ArticlePDF Available

Corporate Crime, Law, and Social Control

Authors:
P1: FYX/FYX P2: FYX/UKS QC: FYX/UKS T1: FYX
CU073 CU073-FM July 25, 2002 6:22
Corporate Crime, Law,
and Social Control
Sally S. Simpson
University of Maryland
v
P1: FYX/FYX P2: FYX/UKS QC: FYX/UKS T1: FYX
CU073 CU073-FM July 25, 2002 6:22
PUBLISHED BY THE PRESS SYNDICATE OF THE UNIVERSITY OF CAMBRIDGE
The Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge, United Kingdom
CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS
The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge CB2 2RU, UK
40 West 20th Street, New York, NY 10011-4211, USA
477 Williamstown Road, Port Melbourne, VIC 3207, Australia
Ruiz de Alarc´on 13, 28014 Madrid, Spain
Dock House, The Waterfront, Cape Town 8001, South Africa
http://www.cambridge.org
C
Sally S. Simpson 2002
This book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without
the written permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2002
Printed in the United States of America
Typeface New Baskerville 10/13 pt. System L
A
T
EX2
ε[TB]
A catalog record for this book is available from the British Library.
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication data
Simpson, Sally S.
Corporate crime, law, and social control / Sally S. Simpson.
p. cm. (Cambridge studies in criminology)
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 0-521-58083-8 ISBN 0-521-58933-9 (pb.)
1. Corporations Corrupt practices. 2. Commercial crimes.
3. Commercial crimes Prevention. I. Title. II. Cambridge studies in
criminology (New York, N.Y.)
HV6768 .S56 2001
364.168dc21 2001025804
ISBN 0 521 58083 8 hardback
ISBN 0 521 58933 9 paperback
vi
P1: FYX/FYX P2: FYX/UKS QC: FYX/UKS T1: FYX
CU073 CU073-FM July 25, 2002 6:22
Contents
Preface page ix
1Criminalizing the Corporate Control Process 1
Denitions 6
Criminalization of Corporate Crime in the Post-Watergate Era 10
The Facts of Criminalization 16
Conclusions 20
2Deterrence in Review 22
Rationality and Crime 22
Empirical Support for Deterrence 26
Conclusions 42
3Assessing the Failure of Corporate Deterrence
and Criminal Justice 45
Criminal Law and the Corporation 45
Criminal Law and Corporate Managers 56
Conclusions 60
4Corporate Deterrence and Civil Justice 61
Civil Law and Corporate Offending 61
Can Civil Law Deter Corporate Crime? 73
Conclusions 78
5Corporate Deterrence and Regulatory Justice 79
Business Regulation in the United States 80
The Deterrent Capacity of Administrative Law 84
vii
P1: FYX/FYX P2: FYX/UKS QC: FYX/UKS T1: FYX
CU073 CU073-FM July 25, 2002 6:22
viii CONTENTS
Punishment or Persuasion 94
Conclusions 97
6Cooperative Models of Corporate Compliance:
Alternatives to Criminalization 98
Enforced Self-Regulation 100
Informal Social Control 106
Enforcement Pyramid 112
Tit-for-Tat Regulatory Philosophy 112
Conclusions 115
7Criminalization versus Cooperation: An Empirical Test 116
Study One 117
Study Two 139
Conclusions 151
8Shaping the Contours of Control 153
The Failure of StrictDeterrence 153
Policy Challenges 155
Future Directions for Compliance Research 160
Appendix A Study One: Questionnaire Items and Responses 163
Appendix B Study One: Sample Characteristics 169
Appendix C Study Two: Questionnaire Items and Responses 170
Appendix D Study Two: Sample Characteristics 173
Name Index 174
Subject Index 176
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
CHAPTER ONE
Criminalizing the Corporate Control Process
The modern tendency of the courts ...has been widening the scope within
which criminal proceedings can be brought against institutions which have
become so prominent a feature of everyday affairs, and the point is being
reached where what is called for is a comprehensive statement of principles
formulated to meet the needs of modern life in granting the fullest possible
protection of criminal law to persons exposed to the action of the many
powerful associations which surround them.1
images of crime in the United States at the end of the twentieth century
increasingly coupled the illegal practices of business executives with those
of America’s underclass. These mirror images of crime and criminals have
had real consequences for how crime is understood and responded to in
our society today. Crime in the suites and on the streets has been indelibly
linked in the public mind. It has not always been so.
Neither street nor business crime is a new social problem. In fact, quite
the opposite is true. Illicit drugs and the violence they spawn have con-
cerned moral entrepreneurs and policy makers in this country for the bet-
ter part of this century;2legislative attempts to curb the market powers of
“robber baron” industrialists stimulated antitrust laws over a century ago.3
1Russell on Crime, 12th ed., ed. F. W. Cecil Turner, vol. 1 (London: Stevens Publishing, 1964),
pp. 96–97.
2See, for instance, James Inciardi, The War on Drugs: Heroin, Cocaine, Crime, and Public Policy
(Palo Alto, Calif.: Mayfield, 1986); Joseph Gusfield, Symbolic Crusade (Urbana: University of
Illinois, 1963); Howard S. Becker, Outsiders (New York: Free Press, 1963); and Troy Duster,
The Legislation of Morality (New York: Free Press, 1970).
3Corporations, until the early 1900s, were rarely subjected to criminal law. Strict liability
was the preferred legal means to pursue acts of corporate malfeasance (William S. Laufer,
1
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
2CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
Historically, however, these populations of criminals were seen as distinct.
For the most part, drug addiction (including alcohol) and violence were
deemed problems for ethnics (Mexican, Chinese, Italian, Irish, and blacks)
and immigrants (predominantly Catholic working class). The realcrime
problem was thought to rest with the constitutionally inferior and morally
lax. Corporate criminals, on the other hand, were drawn from Americas
newly emerging capitalist Brahmins. Although perceived to be opportunis-
tic and ruthless in their business practices, these entrepreneurs were part of
the governing and newly emerging social elite. Consequently, popular def-
initions of and legal responses to crime and criminals were framed within
divergent ideological and social-control orbits. Conventional crime was dealt
with punitively, but corporate misbehavior was handled through adminis-
trative agencies or relatively lenient criminal statutes.4
Today, however, there is substantial overlap between conventional and
white-collar crime control. Since the 1960s politicians and the general pub-
lic have come to believe that the crime problem is pervasive and out of
control. Citizens are bombarded with messages that create and reinforce
this interpretation as media, politicians, and crime specialists document
the illegal activities of business and street criminals. The crack-cocaine epi-
demic of the 1980s coupled with sensationalist reports of drug and school
violence, rapes, robberies, and grisly serial murders comprises a large part of
the cultural image of Americas crime problem. But white-collar cases involv-
ing Michael Milken, Lincoln Savings and Loan, Archer Daniels Midland
even congressional leaders such as Dan Rostenkowski and former president
Clinton have contributed increasingly to this conception.
Public opinion polls show that over the past two decades white-collar
crimes have attained greater signicance in the mind of the populace. For
instance, on a ranking scale where 1 is the most serious, the mean seri-
ousness ranking of corporate and other white-collar offenses by the public
was 91.75 in an 1972 study. This average shrunk to 79.71 in another survey
Corporate Bodies and Guilty Minds,Emory Law Journal 43 [1994]: 647730). The Sherman
Act and Clayton Antitrust Act were passed into law in 1890 and 1914 respectively. There is
some disagreement as to whether the legislation was truly populist or reected the interests of
the capitalist class; see Frank Pearce, Crimes of the Powerful (London: Pluto, 1976); and Gabriel
Kolko, The Triumph of Conservatism (New York: Free Press, 1963).
4To be clear, corporate sanctions often include a criminal component. However, research
demonstrates that civil and administrative remedies have been the preferred method of pur-
suing corporate violators. For instance, between 1890 and 1969, the ratio of civil to criminal
cases brought by the Department of Justice in the antitrust area is 1.23:1 (Richard Posner,
A Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement,Journal of Law and Economics 13 [1970]: 385).
See also Marshall B. Clinard and Peter C. Yeager, Corporate Crime (New York: Free Press, 1980).
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 3
conducted in 1979. Public ranking of the most serious corporate act, sell-
ing contaminated food that results in a death, decreased from a rank of
twenty-sixth in 1972 to thirteenth in 1979.5A survey conducted in 1984
found that environmental crime was ranked seventh, after murder, but
ahead of heroin smuggling.6The perceived severity of environmental
crimes by the general public has remained high in the 1990s, according to re-
sults from a survey commissioned by Arthur D. Little. When asked to evaluate
how seriously authorities should respond to four types of corporate crime,
84 percent of respondents perceived environmental damage to be a serious
crime, with three out of four believing that executive ofcers ought to be
held personally accountable (liable) for such offenses.7In contrast, 74 per-
cent of respondents ranked worker health and safety crimes to be serious,
60 percent felt that price xing was a serious offense, and less than half
(40 percent) held similar beliefs about insider trading.
Data from other Western nations also support the view that the general
public is growing intolerant of certain types of white-collar crime. In Great
Britain, for instance, respondents in a 1985 survey ranked murder with a
weapon as the most serious offense but ranked fth an example of mail-
order fraud in which the offender set up a bogus mail-order company and
fraudulently obtained £1,000 from private individuals.8Similarly, repli-
cation of the crime seriousness surveys in Brisbane, Australia, suggests that
greater media attention for the past twenty years has produced respondents
who view white-collar offenses to be more serious than their U.S. counter-
parts. The mean seriousness score for the Brisbane sample again with 1
being the most seriousranking was 74.23. This average is considerably
lower than what the rst U.S. survey found (91.75) and 5 points lower than
the 1979 surveys average (79.71).9
Finally, the public may be more reactive toward corporate than non-
corporate offenders. In their vignette survey, Miller, Rossi, and Simpson
5Peter H. Rossi, Emily Waite, Christina E. Bose, and Richard E. Berk, The Seriousness of
Crimes: Normative Structure and Individual Differences,American Sociological Review 39
(1974): 224237; Francis T. Cullen, Bruce G. Link, and Craig W. Polznai, The Seriousness
of Crime Revisited,Criminology 20 (1982): 83102.
6U.S. Department of Justice, Bureau of Justice Statistics Bulletin, January 1984, cited in Frederick
W. AllisonIII and Elizabeth E. Mack, Creating an Environmental Ethic in Corporate America:
The Big Stick of Jail Time,Southwestern Law Journal 44 (1991): 1429.
7The Corporate Board, SeptemberOctober 1991, 2425.
8Michael Levi and S. Jones, Public and Police Perceptions of Crime Seriousness in England
and Wales,British Journal of Criminology 25 (1985): 234250.
9Robert C. Holland, Public Perceptions of White Collar Crime Seriousness: A Survey of an
Australian Sample,International Journal of Comparative and Applied Criminal Justice 19 (1995):
91105.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
4CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
show that respondents prefer more severe sanctions when either the crime
victim, or the criminal offender is a corporation, and not an individual.10
However, punitive attitudes vary by the degree of harm and the culpability
of the act.11 Surveys of business executives and criminal justice authorities
also show similar variations in perceptions of white-collar crime seriousness
and appropriate punishment.12 Benson and Cullen, for instance, found
that local prosecutorsperceptions of the corporate crime problem were a
function of community characteristics. Local prosecutors in more populous
jurisdictions, compared with those in suburban or rural areas, were more
apt to regard corporate crime as a very or somewhat serious problem.13
Although Benson and Cullen are unable to determine, based on their cross-
sectional data, whether prosecutors perceptions have changed over time,
they cautiously interpret their data as suggestive that prosecutors become
more concerned with corporate crime during their tenure in ofce. Specif-
ically, prosecutors report that prosecutions have increased and that even
more prosecutions are anticipated in the future.14
The criminal justice system is now playing a larger role in the war against
corporate crime. Champions of this position claim that the criminal process
offers a greater deterrent for corporations and managers than other control
mechanisms.15 But the shift of criminal justice to center stage raises impor-
tant questions about the capacity of criminal law to prevent and control
corporate illegality.
The goal of this book is to address, in detail, some of these concerns. A
key premise of this investigation is that the criminal justice system will fail as
a primary mechanism of corporate crime control, even though criminal law
10 Joann L. Miller, Peter H. Rossi, and Jon E. Simpson, Felony Punishments: A Factorial
Survey of Perceived Justice in Criminal Sentencing,Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology
82 (1991): 396415.
11 Laura Schrager and James F. Short, How Serious a Crime? Perceptions of Common and
Organizational Crimes,in Gil Geis and Ezra Stotland (eds.), White-Collar Crime: Theory
and Research (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1980), pp. 1431; James Frank, Francis T. Cullen,
Lawrence F. Travis III, and John L. Borntrager, Sanctioning Corporate Crime: How Do
Business Executives and the Public Compare?American Journal of Criminal Justice 13 (1989):
139169.
12 Studies are reported and summarized in Michael Levi, Regulating Fraud (New York: Tavistock,
1987), pp. 6970 and 136144.
13 Michael L. Benson and Francis T. Cullen, Combatting Corporate Crime: Local Prosecutors at Work
(Boston: Northeastern University Press, 1998), p. 51.
14 Ibid.
15 John Braithwaite, The Limits of Economism in Controlling Harmful Corporate Conduct,
Law and Society Review 16 (19811982): 481504; John Braithwaite and Gilbert Geis, On
Theory and Action for Corporate Crime Control,Crime and Delinquency 28 (1982): 292314;
Francis T. Cullen and Paula J. Dubeck, The Myth of Corporate Immunity to Deterrence,
Federal Probation 49 (1985): 39.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 5
offers the harshest formal sanction threat to corporate managers (and some
claim the greatest deterrent) namely, incarceration. The position against
the use of criminal law to control corporate misconduct is, by no means,
unique or unprecedented. In fact, more than two decades ago, Christopher
Stone argued:
Those who trust to the law to bind corporations have failed to take into
account a whole host of reasons why the threat of legal sanction is apt to lack
the desired effects when corporate behavior is its target for example, limited
liability, the lack of congruence between the incentives of top executives and
the incentives of the corporation,the organizations proclivity to buffer
itself against external, especially legal threats, and so on.16
Stone asserts that the law will fail because it lacks the necessary exibility
to adjust to and permeate dynamic business organizations. While sympa-
thetic to Stones point, my view of criminal law is informed from a deter-
rence framework, a perspective that has been optimistically embraced by
proponents of a punitive corporate control model but one that lacks sup-
portive empirical evidence. To borrow a phrase from law professor John
Coffee, if such assertions could be cited as evidence, the case [for de-
terrence] ...would be strong indeed. In general, however, little is cited
in support of this contention beyond anecdotal experiences and personal
beliefs.17
Making a similar point, Charles Moore claims that the prospects for
corporate deterrence are bleak because arguments in favor of corporate
deterrence are founded on unrealistic views of the corporate actor and
overly optimistic views of the legal systems capacity to control corporate
behavior.18 Moores critique deals exclusively with the problems associated
with deterring the corporate entity via criminal law (his position on deter-
rence is summarized in the third chapter of this book). The position I ad-
vance is that deterrence is unlikely for both the corporation and its ofcers
16 Christopher D. Stone, Where the Law Ends (New York: Harper and Row, 1975), p. 93. See also
John Braithwaite and Brent Fisse, Self-Regulation and the Control of Corporate Crime
(pp. 194220), and Michael Clarke, Prosecutorial and Administrative Strategies to Control
Business Crimes(pp. 247265), both in Clifford D. Shearing and Philip C. Stenning (eds.),
Private Policing (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1987).
17 John Collins Coffee Jr. Corporate Crime and Punishment: A Non-Chicago View of the
Economics of Criminal Sanctions,American Criminal Law Review 17 (1980): 425. In making
his point, Coffee was contrasting the deterrent value of nes with imprisonment and noting
that commentators explicitly claim that only the latter can deter the businessman. Given the
paucity of empirical evidence on the deterrent effects of any legal sanction brought against
arm or a manager, his words are equally apt here.
18 Charles A. Moore, Taming the Giant Corporation? Some Cautionary Remarks on the
Deterrability of Corporate Crime,Crime and Delinquency 33 (1987): 379402.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
6CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
or managers. Punitiveness, as a strategy for corporate crime control, is not
well grounded in the empirical literature and, in fact, is somewhat anti-
thetical to the limited amount of research that has been conducted in this
area. Research by Diane Vaughan, for instance, explicitly challenges the
rational-choice foundation upon which corporate deterrence rests.19
For most corporate crime scholars, especially those of us who understand
corporate crime as an abuse of power by capital,20 an antideterrence posi-
tion is an ironic one to assume21 but one informed by both theory and
scientic evidence. To lay the groundwork for the arguments and evidence
against deterrence, we rst need to identify the kinds of acts that corpora-
tions and their managers commit that are subject to criminal sanction and
the characteristics that make these acts distinct from other kinds of crimes.
Ironically, many of the uncommon features of corporate crime contribute
to the belief that it is amenable to deterrence. Yet these same attributes sug-
gest that corporate crime control will be more successfully achieved through
processes other than the application of criminal sanctions to violators.
Second, it makes little sense to argue that criminalization is a awed policy
unless it can be demonstrated that a trend toward criminalization actually
is occurring. Thus, the latter part of this chapter is devoted to substanti-
ating this position while attempting to explain why this change is happen-
ing now.
Definitions
What Is Corporate Crime?
Corporate crime is a type of white-collar crime. Edwin Sutherland intro-
duced the latter concept to describe criminal activity by persons of high
social status and respectability who use their occupational position as a
means to violate the law.22 As a subcategory of white-collar crime, corporate
crime has been dened in many ways. Perhaps the simplest denition is that
offered by Braithwaite: corporate crime is the conduct of a corporation, or
19 Diane Vaughan, The Challenger Launch Decision: Risky Technology, Culture, and Deviance at NASA
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); Diane Vaughan, Rational Choice, Situated
Action, and the Social Control of Organizations,Law and Society Review 32 (1998): 2361.
20 See, e.g., Frank Pearce and Laureen Snider, Regulating Capitalism,in F. Pearce and L.
Snider, Corporate Crime: Contemporary Debates (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1985),
pp. 1947.
21 For a position counter to mine, see Laureen Snider, The Corporate Counter-Revolution
and the Disappearance of Corporate Crime(paper presented at the annual meeting of the
American Society of Criminology, Washington, D.C., 1998).
22 Edwin Sutherland, White-Collar Crime (New York: Dryden Press, 1949).
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 7
of employees acting on behalf of a corporation, which is proscribed and
punishable by law.23
Three key ideas are captured in this denition. First, by not speci-
fying the kind of law that proscribes and punishes, Braithwaite accepts
Sutherlands argument that illegality by corporations and their agents
differs from the criminal behavior of the lower socio-economic class prin-
cipally in the administrative procedures which are used in dealing with
the offenders.24 Thus, corporate crime not only includes acts in viola-
tion of criminal law, but civil and administrative violations as well. Second,
both corporations (as legal persons) and their representatives are rec-
ognized as illegal actors. Which or whether each is selected as a sanc-
tion target will depend on the kind of act committed, rules and quality
of evidence, prosecutory preference, and offending history, among other
factors.
Finally, Braithwaitesdenition species the underlying motivation for
corporate offending: on the whole, illegality is not pursued for individ-
ual benets but rather for organizational ends. Thus, in order to main-
tain prots, manage an uncertain market, lower company costs, or put a
rival out of business, corporations may pollute the environment, engage
in nancial frauds and manipulations, x prices, create and maintain haz-
ardous work conditions, knowingly produce unsafe products, and so forth.
Managersdecisions to commit such acts (or to order or tacitly support oth-
ers doing so) may be supported by operational norms and organizational
subcultures.25
Perceptions of organizational needs have been empirically shown to in-
uence the corporate offending decision. Strains and pressures associated
with decline and growth are linked to corporate illegality.26 Interviews with
middle and top managers at a steel manufacturing company conducted by
this author, for instance, reveal how managers confront different realities
under conditions of municence and scarcity. In his description of how
23 John Braithwaite, Corporate Crime in the Pharmaceutical Industry (London: Routledge and
Kegan Paul, 1984), p. 6.
24 Sutherland, White-Collar Crime,p.9.
25 James W. Coleman, The Criminal Elite (New York: St. Martins Press, 1989).
26 Marshall B. Clinard and Peter C. Yeager, Corporate Crime (New York: Free Press, 1980);
Katherine M Jamieson, The Organization of Corporate Crime (Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage,
1994); Melissa S. Buucus and J. P. Near, Can Illegal Corporate Behavior Be Predicted?
An Event History Analysis,Academy Management Journal 34 (1991): 936; Sally S. Simpson,
The Decomposition of Antitrust,American Sociological Review 51 (1986): 859879; Barry M.
Staw and Eugene Swajkowski, The Scarcity Municence Component of Organizational En-
vironments and the Commission of Illegal Acts,Administrative Science Quarterly 20 (1975):
345354.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
8CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
health and safety violations might occur, one manager said:
There are no purists in a survival mode. ... as soon as youre on the threshold
[of economic constraints], then all of the shortcuts come out of the woodwork
and we give them titles like entrepreneur of risk,”“risk analysis.We give
them all kinds of fancy things to accommodate and legitimize the decision
process.27
Such decisions have little to do with an individual employees personal
needs but a lot to do with organizational contingencies, priorities, and needs.
In contrast, embezzlement another type of white-collar crime occurs
when persons accept a position of trust within an organization but, by steal-
ing from it, violate the nancial trust placed in them.28 Both this act and
the conditions just described resulting in health and safety violations occur
within a work setting. Each falls within the parameters of Sutherlands orig-
inal denition. The difference between them lies in motivation and victim.
Unlike corporate crime, embezzlement is motivated by an individuals needs
(e.g., his or her debt, family considerations, perception of an unsharable
problem, greed, revenge).29 The primary victim of embezzlement is the rm
itself.30 Corporate crime, on the other hand, counts many victims, among
them employees, other companies, the government, the environment, and
consumers; however, because the act is undertaken in the pursuit of orga-
nizational goals, the company itself is not directly victimized.
Corporate offending occurs within an organizational context. This fact
sets it apart from most other kinds of illegality. The organization com-
prises hierarchical, diverse, and often highly specialized positions. Work
is autonomous, but it is also interactive and team-dependent. Organizations
themselves are complex entities. Large corporations are divisible into sub-
sidiaries; subunits such as sales and marketing, production, and nance; and
smaller task groups. Like the organization as a whole, these units develop
27 Sally S. Simpson, Corporate Crime Deterrence and Corporate Control Policies: Views
from the Inside,in Kip Schlegal and David Weisburd (eds.), White-Collar Crime Reconsid-
ered (Boston: Northeastern University Press, 1992), pp. 296297.
28 Donald Cressey, Other People’s Money (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1953), p. 12.
29 Donald R. Cressey, Other People’s Money: A Study in the Social Psychology of Embezzlement (1953;
reprint, Montclair,N.J.: Patterson Smith, 1973); Dorothy Zeitz, Women Who Embezzle or Defraud:
A Study of Convicted Felons (New York: Praeger, 1981); Kathleen Daly, Gender and Varieties
of White-Collar Crime,Criminology 27 (1989): 769794.
30 Certain types of white-collar crime, such as the recent savings-and-loan frauds, share ele-
ments of both embezzlement and corporate crime. Calvita and Pontell describe situations
of collective embezzlementin which bank ofcers use institutional resources to enrich
themselves at the expense of the bank, depositors, and the general public. See Kitty Calavita
and Henry N. Pontell, “‘Other Peoples MoneyRevisited: Collective Embezzlement in the
Savings and Loan and Insurance Industries,Social Problems 38 (1991): 94112.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 9
cultures and subcultures. It is here that most managers are socialized into
organizational goals and subgoals. Here, too, employees learn the appro-
priate means and unique opportunities to achieve dened objectives and to
respond to pressures including criminal options. To understand corporate
crime and to determine whether it is amenable to deterrence, one needs
to examine how managers experience and express the moral imperatives of
their work environment and how organizational needs are formulated and
inculcated into managerial decisions.31
What Is Deterrence?
The idea of deterrence has its roots in utilitarian philosophy where individu-
als are seen as rational, pleasure-seeking, and self-interested. In accordance
with hedonistic principles, individuals will maximize pleasurable experi-
ences and avoid painful ones.32 The traditional deterrence model assumes
that fear of legal sanctions keeps persons law-abiding.33 To the extent that
formal punishment risk and consequence are assessed to be greater than the
benets of the criminal act, legality will prevail. The greater the certainty,
severity, and celerity of punishment, the greater the putative deterrent ef-
fects for both offending individuals (specic deterrence) and the general
public (general deterrence).
Deterrence theory emphasizes the formal legal system as the essential
element in the crime inhibition process. Thus, fear of detection, arrest,
and punishment resulting from conviction forms the core of a deterrence
model.34 For deterrence theorists, there is a straightforward answer to the
question, Why do corporations obey the law? They do so because the threat
of criminal sanctions is salient to the organization and its key managers.
Yet managers and corporations may be inhibited from misconduct by other
kinds of fears. For instance, threats to reputation, current or future em-
ployment, access to competitive resources (e.g., bids, contracts), friendship
networks or associations, and family attachments can curb illegal conduct
independent of legal sanctions. Managers and employees may not contem-
plate criminality because of moral habituation or a strong belief in the
morality of the law. Traditional deterrence neglects these kinds of controls,
31 Robert Jackall, Moral Mazes: The World of Corporate Managers (New York: Oxford University
Press, 1988).
32 Jeremy Bentham, An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation, ed. Laurence J.
Laeur (New York: Hafner, 1948).
33 Jack Gibbs, Crime, Punishment, and Deterrence (New York: Elsevier, 1975).
34 Johannes Andenaes, Punishment and Deterrence (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press,
1974).
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
10 CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
which are arguably more important in corporate crime control (as they are
in conventional crime control) for the majority of offenders. More than two
centuries ago, Jeremy Bentham noted that punishment is unnecessary when
other kinds of controls or interventions are successful.35 Later in this work, I
assert that greater enforcement effort should be centered on such informal
controls and interventions.
Criminalization of Corporate Crime
in the Post-Watergate Era
Aget tough on crimerhetoric for criminals of all types is currently in vogue.
On a practical level, this position has translated into mandatory and longer
sentences for some kinds of offenders (e.g., drug offenders, recidivists,
weapons offenses), a preference for prison time over less punitive alterna-
tives, three-strikes legislation, and a return to the death penalty with some
advocates suggesting expansion of the circumstances under which a death
sentence can be imposed (e.g., former president Bushs push to make drug
trafcking a capital crime). For corporate offenders, it has meant more crim-
inal instead of civil or regulatory cases brought against them; a push toward
sentencing parity between white-collar and street criminals; and an increase
in maximum penalty levels for a variety of organizational offenses (e.g., the
Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988; Major Fraud
Act of 1988; Money Laundering Control Act of 1986; Sherman Act).36
The punitive model of corporate crime control has support from both
sides of the ideological spectrum. The reasoning behind this conuence,
however, differs from side to side.37 Several interpretations are offered to
account for this punitive shift.
The Fairness Issue
The perceived inadequacies of the criminal justice process are at least par-
tially responsible for both conservatives and radicals supporting a harsher
35 Bentham, Introduction.
36 Ilene H. Nagel and Winthrop M. Swenson, The Federal Sentencing Guidelines for Corpo-
rations: Their Development, Theoretical Underpinnings, and Some Thoughts about Their
Future,Washington University Law Quarterly 71 (1993): 224225.
37 Zimring and Hawkins have commented on how political ideology affects conservative and
liberal images of crime causation. I extend their perspective to images of corporate crime
control. Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon Hawkins, Ideology and Euphoria in Crime
Control,University of Toledo Law Review 10 (1979): 370388. In a similar vein, the authors
analyze the savings-and-loan crisis. See Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon Hawkins, Crime,
Justice, and the Savings and Loan Crisis,in Michael Tonry and Albert J. Reiss Jr. (eds.),
Beyond the Law: Crime in Complex Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993),
pp. 247292.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 11
response to corporate crime. In direct contradiction to democratic princi-
ples, research indicates that justice has not been blind. Studies have found
that race, gender, and social class affect who will be charged, and how they
will be processed and punished.38 For conservatives, illicit bias in the crim-
inal justice process represents a potential threat to social order. It disputes
the ideology that all are equal before the law and that the state is neutral
in how the law is applied. Disclosures of that bias undermined the laws
neutrality and thus challenged its legitimacy.39
A policy of punitiveness toward corporate offenders is supported by rad-
icals as a means to curb corporate power and to achieve equity in criminal
justice sentencing. If poor minorities are going to be sent to prison, so too
should corporate offenders who are primarily white and middle or upper
class.40 Corporate power and inuence has, for too long, allowed violators
to manipulate the law, escape detection, negate harsh sentencing, or avoid
criminal processing. In his review of corporate criminalization, Sethi sug-
gests that it is not coincidental that the trend toward harsher penalties for
corporate executives has occurred at a time that business credibility in
the public eye is extraordinarily lowand political power elites have been
challenged by persons formerly disenfranchised.41
Paradoxically, the left has taken a criminalization position even though it
rejects punitiveness as an approach to conventional crime. In a recent book,
Michael Levi chastises advocates of more punitive responses to white-collar
criminals:
One suspects that many white-collar crime writers who utilize seriousness
survey ndings to call for tougher policing and sentencing of white-collar
criminalswould be very much less happy to embrace public support for
38 John Hagan, Extra-Legal Attributes and Criminal Sentencing,Law and Society Review 8
(1974): 357383; John Hagan, Structural Criminology (New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University
Press, 1989); Kathleen Daly, Gender, Crime, and Punishment (New Haven: Yale University
Press, 1995); Michael Tonry, Malign Neglect Race, Crime, and Punishment in America (New
York: Oxford University Press, 1995); Ilene Nagel, The Legal/Extra-Legal Controversy,
Law and Society Review 17 (1993): 481515; Victoria L. Swigert and Ronald A. Farrell, Normal
Homicides and the Law,American Sociological Review 12 (1977): 96102. See David Weisburd,
Stanton Wheeler, Elin Waring, and Nancy Bode, Crimes of the Middle Classes (New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1991), and Theodore Chiracos and Gordon Waldo, Socioeconomic Status
and Criminal Sentencing,American Sociological Review 40 (1975): 753772, for alternative
ndings.
39 Francis T. Cullen, William J. Maakestad, and Gray Cavender, Corporate Crime under Attack:The
Ford Pinto Case and Beyond (Cincinnati: Anderson, 1987), p. 13.
40 Research by Kathleen Daly demonstrates that this generalized image of white-collar criminal
demographics appears to be more true for males than for female offenders. See Daly,Gender
and Varieties of White-Collar Crime,Criminology 27 (1989): 769793.
41 S. Prakash Sethi, Liability without Fault? The Corporate Executive as an Unwitting
Criminal,Employee Relations Law Journal 4 (1978): 208.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
12 CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
corporal or capital punishment for offenders coming from more deprived
backgrounds. So the cry of Vox Populi Supreme Lex can turn out to be a hydra-
headed monster, and those academics who are captivated by the notion that
white-collar crime is high on the gravity list should beware of worshipping
false and powerful gods.42
The proportionality and equity issues in the criminal justice response to
white-collar or corporate versus conventional offenders have led to a push
to eliminate or minimize disparities in the justice process.43 As part of this
effort, criminal laws have been rewritten or expanded so that white-collar
offenses carry penalties similar to those of conventional crimes. For instance,
former New York governor Cuomo pushed to redene the seriousness of
white-collar crime in New York State by contrasting the street thief (a person
who threatens violence to steal a wallet) with the one in the three-piece suit
who defrauds millions by manipulating a ledger.44
Further, statutes originally intended to ease prosecution of orga-
nized crime are now used with some success against corporate criminals
(e.g., the Racketeering Inuenced and Corrupt Organizations Act). Perhaps
the most famous use of RICO against a corporate offender was the pursuit
and prosecution of Michael Milken, Wall Streets junk bond king, on se-
curities fraud charges. On November 21, 1990, Milken was sentenced to
ten years in prison for his participation in securities fraud, market manip-
ulation, and tax fraud.45 The threat of a RICO prosecution led Milkens
employer, Drexel Burnham Lambert, to plead guilty to six felony counts of
mail and wire fraud and securities fraud and to agree to major changes
42 Levi, Regulating Fraud, pp. 7475.
43 Disparities clearly still exist. Tillman and Pontells comparison of medicaid and grand theft
cases in California shows greater leniency in the former at least at early sentencing phases.
In terms of time served, the white-collar offenders did not differ from their lower-class
counterparts (Robert Tillman and Henry N. Pontell, Is Justice Collar-Blind?: Punishing
Medicaid Provider Fraud,Criminology 30 [1992]: 547574). Johnson also explores the ques-
tion of whether adjudication and sentencing of white-collar and common offenders have
become more equitableover a three-decade period. He compares aggregate sentencing
data for corporate, white-collar, and common crime from the U.S. district courts, scal
years 1964, 1974, and 1984 and discovers that although white-collar and corporate offend-
ers are being brought to the courts more often and sentences appear to be harsher over
time, offenders are still receiving more lenient sentences than common property offenders.
Kirk A. Johnson, Federal Court Processing of Corporate, White Collar, and Common Crime
Economic Offenders over the Past Three Decades,Mid-American Review of Sociology 11 (1986):
2544.
44 Isabel Wilkerson, Cuomo Asks New White-Collar Crime Terms,New York Times, February
2, 1986.
45 Steve Coll and David A. Vise, On the Trail of Ivan and Mike,Washington Post Magazine,
September 29, 1991, p. 30.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 13
in its organizational structure and oversight procedures.46 Although there
are movements to limit both the criminal and civil provisions of RICO,
prosecutors have used the law successfully against a variety of white-collar
or corporate offenses (especially in false advertising through mail or wire
fraud and securities cases).47
In addition to these changes, the criminal justice system, at least at the fed-
eral level, is dramatically changing the process through which organizations
are sanctioned for violations of criminal law. In 1991 Congress passed into
law newly recommended guidelines for organizational sanctioning from
the U.S. Sentencing Commission.48 Responding to the belief that criminal
organizations are sanctioned leniently and inconsistently, the commission
recommended sentencing guidelines based, in part, on an optimal penal-
ties approach. Optimal penalties specify that the sentencing process take
into account the costs (or harm) associated with the illegal act and efforts to
prevent, detect, and punish crime. This approach, at least theoretically, can
impose extremely costly economic sanctions on the offending corporation.
There can be little doubt that the Organizational Guidelines taken as a
whole greatly increase the potential sanctions for corporate misconduct in-
cluding mandatory retribution, punitive nes capable of rising to hundreds
of millions of dollars, and invasive probationary conditions.49 These penal-
ties are justied by the sentencing objectives of deterrence, proportionality,
public protection, and restitution to victims.
The Relative Seriousness Issue
Proponents of more punitive approaches toward corporate offenders often
argue that illegal acts by companies are more costly, both in terms of hu-
man lives and economically, than conventional crime.50 Data drawn from
46 Laurie P. Cohen, Riding It Out: Fred Joseph Emerges Unscathed after Deal by Drexel and
SEC,Wall Street Journal, April 17, 1989, p. A1; Mary Zey, Reform of RICO: Legal versus
Social Embeddedness Explanations(unpublished manuscript, Department of Sociology,
University of Wisconsin, Madison, 1991).
47 Kay P. Kindred and Ronald R. Sims, The Regulators Perspective on Corporate Fraud,in
Margaret P. Spence and Ronald R. Sims (eds.), Corporate Misconduct (Westport, Conn.:
Quorum Books, 1995), p. 88.
48 U.S. Sentencing Commission, Guidelines Manual (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Print-
ing Ofce, 1991), chap. 8.
49 Evelyn E. C. Queen, Corporate Sentencing Guidelines,in Margaret P. Spencer and Ronald
R. Sims (eds.), Corporate Misconduct (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books, 1995), p. 58.
50 For a critique of the lefts embrace of white-collar crime and the tendency to ignore or
simplify the crime issue, see Nicole Hahn Rafter, Left Out by the Left: Crime and Crime
Control,Socialist Review 16 (1986): 723.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
14 CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
178 corporate offenders in federal courts during the mid-1980s show
that the average monetary harm per offense committed was $565,000.51
In contrast, the average loss per burglary and per larceny during this time
period was $1,000 and $400 respectively.52 Moreover, a single decision to pro-
duce an unsafe product can maim or kill thousands of victims. Homicides
in the United States hover around 22,000 persons per year, a number that
is about one-fth the number of persons who die on a yearly basis from
diseases and injuries related to work.53 When deaths and injuries due to
unsafe products, environmental hazards, and other illegal corporate acts
are added to the equation, corporate crime is perhaps the most dangerous
and consequential kind of crime that occurs in our society.
The Economic Crisis Issue
Scapegoating also has played a role in the push for harsher criminal sanc-
tions against both conventional and corporate offenders. Minorities (partic-
ularly African Americans) are blamed for the loss of working-class jobs
and economic security (via quota systems) for whites. At the same time,
blacks are portrayed as our most dangerous criminals.54 Corporate poli-
cies, such as debt nancing and investment in junk bonds, have resulted in
economic crises in some businesses and banking. Yet, despite bankruptcies
and bailouts, CEOs and other top managers continue to earn multimillion
dollar salaries and benets or golden parachutes as their rms lose money,
are taken over, or go bankrupt. At General Dynamics, for instance, while
the work force was being cut by 18,000 in 1991, 23 top executives received
$35 million in salary, bonuses, and stock options. This was three times the
amount they had earned the prior year.55 The savings-and-loan asco of
the 1980s, in which thousands of victims and the general public directly
or through bailouts lost billions of dollars due to unlawful risk taking and
looting by bank executives, has contributed to the image of the proteering
51 Mark A. Cohen, Corporate Crime and Punishment: A Study of Social Harm and Sentencing
Practice in the Federal Courts, 19841987,American Criminal Law Review 26 (1989): 605660.
52 Federal Bureau of Investigation, Uniform Crime Reports for the United States (Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Government Printing Ofce, 1988).
53 Mark Green and John F. Berry, White-Collar Crime Is Big Business,Nation, June 8, 1985,
p. 707.
54 Sentencing disparities between blacks and whites convicted of cocaine possession and traf-
cking illustrate the white majority concerns over dangerousness. See Michael Tonry, Malign
Neglect: Race, Crime, and Punishment in America (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995).
55 David A. Vise and Steve Coll, The Two Faces of Greed,Washington Post Magazine, September
29, 1991, pp. 1331; Elizabeth Holtzman, When Management Falls Down on the Job,
Washington Post, May 26, 1992, sec. A.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
THE CORPORATE CONTROL PROCESS 15
CEO and the powerless diffuse victim.56 As reported in 1996, AT&T cut its
work force by 40,000 at the same time that CEO Robert E. Allen received
a pay package of $16 million. Richard Cohen observes, The issue is not
whether Allen deserved the package, but whether it was seemly for him to
have taken it.57
Conservative politicians have recognized the power of race-based politics
(Willie Horton was so effectively linked to Michael Dukakis that Republican
pundits called him Dukakissrunning mate) and have exploited white
working- and middle-class fear of blacks. The left manages the politics of
class by building on working- and lower-class resentment of upper-class
privilege.58 Fear and resentment breed punitive responses toward members
of those social groups held responsible for various societal ills. Sutherland
was an early observer of this phenomenon:59 Fear and resentment de-
velop ...principally as the result of an accumulation of crimes, as depicted
in crime rates or in general descriptions. Such resentment develops under
those circumstances both as to white collar crimes and other crimes.
Governmental Mistrust Issue
Jack Katz has suggested that a social movement against white-collar crime
emerged after the Watergate scandal at a time when the presidency lost its
considerable ability to protect lesser power centers from moral attack.60
Consequently, those usually immune from scrutiny, such as government
and business elites, found themselves illuminated by the public spotlight
and under political and legal attack.61 An essential part of this attack has
56 For a discussion of the savings-and-loan cases, see Kitty Calavita and Henry N. Pontell, “‘Heads
I Win, Tails You Lose: Deregulation, Crime and Crisis in the Savings and Loan Industry,
Crime and Delinquency 36 (1990): 309341; Calavita and Pontell, “‘Other Peoples Money
Revisited; and Calavita and Pontell, Thrift Fraud as Organized Crime,Criminology 31
(1993): 519548.
57 Richard Cohen, Lifestyles of the Rich and Shameless,Washington Post, April 18, 1996,
p. A25.
58 See, for instance, Amitai Etzioni, Going Soft on Corporate Crime,Miami Herald, April 15,
1990; Mark Muro, What Punishment Fits a Corporate Crime?Boston Globe, May 7, 1989;
Philip Shenon, The Case of the Criminal Corporation,New York Times, January 15, 1989.
59 Sutherland, White-Collar Crime, p. 46.
60 Jack Katz, The Social Movement against White-Collar Crime,in Egon Bittner and Sheldon
Messinger (eds.), Criminology Review Yearbook, vol. 2 (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1980), p. 178.
61 Ibid., pp. 166171; Cullen et al., Corporate Crime under Attack. Academics are not immune to
these forces. Vaughan (The Challenger Launch Decision), for instance, reected on her initial
inclination to dene and comprehend the disastrous Challenger launch as an instance of
intentional immoral wrongdoing. A careful consideration of the evidence, however, revealed
a more complicated picture of how deviance came to be normalized in organizational policies
and procedures including safety regulations.
P1: UFA
CU073 CU073-01 July 25, 2002 6:21
16 CORPORATE CRIME, LAW, AND SOCIAL CONTROL
involved the use of criminal law (historically the social control tool of choice
against the disenfranchised) against business and government criminals.
Cases studies of the Ford Pinto criminal prosecution and the Imperial Food
Products manslaughter convictions seem to suggest that local prosecutors
are the key actors in socially constructing corporate violence as lawlessness,
setting precedents (legally and otherwise) for criminalization.62
This phenomenon was, by no means, restricted to the United States. In
his review of the rise and fall of the fraud issue in the Netherlands, Brant
ironically observes:
Far from dening the black, the poor, the long-haired hippy, the working
class, the lumpenprolitariate, the lunatic fringe or any other traditional and
easily available scapegoat of capitalism as a threat to societal values, ...the
fraud panic at its height was about the pillars of Dutch society....the way of
coping most frequently resorted to was criminal law.63
Whether the social movement against white-collar crime has had any long-
term institutional effects is debatable. In the United States, Katz saw signs of
its demise during the Carter administration.64 In the Netherlands, after an
expansion of criminal law into all areas of white-collar and corporate crime
during the 1980s, Brant claims that the 1990s saw a reversal in the cycle.65
Others claim that post-Watergate effects on the sentencing of white-collar
offenders have been mixed. More white-collar criminals may have gone to
prison, but for less time than comparable (and less educated) conventional
offenders.66 One fact, however, is indisputable. Criminal law is utilized in
corporate crime cases more than ever before.
The Facts of Criminalization
Prior to 1982, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) relied primarily
on civil penalties to discipline environmental law violators.67 This fact is not
surprising given that the agency did not have any criminal investigators on
62 John P. Wright, Francis T. Cullen, and Michael B. Blankenship, The Social Construction
of Corporate Violence: Media Coverage of the Imperial Food Products Fire,Crime and
Delinquency 41 (1995): 33; Cullen et al., Corporate Crime under Attack.
63 C. Brant, The Systems Rigged or Is It?Crime, Law and Social Change 21 (1995): 105.
64 Katz, Social Movement,p. 178.
65 Brant, The Systems Rigged.
66 John Hagan and Alberto Palloni, “‘Club Fedand the Sentencing of White-Collar Offend-
ers before and after Watergate,Criminology 24 (1986): 603621; Johnson, Federal Court
Processing.
67 Frederick W. Addison III and Elizabeth E. Mack, Creating an Environmental Ethic in
Corporate America: The Big Stick of Jail Time,Southwestern Law Journal 44 (1991): 1427
1448.
... Corporate crime is defined as a white -collar crime (Simpson, 2002) the organizational crime where the individuals inside the corporations or others that act as business entity commit frauds and violate the laws of the environment (Slapper, 1999). In simplest way it was defined by Braithwaite it is the "conduct of a corporation or of employees acting on behalf of a corporation which proscribed and punishable by law" (Simpson, 2002, p. 6). ...
... Even from a pessimistic standpoint, the mandatory CSR regulations direct a symbolic note to their companies that they care regarding society. All in all, it very well may be just political green washing (Simpson, 2002). Organizations are progressively creating overarching sets of principles, climate, wellbeing, and security norms, best practices rules, and socially cognizant projects in a bid to turn out to be all the more socially mindful. ...
Article
Full-text available
Corporate Crime is a relatively new term associated with Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR). The instant study tries to explain corporate crimes in nexus to CSR. It debates what international legal framework prohibits such crimes and how corporations commit violations of such international standards, any deviation from the standard may result in serious damage to society thus affect millions of lives e.g., the growing trend of child labor under hazardous conditions by a corporation. Through increased monitoring on child labor, innocent children can be saved from the havoc of child labor even reaching the level of slavery in some regions. This would help to reduce the number of children having hazardous workplace situation being unfairly compensated for their work.
... "Responsive regulation, as an approach, is used for describing and prescribing how regulator enforcement action best promotes compliance through the Planning Authorities" [18]. "It proposes that in order to be effective, efficient and legitimate, regulatory policy should take neither a solely deterrent nor a solely cooperative approach" (Grasmick and Bursik 1990; [19]; Shover & Hochstetler 2006; [20]. "Responsive regulation proposes a principled way in which to combine the insights from plural theories of compliance and enforcement using planning authorities, including those that propose people comply only when they perceive it to be for their benefit and those that see people complying for normative or social reasons" (Tyler 2006; [19]; Shover & Hochstetler 2006). ...
... "It proposes that in order to be effective, efficient and legitimate, regulatory policy should take neither a solely deterrent nor a solely cooperative approach" (Grasmick and Bursik 1990; [19]; Shover & Hochstetler 2006; [20]. "Responsive regulation proposes a principled way in which to combine the insights from plural theories of compliance and enforcement using planning authorities, including those that propose people comply only when they perceive it to be for their benefit and those that see people complying for normative or social reasons" (Tyler 2006; [19]; Shover & Hochstetler 2006). According to [21] "planning regulations and laws have four distinctive features in their procedure and principles and they form the basis upon which the laws are applied and implemented". ...
Article
In many cities around the globe, humans have shown disdain and neglect to physical planning laws. The consequence is the social and environmental challenges that residents experience therein. This study examines the factors that affect planning laws compliance in the capital cities in the south-south geopolitical region, of Nigeria. The cross-sectional research approach was used. Data for the study were sourced from primary and secondary sources. Copies of the questionnaire were administered to all the 522 practicing town planners in the study area who constituted the study population but only 414 of them responded. Descriptive statistics was deployed in analyzing the data. The study found that corruption ranks first with a mean score of 3.77 followed by customs and traditions which score 3.63. It is also revealed by the study that political interference, weak enforcement of planning laws, and awareness of existing planning laws with mean scores of 3.42, and 3.25 respectively are also constraints to compliance with planning laws. The study, therefore, recommends that agencies of government saddled with the responsibility of enforcing planning regulations and laws should strictly enforce the extant planning laws so that residents will be forced to comply with the planning laws. It is also recommended that urban planners should not allow native laws and customs to interfere with urban planning regulations.
... It also focuses on testing different theoretical propositions on causal links and mechanisms between suggested factors of note and behavior and perceptions, but this may lead to superficial analysis of observable events only, insufficiently engaging with the "real" unobservable structures that generate these. Due to their ontological essence, positivist approaches can investigate both actual and potential compliance-relevant behavior as, for example, when surveys are employed to capture the extent of (non)compliance with particular regulations (e.g., Winter & May, 2001;Kelly, 2010) or when experimental methods are employed to capture potential behavior in a hypothetical scenario (e.g., Simpson, 2002;van Rooij et al., 2017). However, these approaches often neglect a reflexive appreciation of how our observations are theory-dependent, and this has implications for the production of adequate knowledge. ...
Chapter
Compliance, or the behavioral response to legal rules, has become an important topic for academics and practitioners. A large body of work exists that describes different influences on business compliance, but a fundamental challenge remains: how to measure compliance or noncompliance behavior itself? Without proper measurement, it's impossible to evaluate existing management and regulatory enforcement practices. Measuring Compliance provides the first comprehensive overview of different approaches that are or could be used to measure compliance by business organizations. The book addresses the strengths and weaknesses of various methods and offers both academics and practitioners guidance on which measures are best for different purposes. In addition to understanding the importance of measuring compliance and its potential negative effects in a variety of contexts, readers will learn how to collect data to answer different questions in the compliance domain, and how to offer suggestions for improving compliance measurement.
... One of the greatest challenges to the exercise of social control over harmful corporate behaviour is the cultivation of consistent and commensurate legal instruments, enforced through well-resourced and politically supported regulatory agencies (Laufer 2008;Simpson 2002;Braithwaite 2020;Clinard and Yeager 2001;Siegel et al. 2020). This is particularly the case for Brazil. ...
Article
Full-text available
Since the beginning of Jair Bolsonaro´s presidential mandate, existing Brazilian environmental regulations started being rolled back to benefit a small, but powerful, Brazilian bourgeoise, the so-called “Brazilian agribusiness.” The process of deregulation in Brazil (regulatory rollback) is responsible for significant environmental and social harm, which affects largely marginalized peoples and indigenous communities in the Brazilian Amazon rainforest. It is also responsible for operating, and maintaining, dynamics of social inclusion and exclusion which are deepening the democratic deficit in Brazil, which is here denominated as the “mechanisms of environmental victimization.” To demonstrate the Brazilian regulatory rollback the authors analyse legislative and regulatory amendments since the beginning of Jair Bolsonaro´s mandate. Through this analysis, the authors seek to demonstrate how the symbiosis between state and corporate interests can promote significant social and environmental victimization.
Article
Full-text available
In recent years, the Indonesian government has suffered a huge loss of state assets due to the misbehavior of corporations in financial management because the Indonesian legal system does not have a specific regulation to address corporate financial crime. When a corporate financial crime case arises, Indonesian law enforcement approaches this crime using the Anti-Corruption Act. However, the aim to retrieve the stolen government assets purloined by a corporation using the Anti-Corruption Act is still insufficient, therefore, other related regulations such as the Money Laundering Act have to apply as an additional instrument to realize optimal recovery from the misbehaving corporation. Because the long process involved in criminal and civil courts it is sometimes a waste of the law enforcement effort and the funds expended to get paid back from offenders and/or corporations because the money received is much lower than the money lost or even zero. To bridge the gap between the money lost initially and the repayment money, because of the lack of special legal regulation concerning corporate financial crime, this research intends to study the possibility of using a “disgorgement of profits” approach as a faster way to get the maximum repayment of stolen money/assets from instances of corporate financial crime in out-of-court settlements.
Book
Full-text available
Sociology of law is a sub o-discipline of sociology. However, some thinkers consider it part of legal studies, while others believe it is between the disciplines of law and sociology. And some others consider it as neither part of sociology nor law but a part of social sciecne tradition. This book, titled “Sociology of Law,” explores the various concepts necessary to understand law and society. This has been divided into eight chapters.
Article
The protection of victims that has occurred so far has always been state intervention by using the principles of police power or the relevant legal apparatus. The increasing suffering experienced by victims in a society can cause unrest and the victims of certain weak groups may meet their needs unnaturally and cause further losses and chaos. In this case the consumer isn’t the only White Collar Crime in this consumptive society. With many illegal habits that are carried out by the corporation. In this case, it becomes a study in research in the context of victim protection, because victims are surrounded by powers of power so that it will easily lead to victimization. With the existence of victims as a result of victimization from the work of the bureaucracy, as a result of the bureaucracy that may lead to victimization of a person or group, this has an influence on society at large. The perpetrators of corporate crimes are the target of focused attention in creating the current regulations, considering specific penalties. Targeted products are gradually attracting the attention of product designers and lawmakers who recognize that crime-free product design may predate many crimes. In the context of repeated victimization, the structural constraints are real and serious, and that this research can look at how context shapes and influences victim behavior routines. The research method used is a qualitative approach adapted to the needs of the research, namely obtaining in-depth explanations and information regarding efforts to protect victims of corporate crime. The plan in the research of research informants is the main key to explain problems that can result in victims. The object of this research is the Project X Corporation.
Article
Full-text available
O presente artigo investiga as categorias centrais da omissão penalmente relevante à luz da responsabilidade do agente especialista, detentor de conhecimentos especiais. Trata-se de uma temática já bastante explorada pelo Direito penal, em suas diferentes correntes, mas que carece ainda de melhores justificativas quanto a sua legitimidade, particularmente em umcenário cada vez mais complexo de responsabilidades compartilhadas dentro de empresas. Para tanto, utiliza-se do estudo de caso, apoiado ao método tópico, observando a narrativa apresentada pelo Ministério Público de Minas Gerais em relação aos crimes praticados especificamente pela equipe técnica matricial da empresa Vale, que levaram ao rompimento da barragem do córrego do Feijão. O artigo se encontra dividido em três partes, a saber: a) a análise do dever agir do especialista; b) a análise do poder agir dentro de estruturas empresariais; c) o ambiente corporativo para tomada de decisões e sua ilegitimidade para decisões de interesse público. Ao final, o artigo apresenta contribuições críticas à teoria do delito, desde uma ótica normativista, para repensar os mecanismos de atribuição de responsabilidade, bem como a insuficiência do Direito penal frente ao modelo regulatório atual.
Article
This article addresses the issue of renewing a sense of vocation in finance. Drawing on experiences in the UK, Australia, and Ireland, three common law jurisdictions at various phases of developing “an ethical esprit de corps” to professionalize the banking industry, it argues that adopting some aspects of a profession, a “trajectory towards professionalization” of the banking industry, could serve, at least to some extent, to improve the industry‐wide norms that influence firms' cultures and individual behaviors. It contends that professionalization could help to develop bankers with a professional, pro‐social identity, in which there is a recognition of broader obligations to society, that exists independently of the profit‐driven nature of banking and the hierarchy of their own firms. This analysis is informed by an integration of regulatory theory, which casts doubt on the utility of sanctions except as a last resort, behavioral science, which offers insights into how ethics and culture, not just law and markets, can constrain irresponsible behavior in the financial services sector, and criminological theory, which emphasizes that particular types of controls, including individual attachments to groups, build “stakes in conformity” which encourage law abiding and responsible behaviors.
Article
Recent developments in routine activities theory have sought to conceptualize the notion of capable guardianship, as well as to broaden the application of the theory to the corporate crime context. Building on this work with systematically collected qualitative data, we examine the mechanisms in which offenders commit corporate financial fraud and identify the failures in guardianship. In addition to the unique dimensions of corporate crime already identified (i.e., specialized access to targets), our work highlights the need to consider guardian–offender overlap, or instances in which those tasked with guardianship responsibilities become motivated offenders. Our findings suggest financial regulations focusing on adding layers of guardians may be insufficient. They also have broader implications for understanding guardian capability in other forms of crime—namely, the need to consider the costs and benefits of intervention, willingness and ability to intervene in differing contexts, and how these dimensions of guardianship shape offender risk perceptions.
Article
This article reviews briefly the uses and abuses of seriousess surveys and them examines the crime seriousness ratings and rankings of representative samples of the police and public from one Northern and one Southern police force area in England and Wales. It concludes that there is high concordance (both among the public and between police and public) on offences such as violence and theft by a policc officer, but more disagreement on the rating of frauds, burglary, and "victimless crimes". The police understate the absolute and relative seriousness of business fraud offences, probably because of their occupational culture. Few significant differences appear between offenders and non-offenders or between victims and non-victims. Finally, the policy implications are discussed.
Article
Economism is seen as having a number of disadvantages compared with legalism as the preferred model for regulating hazardous industrial practices such as pollution. Economism forces public policy to react retrospectively to hazards when efforts could be made to prevent the hazard before it occurs. Economism engenders a moral relativism which weakens the moral force of law; it makes detection and deterrence more difficult than under legalism. The regulatory approaches of economism may involve reduced cost burdens on business but lesser predictability of those costs. Economism does not relieve business of the burdens of government inspections; it simply replaces technical inspectors with tax investigators because taxes on hazards can easily be evaded. Legalism, unlike economism, is not wedded to the assumption that business enterprises always behave rationally. In practical terms it is impossible to calculate economically optimal levels of taxes on social harm. Even if it were possible, the costs of making such calculations would be prohibitive. It is concluded that economistic strategies have quite limited, though important, roles in business regulation.
Article
Although investigative reports have contributed to the social movement against white-collar crime, few studies assess the extent to which the media socially construct corporate violence as a “crime.” We examine this issue through a content analysis of newspaper coverage of the fire-related deaths of 25 workers at the Imperial Food Products chicken-processing plant, which resulted in the company's owner pleading guilty to manslaughter. The analysis revealed that newspaper reports largely attributed the deaths to the lax enforcement of safety regulations but did not initially construct the deaths as a crime or subsequently publicize the criminal convictions.
Article
Based on a national survey and interviews, this article describes the attitudes and practices of local prosecutors regarding corporate crime. Although most local prosecutors did not regard corporate crime as a serious problem, their willingness to prosecute increases if an offense causes substantial harm and other agencies fail to act. Despite repeated calls for coordinated responses to corporate crime, relatively few local prosecutors participate in interagency control networks. Those in control networks, however, conducted more prosecutions and expressed greater concern over corporate crime. The commitment of organizational resources and resulting career opportunities thereby created may explain differences between network and nonnetwork districts.