of commitment, leading
to poor
performance.
The effect of outside job on threshold is un-
clear. Entrepreneurs
with outside employment may have
lower performance
thresholds because they have supple-
mentary
income to offset low performance,
or they may
have higher
thresholds because of lower switching costs.
Controls
for firm characteristics
include initial
capital
invest-
ment, firm's size, path of ownership (whether
the business
was started, acquired,
or inherited),
breadth
of geographical
niche, informational
ties, and age of the venture. Both firm
766/ASQ, December 1997
3
Recent ecological
findings
cast some
doubt
about the specific form
of age de-
pendence that firms
experience
and the
liability
of newness in particular.
These
findings
suggest that, after
controlling
for
firm size, organizational
age may have a
negative
effect on survival,
or a liability
of
obsolescence or aging (Ranger-Moore,
1991; Barron,
West, and Hannan,
1994;
Baum,
1996). Given
the restricted
range
of organizational
age in our sample (the
oldest firm
in our
sample, as of the third
year,
was only
five years and four
months
old),
we cannot
enter this de-
bate. To the extent that there may be
unobserved
heterogeneity
in the sample,
we expect greater
mortality
of younger
firms during
these early stages of the
venture.
Survival of the Fittest?
size (defined
as number
of employees) and initial
capital
may
improve
efficiency and reduce the liability
of smallness (Han-
nan and Freeman, 1984; Aldrich
and Auster, 1986), while
initial capital
investment may also provide
a liquidity
buffer
for the firm
to survive under
conditions
of low performance
(BrOderl
and SchOssler,
1990; Levinthal,
1991; Fichman
and
Levinthal,
1991). Firms
that were started by the owner are
more likely
to experience a higher
liability
than acquired
or
inherited
businesses, since completely new roles and ties
must be developed (Stinchcombe,
1965). Inherited
busi-
nesses may also experience different
performance
and sur-
vival
dynamics because the owner may have developed prior
firm-specific
human
capital
while working
for the family
firm
and a possible psychic attachment
to the firm. Radius
of
business sales reflects the breadth
of the geographical
mar-
ket niche, a critical
dimension of the firm's strategy that is
likely to influence performance
and survival
(Carroll,
1985;
Briderl, Preisendbrfer,
and Ziegler,
1992). Informational
ties
of the organization,
which can convey relevant
knowledge
and information
to the owner, was measured with an index
of the use and importance
of seven information
and advice
sources (Cronbach
alpha
= .5849). Months in business (age
of the venture) may reflect the liability
of newness (Stinch-
combe, 1965) as well as the extent to which the venture has
experienced the effects of selection (Freeman,
Carroll,
and
Hannan,
1983).3
We controlled
for the age of the venture to
minimize
the potential
for left-censoring
bias (Guo, 1993).
The venture's competitive environment
also has important
influences on economic performance
and survival.
Industry
environments
may differ
in average performance
(Bain,
1956), reinvestment intensity,
sunk costs, and barriers
to
exit (Caves and Porter,
1976; Porter,
1976). We controlled
for nine industry
classifications
using eight dummy variables
(construction,
manufacturing,
transportation,
wholesale, agri-
culture,
financial
services, personal
services, and profes-
sional services), with retail
as the reference group.
The in-
tensity of competition
is also a function
of the changes in
the munificence
of the environment.
Markets
that are grow-
ing may experience less intense competition
for resources,
and vice versa. We controlled
for such munificence by in-
cluding
the growth of gross state product
(GSP)
between
1985 and 1987. We expected high growth of GSP to be as-
sociated with higher
performance
and survival.
Because our
ability
to control
for objective dimensions of the competitive
and institutional
environment
was very limited,
especially if
compared
with the industry-specific
samples often used in
population
ecology studies, we used two perceptual
vari-
ables to describe the environment:
the entrepreneur's
per-
ceptions about the expected change in (number
of) competi-
tors in the next five years and how rapidly
the business is
changing (environmental
dynamism).
While these perceptual
measures may be quite unreliable,
they help minimize
the
data's weaknesses in terms of omitted competitive vari-
ables.
Statistical Methods
From the theoretical
model formulated
above, if a venture's
economic performance
exceeds the entrepreneur's
threshold
level of performance
we expect the entrepreneur
to con-
767/ASQ, December 1997
tinue with the venture. Conversely, if economic performance
is less than the threshold level, the entrepreneur is expected
to exit the venture. Thus, the decision to continue with or
exit from venture n is endogenously determined by the eco-
nomic performance
of the venture and the entrepreneur's
threshold level of performance,
following the decision rule:
EX11T
{
0 i.e., venture
continues, if EPn*(Xn)
> Tn*(Xn)
n l 1 i.e., venture is discontinued, if EPn*(Xn)
< Tn*(Xn).
(5)
EPn*
is a latent variable that represents economic perfor-
mance as of the third
year. When the venture is discontin-
ued, economic performance
(EPn*)
is completely unobserva-
ble. When the venture survives, we observe, instead, money
taken outn,
which indicates whether EPn*
falls between two
known bounds. Tn*
is the latent construct of threshold per-
formance, which is never directly
observed. We seek to esti-
mate the effect of the independent variables
(Xn)
on eco-
nomic performance
and threshold level of performance.
This
estimation presents four methodological
challenges: (1) the
unobservability
of economic performance in the case of exit,
(2) the endogenous nature of the exit decision, (3) the total
unobservability
of the threshold of performance,
and (4) the
ordinal
nature of our measure for economic performance
for
those ventures that continued.
Our
approach
combines two well-known
methodologies in
the econometric literature
involving studies of discrete and
limited
dependent variables
(Maddala,
1983). The first meth-
odology, censored regression (or
tobit) model with unob-
served stochastic thresholds (Nelson, 1977; Smith, 1980;
Maddala,
1983: 174-178), is appropriate
when the depen-
dent variable is only observed when it falls above a particular
level or threshold,
and this threshold varies from observation
to observation
as a function of some independent
variables.
Thus, this methodology deals with the first three challenges
highlighted
above. This method has been used to estimate
the determinants
of female labor
supply (Nelson, 1977) and
the predictors
of market
transaction
costs and internal
orga-
nizational costs (Masten, Meehan, and Snyder, 1991). This
methodology is also useful for avoiding
potential
problems of
self-selection bias (Heckman,
1979). When the observability
of a dependent variable
(in our case, economic performance)
is endogenously determined
by a decision (exit) in which the
economic performance is itself an important
factor, missing
observations (on those firms that have exited) are not ran-
dom. Rather,
they are self-selected based on their lower
economic performance,
higher threshold of performance,
or
both, thus creating
a problem
of selectivity bias that could
make the coefficients unreliable.
The second methodology, grouped data regression (Stewart,
1983; Greene, 1990), attends to the final
challenge identified
above. It is useful when the exact value of the dependent
variable
(in our case, economic performance,
EPn*
is not ob-
served but is known to be in a range between two known
values. It has been applied
to the analysis of income data
from surveys (like
ours) in which the respondent is asked
whether his or her income is between some prespecified
dollar
amounts.
768/ASQ, December 1997
4
The probit equation could be estimated
jointly with a performance equation to
increase the efficiency of the exit param-
eter estimates. We present the single-
equation probit here because it focuses
on mortality alone and is therefore com-
parable to prior research on mortality (no
prior research that we know of has used
joint estimation of exit and performance).
A comparison of coefficients derived
from joint estimation suggests that they
are not different in any meaningful way
from those derived in the single-equation
probit illustrated in column 3.
Survival of the Fittest?
We combined both methodologies here. As in censored re-
gression with stochastic thresholds, the decision to continue
or exit is based on the comparison
of the two latent con-
structs of economic performance
and the threshold (see
equation
4), which are specified as a linear
function
of the
observable independent
variables,
as follows:
EPn = Xb1 Xin
+ e1n (6a)
Tn= Yb *Xin
+ e2n, (6b)
where Xn
is the vector of independent
and control
variables,
b1 and b2 are vectors of regression coefficients, and e1 and
e2 are random
disturbances.
We estimated the censored regression model on economic
performance
and the tobit model on threshold performance
simultaneously
using a maximum
likelihood
procedure.
Since
there is no standard
program
that produces maximum
likeli-
hood estimates for this combination
of models, we math-
ematically
derived
the likelihood
function
and maximized
it
using LIMDEP
7.0. Details about this maximum
likelihood
estimation method are provided
in Appendix
B.
RESULTS
Model Significance
We tested the significance
of the human
capital
variables
in
the threshold model (columns 1 and 2 of table 3) by examin-
ing whether the addition
of these variables
significantly
im-
proved
the ability
to explain
exit through
economic perfor-
mance and performance
threshold.
We used a log-likelihood
ratio
test to compare the full model with two nested naive
models (not shown); the first with only constants for eco-
nomic performance
and performance
threshold,
the second
including
only control
variables.
The first test produced
a chi-
square value of 692.85 (66 d.f.), while the second had a
value of 154.09 (26 d.f.). Both tests were significant
(p < .0001). The first test reflects the overall
significance
of
the model, while the second indicates the joint significance
of the independent (human
capital)
variables
of the model.
Hypothesis Testing
The results for the independent
variables
generally
confirm
the separate effects of both economic performance
and
threshold
on the entrepreneur's
likelihood
of exit. The results
from the full model are presented in table 3. Columns 1 and
2 present the coefficients relating
to economic performance
and threshold, respectively. Column
3 presents the coeffi-
cients of a probit
model on exit.4 The hypotheses were
tested by examining
these three columns. Because we had
prior
expectations about the direction
of hypothesized rela-
tionships, we used a one-tailed
test where appropriate.
Simi-
lar to column 1, column 4 presents the results from a re-
gression on economic performance
but differs in that it does
not control
for the self-selection problem.
Although
column 4
is not directly
related
to our hypothesis testing, we introduce
it to evaluate the effect of self-selection bias in estimating
performance.
In general, hypothesis 1 (relationships
regard-
ing general human capital)
receives partial
support,
while hy-
potheses 2 through
4 (relationships
regarding
specific human
769/ASQ, December 1997
Table 3
Parameter Estimates of Economic Performance, Threshold of Performance, and Exit
Joint Maximum Likelihood Model
Economic Threshold of Binomial Non-censored
Performance Performance Probit Regression on
Equation* Equation on Exit Economic Performance*
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables Coeff. S.E. Coeff. S.E. Coeff. S.E. Coeff. S.E.
Formal
education 6.84-t (2.72) .03t (2.79) -.21- (.13) 4.95 (2.37)
Management
experience 3.75-t (2.75) 6.05t (2.97) .07 (.13) 4.43- (2.48)
Supervisory
experience 5.05Ot (2.06) 1.25t (2.19) -.18- (.09) 3.34- (1.89)
Similar
business 8.89-t (2.12) .04 (2.25) -.38"t (.10) 5.21 (1.85)
Intrinsic
motivation -.39 (.77) -1.87mt (.79) -.07t (.04) -1.15- (.69)
Parents
owned business -.19 (1.53) -3.20"t (1.63) -.1 5t (.07) -2.27- (1.34)
Age of entrepreneur .14 (.10) -.49-t (.11) -.02't (.00) -.10 (.09)
Age2 .00 (.01) .00 (.01) .00 (.00) .00 (.01)
1 Prior
job (vs. none) 5.72 (5.28) -7.30 (5.18) -.55m (.21) -.17 (4.32)
2 Prior
jobs (vs. none) 8.59' (4.77) -2.42 (4.63) -.42" (.20) 4.15 (4.11)
3 or 4 Prior
jobs (vs. none) 6.75 (4.68) -2.05 (4.43) -.30 (.19) 3.71 (4.00)
5+ Prior
jobs (vs. none) .67 (4.69) 1.15 (4.41) .06 (.19) 1.11 (4.06)
Entrepreneurial
experience 4.07- (2.36) 6.45" (2.47) .07 (.11) 5.04 (2.14)
Hours
worked -.01 (.05) -.04 (.05) .00 (.00) -.05 (.05)
Outside
job -11.68-- (2.76) -7.34 (2.90) .16 (.12) -10.82-- (2.63)
Initial
capital
(log) 2.76-- (.71) -1.52" (.77) -.17-- (.03) 1.12- (.61)
Number
of employees (log) 9.07---- (1.01) 3.52-. (1.07) -.16" (.05) 8.30w (.92)
Acquired
business 1.06 (1.79) -1.35 (1.88) -.17 (.08) -1.24 (1.50)
Inherited
business 2.85 (5.61) -11.02 (7.05) -.63 (.30) -3.56 (4.51)
Radius
of business sales -.03 (.03) .100 (.03) .01w (.00) .03 (.03)
Months
in business (log) 7.45-- (1.45) -.59 (1.39) -.35w- (.06) 3.57--- (1.30)
Informational
ties 1.78 (3.92) 1.54 (4.06) -.09 (.18) .25 (3.42)
Industry-construction 12.22--- (2.70) 3.12 (2.77) -.32 (.14) 9.75w (2.45)
Industry-manufacturing 11.11-- (2.79) 3.87 (3.11) -.34w (.14) 8.19- (2.53)
Industry-transportation 9.17- (4.92) 5.80 (4.91) -.09 (.24) 8.88- (4.62)
Industry-wholesale 11.62--- (3.57) 4.73 (3.91) -.29- (.18) 9.650 (3.20)
Industry-agriculture 10.52" (4.78) -.74 (6.56) -.55w (.26) 6.46 (3.96)
Industry-financial
services 25.13w (3.87) 11.66' (4.37) -.71w (.18) 18.90w (2.93)
Industry-personal
services 6.28- (2.24) -.48 (2.31) -.28m (.10) 3.96-- (2.01)
Industry-professional
serv. 23.77w (2.88) 6.08- (3.18) -.69m. (.16) 17.85"--- (2.66)
Environmental
dynamism .44 (.73) .04 (.77) -.03 (.03) .09 (.65)
Growth
in GSP 34.01---- (7.23) 6.74 (7.53) -1.20w (.32) 21.23w (6.36)
Change
in competitors -.48 (.77) .24 (.81) .05 (.04) .08 (.74)
Log-likelihood -2,433.50 -890.64 -1,558.11
N 1547 1547 936
* p < .10; *-p < .05; Up < .01; Amp < .001; two-tailed
Wald test unless otherwise indicated.
* Dependent
variable
uses grouped data methodology.
t One-tailed
Wald
test for hypothesized
relationships.
capital,
psychic income, and switching costs) receive rela-
tively strong support.
General human capital. Measures of general human
capital
should raise the economic performance
of the venture and
the expected returns
outside the venture. Because of these
offsetting factors, we cannot determine the relationship
of
general human capital
to survival a priori;
it depends on the
relative
payoff of human
capital
in the venture versus out-
side the venture. Hypothesis 1 received mixed support.
As
expected, education, management experience, and supervi-
sory experience are positively
related
to the economic per-
formance of the venture, but only management experience
has the expected positive relationship
with threshold. The
insignificant
effect of management experience on exit
seems largely
driven
by the offsetting influence of this vari-
able on both performance
and threshold. In contrast, it ap-
pears that the negative relationship
of supervisory
experi-
ence and education
to exit is largely
driven
by a greater
770/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
payoff to these forms of human capital
in the venture. A
two-tailed
Wald
test shows that supervisory
experience has
a significantly
lower payoff (one-tailed
Wald
test: p < .10) in
other alternatives
(a lower threshold)
than does management
experience.
While not reported
here, we explored
further
the effect of
education
on performance and threshold
by operationalizing
education as a set of indicator
variables for five different
lev-
els of educational
attainment.
Consistent with the linear re-
sults, entrepreneurs with higher
education (with bachelor's
or graduate
degrees) have significantly
higher
performance
than those with medium levels of education (high school
graduates or some college), even though those without a
high school diploma
do not necessarily perform
worse than
the rest. Paradoxically,
entrepreneurs with a high school di-
ploma or with a bachelor's
degree have a lower threshold
than those who did not attain
their high school diploma and
those who went to college but did not obtain a bachelor's
degree. This nonmonotonic
effect may explain the nonsignifi-
cant threshold
effect of the linear
operationalization
of edu-
cation. This result may suggest that those entrepreneurs
who persisted in their studies until
they obtained the degree
are also more likely
to persist in their business.
Human capital specific to the venture. Hypothesis 2 pre-
dicted that because an entrepreneur's
specific human capital
will have little value outside the venture, the decision to exit
will be influenced
primarily by the venture's performance.
Since entrepreneurs
with higher
degrees of specific human
capital
are expected to have better performing
ventures, we
expect them to be less likely
to exit. Our
measure of spe-
cific human
capital,
similar
business, is related
as expected.
As depicted in column 3, the variable
has a strong, negative
relationship
to exit (one-tailed
Wald
test: p < .001). That rela-
tionship is driven
by the very strong and positive impact
on
economic performance
(one-tailed
Wald
test: p < .001) and
the insignificant
effect on threshold.
Psychic income from entrepreneurship. Hypothesis 3 ar-
gued that individuals
who attach high psychic income to en-
trepreneurship
are expected to accept a lower level of per-
formance before exiting
their ventures. While they are not
necessarily performing
better, we expect them to be less
likely
to exit their business. This hypothesis received strong
support. Our
measures of psychic income, intrinsic
motiva-
tion (one-tailed
Wald
test: p < .01) and parents owned a busi-
ness (one-tailed
Wald test: p < .05), are both negatively
re-
lated to threshold,
while having no statistical
relationship
with economic performance. This explains
the negative and
significant
effect of both variables
on exit. It seems that en-
trepreneurs
who are more intrinsically
motivated and have a
family
history
in entrepreneurship
are simply more likely
to
accept a lower level of economic performance
to remain
in
business.
Switching costs. With
age of the entrepreneur
as a mea-
sure of switching costs, our results support hypothesis 4.
The persistence of older entrepreneurs
is due to their
will-
ingness to accept a lower return,
i.e., their lower threshold
(one-tailed
Wald
test: p < .001), since they do not seem to
771 /ASQ, December 1997
perform
significantly differently
than younger entrepreneurs.
The main effect of age on performance
is significant
in a
one-tailed Wald
test at the p < .10 level, but not in a two-
tailed test. Since we do not have initial
theoretical
expecta-
tions about the effects of age on performance,
we believe
the two-tailed test to be appropriate,
but this result may indi-
cate that age is picking up some omitted variables measur-
ing the effect of human capital, such as years of work expe-
rience. Age2 had no significant
effects on either performance
or threshold.
Other influences. Entrepreneurial
experience has a positive
and significant effect on economic performance
(two-tailed
Wald test: p < .10) and threshold (two-tailed
Wald test:
p < .01). It appears that the effect on threshold is greatest.
Consistent with the view that too many or too few jobs may
indicate low general human
capital, we found that entrepre-
neurs with two prior jobs perform better than those with no
previous work experience (two-tailed Wald
test: p < .10) and
than those with five or more prior
jobs (two-tailed
Wald test:
p < .001); and entrepreneurs
with three or four prior jobs
perform
better than those with five or more prior jobs (two-
tailed Wald test: p < .001). The same result does not hold for
the threshold
equation. Instead, entrepreneurs
having held
five or more prior
jobs have higher
thresholds than entrepre-
neurs with only one prior job (two-tailed Wald test: p < .05).
This suggests that entrepreneurs who have held many jobs
are less willing
to tolerate low performance,
perhaps be-
cause they have lower economic or psychic switching costs.
Control variables. The results in table 3 also illustrate
sev-
eral interesting
relationships
for the control
variables. Of the
remaining
variables
related to the entrepreneur,
hours
worked was not related
to any of the dependent variables.
As expected, the economic returns to entrepreneurs with an
outside job was significantly
lower than those concentrating
solely on the venture. Interestingly,
outside job was also re-
lated negatively with threshold, presumably
because entre-
preneurs
could afford to accept lower performance.
Several of the firm-level
control
variables had important
influ-
ences on economic performance, threshold,
and exit. Initial
capital,
number of employees, and months in business had
significant positive effects (two-tailed
Wald test: p < .001) on
economic performance,
suggesting that better capitalized,
larger,
and older firms were better performers.
This explains
the strong and significant negative effects of these variables
on the probability
of exit (two-tailed
Wald
test: p < .001). The
variables,
however, differed in their effect on threshold of
performance.
Initial
capital
had a significant
negative effect
on threshold (two-tailed
Wald test: p < .05), number of em-
ployees had a significant positive effect (two-tailed
Wald
test: p < .001), and months in business had no significant
effect on threshold.
The path to ownership of the venture,
whether the firm
was acquired, inherited,
or developed,
seemed to have no significant
bearing
on either performance
or threshold,
although
owners who inherited their busi-
nesses seemed to be willing
to accept lower performance
(two-tailed
Wald test: p < .12) than those who started their
firms. Both acquired businesses and inherited businesses
were less likely
to exit than start-up
firms. While firms with a
772/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
wider radius
of business sales tended to exit more often,
this result was due primarily
to the firms' higher
thresholds,
because there were no significant
performance
differences.
Information
ties did not show significant
effects in our analy-
sIs.
Several industry
dummies also had significant
effects on per-
formance, threshold,
and exit. All industries
were compared
against the largest industry group-retailing-and all showed
higher
economic performance
than that group. Firms
in fi-
nancial
and professional
industries
tended to perform
better
and exit less frequently.
As expected, economic returns
to
the entrepreneur
were greater when growth in GSP was
higher.
Our
measures of environmental
change and change
in competitors had no significant
influence on performance,
threshold,
or exit.
Effects of Self-Selection Bias
A methodological
problem
of studying determinants
of eco-
nomic performance
in businesses with high attrition
rates is
that the dependent variable is only available
for firms that
survive, yet survival is more likely
for firms with high perfor-
mance. This creates a self-selection problem.
To highlight
the effects of self-selection bias on the analysis of economic
performance,
we compare column 4, a simple grouped data
regression model without correction
for self-selection bias,
with column 1, which corrects for this bias. The magnitude
of the self-selection problem
will differ for each predictor
variable,
depending on whether the variable
is expected to
be related to the selection function, in this case survival
(Heckman,
1979). Variables that have a strong effect on sur-
vival
suffer more from self-selection, which biases down-
ward their coefficients on performance,
because firms that
fail are more likely
to have lower values of these variables.
By modeling performance
effects with only surviving
firms,
the distributions
of affected variables
fall within a narrower
range, creating
effects that are less significant.
In some cases self-selection bias can make insignificant
co-
efficients appear
to be significant
in the performance
equa-
tion. This bias was reflected most visibly
in our measures of
psychic income: intrinsic motivation and parents owned a
business. From
column 4, it appears that entrepreneurs
who
were intrinsically
motivated
or whose parents owned a busi-
ness have lower performance,
but this conclusion reflects
the potentially
incorrect
interpretations
of biased results. Our
earlier discussion suggested that these entrepreneurs
were
more likely
to survive simply because they were willing
to
accept lower levels of performance
to stay in business. This
selection mechanism led to the spurious
observation that
surviving
"unsuccessful" entrepreneurs
were more likely
to
have intrinsic motivation
or family
ties to entrepreneurship,
even though the relationship
was not causally
related
to a
lack of economic success. Another
interesting
observation
is
that the coefficient of months in business, one of the strong-
est effects on performance,
became strongly
biased down-
ward (to less than half of its unbiased
value) if the estima-
tion of the effect was only based on surviving
firms. This
result suggests that the apparent
lack
of consistency be-
tween the effect of venture age on survival
and perfor-
773/ASQ, December 1997
mance-an observation that motivated Meyer and Zucker's
(1989: 19) theory of permanently failing organizations-may
be partly due to self-selection bias. These examples empha-
size the importance of controlling for self-selection bias and
are consistent with Barnett, Greve, and Park (1994), who
also found that controlling for selection bias substantially
in-
fluenced the statistical effects of variables on performance.
DISCUSSION
Assumptions about the relationship between performance
and survival are so entrenched in social science research
that little work has investigated
them empirically.
In some
perspectives, those with Panglossian
overtones, it is as-
sumed that the efficiency of markets
will lead to the "sur-
vival of the fittest." This rhetoric implies unidimensionality
between performance and survival: the lowest performing
organizations
are also the least likely
to survive. Scholars es-
pousing other perspectives recognize that selection does not
necessarily favor
the best performing organizations
(Hannan
and Freeman, 1977; Meyer and Rowan, 1977) but have
failed to study the causal relationships
between these con-
structs (Meyer
and Zucker, 1989; Amburgey
and Rao, 1996).
Our theoretical model and empirical
results suggest that sur-
vival is enhanced by economic performance but not uniquely
determined by it. Rather, organizations
have different re-
quired thresholds of performance,
and survival
(or exit) is
determined by whether performance
falls above (or below)
the threshold. In small and new ventures, the threshold
of
performance
is fundamentally
influenced
by the human
capi-
tal characteristics of the entrepreneur,
including
the value of
this capital
in alternative uses, psychic income, and switch-
ing costs. This paper is the first, we believe, to provide
em-
pirical support
for the assertion that thresholds of perfor-
mance differ
systematically
across firms and play
an
important
role in determining
firm survival.
Several of the
results are worth highlighting.
First,
we found that entrepreneurs
with more general human
capital perform
better but do not necessarily survive more
frequently.
We had expected that entrepreneurs
endowed
with general human
capital
would have higher
performance
requirements
for their businesses and might quit if these
requirements
were not met. This expectation was only par-
tially supported by our results. We found that general man-
agement experience (having managed managers)
influences
an entrepreneur's
threshold
of performance,
while neither
education nor supervisory experience are related.
This sug-
gests that the value of general management experience out-
side the venture may be comparable
to its value in entrepre-
neurship,
while returns
to education and supervisory
experience may be somewhat better in self-employment,
findings
consistent with Evans and Leighton (1989). The ap-
parently divergent payoffs of management experience and
supervisory experience are especially intriguing.
While man-
agement experience may be more generally
applied,
it may
also be that having experience "managing
managers" is
more valuable in larger organizations
with more formal struc-
tures.
Second, we found that entrepreneurial
skills that have little
use outside of the venture, such as prior experience with
774/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
the venture's customers, suppliers,
products,
and services
are related to both performance
and survival.
Furthermore,
by demonstrating no significant
relationship with threshold,
our results support the expectation that human
capital
that is
largely
specific to the venture context should have little or
no bearing
on returns outside of the venture. Apparently,
specific human
capital influences survival
by increasing
the
gap between performance and threshold (i.e., increasing
per-
formance without raising
the threshold).
Third, our findings suggest that some dimensions of human
capital
have important
effects on persistence, even when
they do not influence performance. Factors such as the en-
trepreneur's
age, family experience with entrepreneurship,
or intrinsic motivation
do not have any tangible
effect on per-
formance. Yet entrepreneurs
with a higher level of these at-
tributes are willing
to accept a lower level of performance to
survive. Entrepreneurs
who have inherited businesses are
also more likely
to continue, apparently because of their de-
sire to sustain the family
business (lower threshold)
and not
because of superior performance
associated with any "ex-
tra" knowledge passed on to them.
These findings provide strong support for our threshold
model of entrepreneurial exit and reconcile many of the in-
consistent relationships previously
found in entrepreneurial
performance
and survival research: some human
capital
vari-
ables significantly
influence both performance and survival
(specific human
capital),
some influence performance
more
than survival
(general
human
capital),
and some influence
survival but not performance
(switching costs, psychic in-
come). This evidence suggests that there are differences in
determinants of performance
and survival
and that research
agendas ignoring
the entrepreneur's
choice to accept a given
level of performance are incomplete.
A somewhat surprising result is that entrepreneurial experi-
ence seems to have at least as much effect on threshold as
it does on economic performance
of the venture. If entrepre-
neurial
experience constitutes human
capital
that is specific
to the venture, we would expect its effect to be greater in-
side the venture than outside it. We interpret
the higher
threshold
effect as suggesting that experienced entrepre-
neurs have reduced switching costs into alternative
employ-
ment (maybe trying again with another
venture), perhaps be-
cause they have developed networks or familiarity
with the
routine of starting
businesses. Experienced
entrepreneurs
may also gain a certain "thrill" from the start-up process and
thus experience a negative psychic income once the venture
becomes stable.
As we might expect, entrepreneurs'
history
of previous jobs
seems to reflect their general human capital.
Our
findings
indicate that a low number
of prior
jobs may be associated
with a lack of outside alternatives,
while a high number of
prior jobs may suggest an inability
to perform jobs satisfacto-
rily. Thus, both a low and high number of jobs suggest low
degrees of human
capital
and poor performance
in the ven-
ture. At the same time, we found that a large number of
prior
jobs increases an entrepreneur's threshold, suggesting
that these entrepreneurs are less willing to tolerate low per-
775/ASQ, December 1997
formance. This is likely due to low economic or psychic
switching costs.
By incorporating the threshold construct, our analysis also
provides insight into the effects of some well-studied
factors
bearing on organizational
mortality: initial
capital, size, age,
and strategy of the venture. The first three variables are
strongly related
to performance;
both initial
capital
and size
also influence survival
through
their impact
on threshold.
The
negative effect of initial
capital on threshold may support the
view that initial
capital
provides the entrepreneur a buffer to
withstand poor performance
and liquidity
problems
without
having to exit the business (BrOderl and SchOssler,
1990;
Levinthal,
1991; Fichman
and Levinthal,
1991). It may also
suggest that financial
investments are largely
irreversible.
In
contrast, the positive effect of number of employees (size)
on threshold
suggests that entrepreneurs
of larger organiza-
tions require
higher
performance, perhaps because they can
easily disband if they do not obtain such performance.
This
is assisted by a labor
market that facilitates mobility.
The
lack of any significant
relationship between age of the ven-
ture and threshold suggests that the processes underlying
the "liability
of newness" phenomenon tend to influence
exit mainly
through
the performance
component. Our
finding
that firms with broader
scope exit more frequently
is consis-
tent with Bruderl,
Preisend6rfer, and Ziegler
(1992). We
found that this effect is mainly
due to their higher
threshold
of performance.
The environmental
controls show that industries differ in
both their performance and threshold effects. Financial and
professional
services industries
tend to perform
better but
also to have higher
thresholds, while personal
services and
retail
industries
are characterized
by both low performance
and low thresholds. These patterns may reflect broad differ-
ences in the general human
capital
of entrepreneurs
in those
industries.
Finally,
environmental munificence has a positive
effect on performance
and exit. While it might have been
expected that a good economic environment would also in-
crease the income in alternative
occupations, and thus in-
crease threshold,
the coefficient of munificence on threshold
is positive but not statistically significant.
Alternative Explanations and Limitations
Our
empirical
findings may have alternative
explanations.
It
could be that entrepreneurs
differ in their decision-making
speed and rationality
when faced with poor performance.
Entrepreneurs
who simply delay the exit decision or experi-
ence a psychological
escalation of commitment (Staw,
1981), perhaps because of less training,
would appear
in our
results as having
lower thresholds. It may be that formal
education does not increase underlying
ability
but that it has
value as a market
signal that allows employers to segregate
people of higher
ability
(Spence, 1974). Alternatively,
an en-
trepreneur's
high level of formal
education may increase the
legitimacy
of a small business, facilitating
access to better
trading partners
and leading
to improved
performance
(Meyer
and Rowan, 1977). These alternative theoretical
justi-
fications for our findings should be considered in future stud-
ies, as should factors beyond the scope of our model that
776/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
are examined in prior
research. Venture performance
has
been linked
to network
formation
(Aldrich, Rosen, and
Woodward,
1987), environments
(Carroll,
1987), and strate-
gies (McDougall,
Robinson,
and DeNisi, 1992), as well as
interactions
between environments
and strategies (Ro-
manelli,
1989; Eisenhardt
and Schoonhoven, 1990). A
broader
array
of perspectives will undoubtedly
increase our
insight into new venture thresholds.
There are also some empirical
limitations
to our research,
mainly
because of shortcomings in data availability
and mea-
surement. Because we chose to make the sample as broad
as possible, we lacked
fine-grained
measures of the institu-
tional
dimensions of the environment.
It would be illuminat-
ing to replicate
this study in the context of a single industry
or population
to control
more aptly
for environmental
dimen-
sions. Our
reliance on demographic
variables
(age, parents
who owned a business) as proxies for psychological
con-
structs (psychic income) or switching costs is also another
limitation
that could be overcome with better measures in
future
work. The sociological
and psychological
literatures
may contain useful insights into how to extend our opera-
tionalization
of these important
constructs. Further,
the lack
of available information
on the alternatives
under
consider-
ation by entrepreneurs
did not allow us to specify fully
our
theoretical model, which may therefore be affected by un-
measured heterogeneity. Information on liquidation
values
for discontinued
businesses could have also helped specify
the exit choice more accurately.
Another
potential
limitation
is our measurement of economic
performance
as current
monetary
outlays. Monetary
outlays
to the entrepreneur
may not distinguish
between firms with
low performance
and firms with high reinvestment intensity
or bright
prospects. Firms
with low current
monetary
outlays
may still survive if the expected return to reinvestment activ-
ity is high, a condition
that may be incorrectly
reflected as a
low threshold
effect. Examination
of our results, however,
shows that lower thresholds are associated with entrepre-
neurs who are older, motivated by independence rather
than
growth or financial
goals, who have little prior
management
or entrepreneurial
experience, and who are not fully
commit-
ted to the venture. This description
does not fit the profile
of
entrepreneurs
with high prospects willing
to reinvest aggres-
sively but, rather,
of those with limited alternatives
and posi-
tive psychic income from independence.
Implications for Entrepreneurship and Beyond
This research highlights
the importance
of considering
the
human
capital
characteristics
of the entrepreneur
in the sur-
vival of new ventures. Despite recent criticisms
of inconsis-
tent findings in the "trait"
literature
(Aldrich,
1990: 8), the
multiple
and critically
important
roles of the entrepre-
neur-as chief strategist and decision maker,
as repository
of much of the knowledge and skills that make up the intan-
gible assets of the firm,
as the person who develops the
contacts and networks upon which the new venture de-
pends-cannot be ignored. Our
study suggests that the ef-
fects of these entrepreneurial
characteristics
on entrepre-
neurial thresholds are important
for survival
and can explain
777/ASQ, December 1997
prior
inconsistent findings.
The implication
for entrepreneur-
ship research is that more attention is due to the outside
opportunities
of entrepreneurs,
their psychic income, and
switching costs, even if those variables
do not directly
influ-
ence entrepreneurial
performance.
Prior
research has shown
that entry into entrepreneurship
may be more likely for those
with reduced options elsewhere (Fuchs, 1982; Borjas,
1986;
Brittain and Freeman, 1986; Carroll
and Mosakowski, 1987).
This research showed that those entrepreneurs
are also
more likely
to survive, independent
of performance.
Thus, a
clear appreciation
of thresholds is necessary to understand
the entrepreneurial
process.
The concept of the threshold
of performance
outlined
in this
study can serve as an integrating
construct for understand-
ing performance
and survival
for all organizations,
not merely
new ventures. The question then becomes, "Why
do organi-
zations differ
in their thresholds?" Perhaps the answer to
this question must come from theoretical
perspectives be-
yond human capital
theory. Future research could focus on
the role of governance structures,
coalition
power, and in-
trafirm
conflict (Meyer
and Zucker,
1989), which may limit
the ability
of owners to influence their organizations
and
therefore be associated with persistence under low perfor-
mance. Other research could articulate
thresholds as a func-
tion of slack (Cyert
and March,
1963), initial
resource endow-
ments, or established relationships (Bruderl
and Schissler,
1990; Miner,
Amburgey,
and Stearns, 1990; Levinthal,
1991;
Fichman and Levinthal,
1991) and disentangle the perfor-
mance and threshold effects of these important
constructs.
The nature
of resource commitment (whether
the resources
are sunk or highly
mobile)
would also influence both perfor-
mance (Ghemawat,
1991) and exit barriers
(Caves and Por-
ter, 1976) and may constitute an interesting
area for future
research.
These multiple
theoretical lenses can be brought
to bear in understanding
cross-sectional and longitudinal
dif-
ferences in thresholds of both new and established organiza-
tions. The concept of threshold may also be applied,
within
the firm,
to determine the minimum level of performance
that a multidivisional
organization
requires
to maintain
an ac-
tive division.
Proponents
of the unidimensional
view might argue that
thresholds are simply
temporary
"buffers"
against the inevi-
table success of better performing
firms. While initial
re-
sources or decision-making lags may delay exit, those buff-
ers may ultimately
be depleted by continued low
performance
(Bruderl
and SchOssler,
1990; Levinthal,
1991;
Fichman and Levinthal,
1991), leaving intact the long-term,
unidimensional
relationship
between performance
and exit.
Even if thresholds are temporary,
however, they may be an
important
initial condition
that has long-term
implications
for
performance
and survival
by providing
a buffer
at a crucial
stage of the organization's
development (Eisenhardt
and
Schoonhoven, 1990; Levinthal,
1991). We believe, however,
that thresholds persist over time and that they reflect a will-
ingness to accept lower performance
for the reasons high-
lighted in this paper.
Whether a temporary
buffer or an en-
during quality,
thresholds will influence the long-term
selection processes in populations
of organizations.
If perfor-
778/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
mance is stochastic (as in Levinthal's model of random
walks), lower initial
thresholds allow firms to survive
during
runs of bad performance
until performance
improves and,
therefore, have a path-dependent effect on selection out-
comes. Even if interfirm
performance differences are rela-
tively deterministic
and difficult to change, organizations
that
are willing to remain
in business at low levels of economic
performance
(those having low thresholds, perhaps because
of low resource mobility)
may increase competition and have
a "crowding
out" effect on better performing
but more mo-
bile firms. These arguments suggest that it is difficult to de-
termine a priori
to what extent selection outcomes in a
population
reflect differences in efficiency and performance
or differences in thresholds. Thus, our theoretical model cau-
tions against the use of survival as a measure of perfor-
mance in empirical
studies, since the "survival
of the fit-
test," as this paper shows, cannot be assumed.
REFERENCES
Aiken, Leona S., and Stephen G.
West
1991 Multiple Regression: Testing
and Interpreting Interactions.
Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Alchian, Armen A.
1950 "Uncertainty, evolution and
economic theory." Journal of
Political Economy, 58: 21 1-
222.
Alchian, Armen A., and Harold
Demsetz
1972 "Production, information
costs, and economic organiza-
tion." American Economic Re-
view, 62: 777-795.
Aldrich, Howard E.
1990 "Using an ecological perspec-
tive to study organizational
founding rates." Entrepreneur-
ship Theory and Practice, 14:
7-24.
Aldrich, Howard E., and Ellen R.
Auster
1986 "Even dwarfs started small:
Liabilities of age and size and
their strategic implications." In
B. M. Staw and L. L. Cum-
mings (eds.), Research in Or-
ganizational Behavior, 8: 165-
198. Greenwich, CT: JAI
Press.
Aldrich, Howard E., Arne
Kalleberg, Peter Marsden, and
James Cassell
1989 "In pursuit of evidence: Sam-
pling procedures for locating
new businesses." Journal of
Business Venturing, 4: 367-
386.
Aldrich, Howard E., H. Rosen, and
W. Woodward
1987 "The impact of social net-
works on business foundings
and profit:
A longitudinal
study." In N. C. Churchill et al.
(eds.), Frontiers of Entrepre-
neurship Research:
154-168.
Wellesley, MA:
Babson Col-
lege.
Amburgey, Terry L., and
Hayagreeva Rao
1996 "Organizational
ecology: Past,
present, and future direc-
tions." Academy
of Manage-
ment Journal, 39: 1265-1286.
Aoki, Mashahiko
1984 The Co-operative Game
Theory of the Firm.
Oxford,
UK: Oxford
University
Press.
Bain, Joe Staten
1956 Barriers to New Competition.
Cambridge,
MA:
Harvard
Uni-
versity Press.
Barnard,
Chester I.
1938 The Functions of the Execu-
tive. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard
University
Press.
Barnett,
William P., Henrich
R.
Greve, and Douglas Y. Park
1994 "An
evolutionary model of
organizational performance."
Strategic
Management
Jour-
nal, 15 (Winter
Special Issue):
11-28.
Barron,
David N., Elizabeth
West,
and Michael T. Hannan
1994 "A time to grow and a time to
die: Growth and mortality
of
credit unions in New York
City,
1914-1990." American
Journal of Sociology, 100:
381-421.
Bates, Timothy
1985 "Entrepreneur human capital
endowments and minority
business viability." Journal of
Human Resources, 20: 540-
554.
1990 "Entrepreneur human capital
inputs and small business lon-
gevity." Review of Economics
and Statistics, 72: 551-559.
1995 "Self-employment entry
across industry groups." Jour-
nal of Business Venturing, 10:
143-1 56.
Baum, Joel A. C.
1996 "Organizational ecology." In
Stewart R. Clegg, Cynthia
Hardy, and Walter R. Nord
(eds.), Handbook of Organiza-
tion Studies: 77-114. Thou-
sand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Baum, Joel A. C., and Christine
Oliver
1991 "Institutional linkages and or-
ganizational mortality." Admin-
istrative Science Quarterly, 36:
187-218.
Becker, Gary S.
1975 Human Capital. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Birley, Sue
1984 "Finding the new firm." Pro-
ceedings of the Academy of
Management Meetings, 47:
64-68.
Blau, Judith R.
1984 Architects and Firms. Cam-
bridge, MA: MIT Press.
Borjas, George J.
1986 "The self-employment experi-
ence of immigrants." Journal
of Human Resources, 21:
485-506.
779/ASQ, December 1997
Bortnick, Steven M., and Michelle
Harrison Ports
1993 "Job search methods of the
unemployed, 1991." Monthly
Labor Review, 115: 33.
Brittain, Jack, and John Freeman
1986 "Births of U.S. semiconductor
firms." Paper presented at
Annual Meeting of the Acad-
emy of Management, Chi-
cago.
Bruderl, Josef, Peter
Preisendorfer, and Rolf Ziegler
1992 "Survival chances of newly
founded business organiza-
tions." American Sociological
Review, 57: 227-242.
Bruderl, Josef, and Rudolf
Schussler
1990 "Organizational mortality: The
liability of newness and ado-
lescence." Administrative Sci-
ence Quarterly, 35: 530-547.
Campbell, C. A.
1995 "An empirical test of a deci-
sion theory model for entre-
preneurial acts." Entrepre-
neurship and Regional
Development, 7: 95-103.
Carroll, Glenn R.
1985 "Concentration and specializa-
tion: Dynamics of niche width
in populations of organiza-
tions." American Journal of
Sociology, 90: 1262-1283.
1987 Publish and Perish. Green-
wich, CT: JAI Press.
Carroll, Glenn R., and Yangchung
Paul Huo
1986 "Organizational task and insti-
tutional environments in eco-
logical perspective: Findings
from the local newspaper in-
dustry." American Journal of
Sociology, 91: 838-873.
Carroll, Glenn R., and Elaine Mo-
sakowski
1987 "The career dynamics of self-
employment." Administrative
Science Quarterly, 32: 570-
589.
Caves, Richard E., and Michael E.
Porter
1976 "Barriers to exit." In Rabot T.
Masson and P. David Qualls
(eds.), Essays on Industrial
Organization in Honor of Joe
S. Bain: 39-69. Cambridge,
MA: Ballinger.
Cooper, Arnold C., F. Javier
Gimeno Gascon, and Carolyn Y.
Woo
1994 "Initial
human and financial
capital as predictors of new
venture performances." Jour-
nal of Business Venturing, 9:
371-395.
Cyert, Richard M., and James G.
March
1963 A Behavioral Theory of the
Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall.
Demsetz, Harold, and Kenneth
Lehn
1985 "The structure of corporate
ownership: Causes and con-
sequences." Journal of Politi-
cal Economy, 93: 1155-1177.
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W.
Powell
1983 "The iron cage revisited: Insti-
tutional isomorphism and col-
lective rationality in organiza-
tional fields." American
Sociological Review, 48: 147-
160.
Dixit, Avinash K., and Robert S.
Pindyck
1994 Investment Under Uncer-
tainty. Princeton, NJ: Prince-
ton University Press.
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M., and
Claudia Bird Schoonhoven
1990 "Organizational growth: Link-
ing founding team, strategy,
environment, and growth
among U.S. semiconductor
ventures, 1978-1988." Ad-
ministrative Science Quarterly,
35: 504-529.
Evans, David S., and Linda S.
Leighton
1989 "Some empirical aspects of
entrepreneurship." American
Economic Review, 79: 519-
535.
Evans, David S., and Boyan
Jovanovic
1989 "An estimated model of en-
trepreneurial choice under li-
quidity constraints." Journal of
Political Economy, 97: 808-
827.
Fichman, Mark, and Daniel A.
Levinthal
1991 "Honeymoons and the liability
of adolescence: A new per-
spective on duration depen-
dence in social and organiza-
tional relationships." Academy
of Management Review, 16:
442-468.
Freeman, John, Glenn R. Carroll,
and Michael T. Hannan
1983 "The liability
of newness: Age
dependence in organizational
death rates." American Socio-
logical Review, 48: 692-710.
Friedman, Milton
1953 Essays in Positive Economics.
Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Fuchs, Victor R.
1982 "Self-employment
and labor
force participation
of older
males." Journal
of Human
Resources, 17: 339-357.
Fujii,
Edwin T., and Clifford
B.
Hawley
1991 "Empirical
aspects of self-
employment."
Economic Let-
ters, 36: 323-329.
Ghemawat, Pankaj
1991 Commitment. New York:
Free
Press.
Greene, William H.
1990 Econometric
Analysis.
New
York:
Macmillan.
Guo, Guang
1993 "Event-history
analysis for
left-truncated data." In P.
Marsden
(ed.Y,
Sociological
Methodology,
23: 217-243.
Cambridge,
MA: Basil
Black-
well.
Hannan, Michael T., and John
Freeman
1977 "The
population
ecology of
organizations." American
Jour-
nal of Sociology, 82: 929-964.
1984 "Structural
inertia
and organi-
zational
change." American
Sociological
Review,
49: 149-
164.
Heckman, James J.
1979 "Sample
selection bias as a
specification error." Econo-
metrica,
47: 153-161.
Hirschman,
Albert 0.
1970 Exit,
Voice and Loyalty.
Cam-
bridge,
MA:
Harvard Univer-
sity Press.
Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos
Tversky
1979 "Prospect
theory:
An analysis
of decision under risk."
Econometrica,
47: 263-291.
Kalleberg,
Arne L., and Kevin T.
Leicht
1991 "Gender and organizational
performance:
Determinants of
small business survival and
success." Academy
of Man-
agement Journal,
34: 136-
161.
Jovanovic, Boyan
1982 "Selection
and the evolution
of industry."
Econometrica,
50: 649-670.
Lafuente,
Alberto, and Vicente
Salas
1989 "Types
of entrepreneurs
and
firms: The case of new Span-
ish firms."
Strategic
Manage-
ment Journal,
10: 17-30.
780/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
Lee, Thomas W., and Terence R.
Mitchell
1994 "An alternative approach: The
unfolding model of voluntary
employee turnover." Acad-
emy of Management Review,
19: 51-89.
Levinthal, Daniel A.
1991 "Random walks and organiza-
tional mortality." Administra-
tive Science Quarterly, 36:
397-420.
Maddala, G. S.
1983 Limited-Dependent and Quali-
tative Variables in Economet-
rics. Cambridge, UK: Cam-
bridge University Press.
March, James G.
1988 "Variable risk preferences and
adaptive aspirations." Journal
of Economic Behavior and Or-
ganization, 9: 5-24.
March, James G., and Zur Shapira
1992 "Variable risk preferences and
the focus of attention." Psy-
chological Review, 99: 172-
183.
Masten, Scott E., James W.
Meehan, Jr., and Edward A. Sny-
der
1991 "The costs of organization."
Journal of Law, Economics,
and Organization, 7: 1-25.
Mayer, Kurt B., and Sidney
Goldstein
1961 The First Two Years: Prob-
lems of Small Firm Growth
and Survival. Washington, DC:
Small Business Administra-
tion.
McDougall, Patricia P., Richard B.
Robinson, Jr., and Angelo S.
DeNisi
1992 "Modeling new venture per-
formance: An analysis of new
venture strategy, industry
structure, and venture origin."
Journal of Business Venturing,
7: 267-289.
Meyer, John W., and Brian Rowan
1977 "Institutionalized organiza-
tions: Formal structure as
myth and ceremony." Ameri-
can Journal of Sociology, 83:
340-363.
Meyer, Marshall W., and Lynne G.
Zucker
1989 Permanently Failing Organiza-
tions. Newbury Park, CA:
Sage.
Mincer, Jacob
1974 Schooling, Experience, and
Earnings. New York: National
Bureau of Economic Re-
search.
1986 "Wage changes in job
changes." Research in Labor
Economics, 8A: 171-197.
Miner, Anne S., Terry L.
Amburgey, and Timothy M.
Stearns
1990 "Interorganizational linkages
and population dynamics:
Buffering
and transformational
shields."
Administrative Sci-
ence Quarterly, 35: 689-713.
Mobley, William H.
1977 Employee
Turnover: Causes,
Consequences, and Control.
Reading, MA:
Addison-Wes-
ley.
Nelson, Forrest D.
1977 "Censored
regression models
with unobserved stochastic
censoring thresholds." Journal
of Econometrics,
6: 309-327.
Penrose, Edith Tilton
1952 "Biological
analogies in the
theory
of the firm." American
Economic
Review,
42: 804-
819.
Pfeffer, Jeffrey, and Gerald R.
Salancik
1978 The External
Control
of Orga-
nizations.
New York: Harper
and Row.
Porter, Michael E.
1976 "Please note location of near-
est exit: Exit barriers and plan-
ning."
California Management
Review, 19 (Winter):
21-33.
Preisendorfer, Peter, and Thomas
Voss
1990 "Organizational
mortality
of
small firms: The effects of
entrepreneurial
age and hu-
man capital."
Organization
Studies, 11: 107-129.
Ranger-Moore,
James
1991 "Bigger
may be better but is
older wiser? Age dependence
in organizational death rates."
Unpublished
manuscript,
De-
partment
of Sociology,
Univer-
sity of Arizona.
Romanelli, Elaine
1989 "Environments and strategies
of organization
start-up:
Ef-
fects on early
survival."
Ad-
ministrative Science Quarterly,
34: 369-387.
Ronstadt, Robert
1986 "Exit, stage left:
Why entre-
preneurs
end their
entrepre-
neurial careers before retire-
ment." Journal of Business
Venturing,
1: 323-338.
Sandberg, William R.
1986 New Venture
Performance:
The Role of Strategy
and In-
dustry
Structure.
Lexington,
MA: D. C. Heath.
Shapero, Albert, and Joseph
Giglierano
1982 "Exits and entries: A study in
yellow pages journalism." In
Karl
Vesper (ed.), Frontiers of
Entrepreneurial Research:
113-141. Wellesley, MA: Bab-
son College.
Shrieves, Linda
1995 "Middle-agers need savvy re-
sume for job hunt." Orlando
Sentinel, July 25.
Simon, Herbert A.
1945 Administrative Behavior. New
York: Free Press.
Small, Kenneth A., and Cheng
Hsaio
1985 "Multinomial logit specifica-
tion tests." International Eco-
nomic Review, 26: 619-627.
Smith, James P.
1980 Female Labor Supply: Theory
and Estimation. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Smith, Norman R., and John R.
Miner
1983 "Type of entrepreneur, type
of firm, and managerial moti-
vation: Implications for organi-
zational life cycle theory."
Strategic Management Jour-
nal, 4: 325-340.
Spence, A. Michael
1974 Market Signaling. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard
University Press.
Staw, Barry M.
1981 "The escalation of commit-
ment to a course of action."
Academy of Management Re-
view, 6: 577-587.
Stewart, Mark B.
1983 "On least squares estimation
when the dependent variable
is grouped." Review of Eco-
nomic Studies, 50: 737-753.
Stinchcombe, Arthur L.
1965 "Organizations and social
structure." In J. G. March
(ed.), Handbook of Organiza-
tions: 142-193. Chicago:
Rand-McNally.
Sutton, Robert I., and Barry M.
Staw
1995 "What theory is not." Admin-
istrative Science Quarterly, 40:
371-384.
U.S. Bureau of the Census
1996 Statistical Abstract of the
United States, 116th ed.
Washington, DC: U.S. Govern-
ment Printing Office.
781/ASQ, December 1997
U.S. Small Business Administra-
tion, Office of Advocacy
1994 Handbook of Small Business
Data, 1994 ed. Washington,
DC:
U.S. Government Printing
Office.
Williamson, Oliver E.
1991 "Strategizing,
economizing,
and economic organization."
Strategic
Management
Jour-
nal, 12: 75-94.
Winter, Sidney G., Jr.
1964 "Economic 'natural selection'
and the theory of the firm."
Yale Economic Essays, 4:
225-272.
APPENDIX A: Variable Definitions
Dependent variables Measure
Exitn 1 = firm discontinued; 0 = firm
survived.
Money taken outn Amount (in thousand $) of money (including
salary, draw, dividends, etc.) that
the entrepreneur was able to take out in the previous 12 months. The
variable is ordinal with 7 values: (1) under $1 OK, (2) $1 OK to $15K, (3) $15K
to
$25K, (4) $25K to $35K, (5) $35K to $50K, (6) $50K to $75K,
and (7) over
$75K.
Independent and control variables
Attainment
in work experience Highest level of management experience achieved by owner (multinomial
categorical variable). Supervisory experience
equals 1 if "supervised
others";
0 otherwise. Management experience
equals 1 if "supervised managers";
0
otherwise. Entrepreneurial experience equals 1 if "managed
own business";
0 otherwise. Reference group
is "supervised
no one."
Formal
education Percentage of observations
in sample with less formal education than
entrepreneur.
Similar
business Index of similarity between present business and previous organization
in (a)
products or services, (b) customers, and (c) suppliers (1 = very similar, 0 =
very different) (Cronbach alpha
= .8734).
Intrinsic motivation 1 = the entrepreneur's most important
goal in starting
a new venture
is to "let
you do the kind of work
you wanted to do" or "avoid working for others."
-1 = most important goal in starting
a new venture is to "make more money
than you would have otherwise" or "build
a successful organization."
0 = most important goal in starting a new venture is "other."
Parents owned business 1 = parents
owned a business; 0 = otherwise.
Age of entrepreneur Age of entrepreneur
at the time of first questionnaire.
Number of prior jobs Total number of full-time jobs prior
to venture. Transformed to multiple binary
variables measuring whether there were 1 prior
job, 2 prior
jobs, 3 or 4 prior
jobs, and 5 or more prior jobs. Reference group
is no prior jobs.
Hours worked Total
number
of hours
worked per week by the entrepreneur.
Outside
job 1 = entrepreneur
had a full-time
job outside the venture;
.5 = entrepreneur
had
a part-time
or irregular job outside the venture;
0 = entrepreneur
had no job
outside the venture.
Initial
capital (log) Natural
logarithm
of the amount
of capital (in
thousand
$) invested by the time
of first sale (ordinal,
8 brackets).
Number of employees (log) Natural
logarithm
of the number
of full-time and part-time (.5) employees
(including the owner) at the time of the first questionnaire.
Path
to ownership How entrepreneur became owner of present business (multinominal categorical
variable). Acquired business equals 1 if "purchased it";
0 otherwise. Inherited
business equals 1 if "inherited
it";
0 otherwise. Reference
group
is "started
it."
Radius of business sales Radius
of area in which 80% of customers are located.
Months
in business (log) Natural
logarithm
of the number
of months since business registered
its first
sale at the time of the first questionnaire.
Informational
ties Composite index of use and importance
of seven information sources: (a)
accountant, bookkeeper, (b)
friends or relatives, (c) other business owners,
(d) bankers, (e) trade organizations,
(f) lawyers, attorneys,
and (g) franchisers
or suppliers (1 = very important;
0 = not used) (Cronbach alpha
= .5849).
Industry Eight control variables
for nine different
industries, including construction,
manufacturing, transportation, wholesaling, agriculture, financial services,
personal services, professional services. Reference group is retail industry.
Environmental
dynamism Likert scale agreement with statement "My
business is changing rapidly" (2 =
strongly agree, -2 = strongly disagree).
Growth
in GSP Change
in Gross State Product
from 1985 to 1987 in the U.S. state where the
business is located.
Change
in competitors Expected change per year over next five years in number
of competitors:
Increase over 20% (=3), increase 11 %-20% (=2), increase 3%-1
0% (=1),
unchanged -3%-3% (=0), decrease (=-1).
782/ASQ, December 1997
Survival of the Fittest?
APPENDIX
B: Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Model
The likelihood function
represents the probability that a sample was ob-
tained
from a statistical model with given parameters.
By maximizing
the
logarithm of the likelihood function with respect to these parameters,
we
are able to obtain maximum likelihood
estimates of the coefficients in equa-
tions (6a)
and (6b).
For
a given observation
in
the sample,
we observe
exitn
(the
binary variable
representing exit),
money taken
out, (the
ordinal
variable
representing
the
range of economic
performance, only
observed
if exitn = 0), and
Xr
(the inde-
pendent
variables).
The relevant
parameters
of the model
are b1,
the coeffi-
cients of the independent
variables
on economic
performance, b2,
the coeffi-
cients of the independent
variables
on the threshold,
sl, the standard
deviation
of the disturbance
of the economic performance
equation
(e1),
which
is as-
sumed to be normally
distributed,
and s, the standard deviation of the differ-
ence of the disturbances
of the threshold
equation
and the economic
perfor-
mance, e2 - e1. A required assumption for the full identification of the model is
the assumption
that
e1 and e2 are independent
(Nelson, 1977).
The likelihood
function,
represented by L(b1,b2,s1,s
I exitn, money
taken
outn,Xn),
captures
the
probability
that some given
sample
values (exitn, money
taken
outn,Xn)
were
obtained if the parameter
values were b1, b2,
sj, and s.
For a given observation,
the probability
of observing
exit is:
Prob(exitn
= 1) = Prob(EP*
< T*)
= Prob(Ib1l Xi
+ e1 5 1b2i *
Xi
+ e2)
= Prob(e1 - e2 c (b2i - b1;) Xi
= (b2i - b1i) i),
where F(z) represents the normal cumulative
distribution
function.
For a given observation,
the probability
of observing
continuation
and obtain-
ing a value of k for money taken outn (which
means that the exact eco-
nomic performance
is between a known lower bound
Lk and a known upper
bound Uk)
is:
Prob
(exitn
= 0 and money taken outn = k)
= Prob
(T*
< EP* and
Lk < EP*
< Uk)
= Prob(Xb2i
*
Xi + e2 <
Xbli *
Xi
+ e1 and Lk < Xbli *
Xi
+ e1 < Uk)
= Prob(e2
- e1 < 1(b1 - b2i) *
Xi
and Lk - b1 Xi
< el < Uk - Xb1 (Xi)
= Prob(e2
- e1 < J(b1i
- b2i) *
X1
and el < Uk - Xb1,
j Xi)
- Prob(e2
- e1 <
X(b1
i - b2i) *
Xi
and el < Lk - Xb1
i *
Xi).
Each of the probabilities
in this equation
can be represented
as cumulative
distribution functions
of a standard
bivariate
normal, F2(z1,z2,r).
In
this case,
the first
variable
is z1 = (e2 - e1)/s, and the second is z2=(e1/sl),
while the
correlation of the variables
equals r=(-s1/s)
Thus, we can write Prob
(exitn
= 0 and money taken outn = k)
as
4(b
( -
Sb2i) Xi ),(Uk -bli Xi ) s )
- (( ( - b2i) i ),(Lk lbl i *Xi _ sl
The likelihood function
aggregates these probabilities
by multiplying
them
over all of the observations
in the sample. By taking
the logarithmic
transfor-
mation of this likelihood
function,
we then obtain the log-likelihood
function,
which can be written as:
InL(bj,b2,s1,s
I
exitn,
money taken
outn,
Xn)
1:I ( (b2i - blij) *
Xi
= , lnF(S " X'
exitn=1 /
~e~~c
ln[1U( (Y(bi i - b2j)
' Xi) (Uk- b1i' Xi )5)
carried out in two steps. First,
we use LIMDEP
7.0's grouped
data regres-
sion with sample selection procedure
to obtain
performance
and exit param-
eters, and from those we obtain
initial
estimates of b1, b2, s1, and s follow-
ing the procedure
outlined
by Maddala
(1983: 228-230). We then use those
initial
estimates for the maximization of the log-likelihood
function using a
Davidon-Fletcher-Powell
optimization
algorithm
(Greene, 1990), also available
in LIMDEP.
783/ASQ, December 1997
... Otros autores estudian la relación entre educación empresarial y "entrepreneurial performance" en términos de "ingreso empresarial", que se refiere al salario recibido por el propietario y los socios (Gimeno et al., 1997;Hamilton, 2000), y de "supervivencia de la empresa", que se refiere al tiempo de operación de la empresa (Elert, Andersson & Wennberg, 2015). Pero, en general, la literatura aborda el "entrepreneurial performance" desde variables como: retorno sobre la inversión, crecimiento en ventas, supervivencia de la empresa, crecimiento en activos, crecimiento en empleos, utilidad neta, ingreso neto, participación de mercado, valorización en el mercado ( Actualmente, la universidad cuenta con 141.256 metros cuadrados, ofrece ...
Book
Full-text available
This book includes a first chapter with a review of the literature, which is segmented as follows segmented as follows: education and entrepreneurial activity; education and intrapreneurial activity; and and intra-entrepreneurial activity; orientations about curricular and extracurricular curricular and extracurricular activities in entrepreneurial education; family business, education and family business, entrepreneurial and intrapreneurial education and activity; entrepreneurial performance and entrepreneurship education. The second chapter includes general information about the participating institutions and their actions their actions with respect to entrepreneurship education and entrepreneurship creation (Universidad Icesi, Universidad Sergio Arboleda and Red Reune). Subsequently, the third chapter discusses the methodology used for the study, including type of study and research design, population and sample, measurement instrument, field work procedure, description of curricular and extracurricular.
... The prior literature suggested that human capital possesses abilities and skills (that can be improved) that are the fundamental contributor to innovativeness (Becker, 1985). Gimeno et al. (1997) highlighted that human capital is said to be embodied in expertise, knowledge and skills with the capacity to work as a competitive edge for an organization because it is a significant benefactor of organizational innovativeness . Due to its nature and construction human capital improves the efficiency of an organization to achieve the desired level of innovativeness (Pennings et al., 1998). ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose Empowering leadership has a wide range of positive individual employee-related outcomes. However, a limited number of research studies are available emphasizing the overall organization-related outcomes. The major aim of this study is to delve into the function of organizational identification and intellectual capital (structural, relational and human) in mediating the relationship between empowering leadership and organizational innovativeness. Depending upon the resource-based view theory, this study comprehensively investigates the sequential effects of empowered leadership on the mediating roles of organizational identification and intellectual capital in organizational innovativeness. Design/methodology/approach Data were gathered through a self-administered questionnaire, which got 337 responses from telecom employees. To evaluate the hypotheses, the data were analyzed in SEM-M-Plus using exploratory and confirmatory factor analyses. Findings The findings demonstrate that empowering leadership impacts organizational innovativeness with the sequential mediation of organizational identification and intellectual capital (structural, human and social). Practical implications Organizations can identify and encourage leaders who exhibit empowering behaviors such as delegating responsibilities, providing autonomy and fostering a sense of ownership among employees. Also, organizations can foster intellectual capital by providing opportunities for learning, training and development. Additionally, knowledge sharing and collaboration can help to enhance the intellectual capital of employees. Originality/value While much research has been conducted on empowering leadership, the continued development of knowledge and the emergence of new perspectives related to identification and intellectual capital highlights the importance of exploring alternative paths that have been overlooked. Therefore, there is a pressing need to conduct research that takes into account these additional factors.
... Efficient human resource management enhances the quality of business operations [78][79][80][81] and boosts profits [82][83][84][85]. The educational background of employees plays a crucial role in human resources [86][87][88]. ...
Article
Full-text available
The Chinese government promulgated the National Nutrition Plan 2017–2030 to provide scientific guidance for agrifood consumption and enhance nutrition intake. We categorized the sample into pre-2018 and post-2018 periods. By evaluating the effects of the National Nutrition Plan 2017–2030 through economic theory and a translog revenue function model based on financial statement data from 2015 to 2022, our findings indicate that the National Nutrition Plan 2017–2030 has increased the overall agrifood sales of listed agrifood enterprises, but the increase in agrifood sales produced by large listed agrifood enterprises has been slight. Finally, we offer policy recommendations for regulatory authorities and develop strategies for agrifood firms to encourage local food procurement. This study also contributes to our understanding of China’s agrifood industry dynamics and underscores the significance of the National Nutrition Plan 2017–2030 in enhancing nutritional intake and fostering sustainable growth in China’s agriculture industry.
Article
Research summary Entrepreneurship research overlooks the dynamics of changing diversity in founding teams. Our simulations calibrated from existing studies suggest that founding teams that change diversity exhibit greater discounted performance for their ventures due to being less diverse and thus their ventures surviving longer, compared to teams that maintain their diversity. Moreover, discounted performance is higher for teams changing diversity due to other teams' performance than due to their own poor performance. Simulating without membership changes the interdependence between team diversity, venture performance, and team disruption, we find that while team diversity is overall performance‐enhancing, this association differs across contexts and its impact varies as ventures mature. Founding team diversity should thus be seen as a continuum where moderate diversity can best serve teams in turbulent environments. Managerial summary We simulated the behavior of founding teams over time to show that compared to teams that do not change their diversity, those who do experience greater discounted performance for their business ventures. This improvement stems from the increased longevity, and thus greater accumulated performance, for teams that switch since they are more rather than less homogeneous. Our investigation also indicates that ventures led by teams that change diversity because they aspire to outperform other teams, tend to exhibit greater discounted performance than those that change diversity to outperform themselves. When we investigate the interconnectedness of teams' diversity, ventures' performance, and disruption, albeit without allowing for any changes in team diversity, we find that while diversity usually helps, teams moderately diversified tend to perform best in turbulent times.
Thesis
Full-text available
This master's thesis explores the transformative potential of CryptOTC, an innovative platform that aims to enhance financial inclusion by linking paper money and cryptocurrency through both physic OTC (Over-The-Counter Trading) exchange offices and online channels. As the adoption and popularity of cryptocurrencies continue to grow, there is a pressing need to create seamless pathways between traditional forms of money and digital assets. CryptOTC addresses this need by establishing a network of offline vendors who facilitate secure and convenient exchanges between fiat currency and cryptocurrencies. This research investigates the feasibility, impact, and implications of CryptOTC's hybrid exchange network. It examines the challenges and opportunities associated with bridging fiat money and cryptocurrency, including regulatory compliance, security, customer adoption, and technological infrastructure. Through an in-depth analysis of existing models, case studies, and market trends, this thesis sheds light on the potential benefits and risks of such a platform. The study also explores the concept of financial accessibility and how CryptOTC's solution can contribute to overcoming barriers to entry for individuals seeking to participate in the cryptocurrency ecosystem. Furthermore, it investigates the impact of the hybrid exchange network on financial inclusion, as it provides individuals with offline access to cryptocurrencies without relying solely on digital platforms. By providing valuable insights and recommendations, this thesis aims to assist entrepreneurs, investors, policymakers, and industry stakeholders interested in leveraging hybrid exchange networks to bridge the gap between fiat money and cryptocurrency. The findings contribute to the ongoing discourse surrounding the integration of digital assets into the mainstream financial landscape and offer guidance on the strategic implementation of CryptOTC's innovative solution. Keywords: CryptOTC, fiat money, cryptocurrency, hybrid exchange networks, financial accessibility, regulatory compliance, OTC, customer adoption, financial inclusion.
Article
What influences the success of academic entrepreneurship? Drawing on the motivation theory, this study investigates the effects of entrepreneurial intrinsic and extrinsic motivations on entrepreneurial persistence and consequently academic entrepreneurship performance with the moderating roles of female entrepreneurs and innovation and entrepreneurship support institutions analyzed. To test these effects, we used hierarchical regression with data collected from 211 academic entrepreneurs at Chinese universities. We find that entrepreneurial intrinsic motivation increases (but extrinsic motivation decreases) entrepreneurial persistence, which also mediates their effects on the academic entrepreneurship performance. The positive relationship between entrepreneurial intrinsic motivation and entrepreneurial persistence is strengthened for female entrepreneurs. Innovation and entrepreneurship support institutions alleviates the negative effect of entrepreneurial extrinsic motivation on entrepreneurial persistence and enhances the positive effect of entrepreneurial persistence on academic entrepreneurship performance. This study contributes to the literature of academic entrepreneurship and motivation theory. Managers are advised to pay attention for these motivation aspects and the entrepreneurial persistence to bring academic entrepreneurship performance.
Article
Purpose The purpose of this study is to investigate the technology-focused and technology-supported dilemmas that firms have encountered and their digital orientation from a nuanced perspective to answer the following research questions: What digital orientations do companies take in launching digital initiatives? How does the choice between a proactive digital orientation (Pro-DO) and a reactive digital orientation (Rea-DO) influence firm value? Design/methodology/approach The authors adopted machine learning and a quantitative research approach using observations from China’s listed companies from 2010 to 2020 and applied statistical techniques and regression analysis to examine the effect of digital orientation alternatives on firm value. Findings The findings of this study indicate that firms with a Pro-DO exhibit a positive effect on firm value. In contrast, firms with a Rea-DO do not demonstrate the same positive relationship with firm value. Additionally, this study reveals that firms with better corporate governance practices and lower financing constraints are more responsive to the positive effects of Pro-DO on firm value. Originality/value We elucidate two primary perspectives of digital orientation: Pro-DO and Rea-DO. Additionally, we empirically showcase their nuanced influences on firm value, thereby enriching knowledge in the fields of strategic orientation and digital transformation. Moreover, our findings underscore the importance of corporate governance and financing constraints as moderators.
Article
Empirical investigations of decision making indicate that the level of individual or organizational risk taking is responsive to a risk taker's changing fortune. Several nonstationary random-walk models of risk taking are developed to describe this phenomenon. The models portray a risk taker's history as the cumulated realizations of a series of independent draws from a normal probability distribution of possible outcomes. This performance distribution is assumed to have an unchanging mean and a variance (risk) that changes
Article
This paper emanates from a study of the job generation effect of new firms in St. Joseph County, Indiana. It discusses the methodological problems associated with identifying the new firm and compares the results of a search from three sources, the County Unemployment ES202 Files, the Telephone Directory, and the Dun and Bradstreet Market Identifier Files (DMI). Significant differences emerge. If DMI is used, the basis of the Birch Report, 96% of the new firms found in ES202 would fail to be recorded. The paper concludes that the wide variations found suggest that the data base chosen can significantly affect the results of any study of new firms.
Article
This paper examines evidence concerning the existence of organizational buffers, which insulate an organization from environmental disturbances, and transformational shields, which insulate an organization from the risk of failure due to transformation. It proposes that interorganizational linkages in particular can (1) buffer organizations from failure, (2) affect the likelihood of organizational transformation, and (3) modify the effect of organizational transformation on failure. These propositions are examined using event-history analysis of data on approximately 1,000 Finnish newspapers over a 200-year period. In this population, linkages reduced failure, increased organizational transformations, and altered the chances for failure after transformation. More generally, the findings support the existence of organizational buffers and transformational shields, suggesting further work on their role in population dynamics.
Article
There are many instances in which individuals can become locked into a costly course of action. Because it is often possible for persons who have suffered a setback to recoup their losses through an even greater commitment of resources to the same course of action, a cycle of escalating commitment can be produced. In this paper, I review recent research on the escalation of commitment and try to integrate its complex and often conflicting determinants.