ArticlePDF Available

Childcare Subsidies, Wages, and Employment of Single Mothers

Authors:

Abstract

This paper develops and estimates a model for the choice of part-time and full-time employment and the decision to pay for childcare among single mothers. The results indicate that a lower childcare price and a higher full-time wage rate both lead to an increase in overall employment and the use of paid childcare. The part-time wage effects are found to be too small to have significant behavioral implications. An analysis of cost-effectiveness indicates that the additional hours of work generated per dollar of government expenditure is larger for a childcare subsidy than a wage subsidy.
CHILD CARE SUBSIDIES, WAGES, AND
EMPLOYMENT OF SINGLE MOTHERS
Erdal Tekin*
May 2002
Department of Economics
Andrew Young School of Policy Studies
Georgia State University
University Plaza
Atlanta, GA 30303-3083
Phone: (404) 651-3968
Email: tekin@gsu.edu
* I thank Wilbert van der Klaauw, Naci Mocan, Tom Mroz, Paula Stephan, Helen
Tauchen, and especially David Blau for their helpful comments and suggestions. I also
benefited from the comments of seminar participants at University of North Carolina at
Chapel Hill, Tulane University, Georgia State University, Urban Institute, Research
Triangle Institute (RTI), and the Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Germany. I
gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the Child Care Bureau and the
Georges Lurcy Foundation. All errors are mine.
CHILD CARE SUBSIDIES, WAGES, AND EMPLOYMENT OF
SINGLE MOTHETRS
Abstract
This paper provides a comprehensive analysis of employment and child care payment
decisions of single mothers in the early post-welfare reform environment, using data from
the National Survey of America’s Families (NSAF). I develop and estimate a model that
examines the effects of the price of child care and the wage rate on employment decision
as well as the decision to use paid child care among single mothers. The model
distinguishes between the full-time and part-time employment decisions as well as the
prevailing wages in these two employment markets. A semi-parametric random effects
estimator and the Gaussian Quadrature are used together to estimate the system of
equations for the discrete outcomes of full-time and part-time employment, and child care
payment, and the linear equations of the price of child care, and part-time and full-time
wages in a unified framework. The econometric model also controls for the endogeneity
of child care subsidy receipt and adjusts the hourly price of child care for the amount of
subsidy for mothers who receive one. The results show that full-time working mothers
are more sensitive to the price of child care than part-time working mothers. A lower
price of child care leads to increases in overall employment and the use of paid child
care. However, much of the increase in employment is in the form of full-time
employment. An increase in the full-time wage rate leads to increases in overall
employment and the use of paid child care. The effects of full-time wage rate are
estimated to be much larger than those of the price of child care. Part-time wage effects
are found to be so small to have significant implications.
I. Introduction
The 1996 Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act
(PRWORA), commonly known as the welfare reform legislation, marks a cornerstone in
the U.S. welfare policy. The primary goals of the PRWORA were to increase
employment and reduce welfare dependence among economically disadvantaged
population. In order to facilitate the transition from welfare to employment and help low-
income families maintain economic self-sufficiency, the new law streamlined the child
care assistance system by consolidating four main child care subsidy programs into a
single block grant, the Child Care Development Fund (CCDF), and increased child care
funding substantially.1 Under the new law, states were given unprecedented flexibility to
design and conduct their own child care assistance programs. As part of this general
flexibility, states were given permission to transfer up to 30 percent of their Temporary
Assistance to Needy Families (TANF) funds into the CCDF, and to spend additional
TANF funds directly for child care assistance. 2 These changes have placed child care at
the center stage of the welfare reform debate as policymakers view child care subsidies as
an important tool for the success of welfare reform. Five years after the enactment of
welfare reform, the public and congressional attentions are now focused on the
reauthorization of welfare reform, and child care remains one of the most important items
in the reauthorization agenda.
The objective of this paper is to use data from the early post-welfare reform
period to examine the effects of the price of child care and wages on part-time and full-
1 The main reason for consolidating the four funding streams was to eliminate the fragmentation and help
create a “seamless” system, which would be easier for families to access and for administrators to manage.
See Blau (2000) and Blau and Tekin (2001) for reviews of the child care system under welfare reform.
2In 1999, states spent all of their CCDF allotment of 6 billion dollars and transferred another 4 billion
dollars from TANF into CCDF.
1
time employment decisions, as well as the decision to use paid child care among single
mothers. Despite the increased public and legislative attentions on child care, there are
still gaps in our knowledge regarding the responses of single mothers to the price of child
care, the wage rate, and child care subsidies. It is of important policy relevance to
provide insights into the effects of the price of child care on employment behavior
because child care costs are often considered as a significant barrier to the labor force
involvement of low income mothers. Although it has been well documented in the
literature that the cost of child care serves as a deterrent to the employment of mothers,
most of this literature pertains to married mothers and the evidence on single mothers is
less conclusive. This study focuses on single mothers because they are the main target
group for welfare reform.3 Single mothers also constitute an increasingly large portion of
all mothers with young children.4 Furthermore, the labor force participation rate for
single mothers has risen dramatically over the past two decades, from 52 percent in 1980
to 74 percent in 2000, and outpaced the growth in the rate of married mothers (Census
Bureau).5 This trend is likely to accelerate further as these mothers start hitting the time-
limit on welfare receipt imposed under welfare reform. An obvious implication of these
events is an increase in the demand for child care among single mothers. Therefore, the
issue of providing affordable child care for single mothers trying to get off welfare and
for those trying to sustain employment is central to the welfare reform challenge.
It is equally important to investigate the impacts of wages on single mothers’
behavior in order to understand the implications of different policy options on the success
3 Over 90 percent of the TANF cases in 1998 were single mothers (Committee on Ways and Means, 2000).
4 According to Census data, about 18 percent of families with children were headed by a single mother in
1996, compared with less than 11 percent in 1970.
5 The labor force participation rate for married mothers increased from 54 percent to 70.6 percent during
the same period.
2
of welfare reform. Because the primary goals of welfare reform are to reduce welfare
dependence and increase employment, policies designed to increase the effective wage
rate, such as a wage subsidy like the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), the minimum
wage, training programs, and other skill and career development packages offered by
states may contribute to these goals or can be considered as an alternative to child care
subsidies.
Another contribution of this study stems from the use of a data set from the early
post-reform period. The great majority of existing studies use data that predate welfare
reform and other important policy changes of 1990’s. However, the scope of the policy
changes during this period is so large that drawing inferences on the post-welfare reform
period by using the estimates from these studies may be misleading. In this paper, I use
data from the National Survey of America’s Families (NSAF), conducted in 1997.
Another key advantage of the NSAF is that it is the only available nationally
representative survey with information on child care subsidies.
I develop and estimate a behavioral model for the choices of part-time and full-
time employment decisions, as well as the decisions to pay for child care and receive a
child care subsidy. One innovation of the model is that it controls for the endogeneity of
child care subsidy receipt and adjusts the price of child care for the amount of subsidy for
those mothers who receive one. This allows me to avoid assigning incorrect child care
prices to those mothers who receive a subsidy. I calculate the hourly subsidy rate and
determine a mother’s eligibility for a child care subsidy using the state program rules and
family characteristics. Previous studies could not address this issue because of a lack of
data on the receipt of a child care subsidy. The empirical strategy accounts for the fact
3
that these decisions are made simultaneously. A multinomial choice model of the
discrete outcomes are estimated jointly with the linear wage equations for part-time and
full-time employment, and the price of child care, using a combination of a semi-
parametric random effects estimator and the Gaussian Quadrature. This strategy allows
me to control for correlation across the discrete outcomes and the linear equations and to
account for wages and child care price when they are not observed.
The estimation results show that both the price of child care and the wages
influence the behavior of single mothers in the directions that are predicted by the
economic theory. Specifically, a decrease in the price of child care increases
employment and the use of paid child care. Similarly, an increase in the full-time wage
rate raises overall employment and the use of paid child care. The effect of the part-time
wage rate is estimated to be much smaller than the effect of the full-time wage rate. The
results also reveal that single mothers who are employed full-time are more sensitive to
the price of child care than those who are employed part-time. The full-time wage effect
is estimated to be a stronger determinant of employment and paid child care than the
price of child care. Finally, simulation results suggest that policies which increase the
effective wage rate are likely to have significant effects on both employment and the use
of paid child care if they are targeted on full-time employment.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section two reviews the
literature relevant to this study. Section three describes the theoretical model and
discusses the econometric approach. Section four describes the data set. Empirical
results are discussed in section five. Finally, section six presents the concluding remarks
and policy implications.
4
II. Previous Literature
There is a large body of literature examining the links between the child care
price, the wage rate, and employment behavior of mothers with young children. The
primary motivation of this literature is to provide insights into the impacts of child care
and wage subsidies on employment and child care payment decisions. These studies
consistently find that a lower child care price is associated with higher probabilities that a
mother will work and pay for care, and a higher wage rate is associated with higher
probabilities that she will work and pay for care. Although a consensus appears to have
emerged regarding the presence of an effect, there is no agreement in the literature on the
magnitude of the relationship.6 Also, only a small fraction of this literature focuses on
single mothers, the main target group for welfare reform. The existing studies differ in
their data sources, sample compositions, specifications, and estimation methods.
However, sample compositions and data sources are unlikely to account for much of the
large variation that exists in the estimated price elasticity because the range of estimates
is still large within studies using the same data set and similar sample compositions
(Kimmel 1998; Blau 2000). Therefore, it is likely that specification and estimation issues
cause much of this variation.
6 Estimated price elasticities range from 0.06 to –1.26. Examples for married mothers and combinations of
both married and single mothers include –0.34 (Blau and Robins 1988), -0.74 (Ribar 1992), -0.20 (Blau and
Hagy 1988), -0.92 (Kimmel 1998), -0.20 (Connelly 1992), -0.78 (Averett et al. 1997), -0.30 (Anderson and
Levine 2000), -0.19 (Han and Waldfogel 1999), -0.16 (Michalopoulos and Robins 2000), -1.26 (Hotz and
Kilburn 1994), 0.06 for high income and –0.45 for low-income (Fronstin and Wissoker 1995), 0.04 (Blau
and Robins 1991). For single mothers, researchers found zero (Connelly 1990; Michalopoulos et al. 1992),
-0.22 (Kimmel 1998), –0.47 (Anderson and Levine 1999), -0.41 (Han and Waldfogel 1999), and –0.37 for
part-time employment and –1.22 for full-time employment (Connelly and Kimmel 2000). A review of the
literature on the relationship between the price of child care and employment can be found in Anderson and
Levine (2000) and Blau (2000). Chaplin et al. (1999) review the literature on the effect of the price of child
care on the type of care chosen by mothers.
5
Previous studies exclusively rely on data that predate welfare reform and other
important policy changes of 1990’s. However, the 1996 welfare reform changed the
systems of welfare and child care assistance fundamentally. For example, the pre-reform
system placed less emphasis on moving welfare participants into employment. A mother
might have been able to turn down a child care subsidy offer before welfare reform and
remain out of the labor force without losing her welfare eligibility (Blau and Tekin 2001).
A mother who turned down a subsidy today would be more likely to lose welfare
eligibility. Therefore, the results of the studies conducted in the pre-reform period will
not necessarily be a reliable guide to the behavior in the post-reform era.
Most of the previous literature investigated the discrete “yes” or “no”
employment decision.7 However, it is important to recognize that child care utilization is
likely to differ between part-time and full-time employment due to different
attractiveness and transactions costs associated with each type of work.8 Therefore, child
care price and wages may have different effects on part-time and full-time employment.
Furthermore, there is vast evidence in the labor demand literature, which suggests that
wages are determined separately in part-time and full-time employment markets. For
example, if workers sort themselves into different markets based on their preferences and
skills, there would exist wage differentials between the two groups even under identical
wage determination mechanisms. Alternatively, wages may be determined separately
under the dual labor market theory, which categorizes the labor market into high-wage
7 Exceptions include Michalopolos et al. (1992) and Averett et al. (1997) who estimated hours of work
equations for married mothers; and Powell (1998) (for married mothers), Michalopoulos and Robins (2000)
(for married mothers) and Connelly and Kimmel (2000) (separately for married and single mothers) who
analyzed the part-time and full-time employment choices.
8 For example, Blank (1988) reports that female heads of households face significant fixed costs of work.
6
and low-wage categories.9 Therefore, wages should be estimated separately for the two
employment sectors. This paper is the first in the child care literature to pay attention to
this issue. Consequently, part-time and full-time wages in the two markets are estimated
and their effects are assessed separately.
Most of the previous studies estimate the discrete employment decision by probit.
They predict the price of child care and the wage rate from regression models that are
estimated separately from the employment model, using samples of employed mothers
and those who pay for child care. Both the child care price and the wage equations are
corrected for potential sample selection bias. However, little research has addressed that
the employment decision is made simultaneously with other decisions, such as the
decision to pay for child care and receive a child care subsidy. One important exception
is Blau and Hagy (1998) who extended the literature by conducting a joint analysis of
employment, child care payment, and the choice of mode decisions of mothers, using a
multinomial choice model. They found the elasticity of employment with respect to price
of child care to be –0.20 and the elasticity of paying for care to be –0.34. The present
study contributes to the literature by analyzing the part-time and full-time employment
decisions, and the decisions to pay for child care and to receive a child care subsidy in a
unified framework. This is also the first study in the literature to estimate the supporting
wage and child care price equations jointly with the discrete outcomes.
Previous studies rely on several sources of variation to identify the effect of the
price of child care. The most common approach uses the variation in child care costs
across households (e.g. Powell 2002; Kimmel 1998; Connelly and Kimmel 2000;
9 See Cain (1976) and Dickens and Lang (1985) for more on the dual-labor market theory. Also, see
Hotchkiss (1991) for more on the unique determination of wages in part-time and full-time employment
sectors.
7
Anderson and Levine 2000). Some studies use the variation in child care workers’ wages
(e.g. Barrow 1996; Han and Waldfogel 1999) and others take a natural experiment
approach by comparing the employment outcomes of mothers who are exogenously
separated into different groups (e.g. Berger and Black 1992; Gelbach 1999). This study
uses the variation in household expenditure on child care to construct market level prices
of child care, where a market is defined by a geographic state. Thus, the child care cost
varies only by state of residence and not across individuals.
The vast majority of previous studies evaluate the impact of child care subsidies
by estimating the effect of child care price on employment of mothers. However, there
may be substantial costs to taking up a subsidy, either in the form of time costs required
to negotiate the subsidy bureaucracy or psychic costs (stigma) of participating in a
means-tested program. If this is the case, the receipt of a child care subsidy is
endogenous and a failure to account for this endogeneity would create biased estimates of
the impact of child care subsidy receipt.10 Receiving a child care subsidy is not an option
for non-eligibles and all eligibles do not receive the same amount of subsidy. The
previous literature failed to address this issue mainly because of a lack of data on child
care subsidies. The NSAF data used in this study provide information on the receipt of a
child care subsidy. Therefore, the decision to receive a subsidy can be incorporated into
the mother’s choice set, and consequently, the price of child care can be adjusted for the
amount of subsidy for those mothers who receive one.
10 This is a problem similar to non-participating eligibles in welfare or Food Stamp programs. See Moffitt
(1983) and Fraker and Moffitt (1988) for examples of such studies.
8
III. Theoretical Model and Empirical Strategy
The behavioral model follows the tradition of a single decision-maker framework.
The discrete choices facing a single mother with a child are: (1) whether to work, and
conditional on working, whether to work part-time or full-time; (2) whether to use paid
child care; and (3) whether to use a child care subsidy. I introduce a categorical variable,
I, defined by a cross-classification of the discrete alternatives available to each mother. It
can take on the values 1,….,J, where J is the total number of alternatives.
A single mother maximizes her utility from time at home (L), quality of her
children (Q), consumption of market goods (C), unpaid child care hours (HNP), and the
categorical variable (I). The utility function can be expressed as
U = U(L, Q, C, HNP, I; X, υ1), (1)
where X and υ1 are the observed and unobserved determinants of preferences,
respectively.11 A mother may derive disutility from receiving a child care subsidy, using
a paid child care arrangement, or being employed due to fixed costs associated with each
of these individual choices or combinations of them. For example, there may be direct
disutility from receiving a child care subsidy as a result of stigma. The discrete choice
indicator (I) is included in the utility function in order to represent these fixed utility
costs.12 It can influence utility directly and indirectly by interacting with other variables
in the utility function. I assume that a child care subsidy can only be received if a mother
11 There may be indirect costs associated with the use of unpaid services (such as the value of the care
provider’s time in alternative activities), and these costs may influence the mother’s decision as to whether
to utilize paid care or unpaid care. Including unpaid child care hours in the utility function captures these
indirect costs. Specifically, incorporating unpaid child care hours in the utility function allows for the
possibility that a mother would choose a paid child care arrangement when an unpaid alternative with the
same quality is available. If unpaid child care hours are omitted from the utility function, the model would
lead to a degenerate solution in which the mother uses only unpaid care, which is inconsistent with the data.
12 See Blau and Hagy (1998) for a similar approach.
9
is employed and her income is below the income eligibility limit.13 I also assume that
paid child care can only be used if a mother is employed.14 Following these assumptions,
there are (a maximum of) seven discrete alternatives available to a single mother. A
complete list of possible alternatives is presented in Table 1.
Child quality is the outcome of a production process with the inputs of unpaid
child care time (HNP), paid child care time (HP), the mother’s time at home (L), and the
quality of purchased child care (A). The quality production function can be expressed as
Q = Q(HNP, HP, L, A; X, υ2), (2)
where X and υ2 are the observed and unobserved determinants of quality, respectively.
A child is cared for by his/her mother during the mother’s leisure hours, and
receives care from paid and unpaid sources during her work hours. The time constraints
facing a mother and her child are as follows:
L + H = L + HNP + HP = 1, (3)
where H is the mother’s number of work hours; HP and HNP are paid and unpaid child
care hours, respectively. I limit the employment choices to (i) no work, (ii) part-time
work, and (iii) full-time work. This approach simplifies the labor supply decision to a
multinomial choice problem and avoids the difficulties of dealing with a highly nonlinear
budget constraint. The budget constraint that the mother faces depends on the alternative
chosen, and is displayed in Table 1. It incorporates the cost of child care, PsHP, if she
uses paid care, where Ps is the hourly price of child care in market s; labor income from
13 The law requires parents to be employed or attending a job training or educational program to be eligible
for a child care subsidy. Some of the non-employed mothers in the sample may be using a child care
subsidy if they attend a training or educational program. Given that the focus of the paper is employment
decision, I eliminate the possibility of subsidy receipt for non-employed mothers.
14 This assumption is necessary because of data limitations since child care information is available only for
employed mothers. It is reasonable to assume that the use of paid care among non-employed single
mothers is rare since these individuals tend to live in low-income households, and the mother is the primary
child care provider most of the time.
10
part-time employment, WPTH, if she is employed part-time, where WPT is the part-time
wage rate; labor income from full-time employment, WFTH, if she is employed full-time,
where WFT is the full-time wage rate; and the amount of the child care subsidy, SsHP, if
she uses one (conditional on being eligible for one), where Ss is the hourly subsidy rate in
market s.
The mother maximizes her utility subject to her quality production, budget, and
time constraints, along with the appropriate non-negativity constraints. The outcome of
interest is I, the discrete choice indicator. For a given value of I, the utility function can
be maximized with respect to L, C, HNP, HP, and A, and then the demand functions can be
substituted into the utility and quality production functions. By substituting the quality
production function into the utility function, one can obtain the alternative-specific
indirect utility function for a given value of I as a function of the explanatory variables in
the system. A linear approximation to the indirect utility function for alternative i yields
the following equation
Vi = X βi + αPiPs
* + αPTi WPT + αFTi WFT + εi, i=1,….,J (4)
where εi is the alternative specific disturbance, X is a vector of observed determinants
that are invariant to the alternative chosen (e.g. age, non-wage income, etc.), and the β’s
and α’s are the parameters. The α’s are allowed to differ by employment type and child
care payment status.15 The price of child care used in equation (4) is adjusted for the
amount of child care subsidy for eligible mothers who receive a subsidy. Specifically, for
each of the discrete choices available to a mother, eligibility for a child care subsidy is
determined by a comparison between the mother’s income and the state income threshold
15 Blau and Hagy (1998) and Michalopoulos and Robins (2000) also use specifications that allow varying
effects of price and wage on behavior.
11
for subsidy eligibility. Income is the sum of non-wage income and the labor income from
part-time or full-time employment depending on mother’s type of employment.16 Note
that incomes from all three employment alternatives (no-work, part-time work, and full-
time work) are required for each mother in order to be able to determine eligibility in
each of these employment types. There are three possible scenarios to consider for a
mother. In the first scenario, the mother is not eligible for a child care subsidy regardless
of her employment type. Thus, alternatives 2 and 5 from Table 1 are excluded from her
choice set. In the second scenario, she is eligible for a subsidy only when she is
employed part-time. Thus, alternative 5 is excluded from her choice set. In the third
scenario, she is eligible for a subsidy regardless of her employment type. In this case, all
seven alternatives are relevant to the mother. Therefore, the total number of alternatives
available to a mother, J, can be five, six, or seven, depending on which of the three
scenarios is relevant for her. Consequently, the hourly rate of subsidy is subtracted from
the hourly price of child care for those alternatives in which the mother uses a subsidy.17
Therefore, Ps
* is equal to Ps- Ss in alternatives 2 and 5 and is equal to Ps otherwise (See
Appendix A for a detailed description of these three scenarios).
The theoretical model implies that a higher price of child care reduces the utility
in alternatives in which a mother uses paid child care and it does not affect the utility in
other alternatives (i.e., αP2, αP4, αP5, αP7<0; αP1=αP3=αP6=0); a higher part-time wage
increases the utility in alternatives in which a mother works part-time and it does not
16 Labor income from part-time (full-time) employment is calculated by multiplying the part-time (full-
time) wage rate by the average number of part-time (full-time) hours worked per year in the sample. The
wage rates used in this calculation are predicted from regression models that are corrected for selection into
both labor force and part-time/full-time employment types.
17 The subtraction of Ss from Ps is indicated by the theoretical model and is illustrated in Table 1. The child
care subsidy rate is the hourly rate if the state sets an hourly level. If the subsidy amount is set daily
(weekly), average hourly rate is calculated by dividing the daily (weekly) level by eight (forty).
12
affect the utility in other alternatives (i.e., αPT2, αPT3, αPT4>0; αPT1= αPT5=αPT6= αPT7=0);
a higher full-time wage increases the utility in alternatives in which a mother works full-
time and it does not affect the utility in other alternatives (i.e., αFT5, αFT6, αFT7>0; αF1=
αF2=αF3= αF4=0); and a higher child care subsidy increases the utility in alternatives in
which a child care subsidy is received and it does not affect the utility in other
alternatives (i.e., αP2, αP4< 0; αP1, αP3, αP5, αP6, αP7 = 0).18
Letting i= 1,…..,J be the possible alternatives from the choice set, it will be
optimal for a mother to choose state i if
Vi > Vj, ji or
εi - εj>X(βj - βi )+Ps
*(αPj - αPi)+WPT(αPTj - αPTi)+WFT(αFTj - αFTi), j
i, (5)
Given the discrete nature of the alternatives, a multinomial choice model is used to
estimate equations (4) and (5). In addition to the multinomial choice model, there are
three linear auxiliary equations, two for the wage rates (for part-time and full-time
employment) and one for the price of child. Estimating these equations is necessary for
two reasons. First, these variables may be endogenous. Second, one needs to assign a
child care price and two wage rates to each mother in the sample regardless of her child
care payment and employment status in order to estimate the multinomial choice model.
The price of child care is observed only for mothers who are employed and pay
for child care, and this may be a self-selected sample. Further, the price is not exogenous
because it depends in part on the quality of care purchased. Specifically, the price of
18 It can be argued that the price of child care affects a mother’s decision by lowering her wage rate. In this
case, the coefficients of the price of child care and the wage rates should be equal to each other in
magnitude, but with opposite sign. The specification in equation (4) is more general and does not impose
this restriction. See also Blau and Hagy (1998) and Michalopoulos and Robins (2000) for similar
approaches.
13
child care is determined by the quality of purchased care, A, and the market specific
characteristics that capture the variation in the price of child care caused by differences in
conditions across different markets. In the absence of data on quality attributes of care,
the demand function for the quality of purchased care can be derived as a function of all
exogenous variables in the model by solving the first order conditions to the optimization
problem. Therefore, the variation in the quality of child care can be captured by
household variables. The market specific price variation on the other hand, can be
captured by cross-state variation under the assumption that each geographic state
constitutes a separate child care market. This cross-state variation captures the variation
in the price of child care caused by differences in market conditions and is assumed to be
independent of the choices made by the mothers. This results in a fully reduced form
price equation in the following form
S
P = Σ δsDs + X δP + ξP, (6)
s
s=1
where X is the set of all exogenous variables in the model, the δP‘s are the parameters,
and ξP is the disturbance term. Ds is a binary indicator for residence in state s, and S is
the total number of states. δs is the state specific intercept. Then the quality-adjusted
exogenous price of child care can be constructed from the fitted values, holding X
constant at the sample means.
In order to identify the child care price coefficient in the multinomial choice
model, αPi, one must have at least one variable in the price equation (eq. 6) that does not
affect the mother’s preferences (eq. 4). However, as described above, the child care price
function is a fully reduced form equation, thus it contains all the exogenous variables in
the model. This implies that the only theoretical basis for identification of the child care
14
price coefficient is the intercept term in equation (6), ΣSsδsDs. Therefore, I rely on state
fixed effects to identify the child care price effect in equation (4). Using the set of state
dummies as an identifying restriction implicitly assumes that a mother’s residence of
state has no direct effect on her preferences, but does help determine the price of child
care.19 Equation (6) is estimated jointly with the multinomial choice model, allowing ξP
to be correlated with the εi’s in equation (4). This strategy corrects for selection bias due
to the possibility that mothers who use and pay for child care constitute a nonrandom
sample of the population. The Gaussian Quadrature is used to account for missing prices
by integrating over the distribution of error term in equation (6) for mothers who do not
pay for child care (Butler and Moffitt 1982).20
Likewise, measures of a part-time and a full-time wage rate are required for each
mother in the sample regardless of her employment status in order to estimate the
multinomial choice model. Furthermore, observed wages may be endogenous. Wages
are assumed to be a function of human capital, regional variation, and demand effects.
Labor demand, as measured by the state unemployment rate and labor force participation
rate for females, is used to identify the wage effects (αPTi and αFTi) in the multinomial
choice model. These variables are included in the wage equation, but are excluded from
the discrete choice model under the assumption that they have no direct effect on
mothers’ preferences. The wage equations for part-time and full-time employment are
19 Identification strategy assumes that the location affects preferences only via its effects on price. A more
plausible alternative would be to rely on within-state variation by using county dummies as identifying
instruments, assuming that each county is a different child care market rather than the state. However, this
would add a large number of parameters to the model, which would be computationally infeasible to
estimate. Further, county information is available only for the 13-targeted states in the NSAF.
20 The Gaussian Quadrature allows me to estimate the price and wage equations jointly with the
multinomial choice model. See Appendix B for a description of the method and its implementation in the
present context.
15
estimated jointly with the multinomial choice model, allowing for correlation across the
disturbance terms. This strategy corrects for self-selection into the labor force as well as
part-time and full-time employment sectors. Similar to the estimation of the child care
price, the Gaussian Quadrature method is used to integrate over the distributions of the
error terms in the part-time and full-time wage equations to account for the missing
wages. Specifically, if the mother is not employed, the computation of a two-
dimensional integration is required by the Gaussian Quadrature. If she is employed part-
time or full-time, only one-dimensional Gaussian integration is necessary (See Appendix
B for a detailed discussion).
Error Structure and Econometric Implementation
The possible correlation across disturbances in the indirect utility functions (the
εi’s) could produce biased estimates. Such a correlation is likely to occur because
alternatives are defined by cross classifying the discrete outcomes available to a mother.
For example, if a mother has strong preferences for work, this will affect the εi’s in all the
alternatives in which she is employed (alternatives 2-7). Similarly, if a mother has
unobserved preferences for part-time (full-time) work, this effect will appear in all the
alternatives in which she is employed part-time (full-time). Furthermore, the mothers
who receive child care subsidies are a self-selected sample of the population. A mother’s
decision concerning whether to use a child care subsidy is likely to be correlated with her
labor supply. For example, a mother with strong preferences for work may also have a
higher motivation to use a child care subsidy. However, a multinomial logit model
restricts the correlation among the disturbance terms to zero because of the independence
16
of irrelevant alternatives assumption. A second source of error correlation would be
between the discrete outcomes and the linear wage and child care price equations. For
example, a mother who is strongly motivated for work may also have a higher wage rate.
Further, a higher price of child care may induce a mother to use a child care subsidy or
use unpaid child care.
To estimate the econometric model, I use a semi-parametric random effects
estimator, known as the discrete factor model, which allows the error terms to be
correlated across the discrete outcomes and the linear wage and child care price
equations. The discrete factor model approximates the distribution of the heterogeneity
with a step function and “integrates out” through a weighted sum of probabilities. Mroz
(1999) shows that the discrete factor model provides more robust estimates when
compared with techniques imposing a specific distributional assumption.21
To implement the discrete factor model, I impose the following structure on the
disturbances in the equations for the discrete outcomes and the linear wage and child care
price:
εi = ui + ρi η, (7)
ξP = µP + ρPη, (8)
ξFT = µFT + ρFTη, (9)
ξPT = µPT + ρPTη, (10)
where ξFT and ξPT are the error terms in full-time and part-time wage regressions,
respectively. The ui, µ’s and η are mutually independent disturbances that are also
21 In principle, one could estimate the system of equations by imposing a joint distribution, such as joint
normality, for the sources of unobserved heterogeneity and integrating over its distribution. The problem
with this approach is that it requires computing complex multiple integrals. Further, it requires making
strong assumptions about the exact distribution of heterogeneity. See Blau and Hagy (1998), Hu (1999),
and Mocan and Tekin (in press) for applications of the discrete factor model.
17
assumed to be independent of X, WPT, WFT, and Ps*. The ρ’s are factor loadings.22 This
structure places the restriction that all correlation among the error terms enters the model
through the common factor η that is assumed to have a discrete distribution (Heckman
and Singer 1984). The unobserved factor is then integrated out using the discrete factor
model following Mroz (1999).
The equation for the discrete choice model (eq. 4), the price of child care (eq. 6),
and two wage equations are estimated jointly by full information maximum likelihood
(FIML), with discrete factors integrated out of the model using the discrete factor model.
The Gaussian Quadrature method is also used in the estimation to integrate over the
distributions of the disturbances for wages and price of child care when they are not
observed. The u’s in equation (7) are assumed to have mean zero and to be
independently extreme-value distributed; the µ’s in equations (8)-(10) are assumed to
have mean zero and to be independently normally distributed. The likelihood function
and details of the heterogeneity distribution are discussed in Appendix B.
IV. Data
The data used in the empirical analysis are drawn from the National Survey of
America’s Families (NSAF). The NSAF was conducted by the Urban Institute between
February and November 1997.23 The survey was conducted by telephone on a sample
derived primarily from random-digit-sampling and was designed to help researchers
22 Rather than imposing a one-factor structure, it would be more plausible to consider for multiple factors to
account for possibly a more complex structure of correlation (e.g. Blau and Hagy (1998), Mocan and Tekin
(in press.)). I tried estimating the system of equations using multiple factors. However, given the
complexity of the likelihood function, the optimization routine failed to converge and I had to switch to a
single factor framework to obtain stable estimates.
23 Another round of the NSAF was conducted in 1999, with a new sample. Complete data from the 1999
round have not yet been released to the public.
18
analyze the consequences of devolution of responsibility for social programs from the
federal government to states. Residents of 13 states and households with income below
200 percent of the federal poverty line were over-sampled.24 The full NSAF sample
contains 44,461 households.
The NSAF is particularly well-suited for this study for several reasons. It was
specifically designed to collect detailed information on income, child care, and
participation in various programs, and to provide better data on such variables than can
be obtained from most other surveys. It was conducted after the enactment of the welfare
reform legislation and many other important policy changes of 1990’s. Another
advantage of the NSAF is that it is the only national household survey from the post-
welfare period that contains information about child care subsidies. Unlike
administrative data, the NSAF provides information on both subsidy recipients and non-
recipients. Therefore, the potential endogeneity of child care subsidy receipt can be
addressed. Finally, the NSAF provides a relatively large sample of single mothers, who
are the target group for welfare reform.
The main variables of interest are employment, child care payment, and child care
subsidy receipt. A mother who reports that part or all of her child care expenses are paid
by a welfare or social services agency is coded as receiving a child care subsidy.
Employment is specified as a trichotomous variable defined at zero hours of work, part-
time work, and full-time work.25 Child care payment status is a binary variable equal to
one if the mother reported any payment for child care, and zero otherwise.
24 The 13-targeted states were Alabama, California, Colorado, Florida, Massachusetts, Michigan,
Minnesota, Mississippi, New Jersey, New York, Texas, Washington, and Wisconsin.
25 Mothers with weekly work hours from 1 to 35 are classified as working part-time, and those with 35 and
over are classified as working full-time. Similar definitions have been previously used in both the child care
19
The mother’s wage rate is computed by dividing annual earnings by annual hours
of work. In the NSAF, child care hours are collected for up to two randomly chosen
children, one between ages 0-5, and the other between ages 6-12. Child care
expenditures on the other hand, are collected for all children between ages 0-12.
Therefore, the hourly child care expenditure per child can be approximated by dividing
the total child care expenditures for all children between ages 0-12 by the sum of child
care hours for all children between ages 0-5 (the product of the child care hours for the
randomly chosen child between ages 0-5 and total number of children between ages 0-5)
and child care hours for all children between ages 6-12 (the product of the child care
hours for the randomly chosen child between ages 6-12 and total number of children
between ages 6-12). However, this computation is not possible because the NSAF does
not provide information on the number of children between ages 0-12. Rather, we know
the number of family members between ages 0-5 and 6-17. In order to approximate the
number of children between ages 6 and 12, I obtained the proportion of U.S. population
between ages 6 and 12 among the population between ages 6 and 17 in 1997 from the
U.S. Bureau of Census records. Then I multiplied this figure by the total number of
family members between ages 6 to 17 for the mothers who have more than one child in
this age range. Note that I do not need to make this adjustment for those cases with no
randomly chosen child between ages 6-12 (i.e., the mother has no child between ages 6-
12) or for those cases with a randomly chosen child between ages 6-12 and only one
family member between ages 6-17 (i.e., the mother has only one child between ages 6-12,
literature (e.g. Michalapoulos and Robins 2000; and Connelly and Kimmel 2000) and transfer program
literature (e.g. Fraker and Moffitt 1988; Hoynes 1996; and Keane and Moffitt 1998).
20
thus no adjustment is necessary). Only 28 percent of the single mothers in the sample
have more than one child between ages 6-12.
The statute for federal eligibility criteria for a child care subsidy is that “eligible
children must be under the age 13 and reside with a family whose income does not
exceed 85 percent of the state median income for a family of the same size and whose
parent(s) are working or attending a job training or educational program or who receive
or need to receive protective services” (Child Care Development Block Grant
658E(c)(3)(B), 658P(4)). The federal law allows states to set up the eligibility criteria up
to 85 percent of State Median Income, but only nine states set income eligibility at the 85
percent level and seven states set it at less than 50 percent level in 1997. I supplemented
the NSAF data with information from other data sources on income eligibility limit,
subsidy amounts, and median income for each state in year 1997. Data on income
eligibility limit and subsidy amounts are obtained from the Child Care Bureau and the
State Policy Demonstration Projects web sites. Data on state median income are obtained
from the U.S. Census Bureau.
The other variables used in the analysis include the mother’s age, non-wage
income, race, ethnicity, and binary indicators for the mother’s educational attainment,
health status, the presence of children by age, and the region of residence. These
variables are included in the model to control for mother’s preferences and her quality of
care. Non-wage income is the sum of household income from non-market sources. I also
include the number of family members aged 25 and over to control for the availability of
free care to the mother. Finally, I included the state dummies in the child care price
21
equation, and the state’s unemployment rate and the labor force participation rates for
females in the wage rate equations for identification.
The empirical analysis is performed on a subsample of households headed by a
single mother with at least one child under age 13. 26 After excluding cases with missing
data, sample consists of 4,029 households. Definitions and the summary statistics for the
variables used in the analysis are presented in Tables 2 and 3. Mothers who are
employed and paying for child care have on average a higher level of education
compared to those who are not employed and not paying for child care. Mothers who do
not pay for care tend to have more adults in the household compared to those who pay for
care. Mothers who pay for child care earn on average higher wages compared to mothers
who do not pay for child care. Among mothers who pay for care, the average hourly
expenditure is $2.18 for part-time workers and $2.03 for full-time workers. This is
consistent with the evidence that part-time care is typically more expensive per hour than
full-time care (Hofferth et al. 1991). As expected, mothers working full-time earn higher
wages compared to those working part-time.
Table 4 displays the distribution of employment, child care payment, and child
care subsidy outcomes. About 68 percent of the single mothers in the sample are in the
labor force; 17.2 percent of the sample work part-time and 50.9 percent are employed
full-time. About 56 percent of mothers working part-time and 63 percent of those
working full-time pay for care. Approximately 12 percent of part-time and 10 percent of
full-time workers use a child care subsidy. Sixty four percent of working mothers in the
sample are eligible for a child care subsidy under the income eligibility rules set by states
26I include all single mothers regardless of income in order to avoid conditioning on income from
employment and welfare.
22
in 1997 and 16.7 percent of these eligibles use a child care subsidy. This figure is close
to that of the Administration for Children and Families (1999), which estimates that 12-
15 percent of eligibles are served under the state-set limits in 1998.
V. Results
The full set of results from the estimations of the child care price, and the full-
time and part-time wage equations are presented in Tables C1 and C2. While space
limitation precludes a detailed discussion of these results in the text, they are generally
consistent with those found in the relevant literature.27
The estimates of the discrete choice model are presented in Table C3. The results
presented in the paper are taken from a model with three Hermite and four mass points.28
The reference category is alternative 1 in which the single mother is not employed, does
not pay for child care, and does not use a child care subsidy. A likelihood ratio test
rejected the model with a single price coefficient against a model that allowed price
coefficients to vary by part-time and full-time employment status. Consistent with the
predictions of the theoretical model, a higher price of child care reduces the utility in
alternatives in which the mother works and pays for child care. The coefficient estimate
on the price of child care is -0.198 and significant (t = 2.01) when the mother works full-
27 There is considerable variation in the child care price across states. The coefficient of variation of the
child care price ranges from 0.92 to 5.36 and averages 1.95 across states. The relatively small number of
observations with paid care per state (44.2) accounts for the mostly high standard errors in the estimates.
However, a specification test strongly rejected the hypothesis that the coefficients on state dummies are
jointly zero.
28 I estimated the model with alternative combinations of numbers of heterogeneity and Hermite points. A
model with four Hermite points did not provide a significant improvement in the likelihood over a model
with three Hermite points. Also, a model with five mass points did not yield a higher likelihood compared
to a model with four mass points. Evidence of unobserved heterogeneity in the model is presented by the
estimates of the heterogeneity parameters in Table C4. The factor loadings are estimated to be significant
and large in most cases.
23
time, and is -0.103, but estimated with less precision (t = 1.45), when the mother works
part-time.29 These estimates suggest that the price of child care is a stronger deterrent to
full-time employment than it is to part-time employment. The implied child care price
elasticities with respect to full-time and part-time employment are –0.149 and –0.072,
respectively.30 The finding that the price elasticity with respect to part-time employment
is less than that of full-time employment in absolute value is consistent with other studies
that distinguish between part-time and full-time employment.31 The implied price
elasticity of paying for care is –0.162, and is comparable to estimates in several other
studies.32
The implied price elasticity with respect to overall employment is estimated to be
–0.121. This figure falls in the lower end of the range of estimates found in the literature.
However, both the model and econometric approach used in this paper differ from the
rest of the literature in a number of important ways. First, I account for the decision to
receive a child care subsidy, and consequently implement an adjustment to the price of
child care for the amount of subsidy for those who use one. Second, I distinguish
between part-time and full-time employment. Third, I estimate a multinomial choice
29 A similar differential effect between the part-time and full-time employment types is also found by
Michalopoulos and Robins (2000).
30 To find the price elasticity of employment, the derivative of the probability of choosing state i, Pr(i), with
respect to the predicted price of child care is computed for each mother in the sample. This is then
integrated over the heterogeneity distribution since Pr(i) is a function of the heterogeneity. Then the
expression, [WORK(Pr(i)/P)]P/Pr(WORK), is calculated, where WORK represents the set of alternatives
in which the mother is employed, Pr(WORK) is equal to WORKPr(i), and Pr(i)/P is equal to αPiPr(i)[1 –
Pr(i)]. Finally, the elasticity is obtained by averaging this term over the sample.
31 Examples include Powell (1998) (who estimated the elasticities to be –0.20 for part-time employment
and –0.71 for full-time employment using a sample of married mothers from Canada), Connelly and
Kimmel (2000) (who estimated the elasticities to be –0.372 for part-time and –1.221 for full-time
employment for single mothers), and Michalopoulos and Robins (2000) (who estimated the elasticities to
be +0.159 for part-time and –0.342 for full-time using a sample of two-parent families from Canada and the
U.S.).
32 Examples of several other estimates of the price elasticity of paying for care are –0.34 for a sample of
both married and single mothers (Blau and Robins 1988 and Blau and Hagy 1998) and –0.298 for single
mothers (Michalopoulos et al. 1992).
24
model, whereas most of the literature estimated binary models of employment. Fourth, I
estimate the full system of equations in a unified framework. Specifically, I control for
the unobserved heterogeneity and correlation across the errors in the discrete choice
model and the linear equations of wages and the price of child care, using a combination
of the discrete factor model and the Gaussian Quadrature. Nonetheless, the elasticity
found in this paper is comparable to those of several other studies that are similar to the
present study in several respects.33
Table 5 displays the generated simulations of the impact of subsidizing the price
of child care on the state choice probabilities. In each simulation, a price of child care,
and a part-time and a full-time wage rate are predicted for each mother in the sample by
using the coefficient estimates. Then the state choice probabilities are computed for each
mother, integrating over the estimated heterogeneity distribution, which are then
averaged across the sample. The first simulation reduces the price of child care by fifty
percent from its current level. This can be considered as a subsidy that is available to all
the mothers and is equivalent to an annual subsidy of about 1,900 dollars for a full-time,
full-year worker using paid child care. As displayed in Table 5, the simulation results
indicate that single mothers respond to reductions in the price of child care moderately.
A fifty percent reduction in the price of child care would increase full-time employment
by 3.5 percentage points (a 6.7 percent increase) and part-time employment by 0.6
percentage point (a 3.3 percent increase). Combining these two effects, the overall
employment would increase by about 4.1 percentage points (a 5.8 percent increase) as a
33 Examples include –0.09 of Ribar (1995) and -0.38 of Blau and Robins (1988) both of whom estimate a
discrete choice model with multinomial logit; -0.342 of Michalopoulos and Robins (2000) who estimate a
multinomial logit distinguishing between full-time and part-time employment; and –0.20 of Blau and Hagy
(1998) who estimate a discrete choice model by a semi-parametric estimator similar to the one employed in
the present study.
25
result of the subsidy. The probability of paying for child care increases by 3.2 percentage
points (a 7.5 percent increase) in response to a fifty percent reduction in the price of child
care. If the price of child care is fully subsidized, the predicted probabilities of full-time
and part-time employment would increase by 6.0 percentage points (11.5 percent) and 1.2
percentage points (6.2 percent), respectively. The probability of paying for child care
would increase by 6.2 percentage points (14.5 percent).
Turning to the wage effects, a higher part-time (full-time) wage increases the
utility in those alternatives in which the mother works part-time (full-time) and does not
affect the utility in other alternatives, confirming the predictions of the theoretical model.
A likelihood ratio test rejected the model that restricted the part-time and full-time wage
coefficients to be the same across these two employment types against a model that
allowed separate effects. The coefficient estimates on the part-time and full-time wage
rate are 0.229 (t=1.94) and 1.109 (t=4.51), respectively. The implied elasticity of full-
time employment is 0.897 with respect to the full-time wage rate, and is -0.095 with
respect to the part-time wage rate. Similarly, the implied elasticity of part-time
employment is 0.511 with respect to the part-time wage rate, and is –0.102 with respect
to the full-time wage rate. Combining the impacts on the full-time and part-time
employment, the implied elasticity of overall employment is 0.694 with respect to the
full-time wage rate, and is 0.081 with respect to the part-time wage rate. These results
imply that full-time wage is a much stronger determinant of overall employment than the
part-time wage rate.
According to the simulation results presented in Table 5, a 15 percent increase in
the full-time wage rate leads to a 8.7 percentage points (16.7 percent) increase in full-
26
time employment and a 0.3 percentage point (1.7 percent) decrease in part-time
employment. Thus, the overall employment increases by 8.4 percentage points (11.9
percent). A similar increase in the part-time wage rate leads to a 1.7 percentage points
(9.4 percent) increase in part-time employment and a 0.8 percentage point (1.5 percent)
decrease in full-time employment, which represents a 0.9 percentage point (1.3 percent)
increase in overall employment.
The full-time wage elasticity of paying for care is estimated to be 0.756 and the
part-time wage elasticity of paying for care is estimated to be 0.126. Similar to the effect
on employment, full-time wage rate is a much stronger determinant of paying for child
care than the part-time wage rate. As shown in Table 5, a 15 percent increase in the full-
time wage rate leads to a 5.5 percentage points (12.8 percent) increase in using paid child
care. A similar increase in the part-time wage rate generates only a 0.6 percentage points
(1.4 percent) increase in using paid care.
Finally, I simulated the impact of reducing the income eligibility limit for a
subsidy on the state choice probabilities. The simulation decreases the eligibility limit by
25 percent, holding the price of child care constant. Approximately 65 percent of the
working mothers are eligible for a child care subsidy at the original eligibility limit. With
a 25 percent decrease in the income eligibility limit, the proportion of the sample eligible
for a subsidy increases to about 84 percent. As displayed in Table 5, the full-time and
part-time employment probabilities increase by 2.7 percentage points (4.8 percent) and a
half percentage point (2.8 percent), respectively, which represents an increase in overall
employment by 3.2 percentage points (about 5 percent). The probability of using paid
child care increases by 2 percentage points (4.7 percent).
27
Sensitivity Analyses and Specification Tests
As discussed earlier, one of the innovations of this paper that distinguishes it from
the rest of the literature is its inclusion of the child care subsidy receipt as an additional
alternative in the mother’s choice set and its adjustment of the child care price for the
amount of the subsidy in the estimation. To determine the sensitivity of the results to this
treatment and to provide a set of results that are more comparable to previous studies, I
estimated the model excluding the subsidy decision from the model. In this case, the
single mother only makes employment and child care payment decisions, which
generates a model with five alternatives. The results show that the responses of
employment and child care payment to the price of child care are more elastic in the five-
choice model relative to the benchmark results presented earlier. The elasticity of overall
employment with respect to the price of child care is estimated to be –0.348 and the
elasticity of paying for care is –0.421. Results also indicate that exclusion of the subsidy
receipt from the model has little effect on the estimated wage elasticities.
Note that the amount of child care expenditures in the survey is reported by the
mother and this is assumed to represent the amount net of subsidy, Ps-Ss, for those who
receive one. This is equivalent to assuming that all subsidies were directly paid to the
provider and any expenditure made by the mother represents her out-of-pocket payment,
not the total price of child care. This assumption is necessary because it is not possible to
identify in the data whether the mother uses a voucher. A violation of this assumption
would cause Ps-Ss to be overestimated. If voucher versus direct payment to the provider
were random and uncorrelated with the explanatory variables in the model, then the child
care price coefficient would still be estimated with no bias. If this is not the case,
28
however, the price effect will be biased. In order to test the validity of this assumption, I
estimated the model treating the subsidy recipients as if the price of child care for them is
unobserved. This is equivalent to treating these cases as if they use unpaid child care.
This allowed me to avoid making an assumption as to whether the cost of child care is
subsidized with a voucher or through a direct payment to the provider. Therefore, the
price of child care is substituted with a regression function for these mothers, just like
those who use unpaid child care.34 Note that this implementation is necessary only for
294 mothers in the sample who reported receiving a subsidy. The price elasticity of
overall employment is estimated to be –0.149 and the price elasticity of paying for care is
estimated to be -0.191. These results are close to those of the benchmark model and do
not change any of its implications.
VI. Conclusions
This paper provides new evidence on the effects of the price of child care and
wages on employment and child care payment decisions of single mothers in the early
post-welfare reform period. It improves on previous work in several aspects. First, it
uses data from a new survey, which was conducted after the enactment of welfare reform
and other important policy changes of early and mid-1990s. Second, it addresses the
endogeneity of child care subsidy receipt by incorporating the subsidy decision into the
mother’s choice set. This also allows to appropriately adjust for the price of child care by
the amount of subsidy for eligible mothers. Third, it distinguishes between the part-time
and full-time employment markets as well as the wages prevailing in these markets. This
34 Note that the Gaussian Quadrature is used to integrate over the distribution of the error term of the price
of child care for these cases.
29
accounts for the possibilities that each of these employment markets may have different
wage determination mechanisms and the mothers’ behavior in one market may
systematically differ from that of the other. Fourth, the econometric strategy employed in
the paper estimates the system of equations in a unified framework using full information
likelihood (FIML). This is the first paper to employ the discrete factor method and the
Gaussian Quadrature together in the estimation. This empirical strategy allows the
outcomes analyzed to be determined simultaneously.
The results suggest that single mothers who are employed full-time are more
sensitive to changes in the price of child care than those who are employed part-time. A
lower price of child care increases the employment and the use of paid child care among
those who are employed full-time, but has much smaller impacts on those who are
employed part-time. Income from part-time employment may be so low that even with a
reduction in the price of child care, mothers may not have enough incentive to leave
welfare and seek employment. Also, mothers who are employed part-time may rely more
on relative care during their work hours compared to their full-time working counterparts.
The estimated elasticity of overall employment with respect to the price of child care is
–0.12, which falls in the lower end of the range of estimates found in the literature.
An increase in the full-time wage leads to an increase in overall employment and
the use of paid care. However, the full-time wage effects are found to be much more
elastic than to the price effects. The elasticity of overall employment with respect to the
full-time wage rate is estimated to be 0.69. The part-time wage rate on the other hand, is
estimated to have much less of an effect on the behavior of single mothers. The implied
elasticity of overall employment elasticity with respect to the part-time wage rate is only
30
0.08. Part-time employment may not be financially rewarding enough for single mothers
to induce them choose employment over a potentially more attractive alternative of
welfare.
One important implication of the findings is that policies that provide financial
incentives to mothers, such as the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), minimum wages,
and enhanced earnings disregards are likely to have significant effects on the work effort
of single mothers, especially if they are targeted to the full-time labor market. At the
federal level, the EITC provides earnings subsidies for low-income families with
children. It has been expanded substantially in the 1990s and the real EITC maximum
subsidy rose by 216 percent for a family with two children between 1990 and 1998
(Blank et al. 2000). The minimum wage was also increased in 1990, 1991, 1996, and
1997, with a cumulative 9 percent increase in real terms between 1990 and 1998. States
also introduce financial incentives into their welfare systems, most often via increased
earnings disregards. In addition to these financial incentive programs, state initiatives
subsidizing skill formation (e.g. career and job skills development and training programs)
that would lead to increases in future wages would also strengthen the welfare-to-work
efforts of low-income mothers.
The results presented in this paper do not provide evidence on the tradeoff
between the quality and the quantity of child care since all the price effects are quality-
adjusted. Therefore, no inferences can be made about the child care quality dimensions
of the price and wage impacts. If child care subsidies are employment-related, that is,
they are aimed only at increasing employment with no restrictions on the quality, the
results suggest that they could be useful in achieving this goal. Given that these subsidies
31
are found to be effective only for full-time employment, they could also help single
mothers achieve economic self-sufficiency and reduce future welfare dependence if on-
the-job-training and experience in full-time jobs lead to improved skills over time. An
example of employment-related child care subsidies is the Child Care Tax Credit (CCTC)
that provides a tax credit to families with young children without placing any restrictions
on the quality of child care.
32
Table 1
Frequency Distributions of the Discrete Outcomes
Alternative Employment
Status
Child Care
Payment Status
Child Care
Subsidy Status
Budget Constraint
1 No --- --- C=N
2 Part-time Yes Yes C+(Ps-Ss)HP=WPTH+N
3 Part-time No No C=WPT H+N
4 Part-time Yes No C+PsHP=WPTH+N
5 Full-time Yes Yes C+(Ps-Ss)HP=WFTH+N
6 Full-time No No C+HP=WFTH+N
7 Full-time Yes No C+PsHP=WFTH+N
Total
Table 2
Variable Definitions
Discrete Choice
Indicator, I
= The categorical variable defined by the cross-classification
of employment, child care payment, and subsidy status.
Age = Mother’s age in years
Racea
White =1 if mother is white, 0 otherwise
Black =1 if mother is black, 0 otherwise
Hispanic =1 if mother is of Hispanic ethnicity, 0 otherwise
Regionb
Northeast =1 if mother lives in Northeast, 0 otherwise
Midwest =1 if mother lives in Midwest, 0 otherwise
South =1 if mother lives in South, 0 otherwise
Health =1 if mother is in good health, 0 otherwise
Mother’s Educationc
Highsch =1 if mother is high school or some college graduate, 0
otherwise
Bachelor =1 if mother is college graduate or more, 0 otherwise
Othadult = Number of family members aged 25+ in the household
Nonwage = Annual non-labor income (= total income-own earned
income – income from means tested programs)
Presence of childrend
Child0-5 =1 if mother has at least one child between 0-5, 0 otherwise
Child6-12 =1 if mother has at least one child between 6-12, 0 otherwise
Wagepart-time = Hourly part-time wage rate in dollars
Wagefull-time = Hourly full-time wage rate in dollars
Pricechild care = Hourly price of child care
Slfp = State labor force participation rate for females in 1997
Sunemp = State unemployment rate for females in 1997
a Omitted category is Other.
b Omitted category is West.
c Omitted category is Nodegree.
d Omitted category is Childboth.
33
Table 3
Descriptive Statistics
Variable Full
Sample
Non-
employed
Employed
part-time
Employed
full-time
Pay for
Care
Don’t Pay
for Care
Age 31.94
(6.89)
30.56
(6.90)
31.54
(6.87)
32.93
(6.74)
31.43
(6.56)
32.29
(7.10)
Black 0.32
(0.47)
0.36
(0.48)
0.29
(0.45)
0.31
(0.46)
0.30
(0.46)
0.34
(0.47)
White 0.65
(0.48)
0.60
(0.49)
0.68
(0.47)
0.66
(0.47)
0.68
(0.47)
0.63
(0.48)
Northeast 0.23
(0.42)
0.27
(0.45)
0.25
(0.44)
0.19
(0.39)
0.22
(0.41)
0.24
(0.43)
Midwest 0.29
(0.46)
0.22
(0.42)
0.33
(0.47)
0.33
(0.47)
0.33
(0.47)
0.27
(0.44)
South 0.31
(0.46)
0.32
(0.47)
0.25
(0.43)
0.33
(0.46)
0.29
(0.45)
0.33
(0.47)
Health 0.93
(0.25)
0.90
(0.30)
0.95
(0.22)
0.95
(0.23)
0.95
(0.23)
0.92
(0.27)
Highsch 0.73
(0.44)
0.64
(0.48)
0.77
(0.42)
0.78
(0.42)
0.78
(0.41)
0.69
(0.46)
College 0.11
(0.32)
0.06
(0.25)
0.11
(0.32)
0.14
(0.35)
0.14
(0.34)
0.09
(0.29)
Hispanic 0.14
(0.35)
0.20
(0.40)
0.12
(0.33)
0.11
(0.32)
0.11
(0.31)
0.17
(0.34)
Othadult 0.35
(0.69)
0.38
(0.73)
0.32
(0.67)
0.35
(0.64)
0.29
(0.63)
0.40
(0.73)
Nonwage
(/1000)
7.57
(14.14)
6.44
(13.94)
7.39
(13.89)
8.31
(14.30)
7.87
(14.01)
7.33
(14.22)
Child0-6 0.33
(0.47)
0.38
(0.49)
0.34
(0.47)
0.40
(0.49)
0.39
(0.49)
0.29
(0.49)
Child6-12 0.45
(0.50)
0.33
(0.47)
0.44
(0.49)
0.52
(0.50)
0.37
(0.48)
0.50
(0.50)
Wagepart-time 6.69
(1.46)
--- 6.69
(1.46)
--- 6.833
(1.52)
6.510
(1.38)
Wagefull-time 8.22
(3.41)
--- --- 8.22
(3.41)
8.44
(3.48)
7.83
(3.12)
Pricechild care 2.07
(1.77)
--- 2.18
(1.79)
2.03
(1.76)
2.07
(1.77)
---
Slfp 60.49
(5.36)
59.74
(4.95)
60.71
(5.44)
60.79
(5.50)
60.78
(5.47)
60.21
(5.23)
Sunemp 5.17
(1.45)
5.37
(1.42)
5.09
(1.48)
5.11
(1.46)
5.08
(1.45)
5.28
(1.45)
Sample Size 4,029 1,285 697 2,407 1,679 2,350
Note: Standard deviations are in parentheses.
34
Table 4
Frequency Distributions of the Discrete Outcomes
State Employment
Status
Child Care
Payment Status
Child Care Subsidy
Status
Count Percentage
Total
1 No --- --- 1,285 31.9
2 Part-time Yes Yes 86 2.1
3 Part-time No No 308 7.6
4 Part-time Yes No 303 7.5
5 Full-time Yes Yes 208 5.2
6 Full-time No No 757 18.8
7 Full-time Yes No 1,082 26.9
Total 4,029 100.0
Table 5
Simulations of Employment and Child Care Payment Probabilities
Full-time
Employment
Part-time
Employment
Paying for Child
Care
Predicted base probability a 52.2 18.1 42.9
PriceChild Care (-50%) 55.7 18.7 46.1
PriceChild Care (-100%) 58.2 19.3 49.1
Wage Full-time (+15%) 60.9 17.8 48.4
Wage Part-time (+15%) 51.4 19.8 43.6
Eligibility limit (-25%) 54.9 18.6 44.9
aA comparison between the predicted choice probabilities and the actual percentages of the discrete
outcomes reveals that the model fits the data fairly well, although the probabilities of employment and
paying for care are slightly over predicted. However, the predicted probabilities come within about two
percentage points of accurately predicting the actual probabilities.
35
APPENDIX A
The Possible Scenarios of Alternatives Available to A Single Mother
A mother makes her employment decision among no employment, part-time
employment, and full-time employment. Her total income in these employment states
can be expressed as
IN (Income when not employed) = N (non-wage income),
IPT (Income when employed part-time) = N + WPTH,
IFT (Income when employed full-time) = N + WFTH.
According to the theoretical model developed in the paper, each mother will
choose from one of three sets of alternatives, which is determined by her eligibility status
for a child care subsidy. Below, I provide a description of these scenarios:
1. In this scenario, the mother is ineligible for a child care subsidy regardless of
hours worked (IN>E, where E denotes the income eligibility limit for a child care
subsidy). Alternatively, the mother’s income may satisfy the eligibility criteria when not
employed (IN<E), but she may be ineligible when employed part-time or full-time
(IPT>E). In these cases, subsidy receipt is not part of the mother’s choice set and she
makes a choice from the alternatives 1, 3, 4, 6, and 7 listed in Table 1. In alternative 1,
she is not employed and is therefore ineligible for a subsidy. In alternatives 3 and 6, no
paid child care is used, so no subsidy can be received. In alternatives 4 and 7, the mother
is employed and pays for child care, but is ineligible for a child care subsidy since her
income exceeds the eligibility limit.
2. In this scenario, the mother is eligible when employed part-time (IPT<E), but
ineligible when employed full-time (IFT>E). In this scenario, she makes a decision
36
among the alternatives 1-4, 6, and 7 in Table 1. In alternative (1), she is not employed
and is therefore ineligible for a subsidy. In alternatives 2 and 4, she is employed part-
time and her income is less than the eligibility limit, so she is eligible for a subsidy. In
alternatives 3 and 6, no paid child care is used, so no subsidy is received. In alternative 7,
the mother pays for child care, but she is ineligible for a child care subsidy since her
income exceeds the eligibility limit.
3. In this scenario, the mother is eligible when employed full-time (IFT<E). If the
mother’s income satisfies the eligibility criteria when she is employed full-time, it will
also satisfy it when she is employed part-time. Therefore, all seven states listed in Table
1 are in the mother’s choice set.
The price of child care that a mother faces is alternative-specific rather than just a
single variable that is invariant across alternatives. If alternatives 2 or 5 are in the
mother’s choice set, the price of child care in these alternatives is net of the subsidy
amount. The appropriate price of child care to be included for each alternative in the
model is displayed in Table A1.
Table A1
The Adjusted Price of Child Care under Each Scenario
State Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3
1 0 0 0
2 --- Ps-Ss P
s-Ss
3 0 0 0
4 Ps P
s P
s
5 --- --- Ps-Ss
6 0 0 0
7 Ps P
s P
s
37
APPENDIX B
Heterogeneity Specification
Assume that the u’s in equation (7) are drawn from independent extreme-value
distributions, and the µ’s in equations (8)-(10) are drawn from independent mean-zero
normal distributions. Further, the distribution of η in equations (7)-(10) is assumed to be
given by the following step function:
Prob(η = nm) = pm, m= 1,………,M, pm 0,
and
M
Σ pm = 1,
m=1
where nm is the mth point of support in the factor distribution, and pm is the probability
that the factor m takes on the value nm. M is the number of points in the support of the
distribution of η. The p’s, ρ, and n’s are parameters to be estimated along with other
coefficients of the explanatory variables in the model.
The n’s and p’s are parameterized as follows:
,5.0 and 1),-M2,.......,(m 5.0
)exp(1
)exp(
,5.01==
+
== M
m
m
mn
q
q
nn
and
,
)rexp(1
1
pand1M1m
)rexp(1
)rexp(
p
m
1M
1m
M
m
1M
1m
m
m
=
=
+
==
+
= ,,...,
where qm and rm are free parameters to be estimated.
Likelihood Function
Note that the total number of alternatives relevant to each mother depends on her
eligibility for a child care subsidy at different employment states. Apart from her
38
eligibility, a single mother’s contribution to the likelihood function depends on her
employment and child care payment status. There are five possible cases available to
each mother. These cases are considered below:
In case (1), the mother is employed full-time and pays for child care. In this case,
we observe the full-time wage rate and the price of child care, but do not observe the
part-time wage rate. Let Di = 1 if the mother j chooses state i, and Di = 0 otherwise.
Then the likelihood function contribution for this mother is
M
Lj = Σ pm Prj(Di | ηm, Ps*, lnWFT) Prj(Ps|ηm) Prj(lnWFT|ηm), (A1)
m=1
where Prj(Di | ηm, Ps*, lnWFT) is the probability that mother j chooses state i conditional
on the value of the discrete factor, the price of child care, and the full-time wage rate.
Prj(Ps|ηm) is the probability of observing Ps conditional on ηm, and Prj(lnWFT|ηm) is the
probability of observing lnWFT conditional on ηm.
In case (2), the mother is employed part-time and pays for child care. Therefore,
we observe the part-time wage rate and price of child care, but not the full-time wage
rate. The likelihood function contribution for this mother is
M
Lj = Σ pm Prj(Di | ηm, Ps*, lnWPT) Prj(Ps|ηm) Prj(lnWPT|ηm). (A2)
m=1
In case (3), the mother is employed full-time and does not pay for child care.
Therefore, we observe the full-time wage rate, but not the part-time wage rate and price
of child care. The likelihood function contribution for this mother is
M
Lj = Σ pm Prj(Di | ηm, lnWFT) Prj(lnWFT|ηm) (A3)
m=1
In case (4), the mother is employed part-time and does not pay for child care.
39
Therefore, we observe the part-time wage rate, but not the full-time wage rate and price
of child care. The likelihood function contribution for this mother is
M
Lj = Σ pm Prj(Di | ηm, lnWPT) Prj(lnWPT|ηm). (A4)
m=1
Finally, in case (5), the mother is not employed and does not pay for child care.
Therefore, we do not observe the full-time wage rate, the part-time wage rate, and the
price of child care. The likelihood function contribution for this mother is
M
Lj = Σ pm Prj(Di | ηm). (A5)
m=1
Below, I derive the exact form of the likelihood function contribution for cases (1)
and (5). The basic approach for other cases is similar and the exact forms are available
from the author.
The likelihood function contribution for a mother in case (1) can be rewritten as
M
Lj=Σpm Prj(Di |ηm, Ps*, lnWFT, lnWPT)Prj(Ps|ηm)Prj(lnWFT|ηm)
m=1
Prj(lnWPT|ηm)dlnWPT, (A6)
where Prj(Di | ηm, Ps*, lnWFT, lnWPT) represents the probability that mother j chooses state
i conditional on the values of η, Ps*, lnWFT, and lnWPT. Prj(Ps| ηm), Prj(lnWFT | ηm), and
Prj(lnWPT|ηm) are the probabilities of observing Ps, lnWFT, and lnWPT conditional on ηm.
The regression functions for lnWFT, and lnWPT can be specified as follows
lnWPTj = δ1PT + Rjδ2PT +µPT+ρPTηm, (A7)
lnWFTj = δ1FT + Rjδ2FT +µFT+ρFTηm, (A8)
where R is a vector of variables determining wages and δ’s are the parameters to be
estimated. Given that the u’s in equation (7) are drawn from independent extreme-value
40
distributions and that µ’s in equations (8)-(10) are drawn from independent mean-zero
normal distributions, equation (A6) can be rewritten as
M
=
m=1
Σ pm [exp{X jβi + αPiPsj* + αPTi(δ1PT+ Rjδ2PT +µPT+ρPTηm) +
αFTi lnWFTj+ ρi ηm}/ j] φ((lnWFTjδ1FT- Rjδ2FT - ρFTηm)/ σFT)
φ((PsjΣSsδsDs - XjδP - ρPηm) / σP) Prj(lnWPT|ηm) dlnWPT, (A9)
where φ is the standard normal probability density function. σFT and σFT are the standard
deviations of the µFT and µP, respectively. Prj(lnWPT|ηm) is the shorthand for Prj(δ1PT +
Rjδ2PT +µFT + ρFTηm | ηm).
K
=Σexp{X jβk+ αPkPsj* + αPTk(δ1PT + Rjδ2PT +µPT+ρPTηm)+ αFTk lnWFTj+ ρkηm},
j
k=1
with β1 0, and K is total number of alternatives relevant to the mother and can take on
the values of five, six, or seven, depending on the eligibility of mother j for a child care
subsidy as discussed in Appendix A.
Equation (A9) integrates out the distribution of ηm through a weighted sum of
probabilities using the discrete factor method. To integrate out the distribution of the
error term of lnWPT, the Gaussian Quadrature method is used. It is a convenient method
to approximate an integral accurately at a low computing cost.35 The Gaussian
Quadrature approximates an integral of the form, exp(-r2)h(r)dr, as ΣYτwτ h(rτ), where Y
is the number of points used in the approximation, wτ is the weight applied to the τth point
of support, and rτ is the τth point of support in the approximation. wτ and rτ are available
in statistical handbooks for alternative values of Y.
Note that equation (A7) has the form exp(-r2)h(r)dr, where r = µPT /(σ PT 2), and
35 See Butler and Moffitt (1982) for a detailed description of the Gaussian Quadrature Method.
41
M
h(r) = π-1/2 Σ pm [exp{X jβi +αPiPsj* +αPTi (δ1PT+ Rjδ2PT+ r2σ PT+ρPTηm)+αFTi lnWFTj
m=1
+ ρi ηm}/j]φ((lnWFTjδ1FT - R jδ2FT - ρFTηm)/ σFT) φ((PsjΣSsδsDs - XjδP -
ρPηm)/σP) dr.
Incorporating the Gaussian Qudrature into equation (A9), the likelihood function
contribution of mother j can be approximated as follows:
Lj ΣYτ ΣMm π-1/2wτ pm [exp{X jβi + αPi Psj* + αPTi (δ1PT + Rjδ2PT+ rτ2 σ PT+ρPTηm)+
αFTi lnWFTj+ ρiηm}/j] φ((lnWFTjδ1FT -R jδ2FT- ρFTηm)/ σFT) φ((PsjΣSsδsDs -
XjδP - ρPηm)/σP). (A10)
In case (5), Lj can be rewritten as
M
Lj = ∫∫∫Σ pm Prj(Di | ηm, Ps*, lnWFT, lnWPT) Prj(Ps|ηm) Prj(lnWFT|ηm) Prj(lnWPT|ηm)
m=1
dPsj dlnWFTj dlnWPTj.
Under the same similar distributional assumptions about u’s and µ’s in equations
(7)-(10), Lj can be rewritten as follows:
M
= ∫∫∫ Σ pm [exp{X jβi + αPi(ΣSsδsDs+ XjδP + µP+ρPηm)+αPTi(δ1PT+Rjδ2PT
m=1
+µPT+ρPTηm)+αFTi(δ1FT+Rjδ2FT+µFT+ρFTηm) +ρiηm}/j]
Prj(Ps|ηm)Prj(lnWFT|ηm)Prj(lnWPT|ηm) dPsj dlnWFTj dlnWPTj. (A11)
Equation (A11) integrates over the error distributions of the price of child care,
the full-time, and the part-time wage. This equation is similar to case (1) in which the
integration was necessary only for the distribution of the error term in the lnWPT
equation. Also, note that each of the integral terms in (A11) can be approximated by the
Gaussian Quadrature method since they can be represented in the form exp(-r2)h(r)dr.
Therefore, the likelihood contribution for mother j can be obtained as
42
Lj ΣY1τ1ΣY2 τ2ΣY3 τ3ΣMm -1/2)3 w τ1 w τ2w τ3 pm [exp{X jβi+αPi(ΣSsδsDs+XδP +
r τ32σ PPηm) + αPTi (δ1PT + Rjδ2PT+ r τ12σ PT + ρPTηm) +
αFTi(δ1FT + Rjδ2FT + r τ22σ FT+ρFTηm) + ρiηm}/j]. (A12)
The log-likelihood function for the full sample can be written as
N
lnL = ΣlnLj, (A13)
j=1
where Lj is the likelihood function contribution for mother j ,and N is the sample size. I
maximize equation (A13) with respect to the parameters defined in equations (4), (6),
(A8), and (A9) along with the parameters of the heterogeneity distribution.
43
APPENDIX C
Table C1
Estimates of the Wage Models
Variable Log WageFull-time Log WagePart-time
Intercept 0.433 -0.219
(1.292) (-1.518)
Age 0.201 0.223
(3.119)* (5.243)*
Age2 a -0.218 -0.435
(-4.131)* (-8.217)*
Health 0.107 0.114
(1.888)* (-2.025)*
Northeast 0.126 0.133
(4.894)* (1.942)*
Midwest 0.151 0.210
(1.215) (0.710)
South -0.123 -0.191
(-1.892)* (-1.122)
Highsch 0.317 0.145
(6.218)* (1.947)*
College 0.528 0.297
(4.646)* (2.106)*
Black -0.061 -0.056
(-0.770) (0.442)
White 0.080 0.121
(1.991)* (1.381)
Hispanic -0.024 0.049
(-0.409) (0.834)
Slfpb -0.993 -1.028
(-2.014)* (-2.909)*
Sunempb -0.241 -0.186
(1.822)* (-1.754)*
Sample Size 2,047 697
Note: t-statistics are in parentheses.
a Variable has been divided by 1,000.
b Variable has been divided by 100.
* Significant at 5% level or better.
44
Table C2
Estimates of the Child Care Price Equation
Variable Coefficient t-statistics
Intercept 0.499 (0.982)
Age 0.131 (12.223)*
Age2 a -1.767 (-1.854)*
Black -0.661 (-1.433)
White -0.521 (-1.427)
Hispanic -0.127 (-0.519)
Health -0.123 (-1.144)
Highsch 0.169 (0.665)
College 0.474 (1.931)*
Child0-5 0.044 (0.298)
Child6-12 0.353 (3.836)*
Othadult -0.289 (-1.853)*
Nonwage a 0.018 (4.508)*
Alabama 0.081 (0.241)
Arkansas -0.258 (-0.280)
Arizona 0.712 (1.227)
California 0.544 (1.463)
Colorado 0.491 (0.892)
Florida 0.054 (0.150)
Georgia 0.123 (0.144)
Hawaii 0.143 (0.735)
Iowa 0.006 (0.071)
Idaho 0.514 (0.955)
Illinois 0.067 (0.082)
Indiana -0.441 (-0.418)
Kansas -0.256 (-0.232)
Kentucky -0.649 (-0.724)
Louisiana -0.591 (-0.423)
Massachusetts 0.567 (1.392)
Maryland -0.157 (-0.182)
Maine -0.152 (-0.189)
Michigan 0.279 (1.014)
Minnesota 0.028 (1.101)
Missouri 0.224 (0.243)
Mississippi -0.199 (-0.863)
Montana -0.469 (-0.511)
North Carolina 0.152 (0.163)
North Dakota -0.457 (-0.444)
New Jersey 0.493 (1.714)*
New Mexico 0.018 (0.030)
Nevada -0.518 (-0.532)
New York 0.425 (1.819)*
Ohio -0.451 (-0.552)
Pennsylvania 0.295 (0.472)
South Carolina -0.754 (-0.629)
45
Tennessee -0.076 (-0.789)
Texas 0.513 (0.991)
Virginia -0.222 (-0.737)
Washington 0.265 (0.813)
Wisconsin 0.191 (1.831)*
West Virginia -0.539 (-0.572)
Sample Size 1,679
a Variable has been divided by 1,000.
* Significant at 5% level or better.
46
Table C3
Maximum Likelihood Estimates of the Discrete Choice Model
Variable State 1
Work=No
Paid care=No
Subsidy = No
State 2
Work=Part-time
Paid care=Yes
Subsidy=Yes
State 3
Work=Part-time
Paid care=No
Subsidy=No
State 4
Work=Part-time
Paid care=Yes
Subsidy=No
State 5
Work=Full-time
Paid care=Yes
Subsidy=Yes
State 6
Work=Full-time
Paid care=No
Subsidy=No
State 7
Work=Full-time
Paid care=Yes
Subsidy=No
Intercept --- 1.088 -1.271 -.889 -0.979 -1.037 0.714
(2.991* (1.808)*(-1.485) (-1.604) (-1.082) (1.477)*
Age --- -0.102 0.101 0.112 0.101 0.011 0.087
(-2.123)*(1.992)*(1.342) (1.218) (0.311) (3.122)*
Northeast --- 0.886 0.762 0.563 0.433 0.564 0.488
(3.178)*(2.165)*(1.973)*(2.079)*(0.830) (2.614)*
Midwest --- 0.412 0.702 0.615 0.921 1.312 0.963
(0.740) (1.937)*(2.113)*(3.082)*(2.310)*(2.776)*
South --- -0.227 -0.431 0.253 -0.592 -0.612 0.416
(-1.049) (-1.212) (0.591) (-1.781)*(-0.939) (0.813)
Black --- -0.542 -0.483 -0.191 0.614 0.892 -0.104
(-1.717)*(-1.314) (-0.830) (0.926) (1.268) (-1.322)
White --- 0.582 0.362 0.243 0.886 1.361 0.524
(0.872) (1.281) (1.877)*(2.653)*(1.931)*(1.864)*
Hispanic --- -0.793 -0.555 -0.280 -0.721 -0.602 -0.723
(-1.911)*(-0.740) (-2.194)*(-1.146) (-0.864) (-2.059)*
Health --- -0.526 -0.212 0.113 -0.351 -0.159 0.446
(-0.709) (-0.629) (0.767) (0.792) (-0.227) (1.243)
Highsch --- 0.943 0.246 0.769 0.653 1.413 0.912
(2.435)*(1.814)*(3.117)*(2.142)*(2.544)*(2.561)*
College --- 0.996 0.669 0.997 0.669 1.832 0.997
(3.752)*(1.494) (2.544)*(1.881)*(2.663)*(2.523)*
Nonwagea--- -0.801 -0.508 -0.182 -0.251 0.413 -0.227
48
(-2.111)*(-1.913)*(-1.956)*(-1.514) (1.118) (1.504)
Child0-5 --- 0.214 0.288 -0.025 -0.102 -0.177 0.067
(0.489) (0.873) (-0.443) (0.527) (-0.393) (0.591)
Child6-12 --- 0.418 0.302 -0.066 -0.415 -0.714 0.346
(1.332) (1.816)*(-1.092) (-1.569) (-1.240) (1.352)
Othadult --- 0.112 0.182 -0.141 -0.109 -0.349 -0.412
(1.163) (2.405)*(-1.241) (-1.368) (-1.291) (-2.419)*
Pricechild Care --- -0.198
(2.014)*
--- -0.198
(2.014)*
-0.103
(1.452)
--- -0.103
(1.452)
Log Wagepart-time --- 0.229
(1.942)*
0.229
(1.942)*
0.229
(1.942)*
--- --- ---
Log Wagefull-time --- --- --- --- 1.109
(4.508)*
1.109
(4.508)*
1.109
(4.508)*
Number of
observations
4,029
Log likelihood -10,871.1
Note: t-statistics are in parentheses. State 1 is the omitted category.
a Variable is divided by 1000.
* Significant at the 5% level or better.
49
Table C4
Estimates of the Heterogeneity Parameters
State Factor Loading
State 1
---
State 2 -2.771
(1.424)
State 3 -4.162
(-2.108)*
State 4 -1.994
(-2.753)*
State 5 0.969
(3.011)*
State 6 -1.344
(2.659)*
State 7 2.418
(1.813)*
ρP -0.347
(-2.347)*
ρFT 0.889
(4.461)*
ρPT 0.591
(3.870)*
Mass Points Probability Weights
Support #1, n1 -0.500 5.65%
Support #2, n2 0.273
(2.691)*
71.56%
(13.70)*
Support #3, n3 0.341
(6.194)*
21.51%
(11.83)*
Support #4, n4 0.500 1.28%
*Coefficient is significant at 5 percent level or better.
50
References
Administration for Children and Families (1999). “Access to Child Care for Low-Income
Working Families,” http://www.acf.dhhs.gov/news/ccreport.htm, Washington D.C.
Anderson, Patricia M., and Philip B. Levine (2000). “Child Care and Mothers’
Employment Decisions,” in David E. Card and Rebecca M. Blank (eds.) Finding Jobs:
Work and Welfare Reform, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Averett, Susan L., H. Elizabeth Peters, and Donald M. Waldman (1997). “Tax Credits,
Labor Supply, and Child Care,” Review of Economics and Statistics 79 (1), February:
125-135.
Barrow, Lisa (1996). “An Analysis of Women’s Labor Force Participation Following
First Birth,” Working Paper, Princeton University, June.
Berger, Mark C., and Dan A. Black (1992). “Child Care Subsidies, Quality of Care, and
the Labor Supply of Low-Income Single Mothers,” Review of Economics and Statistics
74 (4), November: 635-642.
Blank, Rebecca M. (1988).”Simultaneously Modeling the Supply of Weeks and Hours of
Work among Female Household Heads,” Journal of Labor Economics 6 (2), April: 177-
204.
Blank, Rebecca M., David E. Card, and Philip K. Robins (2000). “Financial Incentives
for Increasing Work and Income Among Low-Income Families,” in David E. Card and
Rebecca M. Blank (eds.) Finding Jobs: Work and Welfare Reform, New York: Russell
Sage Foundation.
Blau, David M., and Philip K. Robins (1988). “Child Care Costs and Family Labor
Supply,” Review of Economics and Statistics 70 August: 374-381.
Blau, David M, and Philip K. Robins (1991). “Child care Demand and Labor Supply of
Young Mothers Over Time,” Demography 28 (3), August: 333-352.
Blau, David M., and Alison P. Hagy (1998). “The Demand for Quality in Child Care,”
Journal of Political Economy 106 (1), February: 104-146.
Blau, David M. (2000). “Child Care Subsidy Programs, “National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper 7806.
Blau, David M. (2001). “The Child Care Problem: An Economic Analysis,” Russell Sage
Foundation: New York.
51
Blau, David M., and Erdal Tekin (2001). “The Determinants and Consequences of Child
Care Subsidies for Single Mothers,” Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) Working
Paper 383, November.
Butler, J. S., and Robert Moffitt (1982). “A Computationally Efficient Quadrature
Procedure for the One-Factor Multinomial Probit Model,” Econometrica 50 (3), 761-764.
Cain, G. G. (1976). “The Challenge of Segmented Labor Market Theories to Orthodox
Theory: A Survey,” Journal of Economic Literature 14: 1215-1257.
Chaplin, Duncan D., Philip K. Robins, Sandra L. Hofferth, Douglas A. Wissoker, and
Paul Fronstin (1999). “The Price Elasticity of Child Care Demand: A Sensitivity
Analysis,” Working Paper, Washington D.C., The Urban Institute.
Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives (2000). “2000 Green
Book,” Washington D.C., May.
Connelly, Rachel (1990). “The Cost of Child Care and Single Mothers: Its Effect on
Labor Force Participation and AFDC Participation,” Discussion Paper 920-900, Institute
for Research on Poverty.
Connelly, Rachel (1992). “The Effects of Child Care Costs on Married Women’s Labor
Force Participation,” Review of Economics and Statistics 74 (1), February: 83-90.
Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel (2000). “Marital Status and Full-time/Part-time
Work Status in Child Care Choices,” Working Paper, W.E. Upjohn Institute, March.
Dickens, W. T., and K. Lang (1985). “A Test of Dual Labor Market Theory,” American
Economic Review 75: 792-805.
Fraker, Thomas, and Robert Moffitt (1988). “The Effect of Food Stamps on Labor
Supply: A Bivariate Selection Model,” Journal of Public Economics, 35: 1-24.
Fronstin, Paul, and Doug Wissoker (1995). “The Effects of the Availability of Low-Cost
Child Care on the Labor-Supply of Low-Income Women,” Working Paper, Urban
Institute, Washington D.C., January.
Gelbach, Jonah B. (1999). “How Large an Effect Do Child Care Costs Have on Single
Mothers’ Labor Supply? Evidence Using Access to Free Public Schooling,” Working
Paper, Department of Economics, University of Maryland, College Park, December.
Han, Wen-Jui, and Jane Waldfogel (1999). “The Effect of Child Care Costs on
Employment of Single and Married Mothers: Evidence from the Current Population
Survey,” Working Paper, School of Social Work, Columbia University, New York, July.
52
Heckman, James J., and Burton Singer (1984). “A Method for Minimizing the Impact of
Distributional Assumptions in Econometric Models for Duration Data,” Econometrica
52, March: 271-320.
Hofferth, Sandra, L., April Brayfield, Sharon Deich, and Pamela Holcomb (1991).
“National Child Care Survey, 1990,” Washington D.C.: Urban Institute, Report 91-5.
Hotchkiss, Julie L. (1991). “The Definition of Part-time Employment: A Switching
Regression Model with Unknown Sample Selection,” International Economic Review 32
(4), November: 899-917.
Hoynes, Hilary W. (1996). “Welfare Transfers in Two-Parent Families: Labor Supply
and Welfare Participation Under AFDC-UP,” Econometrica 64 (2) March: 295-332.
Hotz, V. Joseph, and M. Rebecca Kilburn (1994). “Regulating Child Care: The Effects of
State Regulations on Child Care Demand and Its Costs,” Working Paper, RAND, Santa
Monica, CA, August.
Hu, WeiYin (1999). “Child Support, Welfare Dependency, and Women’s Labor Supply,”
Journal of Human Resources, 34 (1)”71-103.
Keane, Michael, and Robert Moffitt (1998). “A Structural Model of Multiple Welfare
Program Participation and Labor Supply,” International Economic Review 39 (3),
August: 553-589.
Kimmel, Jean (1998). “Child Care Costs as a Barrier to Employment for Single and
Married Mothers,” Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (2), May: 287-299.
Michalopoulos, Charles, Philip K. Robins, and Irwin Garfinkel (1992). “A Structural
Model of Labor Supply and Child Care Demand,” Journal of Human Resources 27 (1),
Winter: 166-203.
Michalopoulos, Charles, and Philip K. Robins (2000). “Employment and Child-Care
Choices in Canada and the United States,” Canadian Journal of Economics 33 (2),
May:435-470.
Mocan, H. Naci, and Erdal Tekin (in press). “Nonprofit Sector and Part-time Work: An
Analysis of Employer-Employee Matched Data of Child Care Workers,” Review of
Economics and Statistics.
Moffitt, Robert (1983). “An Economic Model of Welfare Stigma,” American Economic
Review, (73) December: 1023-1035.
Mroz, Thomas A. (1999). “Discrete Factor Approximations in Simultaneous Equation
Models: Estimating the Impact of a Dummy Endogenous Variable on a Continuous
Outcome,” Journal of Econometrics 92: 233-274.
53
Powell, Lisa M. (1998). “Part-time Versus Full-time Work and Child Care Costs:
Evidence for Married Mothers,” Applied Economics 30 (4): 503-511.
Powell, Lisa M. (2002). “Joint Labor Supply and Childcare Choice Decisions of Married
Mothers,” Journal of Human Resources, 37 (1), Winter: 106-128.
Ribar, David (1992). “Child Care and Labor Supply of Married Women: Reduced Form
Evidence,” Journal of Human Resources 27 (1), Winter: 134-165.
Ribar, David (1995). “A Structural Model of Child Care and the Labor Supply of Married
Women,” Journal of Labor Economics 13 (3), July: 558-597.
54
... Larger elasticities are also reported Michalopoulos and Robins (2000), who find an elasticity of -1.0 for center-based care but no effect for other child care arrangements in a sample of married parents with children under age five. Finally, in a related line of work, Tekin (2007) generates an elasticity of paying for child care of -0.47 for single mothers with at least one child under age 13. ...
... Finally, Baker et al. (n.d.) study of universal child care in Quebec generates 46 A number of other data sources have been used in this literature. Tekin (2007) uses the National Survey of America's Families to examine single mothers with children under age 13, allowing for differences across full-and part-time work. He finds employment elasticities of -0.15 for full-time work and -0.07 for part-time work. ...
... Despite the large number of studies, there is still uncertainty about the size of this elasticity. Blau (2001); Morrissey (2017); Tekin (2007); Herbst (2010) each provide a broad review of the literature and summarize the range of estimates. Blau and Currie (2006) report the range of estimates as between 0.04 and -1.26. ...
... To examine childcare subsidy receipt, five studies used administrative data (Ficano et al., 2006;Ha, 2009;Ha & Miller, 2015;Huston et al., 2001;Showalter et al., 2019). Other studies used self-reported receipt of childcare subsidy (Ahn, 2012;Blau & Tekin, 2007;Danziger et al., 2004;Gennetian et al., 2004;Marshall et al., 2013;Meyers et al., 2002;Press et al., 2006;Tekin, 2007aTekin, , 2007b, or state-level childcare policies or expenditures on subsidies (Bainbridge et al., 2003;Black, Devereux, Løken, & Salvanes, 2014;Herbst, 2008;Queralt et al., 2000). ...
... Two studies used international or partially international samples, including one set in Norway (Black, Devereux, Løken, & Salvanes, 2014) and one in both the U.S. and Canada (Gennetian et al., 2004). Six studies used national samples from the U.S. (Ahn, 2012;Bainbridge et al., 2003;Blau & Tekin, 2007;Herbst, 2008;Tekin, 2007aTekin, , 2007b, and the remaining used samples from individual states within the U.S. (Danziger et al., 2004;Ficano et al., 2006;Gennetian et al., 2004;Ha, 2009;Ha & Miller, 2015;Huston et al., 2001;Marshall et al., 2013Marshall et al., , 2013Meyers et al., 2002;Press et al., 2006;Queralt et al., 2000;Showalter et al., 2019). ...
Article
The current study sought to understand existing literature regarding the relationship between early childhood education and care policies in the U.S. (i.e., childcare subsidies, Head Start, and universal pre-k) and family violence (i.e., child maltreatment and IPV). We examined articles that assessed either of these two family violence outcomes or their related risk factors, including food insecurity, employment, poverty, and parental mental health issues. We conducted a rapid review of literature from the following academic databases: Web of Science, Academic Search Complete, and JSTOR. We examined peer-reviewed journal articles that were published in English between the years of 1996 to 2021. Few studies have investigated the associations between early childhood education and care policies and family violence outcomes. However, of those studies that have examined associations between early childhood education and care policies and family violence outcomes, there is promising evidence to support these policies as a violence prevention strategy.
... We find that some of the variables operate as we predicted. A higher ratio of adult women to men is associated with better access to child care, likely due to greater demand for child care among working women in a single parent family (Tekin, 2007). For similar reasons, the percentage of children with duo-working parents is also positively associated with child care access. ...
... Moreover, parents who have multiple children (at shorter intervals) may display more traditional gender role expectations for mothers. In addition, single mothers may need specific childcare strategies and excluding this group may have affected the results (Tekin, 2007). It would, therefore, be interesting to address in future research to what extent migrant-native uptake gaps and the impact of increasing local childcare coverage are related to household composition. ...
Article
Full-text available
Research indicates that the uptake of formal childcare for children under age 3 is lower among migrant origin parents than among native parents in most European countries, and that these differentials extend to the second generation. Despite considerable investments in formal childcare availability in many European countries, it remains unclear whether and to what extent expanding local childcare availability effectively diminishes migrant-native uptake differentials due to the lack of longitudinal research. Therefore, this study assesses for Belgium to what extent expansions in childcare availability within municipalities in the period 2010–2014 has increased the uptake of formal childcare for children under age 3 among households where the mother has a second generation Southern European, Maghreb or Turkish background, versus no migration background. We use longitudinal census and register data for Belgium that were linked to longitudinal tax return data on childcare expenses and municipality-level data on childcare availability for children aged 0–3. Our results show that Southern European and Turkish origin mothers become more likely to use formal childcare when childcare places become more widely available within their municipalities, but also that the uptake gap with native mothers persists, since there is no differential effect of increasing local childcare availability. Since local childcare expansions entail a slightly stronger increase in formal childcare uptake among Maghreb origin mothers compared to native mothers, this results in slightly decreasing migrant-native uptake gaps, although considerable uptake gaps remain. To our knowledge, this is the first longitudinal study addressing the relationship between local childcare availability and uptake differentials by migration background. This study can inspire avenues for follow-up research which could provide additional insight into the possible mechanisms behind the varying effects of increasing local childcare availability by migration background and the persisting migrant-native uptake gaps.
... Earlier studies tend to find large favorable effects (Blau and Robins 1988;Ribar 1992;Anderson and Levine 1999), while later papers more frequently document smaller or null impact (Fitzpatrick 2010(Fitzpatrick , 2012Havnes and Mogstad 2011;Cascio and Schanzenbach 2013;Bick 2016) perhaps due to declining elasticities over time as different policies have been introduced and existing policies have become more widespread. There is relatively more established consensus on the finding that childcare policies are likely more effective for low-income single mothers (Kimmel 2005;Tekin 2007;Cascio 2009). See Olivetti and Petrongolo (2017) and Morrissey (2017) for recent reviews of this literature. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper presents new evidence on the causal link between fertility and female labor supply by focusing on how informal employment interacts with maternal labor supply. We employ an IV strategy based on an unused data source for twin births in Turkey|a large middle-income country with extensive labor informality. We find that, following the first birth, female labor supply declines significantly and mothers who drop out of labor force are mostly the informally employed ones. This is contrary to the perception that informal jobs might be easier to sustain during motherhood as they are more flexible. Following further increases in family size, formally employed mothers start dropping out of labor force and their hours of work also decline. Higher fertility also leads to lower wages and lower job search intensity among mothers. We document substantial differences between maternal versus paternal labor supply in response to changes in family size. Unlike mothers, fathers increase their labor supply, which mostly comes from elevated informal employment|possibly due to a decline in their reservation wages. As a result, wages decline, hours of work increase, and job search activity shifts from formal to informal search methods for fathers. These results suggest that higher fertility might be associated with increased vulnerabilities and high labor income risks in countries with pervasive labor informality. Our estimates are robust to using alternative IV specifications based on gender composition of siblings.
... Thus, household income and price of services act as budgetary constraints, analysed in conjunction with the economic gains derived from the mothers working. The cost of care services acts as a weighting factor in decision-making, one that is especially relevant in terms of the mother staying in the labour market or leaving it (Blau & Robins, 1988;Connely, 1992;Ribar, 1995;Del Boca & Vuri, 2007;Tekin, 2007;Van Gameren & Ooms, 2009;Borra, 2010). In terms of the services offered, some of the research has highlighted how the quality of the care services available is also a determining factor in the decision to outsource care or not (Alam, 2020). ...
Article
Full-text available
Access to early child education services has been proven to be an efficient tool in fighting educational inequalities. However, while wealthier families are likely to use childcare services, disadvantaged children tend to be left out. Research has explained this effect, known as Mathew Effect, and has studied both the constraints in the availability and affordability of childcare services, and the cultural norms surrounding motherhood. This paper aims to highlight other factors that also explain the Mathew Effect from a public policy perspective, beyond the economic barriers that limit access to formal childcare services. Through 34 interviews with mothers who have children between one and three years of age who attend both state and private nurseries in the city of Barcelona, we examine the characteristics of regulated childcare services and the objective factors of those mothers’ everyday lives in order to understand the decision-making processes involved in choosing childcare for the under-threes. The results indicate that sliding-scale pricing has allowed mothers with low incomes to access state nursery schools, while the quality of the services offered has served to attract the middle and upper classes. However, early childhood care services have not been adapted to the needs of working-class mothers who, although not being in a situation of social vulnerability, cannot afford private nurseries because of their high costs.
... Our paper, firstly, contributes to the broad literature that investigate the factors affecting female labor force participation such as social norms, religiosity and culture (Akerlof and Kranton, 2000;Fernandez, 2007;Fernández and Fogli, 2009;Dildar, 2015;Akyol and Okten, 2019), fertility and motherhood (Angrist and Evans, 1998;Cristia, 2008;Aguero and Marks, 2008;Lundborg et al., 2017 andKleven et al., 2019), availability and cost of childcare (Baum, 2002;Berlinski and Galiani, 2007;Tekin, 2007;Fitzpatrick, 2010;Berlinski et al., 2011;Brilli et al., 2016;Morrissey, 2017;Müller and Wrohlich, 2020). We complement this literature by providing evidence that the proximity of the grandmothers can increase women's labor force participation through their childcare provision or impede their labor force participation by imposing prevalent unequal gender norms on women. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This paper investigates the causal effects of grandmothers' geographical proximity on the labor supply decisions of married women with young children by using data from the Turkish Family Structure Survey. We deal with the reverse causality and endogeneity problems arising from mothers' and grandmothers' joint location and labor supply decisions by implementing a two-stage least squares estimation method using the number of alive grandmothers as an instrument. We argue that although grandmothers' proximity can increase mothers' labor supply through their free and flexible child care services, geographically close grandmothers can better impose the traditional gender norms prevalent in Turkey, which will decrease mothers' labor supply. The overall effect depends on the relative size of these two opposing factors. Our results suggest that living in the same neighborhood to grandmothers increases the probability of labor force participation as well as the employment rates of women with young children by 18.2 ppt and 16.4 ppt, respectively. We also show that grandmothers' proximity does not have a significant effect on the labor supply and the employment probability of men with young children and women with no children or older children. In addition, we find that grandfathers' proximity does not affect the labor market outcomes of women with young children. Therefore, we conclude that grandmothers' child care provision drives these results, and the effect of the "traditional gender norm" channel on average is small. JEL Classification: J13, J20, J21
Preprint
Full-text available
In this paper, we consider access to daycare as a matching problem. We propose mar- ket design models to define assignment mechanisms and analyse the consequences of design choices in a field experiment. The problem is akin to school choice, but specific constraints affect the definition and scope of stable matchings. Our algorithms provide Student Optimal Fair Assignments (SOFA) in different versions of the problem. Our analysis focuses on the Matthew effect, demonstrating how design and policy choices influence it. Our tools promote fairness and transparency in assignment processes.
Article
Participation in non‐parental child care arrangements is now the norm for preschool‐age children in the U.S. However, child care services are becoming increasingly expensive for many families, and quality is highly uneven across providers and sectors, raising questions about the impact of child care costs and quality on parental employment and child development. The U.S. policy landscape is dominated by three policies that subsidize costs for low‐income families or attempt to improve the safety and quality of providers: the Child Care and Development Fund, regulations, and quality rating and improvement systems. In this paper, I provide a thorough review of the evidence on each policy, focusing on how they influence a wide range of family and provider outcomes. The paper begins with a detailed description of the structure and functioning of the child care market, using the most up‐to‐date data on families’ utilization of care services and provider characteristics. I then draw on a diverse set of studies across multiple fields to summarize the evidence on the impact of child care policy. In the final section of the paper, I offer recommendations for future research in each policy area.
Article
Full-text available
Executive Summary Out of necessity or choice, mothers are working outside the home in greater numbers than ever before. In 1996, three out of four mothers with children between 6 and 17 were in the labor force, compared to one in four in 1965. Two-thirds of mothers with children under six now work. Reliable, high-quality child care is critical to these mothers' productivity at work, as well as to their children's health and intellectual development. With the unemployment rate at 4.2 percent, a 30-year low, many employers are having difficulty finding the workers they need. Women are expected to make up over 60 percent of new entrants to the labor force between 1994 and 2005. Welfare reform makes it likely that the demand for quality child care will be even greater in the future. Unfortunately, the cost of child care is often beyond the means of low and moderate-income working families, including those that have never been on welfare.
Article
Full-text available
This paper empirically analyzes family demands for market and nonmarket child care services and the impact of these demands on the work effort of married women. The paper first develops a general model of child care and labor force participation. The model predicts that higher wages increase the likelihood of labor force participation and that higher costs decrease the likelihood of child care utilization. The paper then develops a three-equation, reduced-form econometric specification of the general model. The equations in the specification are estimated simultaneously using 1985 data from the Survey of Income Program Participation. The estimates reveal that the cost of market child care has a strong negative effect on the labor supply of married women.
Article
Full-text available
This paper specifies and estimates a structural model in which the decision to purchase market child care-and the quality purchased-is made simultaneously with the employment decision of the mother. Separate analyses are performed for married mothers and single mothers. The structural estimates are used to simulate the effects and costs of changes in the federal child care tax credit. The simulations indicate that a refundable child care tax credit would distribute child care benefits more equally across the population by increasing the shares of subsidies received by low-income families, and would induce a considerable increase in expenditures on market child care. Labor supply also increases, but by considerably less than child care expenditures. A surprising result is that, despite large increases in child care expenditures, the overall quality of child care does not change very much. The primary beneficiaries of more generous subsidies are current users of high quality free care who are induced to purchase slightly higher-quality market care.
Article
This paper examines the impact of childcare prices and wage rates on the joint employment and childcare mode (center, sitter, relative, and husband) choice decisions of married mothers by estimating both a mixed logit and universal logit choice model. Data are drawn from the 1988 Canadian National Child Care Survey and the 1988 Labour Market Activity Survey. The estimation results show that wages have a positive impact on the probability of choosing any of the working states and that childcare prices for center, sitter, and relative care reduce the probability of working and using each respective mode of care. Sensitivity analyses reveal that the wage elasticity for employment is fairly robust across model specifications, while the own-price elasticity of childcare is sensitive to model specification, differing identifying assumptions in the estimation of childcare price equations, and sample selection. The simulation results show that differences exist in the degree to which government subsidies in the form of wage subsidies, targeted childcare subsidies, or unconditional childcare subsidies, impact on labor supply decisions and decisions to substitute across different modes of care by those mothers already in the labor market.
Article
This study evaluates the potential effectiveness of alternative child support policies in reducing welfare program participation. Employing longitudinal data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, the analysis addresses the simultaneity of women's decisions regarding welfare participation, labor force participation, and annual hours of work following marital breakup. The estimation framework accounts for the endogeneity of child support payments with female labor supply and for the selection bias due to differential rates of remarriage among divorced/separated women. Results show that higher child support payments would (i) decrease welfare participation and (ii) increase average hours of work. The empirical estimates are used to assess the potential effects of adopting alternative child support policies such as the Wisconsin child support assurance system. These results suggest that large potential welfare cost savings are attainable but significant reductions in welfare participation rates would only be achieved through substantial improvements in child support enforcement or through government-assured child support payments.
Article
We estimate a model of demand for quality-related attributes of child care: group size, staff/child ratio, and provider training. The model is estimated jointly with equations for mode, expenditure on and hours of care, and the mother's labor supply. The results show that a lower price of child care in a particular mode leads to substitution toward that mode and an increase in the use of paid child care. A decrease in the price of care causes an increase in hours of care demanded and a decrease in the demand for quality-related attributes. Income effects on demand for quality are small.
Article
This paper explores the differential nature of labor-supply decisions regarding weeks o f work per year and hours of work per week among female household hea ds. A model of labor supply that separates the weeks/hours decision i s presented and estimated, allowing for simultaneity in the weeks/hou rs decision, as well as for the presence of either fixed costs or wee ks and hours constraints. The results indicate that not only are week s and hours decisions separate from the labor-market participation de cision, but they are also quite different from each other, although t hey appear to be simultaneously determined. Copyright 1988 by University of Chicago Press.