ArticlePDF Available

Employee benefits: Literature review and emerging issues

Authors:

Abstract

Many have noted the lack of human resource management research on employee benefits, which is surprising because employer-sponsored benefits are a primary concern of executives and employees alike. Moreover, of special interest to scholars, benefits provide a unique opportunity to examine fundamental theoretical and empirical questions about employee behavior and contemporary employment relationships. This paper provides a foundation for such research by providing an overview of the context from which U.S. employer-provided benefit programs evolved and the contemporary state of benefits research in human resource management. Propositions related to primary employee benefit research are provided.
Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues
James H. Dulebohn
a,
, Janice C. Molloy
a
, Shaun M. Pichler
a
, Brian Murray
b
a
Michigan State University, School of Labor & Industrial Relations, 412 South Kedzie Hall, East Lansing, MI 48824, USA
b
College of Business, University of Dallas, 1845 East Northgate Drive, Irving, TX 75062, USA
article info abstract
Available online xxxx Many have noted the lack of human resource management research on employee benets,
which is surprising because employer-sponsored benets are a primary concern of executives
and employees alike. Moreover, of special interest to scholars, benets provide a unique
opportunity to examine fundamental theoretical and empirical questions about employee
behavior and contemporary employment relationships. This paper provides a foundation for
such research by providing an overview of the context from which U.S. employer-provided
benet programs evolved and the contemporary state of benets research in human resource
management. Propositions related to primary employee benet research are provided.
© 2008 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Employee benets
Health care
Retirement
Pension
Work-family
The implications of employee benet decisions are among the most relevant for remaining competitive in the labor market.
From a total compensation perspective, indirect compensation or benets plays a signicant factor in the attraction and retention
of employees. This is particularly true for costly benets such as health insurance and pension plans, the provision of which is an
increasingly important issue to both employers and employees. Executives have long been concerned about the costs of providing
competitive employee benets (Conference Board, 2007). Typically, benet costs comprise about one-third of an organization's
total labor costs and such costs have steadily increased (Hewitt, 2002). As such, benet decisions often have a signicant effect on a
company's bottom line. For example, the decision to promise current employees health benets or certain types of pension plans
following their retirement has long-term nancial implications. The general managerial focus and concern regarding benets such
as health care is reected in statements by CEOs such as Bill Ford who said: Clearly, it's our biggest issue we have, bar none. The
health care issue is one that I nd intractable(Wilson, 2003).
In spite of the prominence of benet issues to organizations, when reviewing the human resource management (HRM)
literature, there is a surprising general absence of attention given to employee benets. Indeed, in their analysis of gaps between
HRM academic research and practitioner interests, Deadrick and Gibson (2007) found that the largest gap was in the areas of
compensation and benets. While employee benets are recognized as a major area of HRM practice, HRM researchers generally
have not taken adequate steps to provide research in this area to inform practice. In an era when HRM scholars wish for greater
inuence with executives, greater attention by HRM researchers to these areas of concern among organizational leaders can
contribute to elevating the role and perceived value of HRM.
The purpose of this article is to begin to address this academic research-practice gap by identifying core topics in the benets
literature, and for each topic, identifying emerging issues for future benets research. To this end, ve benet topics are identied:
(1) the context of employer-sponsored benets, (2) benets satisfaction, (3) pensions, (4) health care, and (5) work family benets.
For each topic, extant research is examined, and future research propositions are provided. The paper continues by dening
benets, the scope of the paper, and how welfare capitalism has inuenced benets.
Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 517 432 3984.
E-mail address: dulebohn@msu.edu (J.H. Dulebohn).
HUMRES-00297; No of Pages 18
1053-4822/$ see front matter © 2008 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Human Resource Management Review
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/humres
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
1. Context: denitions, scope, and welfare capitalism
During the 20th century, employers increased the economic security of employees by providing, in exchange for labor, benets
in addition to direct compensation. Apart from direct compensation, benets encompass all other inducements and services
provided by an employer to employees (BLS, 2005). Like other HRM policies, employer-sponsored benets have been shaped by
social, cultural, and legislative forces (Kaufman, 2004). To maintain focus, this manuscript addresses voluntary employer-provided
benets for individuals in the U.S. Employer-provided benets in countries other than the U.S. are not addressed given the
signicant variation in legislation, norms, and implementation. Similarly, statutory benets that federal and state governments
require employers to provide to U.S.-based employees (e.g., workers' compensation insurance), are not addressed given the
signicant variation in legislation, cost-containment strategies, and implementation approaches across states.
Most industrialized nations assure the welfare of citizens through government-sponsored systems that provide for the health
and safety of citizens, protecting them from consequences of economic uctuations. In contrast, in the U.S. a system of welfare
capitalism emerged whereby employers, rather than the government, played a primary role in assuring the health and welfare of
employees and their families. Welfare capitalism encompassed a wide range of private, rm-level social and benet policies,
including employee representation, recreation, stock ownership, and benets relating to retirement, sickness, paid time off, and
unemployment (see Jacoby, 1997).
Prior to the Great Depression of the 1930s, welfare capitalism was centered in high wage industries. Accordingly, relatively few
workers were provided employer-sponsored benets in addition to direct compensation. The Depression brought the inadequacies
of the welfare capitalism that existed at the time into sharp relief. In response, New Deal policymakers joined labor leaders and
reform activists to establish the basis of the modern U.S. welfare state. Private employer benets, subsidized by tax incentives,
became an essential supplement to the basic government safety net and a key bargaining chip in negotiations with organized labor.
Welfare capitalism expanded beginning with the economic recovery after the Depression and this expansion was supported by
government legislation and workforce unionization.
Today the U.S. continues to retain aspects of welfare capitalism, but what has changed is that organizations face more intense
competitive pressures than when welfare capitalism rst emerged. The benets responsibilities employers shoulder today are
increasingly portrayed as a burden given the competitive pressures brought about by the globalization of product and service
markets, demographic shifts in the workforce (e.g., the baby boomer generation nearing retirement being followed by a much
smaller base of employees to potentially fund retirement benets), health care ination rates that outpace ination and growth,
and uncertain immigration policies. Such strain has led to discussion of shifting responsibility for major benets such as retirement
savings and health care from employers to employees as well as to the government.
2. Satisfaction with employee benet offerings
A number of factors have contributed to employer provision of non-mandatory benets such as health insurance and pension
plans. These include self interest of the decision makers, union bargaining, tax advantages provided to companies by the federal
government for offering certain benets, the need to be competitive and retain employees, and union avoidance. The logic
underlying employer strategies to voluntarily provide benets suggests that benet offerings are associated with employee benet
satisfaction, which in turn is associated with attitudes and behaviors that serve the employer's interests (Harris & Fink, 1994). The
implied process, based on social exchange, is that when employees are satised with benets provided to them, they are
committed to the employer, remain with the employer, and perform their jobs well, which in turn leads to strong organizational
performance. Benet satisfaction has been one area that has received some research attention by HRM scholars.
One might expect employee satisfaction to be related to the actuarial value of benets and the level (i.e., amount and type of
benets) of a benets package to be positively associated with employee satisfaction (Micelli & Lane, 1991). Scholars have studied
the relationship between benet level and employee satisfaction with the benets package (e.g., Dreher, Ash, & Bretz, 1988) and,
despite its intuitive appeal, such research does not support that the level of benets offered and satisfaction with those benets are
positively associated. This paradoxical nding prompted Gerhart and Milkovich (1992) to state:
The state of knowledge about the inuence of benets on employee attitudes and behaviors is dismal. Studies
examining the links between the forms and levels of benet coverage with valued outcomes (e.g., turnover, attraction)
offer potential important contributions to our understanding of employment relationships.(p. 541)
To begin to disentangle factors underlying the paradoxical nding that the actuarial-value of benets and employees' benet
satisfaction are not correlated, scholars have examined three distinct elements of benets: the benet offering construct,
antecedents and moderators of benet satisfaction, and organizational outcomes associated with benet satisfaction.
2.1. Benet satisfaction construct
Employee satisfaction has historically been conceptualized as a uni-dimensional construct that captures the value, or level, of
benets (Dreher et al., 1988). In this line of research, the level of benet offerings has been assessed with a four-item benet scale
embedded in the Pay Satisfaction Questionnaire (PSQ) (Heneman & Schwab, 1985). Items on this benet scale include satisfaction
with my benet package,’‘the value of my benets,amount the company pays toward my benets,and the number of benets I
2J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
receive.Advantages of operationalizating benets as part of the PSQ include that this approach allows measurement of benets
within the context of compensation, is distinct from pay-related scales, and consistently exhibits high internal consistency (i.e.,
coefcient alpha values greater than .85) (Williams, Malos, & Palmer, 2002).
Later, with the onslaught of changes in benet delivery systems (e.g., exible benet programs), Williams et al. (2002)
conceptualized and validated a benet offering construct consisting of two dimensions. One dimension related to benetlevel,
reecting the value of benet plans (e.g., levels of coverage, nancial payments provided). The new dimension related to benet
system satisfaction which reected employee perceptions of the system used to deliver such benets (e.g., communications, billing
support, ease of use). Whereas the benetlevel dimension focused on the specications of the benet plans, the system dimension
reected the employee's perceptions of how benets were administered.
Given that perceptions of other HRM practices may be inuenced by both the content of the HRM practice and administration/
delivery of the practice, the Williams et al. (2002) perspective may be expanded to compare with other HRM practices. Indeed, an
opportunity exists to incorporate the level and system dimensions posed by Williams et al. (2002) with the content and process
dimensions that Bowen and Ostroff (2004) suggest underlie all HRM practices and the objectives/content and delivery dimensions
in the training and development literature (Salas & Cannon-Bowers, 2001). Such integration may address construct proliferation
and allow ndings in the benets literature to inform the strategic HRM literature and vice versa.
2.2. Antecedents and moderators of benet satisfaction
2.2.1. Generational differences and implications for measuring benet offerings
Dencker, Joshi, and Martocchio (20 07) argued that individual differences in benet preferences emerge from the particular
employment relationships with which individuals have the most experience. For example, older employees likely experienced
or observed the period when career-long employment and cradle-to-grave benets were provided by employers. As such, and
given that they may have extensive service with an employer, they may prefer benets in which the employer shoulders the
risk of economic uctuations and provides packages with dened benets. In contrast, given that during their formative years
members of Generation X and Y witnessed the dismantling of internal labor markets, job security and lifelong benets, these
individuals may not expector even be willing to trustemployers to provide for their economic and health security. As such,
these employees may prefer benet programs in which employers dene contributions and clarify which risks they will and
will not bear.
Given that today's employers are populated by individuals who grew up in different times and have different expectations of
employers (up to four different generations may work side by side), the potential effectiveness of a one size ts allbenets
approach is strained. Consistent with arguments of Boudreau and Ramstad (2007),Dencker et al. (2007) argued that market
segmentation of employees (and offering market segments different benets) may strengthen the benets return-on-
investment.Such return-on-investment may be achieved by either varying benet offerings by employee segments (which may
present legal issues) or giving employees the choice among an array of benets. A research need exists to examine preference
differences that exist among age groups in the workforce.
Proposition 1a. Benet preferences may vary by generation or age cohorts. Therefore, the relationship between benet offerings and
benet satisfaction will be moderated by the cohort to which the employee belongs.
Proposition 1b. The level-dimension of the benets satisfaction construct likely has facets which include the: (a) actuarial value of the
offerings, (b) locus of responsibility (between the employee and employer), and (c) time orientation (i.e., the extent to which the benets
are used now(i.e., during employment) or in the future (e.g., retiree health care). The relationship between each facet level-dimension
and benets satisfaction will be moderated by cohort membership.
Although Dencker et al.'s (2007) arguments regarding the variation of benet preferences by generations are interesting, one
could also argue that a portion of any perceived variations are statistical artifacts of cross-sectional studies; hence, variance in
benet preferences may not solely be associated with generation but may also be associated with life and/or family stages (e.g.,
Levinson, 1986; McGoldrick & Carter, 1982). For example, perhaps employees (regardless of generation membership) are likely to
value future-oriented benets more when they are in their maintenance or mid-adult stage than when they are in their
establishment or early-adult stage. If so, then longitudinal studies comparing different generations at specic life stages may show
that there are actually more similarities than differences among generations at various life stages (i.e., baby boomers during
establishment, Generation Y during establishment, etc.). Accordingly, ndings regarding variations in benet preferences may
arise in part from life stage rather than only generation.
The difference between variation bygeneration or life stage may appear subtle. However, accurately isolating factors predicting
variation in benet preferences has implications that are anything but subtle for employers' allocation of scarce benet dollars.
Indeed, expecting benet preferences to remain xed when they vary in predictable ways over time may lead executives to make
misguided decisions. To partition variation associated with life stage vs. generation, longitudinal datasets gathered by the Bureau
of Labor Statistics or consultancies may be helpful.
Proposition 2. Although differences exist between life stages, benet preferences change in predictable ways over time. Incremental
variance in employee benet offering preferences (e.g., time orientation of benets) predicted by generation (over and above life stage),
therefore, may not be signicant.
3J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
2.2.2. Actuarial- vs. perceived-level of benets
Research has demonstrated that actuarial and perceived levels of benets have differential impacts on benets satisfaction. For
example, Williams (1995) tested a model of benet satisfaction antecedents developed by Micelli and Lane (1991). She found that
employees' perceived level of benets was more highly associated with benet satisfaction than the trueactuarial-value level of
benets provided. Moreover, she found no support for a positive relationship between perceived level and actuarial-value level,
which provides a hint about a potential root cause of the benet-satisfaction paradox. Williams also identied a set of individual-
difference factors including negative affectivity and the perceived-level of previous benets among others that moderated
relationships between both actuarial-value level and perceived-level, and actuarial-value level and benet satisfaction.
The lack of support for the relationship between actuarial-value level and benet satisfaction provides an opportunity for
benet researchers to contribute to the emerging strategic HRM literature on perceived vs. intendedHRM practices. Williams'
study foreshadowed evolving strategic HRM theory (e.g., Nishii & Wright, 2008) that proposes differences between the HRM
practices an employer intends (e.g., a rich benet program) and employee perceptions of the HRM practice (e.g., an average benet
program). These related ndings in strategic HRM and employee benets point toward an opportunity to develop a rened model
of benet and HRM system satisfaction. To create such a model, aspects of theory and research from compensation (e.g., Heneman,
Greenberger, & Strasser, 1988) and strategic HRM (Nishii & Wright, 2008) necessarily must be integrated.
3. Pensions
3.1. Denitions and context
Although historically in the U.S. income security for the elderly was provided for by the extended family, Social Security
legislation was passed by Congress in 1934 when it was estimated that approximately half of the elderlyin the U.S. did not have the
means to be self-supporting and the unemployment rate was 25%. Initial contribution rates were 1% for both employer and
employee. Replacement rates for median earners were 23.4% in 1940, the rst year anyone received benets, and 41.3% in 2006.
However, while Social Security replaces about 40% of the average worker's earnings, in the future it will not replace as much. For
example, by 2030 the replacement rate will be 30% based on future Medicare premiums, taxes, and planned benet reduction
legislation that has been passed. A majority of public and private sector companies in the U.S. provide their employees with
pension plans as a form of indirect compensation (Kramerich, 1999). In contrast to Social Security's replacement ratio of 40%,
employer-sponsored pension plans provide about 20% of income for all individuals over age 65.
The salience of employer-sponsored retirement plans to American employees has grown in recent years as a result of a number
of factors including the graying of the labor force, the increasing concern regarding the future solvency of Social Security, and the
decreasing replacement rate (Dulebohn, Murray, & Sun, 2000). Widespread agreement exists today among scholars and public
policy makers that the retirement income security of future retirees will increasingly depend on their participation in employer-
sponsored retirement plans and their own savings rather than on social security (Kramerich, 1999; Mitchell & Moore, 1998).
Employer-sponsored pension plans play a number of important roles for both employers and employees. While employers
provide pension plans for a variety of reasons, the overall goal of organizations is to design compensation systems that are
consistent with their human resource policies (Mitchell & Rappaport, 1993). The two major types of qualied pension plans offered
by employers are dened benet (DB) plans and dened contribution (DC) plans.
DB plans were the pension plan typically provided by companies in the past as part of the use of internal labor markets
(Dulebohn & Werling, 2007). DB plans are formula-based pension plans in which employers typically promise to pay their
employees a benet based on the employee's retirement age, nal average salary, and years of service. The employer maintains a
pension fund and holds the risk of investment and returns on that fund. It also possesses the risk of paying out greater benets if
workers live longer than expected. The risks faced by workers in a DB plan include the funding-level and solvency of the plan and
the necessity to maintain employment at a single employer (i.e., immobility and non-portability).
During the past 25 years there has been a decline in qualied DB plans from approximately 250,000 in 1980 to less than 80,000
in 2005. Concurrently, there has been growth in the use of DC plans among both private and public employers (Dulebohn, 2002).
DC plans are similar to savings plans and provide a benet based on annual contributions, as a percentage of pay made on behalf of
the employee, and accumulated investment earnings on the employee's account. The employer's obligation is limited to providing
a plan that meets regulated guidelines and to any promise to contribute to the plan on behalf of the employee. Consequently,
participants of DC plans bear the risk of investment loss. The risks faced by the worker also include accumulating sufcient capital
to replace earned income in retirement, outliving one's savings, nancially surviving catastrophic health, and maintaining
sufcient savings in the face of economic conditions (e.g., interest rate changes) and nancial market uctuations. Furthermore, a
number of employers have begun offering employees "hybrid" plans combining features of both plan types (Bodie & Merton, 1993).
3.2. Issues in pension research
Several foci emerge with respect to employer-sponsored pension plans. First, is the choice among plans that employees who
have to select among plans may face (e.g., a DB vs. DC plan). Some employers, particularly in the public sector, offer employees an
irrevocable choice among major plan types. Second, is the issue for DC plan participants of managing their retirement savings.
Specically, this involves the topic of risk and selecting investments involving different levels of risk. Third, is the issue of
retirement savings adequacy and retirement preparation. The question exists whether employees are saving enough for
4J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
retirement. This issue has employer implications for outow, because employees who do not have adequate savings may want to
remain with their employer past normal retirement age.
3.2.1. Pension plan choice
Although the changes occurring in employer offerings of pension plans have received notable research attention (cf., Clark &
McDermed, 1990; Gustman & Steinmeier, 1992), a review of the literature indicates that only a couple studies have investigated
employees' choice among retirement plans. The rst, a study by Clark, Harper, and Pitts (1997) examined direct effects of
demographic predictors on a choice between a DC plan and a DB plan among faculty members at a state university. Their results
indicated that age and years of service were positively related to the selection of the DB plan, while salary was positively related to
the selection of the DC plan.
The second study by Dulebohn et al. (2000) involved a eld survey of 2400 employees who participated in a state sponsored
retirement system covering 60 participating employers. Their results identied primary predictors distinguishing plan selection
and indicated that employees' preferences for plan features (such as investment choice for a DC plan, benet formula for a DB plan,
and portability for a hybrid plan) explained signicant variation in their selection among pension plans. The results highlighted the
critical role played by individual differences in plan choice beyond demographic predictors.
A research question that still exists with respect to plan choice is: what choice will be made by new organizational members
who are given a choice? As noted previously in the discussion of generational and career stage differences, it is logical to assume
that different predictors of plan choice may play a role among younger, new employees than older employees with some seniority.
Consequently, exploratory analysis should be done with respect to investigating whether there are differences in determinants of
plan choice among employees based on their age or career stage.
3.2.2. Managing risk in DC saving plans
Because of the growth in the provision by employers of DC pension plans, issues surrounding managing DC savings plans are
topics warranting continued research attention. Unique to the DC environment is the necessity for workers to act as personal fund
managers by allocating savings among investment options that have differing levels of outcome risk. The decisions they make
regarding the risk levels in those funds have important effects on the level of savings they are able to achieve (Mitchell & Moore,
1998; Porterba, 2004). Because greater investment returns are often associated with taking on greaterrisk, if a worker is to achieve
sufcient savings, she or he will have to choose among investment options, such as equities, that have greater variability in
outcomes (Burtless, 2003; Shapira, 1995). For the naïve investor, selecting simply among high and low risk is a difcult task, but in
the present DC environment employers are increasing the number of investment allocationchoices available to workers (Employee
Benet Plan Review, 2001; Institutional Investor, 2001), which is causing dysfunctional responses from workers such as non-
participation (Sethi-Iyengar, Huberman, & Jiang, 2004). Most troubling for investment outcomes is the decision by a full third of
401(k) participants in the U.S. to place all of their assets in non-equity savings options (Munnell & Sunden, 2006).
To better understand the risk-taking decisions workers make when managing their retirement savings in DC plans, our review
focuses on the risk allocation question and summarizes key ndings in each of the major approaches that historically have been
used to examine risk-taking behavior. First, we review literature on demographic correlates to risk-taking based on initial risk
taking research that focused on this area. Second, we review research on behavioral tendencies in decision-making. Third, we
review literature on attitudinal, perceptual, and dispositional modeling of the risk allocation decision.
3.2.2.1. Demographics. Several demographic factors have been studied relative to risk-taking in retirement savings, including
age, income, education, gender and marital status. The relationships that have been found have not been consistently supported
across all studies. Age, for example, has been shown to be negatively related to increased risk-taking in retirement savings
allocations (Agnew, Balduzzi, & Sunden, 2000; Dulebohn, 2002). As people near retirement, their time horizon for recovering from
losses in accumulation decreases, so they are less able to include investment options that have greater volatility in their outcomes.
However, in alternate studies of risk-taking correlates, age has either not been found signicant (Sunden & Surette, 1998) or the
opposite relationship was observed (Dulebohn & Murray, 2007). The examination of age as a proxy variable for time horizon to
recover from loss is representative of demographic variables serving as proxies for underlying economic or behavioral principles.
Income and education have demonstrated positive relationships to risk-taking (Agnew et al., 2000; Dulebohn, 2002).
Individuals who have greater wealth, beyond that needed to survive, should be better positioned to substitute other savings or
accept losses in retirement savings (Munnell, Sunden, & Taylor, 2000). Likewise, it is speculated that individuals with higher
education either have greater earning potential or are better able to understand the role of risk in their retirement savings
(Munnell, Sunden, & Taylor, 2000). However, as with age, these expectations have not been consistently supported. Relative to
income, after controlling for attitudinal and dispositional factors, Dulebohn and Murray (2007) found no relationship for income
with the risk level of savings allocations. Relative to the education correlation, some studies have demonstrated no effect
(Dulebohn, 2002; Dulebohn & Murray, 2007; Sunden & Surette, 1998), while others showed that higher education was negatively
related to risk taking in the form of stock inclusion in savings plans (Bernasek & Shwiff, 2001).
As a general observation, females are less likely to include greater amounts of risk in their retirement savings allocations
(Agnew et al., 2000; Bernasek & Shwiff, 2001; Dulebohn, 2002; Dulebohn & Murray, 2007); however, that assertion depends on
marital status and the characteristics of the spouse (Bernasek & Shwiff, 2001; Lyons & Yilmazer, 2004; Sunden & Surette, 1998).
Female plan participants whose male partners were willing to take on additional risk in retirement savings, or whose male
partners expected to receive social security benets, elected to take less risk in their own savings choices (Bernasek & Shwiff,
5J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
2001). Single females also are more risk adverse than single men (Jianakoplos & Bernasek, 1998) or married females (Sunden &
Surette, 1998). Overall, demographic correlations do not explain much of the variance in retirement decision-making behavior
(Dulebohn et al., 2000). Consequently, researchers have looked to other areas of research including that focusing on decision-
making and attitudes for additional explanation of retirement risk savings behavior.
3.2.2.2. Decision making. Research on decision making has provided several contributions to our understanding of how workers
approach allocating their retirement savings. Thaler et al. have identied investment decision issues including self-control, lack of
commitment to decision preferences, the avoidance of short-term losses, and a bias toward allocations based on the over-
weighting of fund types among choice options (Benartzi & Thaler, 1999; Thaler,1981; Thaler & Shefrin,1981). Self-control manifests
itself as the disconnect between intentions and actions; for example, people intend to balance their portfolio of savings in a way
that includes enough risky assets to support growth over the long run, but never get around to doing the work to make the choices
to make it happen. A lack of commitment or decision preference is evident when individuals are easily inuenced to change
savings allocations based on situational context (Benartzi & Thaler, 2002); consequently, a specic plan of savings is more often
emergent than purposely formulated. The avoidance of short term losses impacts workers' investment decisions by causing them
to construct less aggressive portfolios with fewer equity holdings when they review annual rather than long-term compound data
(Benartzi & Thaler, 1999). Finally, the mix of investment options also inuences workers' allocation decisions. When the offerings
are weighted toward more equity options, workers will construct a more aggressive portfolio with more holdings in equities
(Benartzi & Thaler, 2001).
Kahneman and Tversky's (1979) work on decision heuristics and prospect theory has also provided a foundation for
understanding workers' decisions relative to risk-taking. Some important implications from their work are that we expect workers
to react more strongly to potential losses than gains, and we expect them to focus more on incremental losses and gains than on
their total retirement savings accumulations when making decisions.
3.2.2.3. Attitudes, dispositions and perceptions. Researchers have demonstrated that several attitudinal and individual difference
constructs drawn from psychology are useful for explaining risk-taking behavior in retirement savings allocations. Drawing on past
research on the inuence of knowledge on risk-taking (Baird & Thomas, 1985; Funk, Rapoport, & Jones, 1979), Dulebohn and
Murray (2007) demonstrated that workers' knowledge of investment principles was positively related to the risk level in their DC
savings plan allocations. Extending into attitude research, they also showed that investment risk preference directly inuenced
risk-taking in allocations, and moreover demonstrated that it served a key mediating role for the relationships of general risk
propensity, investment risk inertia, and opportunity perceptions with risk-taking. They further showed that risk opportunity vs.
threat perception mediated a relationship between a worker's experienced investment outcome history, self-efcacy toward
managing investments, and locus of control with investment risk preference and risk-taking in allocations. Their ndings
supported prior work that also found empirical support for relationships between general risk propensity, investment principles
knowledge, and self-efcacy with risk taking behavior in retirement savings investment allocations (Dulebohn, 2002). Together
this research represents initial steps in examining the role of attitudes as determinants of risk-taking.
3.2.2.4. Inertia. Inertia, whether purposefully or by default, has also been found to inuence retirement savings risk-taking.
Researchers have noted that the way in which individuals respond to risk in specic contexts tends to continue over time and
forms a relatively stable pattern (MacKenzie, 1998; Sitkin & Pablo, 1992; Slovic, 1972). This nding is consistent with research
that has found that employees who participated in DC pension plans often exhibit inertia by continuing with, rather than
changing, the risk level of their initial investment choices or the initial default allocation selected by the employer (Choi,
Laibson, Madiran, & Metrick, 2001; Madrian & Shea, 2001). Research on the role of individual difference predictors in inertia
behavior is needed. Specically, based on prior research and ndings on predictors of investment risk-taking, it is expected that
individual difference variables such as self-efcacy, investment risk preference, and investment knowledge will be associated
with inertia.
Proposition 3.Individual difference variables, including self-efcacy, investment risk preference, and investment knowledge, will
explain variance in inertia in retirement savings behavior.
3.2.2.5. A planned behavior perspective. Based on our literature review, we observed that demographics are often studied as
proxy variables for underlying economic or behavioral principles, and as such are not always consistent in their relationships to
risk-taking. As more proximal or direct attitudinal or dispositional inuences on risk-taking, which more directly represent the
attitudes or preferences proxied by the demographic variables, are included in empirical models, these distal or proxy effects
disappear. Our observation is consistent with prior research conclusions that demographic variables do not add signicant
explanation beyond comprehensive attitudinal variables (Ajzen, 2001; Albarracin, Fishbein, & Godestein, 1997).
From this observation, we suggest that a planned behavior model (Ajzen, 1988,1991) would be a useful extension of the attitude
approach in examining risk-taking in retirement savings allocations, because it might identify additional psychological constructs
more directly inuential to allocation decisions than demographic characteristics. The planned behavior approach extends or
complements past research, because it addresses issues different from decision heuristics or biases of behavioral nance or
prospect theory, and it adds tothe attitudinal approach a general theoretical framework that goes further than present research by
incorporating questions of social norms and inuence. Finally, and most importantly, it serves as a meta-framework that marries
6J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
the behavioral nance and attitudinal research by bring together the issues of the imperfect relationship between intention and
actual behavior and of the role of inertia or habit in behavior.
In addition to its potential efcacy as a unifying theoretical perspective, planned behavior also has demonstrated its
usefulness in the study of risk taking in a variety of situations. For example, it is a dominant theoretical perspective in the study
of risky health-related behaviors (Martin, 2006; Reinecke, Schmidt, & Ajzen, 1997; Rivis & Sheeran, 2003) and has been
demonstrated as a model of risky driving intentions and behaviors (Parker, manstead, Stradling, & Reason, 1992). Accordingly,
though it is generally held by researchers that risk-taking behavior does not necessarily generalize across situations and may
vary among individuals (Bromiley & Curley, 1992; Wiseman & Levin, 1996), we expect that the planned behavior model as a
general framework will likewise explain signicant variation in risk intentions and behaviors related to risk-taking in retirement
savings investment allocations.
Proposition 4. A planned behavior model, incorporating expectancies, social norms, perceived behavioral control, and intentions, will
explain variance in risk-taking behavior in retirement savings plans.
3.2.3. Retirement preparation and savings accumulation
The retention and planned exit of employees has become increasingly more difcult to manage due to the shift toward DC
retirement programs. Historically, organizations' provision of DB plans represented a predictable process for moving older
employees out of the organization by providing a benet based on years of service and nal salary. Retirement was variously
viewed as a scheduled transition, an achievement, or something the employee had earned; consequently, organizational exit was
more of an expectation than a choice once the requirements for the dened benet were met. In contrast, in today's DC
environment, there are a larger number of determinants of, and greater variability in, savings levels and future retirement income
adequacy across employees. Thus, employees are not always able to retire on schedule,they may look for opportunities to extend
their careers, and there is greater uncertainty in stafng forecasts and retention management relative to retirements (Munnell,
Sass, & Aubry, 2006).
3.2.3.1. Retirement savings consequences. A worker's nancial condition has long been recognized as an important determinant
of retirement related choices and outcomes (Adams,1999; Beehr,1986; Beehr, Glazer, Nielson, & Farmer, 2000). Inadequate savings
accumulation has been shown to be related to lower future income replacement ratios (Holden & VanDerhei, 2006), a delay of
retirement (Munnell et al., 2006), and participation in bridge employment (Kim & Feldman, 2000). Employees who possess
sufcient accumulated wealth or who are satised with their planned retirement income retire at younger ages on average than
those who possess less accumulated savings or do not have sufcient nancial resources (Adams, 1999; Beehr et al., 2000).
3.2.3.2. Retirement savings determinants. Because savings accumulations play an important and consistent rolein the retirement
decision, it is important for HRM managers and researchers to know what is related to savings behavior and accumulations in
order to better understand or manage the stafng and retirement process. The literature provides three categories of variables.
First, there have been several studies of demographic correlates. Demographic variables that have received consistent support
include age, job tenure, and income (Holden & VanDerhei, 2006). The logic underlying these variables is largely grounded in
opportunity. Older individuals have had a greater opportunity to accumulate savings over time than younger workers. Likewise,
individuals with greater job tenure have had a greater opportunity to contribute consistently to a savings plan and are less likely to
have cashed out savings on one or more occasions when changing employers due to disruption in their job-generated income
stream. Workers with higher income levels are able to assign a greater nominal amount of dollars to savings than lower income
workers.
Second, differences in savings accumulations have been attributed to specic savings behaviors, including employee
contribution levels, decisions to participate in optional savings programs, asset allocation and diversication choices, occasional
withdrawal or borrowing from savings, and cashing out when changing employers (Holden & VanDerhei, 2006; Munnell & Sunden,
2006). Chief among the determining behaviors is the decision whether to participate in an employer-sponsored retirement savings
program, and then to elect to contribute additional income to the savings plan. Younger employees and those with lower income
tend to participate less often or to contribute fewer dollars to the plans.
Also important among the behaviors are those that affect the return on the investment. Because the total savings accumulation
is a function of both the initial contributions and the subsequent capital appreciation, an employee can affect the savings outcomes
in several ways. Common behaviors that negatively affect accumulation levels include the tendency to not diversify investment
holdings adequately, to over-invest in the employer's stock, and through inertia fail to balance the portfolio as investment returns
alter the proportions of allocations among fund types (Munnell & Sunden, 2006).
Third, there are structural or plan characteristics that affect an employee's savings accumulation. Among these characteristics
are automatic enrollment, employer contributions, and automatic rollover (Munnell & Sunden, 2006). Automatic enrollment
programs overcome the challenge of motivating employee participation by making participation the default behavior and
requiring the employee to take specic steps if he or she does not want to participate. Employer contributions supplement the
employee's level of savings contributions. Because employer contributions are sometimes contingent on the amount of employee
contribution, they can motivate additional savings on the part of the employee. Automatic rollover provisions positively inuence
long-term accumulation by discouraging cashing out behavior by moving funds directly into individual retirement accounts when
employees exit the organization.
7J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
3.2.3.3. Future research. Research in retirement savings is needed to better identify both consequences and determinants of
savings accumulations that have not yet been fully examined. Most important among the consequences is workplace productivity
and health. There are at least two reasons to expect an effect of savings adequacy on employee performance. First, research has
demonstrated that one of the motivators of retirement is being tired of working(Beehr et al., 2000). If an employee is forced to
work for nancial reasons beyond the time when he or she has psychologically exhausted his or her intrinsic motivation to work,
work effort consequently will decrease. Second, individuals who are ill perform at lower levels than fully healthy workers (Kessler
& Stang, 2006). Given that individuals delay retirement due to inadequate savings and in order to maintain healthcare insurance
(Freidberg, 2007), it is reasonable to expect that the individuals who most need retirement for health reasons are the workers who
are least able to retire. If these individuals are working, out of necessity, when they are experiencing health challenges, then it is to
be expected that their productivity at work will suffer.
Proposition 5. For employees who would otherwise be eligible for retirement, inadequate savings accumulation will be negatively
correlated with workplace productivity.
Among the determinants of savings accumulations, the most benecial new research would examine dispositions and
attitudes. We expect that there are at least three dispositions that would relate to savings. First, research including the Big Five
personality constructs has been especially informative in human resources, and most important among these for retirement
savings is conscientiousness. Long-term savings accumulation relies on disciplined and regular contributions that are allowed to
grow over time and are prudently managed in portfolios that are regularly rebalanced. Each of these requisite behaviors is a
manifestation of the conscientiousness construct as it is traditionally dened (Barrick & Mount, 1991).
Proposition 6. Conscientiousness positively correlates with savings accumulation, controlling for opportunity to save (e.g., time,
income, and employer contributions).
Second, prior research has established a relationship between external locus of control and self-assessed ability to manage
personal nances (Perry & Morris, 2005); we extend this nding with an expectation that employees' locus of control will be
related to their savings accumulation. On the one hand, employees with an external locus will expect that their nancial condition
at retirement will be affected primarily by external forces. They would be most likely to believe that the employer, government or
other funding source will determine their savings accumulation. These employees would benet most from the automatic
enrollment, asset management, and rollover provisions that protect them from non-participation and inertia effects. On the other
hand, employees with an internal locus of control will believe that their nancial condition at retirement primarily will be the
consequence of the decisions they make about savings and investment. Accordingly, they would be more likely to see and respond
to the relationship between savings behaviors and accumulations.
Proposition 7. Employees possessing an internal locus of control will have a higher average level of savings accumulations, all else
equal, than employees possessing an external locus of control.
Third, we expect that individuals with a greater propensity to hoard, in general, will extend that disposition into their savings
behaviors. Hoarding behavior has traditionally been dened as an obsessivecompulsive disorder through which individuals
accumulate an excess of objects (Maier, 2004). In the case of retirement planning, we are referring specically to the behavioral
response tendency to save or accumulate for the sake of saving itself. Individuals who are motivated by accumulating and are
reticent to expend those savings will over time accrue a greater amount of savings than those individuals who are not as
psychologically attached to the accumulated wealth itself.
Proposition 8. A hoarding disposition is positively related to accumulated retirement savings.
In addition to the dispositional inuences, we expect that some retirement savings behavior is due to an attitudinal fear or risk
preference response. Jacobs-Lawson and Hershey (2005) demonstrated that nancial risk preference was related to self-reported
retirement savings behaviors. A useful extension of their nding is to consider the fear-responsive behaviors exhibited by workers
planning for retirement. Saving is a future-oriented behavior that is engaged to ensure economic security in retirement. Because
there are substantial risks for retirees, including healthcare costs, outliving retirement savings, and declining government benets,
individuals may mitigate the stress due to fear or risk aversion by building a larger savings accumulation.
Proposition 9. Fear of economic risk in retirement is positively related to savings accumulation.
Overall, the examination of these individual differences could inform employers and assist them in planning interventions to
assist employees in preparing for retirement. For example, if locus of control is found to be a strong predictor, employers could
assess this and then provide training to help orient individuals to be aware of their orientation and its possible impact on their
retirement savings behavior.
4. Health care
While representing one of the most expensive and salient employer-sponsored benets, health care benets have been the
focus of only limited research in HRM. Other elds such as economics, nance, and public policy have devoted more attention to
the topic. Because of its salience today and its centrality to total compensation and the employment relationship it is our
contention that health care benets deserve more attention from HRM.
8J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
4.1. Contextfrom sickness to health
Early health care plans emerged in the 1920s and were termed sickness insuranceprograms given that they provided
coverage only for hospitalizations. (Davis, 1934; Davis & Rorem, 1932). Due to outcomes of union negotiations (and the interests of
nonunionized employers looking to avoid unionization), employer-sponsored sickness programs became more prevalent in the
1930s. By the 1950s, middle class families were accustomed to sickness benets being provided through employment relationships
(Faulkner, 1960).
The 1960s were a turning point when the scope of coverage shifted dramatically in two ways in response to the passage of
Medicare and Medicaid legislation in 1965 and union negotiations. First, whereas earlier health care policies covered
hospitalization and insured individuals against catastrophic expenses, policies also began to provide full-coverage (100%
payment) of less expensive health-related products (e.g., prescriptions) and services (e.g., physician ofce visits) (Falk, Rorem, &
Ring, 1933). As such, a change in terminology emerged as these benets began to be called health benetsrather than sickness
insurance(Hewitt, 2005). This terminology reected a shift in the employers' responsibility from providing protection from
nancial ruin due to catastrophic health care expenses (i.e., sickness insurance) to providing insulation from the costs of
maintaining and enhancing the health and welfare of employees.
The second shift was that employers provided health benets not only to the employee, but also the employee's dependents (e.g.,
spouse, children under age 21). With this change, benet analysts examined not only the number of employees covered and the
number of livescovered (employees and their dependents). This norm of providing coverage to employees and their eligible
dependents increased the average number of lives covered by a factor of 2.8 and health care costs by a factor of 3.2 (Henderson, 2002).
With the 1970s came the prevalent use of indemnity plans that were designed to have employees share in the cost of health
care they used (Scofea, 1994). Also during this decade, Health Maintenance Organizations (HMOs) were instituted that
contracted with networks of physicians, hospitals, and other medical providers, negotiated reduced rates for providers,
encouraged providers to use treatment protocols such as primary care gatekeepers, and encouraged individuals to seek
preventative care by charging modest or no fees for such services (Allen & Sullivan, 2006). Although HMOs effectively curtailed
rising health care costs to some extent, they also desensitized individuals to the true cost of their medical expenses. For
example, the use of modest charges for routine ofce visits and prescriptions (e.g., $10 co-pay per visit or prescription) led to an
increase in ofce visits along with an increase in the use of prescription drugsdrugs which were increasingly marketed directly
to consumers (Gaynor, Haas-Wilson, & Vogt, 1999). Thus, the managed care plans that had been able to contain health care costs
by inuencing how medical care is supplied ultimately led to sharp increases in the health care services that individuals were
demanding.
During the 1990s, health care ination rates far outpaced general ination rates, with companies enduring double-digit
ination and spiraling costs for many consecutive years (Aon, 2007). Employers reacted to cost increases by signicantly increasing
employee contributions, shifting costs of accessed care through increased co-payments, decreasing or eliminating health care
coverage in retirement, and in some cases, requiring employees to pay signicant portions of the cost of their dependents' coverage
(Chernew, Cutler, & Keenan, 2005).
In 2007, employers provided access to health care benets for 62% of those under age 65 in the U.S. (those 65 and older were
covered by government-sponsored Medicare programs), while an additional 22% of those under 65 were covered through either
private health insurance contracts or government programs such as Medicaid (Kaiser, 2007). The remaining 16% of individuals
under age 65 do not have health insurance for various reasons including unemployment, lack of access, inability to afford the plans
offered by employers, or the prohibitive costs of private insurance (Ellis & Manning, 2007; Kaiser, 2007).
4.2. Balancing cost management and quality care
Since the most recent review of the benets literature (Williams & MacDermid, 1994), employers have experienced health care
ination rates that vary widely (215%) from year to year along with increased utilization of health plans, leading to spiraling
claims from the period between 1995 and 2007 (EBRI, 2008; Kaiser, 2007). Employers have responded by advocating national
changes in public policy and implementing localcost control initiatives. Public policy debates include how to reform the health
care delivery systems, whether to implement play or paymandates which penalize employers not offering health insurance
(Baicker & Levy, 2007), consideration of universal coverage (Ellis & Manning, 2007), and assistance to employers struggling with
providing health care benets while remaining competitive (e.g., Allen & Sullivan, 2006; Goldsmith, 2001). Local cost-control
initiatives have most commonly been tweaks in benet plan designs that shift costs to employees. However, such reactive xes
have not addressed the underlying causes of uncertain inationary increases and increased utilization.
4.2.1. Emerging supplyside initiatives
Given that health care providers are employees who work under contracts with managed care networks, some research has
examined the role of incentive programs in containing health care costs while upholding or enhancing patient health outcomes. For
example, Gaynor, Rebitzer, and Taylor (2004) studied the implementation of a group-based incentive plan within an HMO network,
looking at how it inuenced amount of care provided. The authors found that the program was associated with a 5% reduction in
medical expenditures. Barro and Beaulieu (2003), likewise, examined the transition of physicians from xed salary compensation to
a reduced salary with opportunities for prot sharing. Consistent with theory and the ndings of Gaynor et al. (2004), they
demonstrated that the quantity of health care services supplied signicantly decreased during the time of the incentive program.
9J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
What remains unclear from physician-incentive research is the extent to which such incentives and reductions in expenditures
are associated with both provider outcomes and changes in patient outcomeseither positive (e.g., restored health) or negative
(e.g., reoccurrence rates). Accordingly, research into the relationships between incentive programs based upon quality of care, in
addition to the cost of care provided, and patient outcomes also is warranted. Two important research streams are evident. First,
longitudinal analysis of physician productivity and patient outcomes (e.g., recovery, reoccurrence, death rate) would yield
important information regarding intended and potentially unintended correlates of provider-incentive programs such as cost and/
or quality of care. Second, analysis of job attitudes and turnover patterns of providers employed through various incentive
programs may yield important insights regarding (a) the extent to which providers view the objectives of containing costs and
optimizing patient care as conicting objectives, and (b) how managed care employers can best structure employment
relationships with and design jobs for providers.
4.2.2. Emerging demandside initiatives
Having achieved the improvements possible through renements of existing benet plan designs, employers are increasingly
taking more proactive approaches to inuence the factors underlying health care demand. These initiatives include consumerism
and disease management.
4.2.2.1. Consumerism. Consumerism, or consumer-driven health care, is the name given to employer efforts to make employees
take ownership for their own health and to gain (or regain) an understanding of the true cost of health care services (Aon, 2007;
Hewitt, 2005; Kaiser, 2007; Sharon & Donahue, 2006). The logic underlying consumerism initiatives is that exposing employees to
more information about the cost of health care, as well as more of the actual cost of it, will motivate employees to better manage
(i.e., typically decrease) their use of the health care system (Hiles, Hogg, Tapia, & Winkler, 2007).
Consumerism initiatives typically consist of at least three components (Henderson, 2002; Hewitt, 2007). First, communications
detail the total cost of employee health benetsand clarify that the portion that employees pay through premiums and
coinsurance is much smaller than the costs shouldered by the employer. In addition, information regarding the skyrocketing costs
of health care not only for the employer, but also across the U.S., is discussed with an emphasis on the toll of such costs on the
employer's competitiveness and viability. Second, employees are encouraged to engage in healthy lifestyle behaviors (e.g., exercise,
nutritional eating) as a way to minimize their need for extensive health care. Third, when employees do use health care, they are
encouraged to become more active consumers of health care. Relative to passive patients, active health care consumers act as if
they are spending their ownmoney when making health care decisions.
An evolving form of consumerism is the dened contribution health plan, which results in employers having less responsibility
for managing employee health care and emphasizes the consumer role of the employee. It involves sweeping changes in how
employers dene and fulll their health care obligations to employees. These initiatives move far beyond traditional efforts that
tweak(i.e., make minor adjustments in) plan designs by increasing employee premiums or deductibles. There are many
variations of these plans, including health reimbursement arrangements, which are accounts to which employers contribute a
dened amount of money employees use to pay for health care expenses, health savings accounts, to which an employee may
contribute, and self-designed health care plans.
Dened contribution health insurance programs function in a manner similar to dened contribution pension programs. The
employer contributes a dollar amount toward health benets at the same time informing employees that they are responsible for
acquiring health care and the risks and consequences of their decisions. The benet to employers of these plans is a substantial
reduction in administrative burden and more predictable cost. Employees in these programs may have expanded choice of health
care options and are believed to be more active consumers than those in other types of plans. These changes in employee behavior
are expected given that employees are involved in instead of insulated fromthe realities of health care expenses.
Pure dened contributionplans for active employees generally are not used in the U.S. due to substantial resistance from
employees and questions regarding the tax-qualied status of these plans; however, theyare in current use for employerprovided
retiree health plans (Patterson, 2004). A hybrid consumerism alternative of them, however, that is gaining a foothold is the high-
deductible health insurance plan accompanied by a health savings account or health reimbursement arrangement (e.g., Kelley,
2003). It combines a catastrophic health insurance program with an employer-contributed or employer- and employee-
contributed reimbursement or savings account.
4.2.2.1.1. Correlates of consumerismindividuals. Research regarding the effects of consumer-driven or dened contribution
health plans is only recently emerging, and on some points is validating expectations based on consumerism while highlighting
limitations. Important ndings include: employee-participants in these types of plans (relative to their counterparts who are
covered by comprehensive health insurance) exhibit lower health benets satisfaction and higher out-of-pocket expenditures,
more often forgo or delay seeking health care, and include cost as a more important consideration in health care decision making
(Fronstin & Collins, 2005). In their utilization of health services, employees use (a) fewer or less costly alternatives for those
services for which there are real or perceived options, and (b) more preventive health services (Kelley, 2003).
4.2.2.1.2. Correlates of consumerismemployers. Research by consulting rms suggests that employers who implement
consumerism initiatives decrease the rate of health care ination for their plans by approximately 1 to 3% (Aon, 2007; Hewitt,
2007). Consumerism initiatives, however, are often simultaneously implemented with plan design and other cost sharing
initiatives. Thus, it remains unclear if gains attributed to consumerism relate to any of the three components, including reduced
health care demand, reduced need for health care given a healthy lifestyle, or provision of more cost-effective care through
employees' active partnerships with providers. Therefore, research in these three components is warranted.
10 J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
Existing research regarding the efcacy of consumerism most often has been completed at the employer level of analysis using
either health-care ination rates or plan expenditures as a dependent variable. The basis for comparison may be absolute
comparisons of the employer's health care ination year-over-year (i.e., within-employer comparisons over time) or relative
comparisons to the national average (i.e., to a standard) or to employers not having consumerism initiatives (i.e., between-
employers). Thus, methodological work regarding the robustness of potential dependent variables (e.g., health care ination rates
vs. plan expenditures vs. claims experience) and the nature of comparisons (e.g., within employer, between employer) is needed to
understand the true effects of consumerism.
Since research on efcacy of consumerism typically has taken place at the employer level of analysis, such analysis may obscure
potentially interesting variations between individuals nested within the employer. Individual difference research may uncover
important variations between groups of employees. For example, one could possibly argue that those highly committed to the
employer may be more likely to embrace healthcare consumerism than those employees who are disgruntled, because they
are more sympathetic to the effects of health care costs on the employer or organization.
Moreover, other individual differences could be associated not only with job performance, but also health care consumption.
For instance, conscientiousness, cognitive ability, and extroversion are characteristics that consistently predict job outcomes.
Perhaps conscientious employees may be more likely to acquire preventative care, and when treatment is needed, engage
providers in a dialogue regarding the cost and efcacy of treatment alternatives. Or one could argue that employees with higher
cognitive ability are more likely to have the condence and problem solving skills to engage providers, who are often better
educated, in a dialogue regarding treatment options. Such employees may be more likely or able to research their condition and
process the volumes of information available on the Internet and other sources. Finally, extroverted employees may be more likely
to engage providers in dialogue regarding whether tests are necessary or the recommended treatments have been well-studied.
Proposition 10. Individual differences commonly studied in employment (i.e., organizational commitment, cognitive ability,
conscientiousness, and extroversion) are associated with the manner and extent to which individuals engage in health care consumerism.
4.2.2.2. Disease management. A second approach employers use to manage demand for health care is disease management (Aon,
2007; EBRI, 2008; Kaiser, 2007). Disease management involves the targeted education and interactions with those claimants
having chronic diseases commonly associated with intense health care utilization. Interest in disease management stems from
examination of health care utilization patterns, which across samples (e.g., a large employer's claims experience or the claims
experience of all those in a health care plan) have shown that a small number of claimants are associated with abnormally high
health care costs (i.e., more than 25% of costs typically result from the utilization of fewer than 5% of claimants) (EBRI, 2008).
Likewise, as few as six chronic conditions, including back pain, cancer, coronary heart disease, diabetes, depression, and renal
disease, are associated with up to half of all plan payments (Kaiser, 2007; Kelley, 2003). Accordingly, high-cost claimants and
chronic conditions are often targets of disease management programs.
Disease management programs have beena catalyst for both theoretical and empirical research onhealth and well-being in the
workplace (e.g., Allen & Sullivan, 2006; Danna & Grifn, 1999; Manning, Jackson, & Fusilier, 1996; Wolff, 2003). Although this
research began in the HRM literature decades ago with a comprehensive theory of employee wellness (Beehr & Newman, 1978),
much of it currently takes place in the health economics and medical literatures using theories borrowed from the OB/HRM and
social psychology literatures (e.g., theories of motivation, commitment). Its primary objective has been to enhance adherence to
wellness programs and disease treatment protocols with a typical focus on the individual-level of analysis.
HRM scholars could contribute to disease management research by focusing on how such adherence and commitment
inuences organization-level outcomes such as absenteeism and health care costs. Indeed, one could argue that employers who
engage in disease management initiatives may have healthieremployees than rivals. Such healthyemployers may enjoy higher
productivity, less absenteeism, and lower health care costs than competitors.
Proposition 11. Organizations that provide disease management benets for their employees experience superior attendance, health
care cost-containment, and productivity outcomes.
Moreover, HRM scholars could examine to what extent health inuences one's perception of their labor market mobility.
1
That
is, one could argue that an individual who is healthy may feel less boundto the current employer through health care coverage.
For example, a healthy employee may feel more mobile than an employee who is not as healthy given that the healthy employee
may not feel as vulnerable to the temporary gaps in health care benets that are sometimes encountered when changing
employers. Or, any coverage limitations the new employer may have for pre-existing conditions may not be of concern to healthy
individuals (although such limitations may be of signicant concern to those employees who are not as healthy). These are
important empirical questions for HRM scholars to address.
5. Workfamily
Workfamily benets are a form of accommodation and enhancement benet; that is, they are a benet designed to promote
effective coping skills and educational opportunities for employees and, sometimes, family members(Martocchio, 2003, p. 340).
They are designed to address the conicting demands between work and family. Despite the relative newness of workfamily
1
We thank an anonymous reviewer for this insight.
11J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
benets, workfamily benets have come to represent a potentially important source of variability between organizations in terms
of discretionary benetsand thus a source of potential value in terms of attracting and retaining a talented workforce.
Although these benets could be strategically valuable to the organization, the prevalence of workfamily benets is
surprisingly low (Osterman, 1995). For instance, representative estimates indicate that only 2% of workers have access to
employer-sponsored childcare, and only 5% of workers have access to exible work schedules (BLS, 2000). Several reasons have
been offered for the lack of benets: (a) not all organizations are family-friendly,(b) only certain types of employees working
for certain types of organizations have access to these policies and programs, and (c) even when employees have access to
workfamily benets, they may not utilize them due to fears about negative repercussions (perceived or actual) for their long-
term career trajectory.
The scholarly management and organization literature in employee benets has tended to focus on workfamily benets,
even more than on health and economic security benets. Given that this area of benets has received so much attention, it is
important to review this literature to get a sense of the reasons why employers sponsor workfamily benets, the potential
payoffs to employers for doing so, and the outcomes for employees who utilize these benets. Accordingly, in this section we:
(a) identify workfamily benets mandated by public policy, (b) introduce and dene workfamily benets from a
management and organization perspective, (c) review literature that has attempted to explain why organizations adopt
workfamily benets, and (d) outline the outcomes for both employers and employees of adopting and utilizing these
benets.
5.1. Workfamily benets and public policy
The demography of the American workforce has changed dramatically in recent decades (Bond, Thompson, Galinsky, & Prottas,
2003), and consequently, demographicspecic issues have captured the concern of employers and employees. Women continue
to participate in the labor force in increasing numbers, dual-earner parents are increasingly common, and the number of baby
boomers for whom elder care is a concern is growing (Kossek & Pichler, 2006). Based on survey data of human resource executives,
Galinsky and Stein (1990) identied seven major work/family-related problems faced by employees: childcare, elder care, work
time/timing, relocation, job demands/autonomy, supervisory relationships, and culture (pg. 369).
Given these trends and issues, policymakers have attempted to enact legislation to facilitate the labor force participation of an
increasingly diverse population. These policies are generally piecemeal and are far from comprehensive (Kelly, 2006). Therefore,
some employers have chosen voluntarily to develop and offer workfamily benets in order to support the workfamily balance of
their employees. Employer adoption of specic provisions has been responsive to the limitations of public policy related to each
type of benet(Kelly, 2006). Before considering the types of benets employers offer and why, it is important to briey review two
major legislative initiatives related to workfamily benets as well as their limitations.
The primary workfamily issue is the availability and control over one's time. Federal regulation of work time has attempted to
support employees in terms of maximumwork hours per week and additional pay for excess work time primarily through the Fair
Labor Standards Act of 1938 and subsequent amendments to the Act. Legal restrictions related to work hours and work scheduling,
however, are minimal in the U.S., especially as compared to other developed countries. Managerial and professional workers, for
example, are exempt from the hours of work limitations; consequently, given the growth of the service sector in recent years and
the increase in knowledge workers, an increasing number of U.S. workers remain unprotected.
A second workfamily issue is the need for extended time away from work that does not limit or negate an employee's ability to
return to work without losing one's position or being disadvantaged in one's career. In terms of leaves of absence for family-related
care, the primary legal mechanism for unpaid leave is the Family Medical Leave Act of 1993, which mandates twelve weeks of
unpaid leave from work for the care of a newborn, parent, severely ill child, or to recover from an illness. Weaknesses of legislated
leave time include the generally discretionary nature of paid leave and the limitations on the scope of eligible events.
5.2. Employer-sponsored workfamily benets
In light of the fact that the U.S. has relatively paltry policies for workfamily benets, some employers have chosen to adopt
family-supportive workplace benets. Kahn and Kamerman (1987) coined the term family-responsive workplaceto refer to work
organizations that offer supportive policies and practices to help employees manage conicting work and family demands. Kelly
(2006) suggested that there is a relatively well-developed set of employer-based benets for working families.(pg. 99) Secret
(2000), moreover, proposed that while the total list of workfamily benets offered by employers is potentially long, there are four
primary types of workfamily benets: alternative or exible work arrangements, leave time allowances, well-being programs and
dependent care services.
Researchers in the management and organization literature have most often focused on childcare services and exible work
arrangements. They have shown thatemployer support of childcare typically involves subsidizing on-site childcare, directly paying
for childcare (either as an employee benet or through a third-party vendor), or by providing information and referral services
(Goodstein, 1994). Researchers have also found that workplace exibility typically involves such programs and practices as
extime, part-time or reduced load work, job sharing and other ex options (Goodstein, 1994). Access to exible work
arrangements and exible scheduling, however, is generally determined on an individual basis, and only the highest performers
typically are awarded the opportunity to work on an alternative basis, thus limiting access to this type of perkfor most workers
(Kelly, 2006).
12 J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
While some employers have chosen to offer workfamily benets to support the challenges faced by an increasingly diverse
workforce, researchers have found that their prevalence is limited (Friedman, 1990; cf, Secret, 2000). For example, Seyler, Monroe,
and Garand (1995) found among a representative sample of Louisiana businesses that organizations rarely offered a systematic or
comprehensive set of family-related benets. Likewise, nationally representative data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (2000)
indicated that the adoption of workfamily benets is generally low compared to other employee benets. Osterman (1995), using
data from the Survey of American Establishments on private sector employers with 50 or more employees, reported that work/
family programs are less widespread than the popular press might lead one to believe(pg. 685), with only 2% of employers
offering on-site daycare, 9.4% offering eldercare referral services and 40.2% offering exible work hours.
5.3. The adoption and diffusion of workfamily benets
Why do some employers offer non-mandated workfamily benets, benets which often represent signicant costs, while
others do not? On one hand, organizational theory suggests that institutional pressures dictate which types of organizations are
more or less likely to adopt non-mandated benet programs. On the other hand, the business case for workfamily benets, or the
rational choice argument, contends that employers adopt benets to gain competitive advantage through recruiting and retaining
a high-talent, high-commitment workforce (Galinsky & Stein, 1990). Research in the management and organization literature has
tested both arguments, and the results are somewhat supportive of each.
5.3.1. Institutional pressures and rational choice
Several organizational characteristics have been studied relative to workfamily benets adoption. In general, research has
demonstrated that adoption is more likely among industries with relatively greater diffusion of benets (public sector), and that
larger organizations are more likely to adopt workfamily benets (e.g. Goodstein, 1994; Osterman, 1995), perhaps because they
are more visible and thus subject to more public scrutiny (Kahn & Kamerman, 1987).
Responding to the basic tenet of organizational theory that behavior at the organization level is shaped by social norms and
pressures, Oliver (1991) argued that organizations behave strategically in response to these institutional pressures. Goodstein
(1994) tested this thesis using the adoption of workfamily benets as his focal dependent variable. He found that institutional
pressures, identied as the diffusion of workfamily programs across an industry and geographic region, were related to adoption
at the establishment level. He also concluded that mimetic pressures may be more relevant than coercive pressures when it comes
to workfamily benets.
Consistent with a strategic choice perspective, Goodstein (1994) found that organizations were more likely to adopt work
family programs when there was a perceived benet. He showed that the amount of women in an establishment, and the number
of unemployed women in an industry group, were differentially related to the adoption of workfamily programs, suggesting that
organizations adopt these programs to attract and retain women. While institutional factors were important, so too were technical
factors, suggesting that organizations respond strategically to institutional forces depending on their particular technical strengths
and weaknesses.
Goodstein's (1994) study complements the statistics reported previously, which indicated that certain types of workfamily
benets are more widespread than others, (e.g., exible work arrangements vs. childcare services). Likewise, it ts with Osterman's
(1995) conclusion presented earlier that employers do not necessarily adopt a uniform set of workfamily benets, but instead
adopt those benets that are more or less relevant to their workforce. Together the research evidence directs us to propose that:
Proposition 12a. Employers adopt workfamily benets strategically in order to support the particular needs of their workforce.
Research indicates that different employment relationships are negotiated and enacted with different types of employees (Tsui,
Pearce, Porter, & Tripoli, 1997). Accordingly, employee groups with greater power in negotiation receive more favorable terms.
Applying this logic to workfamily benets, theory and research would suggest that organizations utilizing low-cost, low-skill
labor would be unlikely to offer non-mandated benets like workfamily benets, whereas organizations with more highly skilled
employees are more likely to adopt these benets. In support of this expectation, Konrad and Mangel (2000) found that the
proportion of female and professional employees in an organization was positively related to the adoption of workfamily benets.
Glass & Fujimoto (1995) found that professional and managerial workers were more likely to have access to leave policies and
telecommuting. The authors contended that workers with relatively greater market power are more likely to have access to work
family benets, supporting a rational choice argument for policy adoption.
In a constructive replication of Goodstein's (1994) work, Ingram and Simons (1995) argued that women's power in an
organization (the proportion of women managers) and perceived technical benets from workfamily programs
(remedying problems associated with employees missing work for childcare) should be positively related to adoption,
whereas an organization's countervailing power (i.e. high unemployment rates for women) should be negatively related to
adoption. They found support for the women's power and countervailing power hypotheses, but not the technical benets
hypothesis.
In subsequent research on women and workfamily benets, Milliken, Martins, and Morgan (1998) found, in a survey of
human resource executives, that although the proportion of female employees was unrelated to the adoption of work
family benets, perceptions among human resource executives about the importance of (a) the potential productivity
impact of non-adoption, (b) the increase in women in the labor force, and (c) the salience of changes in family structure
were all positively related to adoption. Taken as a whole, the research evidence suggests to us that when groups have actual
13J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
or perceived power in the labor market, employers will respond to those groups with workfamily benets tailored to their
needs:
Proposition 12b. Workers with relatively greater market power are more likely to have access to workfamily benets than are
workers with relatively less market power.
Consistent with Goodstein (1994) and a rational choice argument for benet adoption, empirical evidence in the management
literature suggests that customer demographics may also be related to workfamily benet adoption. Organizations that market
primarily to or tend to serve families or groups with family-related concerns are more likely to offer workfamily employee
benets (Friedman, 1990).
Proposition 13. Employer adoption of workfamily benets is responsive to the demographics of external organizational constituents
(e.g., customers) such that adoption is more likely when external constituents have greater family-related needs.
5.3.2. Organizational structure and strategy
Research evidence suggests that the adoption of workfamily programs also is dependent on the formal structure of the human
resource function and its particular emphasis on high-commitment. Osterman (1995) found that having an HR department in and
of itself was related to adoption. The ndings implied that the extent to which HRM is planned and organized is key to benet
adoptionand perhaps to the effectiveness of these benets. Testing the hypothesis that organizations expect high levels of
commitment from their employees will also invest in workfamily benets, Osterman also showed that high commitment HRM
practices at the establishment level were positively related to the adoption of workfamily programs. With Osterman's work as a
foundation, we propose that additional research is necessary regarding:
Proposition 14. Employer adoption of workfamily benets is more likely among organizations with (a) an organized HRM department
and (b) a high-commitment HRM strategy.
Drawing from the bundlesapproach to high performance work practices, Ingram and Simons (1995) argued that if work
family benets are going to benet organizations, they should be consistent, complementary and mutually reinforcing. They
proposed that organizations with bundled workfamily benets will outperform rms with relatively unbundled benets, for
which their analysis provided supportat least in terms of perceptual measures of performance. Similarly, Konrad and Mangel
(2000) found that an index of complementary workfamily benets was positively related to an objective measure of
organizational productivity among organizations that employed relatively large proportions of women and professionals. Recent
research also has indicated that integrating workfamily considerations into an organization's broader business strategy is related
to positive career-related outcomes for employees (Kossek, Pichler, Ryan, & Lee, 2006). Thus, a key message of this research is that a
comprehensive, integrated set of workfamily benets is more likely to be related to performance gains for organizations than are
disconnected programs implemented in a non-strategic fashion, which is perhaps typical of most organizations.
Proposition 15. Productivity gains from workfamily benets are more likely among organizations with a consistent and mutually
reinforcing set of benets.
5.4. Utilization of workfamily benets
Scholars have argued that the mere presence of workfamily benets will not lead to desired outcomes for employees or
employers when employee utilization of benets is low (Thompson, Beauvais, & Layness, 1999). Secret (2000) found in a multi-
organization study that while most employees had access to workfamily benets, utilization is most categories was relatively low
considering their availability. For instance, of the employees who had access to exible work arrangements, 37% used them.
Similarly, and more striking, only 1% of employees who had access to childcare services utilized them. Secret (2000) found that
family role and demographic variables such as marital status and dependent care status were generally unrelated to benet
utilization, as were job attribute variables such as salary level and job tenure.Workplace structure characteristics, including sector,
size and culture, however, were all signicant predictors of benet utilization. These results suggest that, when considered
simultaneously, organizational characteristics, more so than family-related responsibilities, are key predictors of benet utilization.
Since employees for whom workfamily benets are intended for do not consistently utilize these benets, it is important to
understand why this is the case. Workfamily scholars argue that there may be an economic penalty associated with the utilization
of workfamily benets. For instance, there is a pervasive perception that face time is important for recognition and, ultimately,
career advancement. In support of this maxim, Glass (2004) found that new mothers who took advantage of workfamily benets
experienced a slower wage growth than mothers who did not use the benets. Consistent with arguments that a lack of visibility in
the workplace, perhaps due to the utilization of benets such as extime, can threaten employee's careers. Judge, Cable, Boudreau,
and Bretz, (1995) found that (long) work hours were positively related to managerial career advancement. The argument that
workfamily benet utilization is low because of perceived negative career repercussions among employees seems legitimate.
5.5. Employee outcomes
Given the traditional focus in the management literature on formal workfamily benets for employees, researchers have
attempted to determine if these benets in fact result in desired outcomes among employeesoutcomes that are ultimately
14 J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
benecial for employers as well. There have been disagreements in the literature in terms of whether or not workfamily benets
are effective for employees and, hence, worthwhile to employers. For instance, despite evidence that alternative work
arrangements are related to increased job satisfaction and decreased turnover (e.g. Thomas & Ganster, 1995), workfamily leaders
such as Christensen and Staines (1990) caution that exible work arrangements do not necessarily increase productivity or
organizational performance. The purpose of this section is to review literature related to employee outcomes of exible work
arrangement benet utilization, as well as the inuence of culture and the outcomes for non-users.
5.5.1. Outcomes of use of exible work arrangements
Research on the outcomes of exible work arrangements is more consistent in its ndings. The literature indicates that these
arrangements are related to increased job satisfaction (Thomas & Ganster, 1995), decreased turnover (Dalton & Mesch, 1990), and
decreased absenteeism (Christensen & Staines, 1990). Similarly, extime has been linked to decreased physical and psychological
symptomatology (Thomas & Ganster, 1995) and decreased workfamily conict (Christensen & Staines, 1990). In their meta-
analysis, Baltes, Briggs, Huff, Wright, & Neuman (1999) found that both exible schedules and compressed work weeks were
related to increased job satisfaction and satisfaction with work schedules. Effect sizes are generally more mixed when it comes to
actual productivity-related outcomes such as absenteeism; however, there may be unidentied moderators or mediators of the
workfamily benet and employee outcome relationship.
5.5.2. Outcomes of use of workfamily supportive culture
Given the potential importance of informal support for work and family in addition to formal workfamily benets,
management research has recently shifted its focus from formal benets per se to cultural support for these benets (Thompson
et al., 1999) and social support for work and family more generally (Allen, 2001; Kossek, Pichler, Hammer, & Bodner, 2007). This
research tends to indicate that the utilization of workfamily benets is often surprisingly low, and that cultural and social support
for work and family is a necessary complement for the effective implementation of these benets (Kossek et al., 2007).
For workfamily benets to be effective, they must be culturally supportedincluding support from direct supervisors.
Empirical results indicate that workfamily benets are positively related to employee attitudes (e.g., organizational commitment)
only when employees believe utilizing them will not result in adverse career consequences (Eaton, 2003). In their study of
organizational cultural support for work and family, Thompson et al. (1999) similarly found that benet utilization was more likely
when benets were more readily available and when their use was supported by managers.
Sahibzada, Hammer, Neal and Kuang (2005) found that the availability of workfamily benets and a supportive workfamily
culture interactively determined employee job satisfaction such that the former was generally important when the latter was low
and vice versa. While these results should not be interpreted to indicate that formal supports are unimportant, they do stress the
importance of interactive effects of formal and informal workfamily supports for employee outcomes.
Proposition 16. The relationship between employee utilization of workfamily benets and employee attitudes such as job satisfaction
is moderated by cultural support for work and family and by support among coworkers and supervisors for utilization, such that it is
more strongly positive at higher levels of the moderator.
5.5.3. Non-user outcomes
Given that some family-supportive benets, such as childcare services, are applicable only to certain employees or groups of
employees, a concern about backlashamong coworkers who lack a need for such benets has developed in the popular press.
Pundits argue that employees who receive no direct benet potentially perceive a lack of equity or justice in the workplace. Survey
data from two companies with on-site childcare centers, however, indicated that attitudes towards childcare centers are more
positive among users or potential users, but that differences in attitudes between users and non-users are not manifested at a more
general level (Rothausen, Gonzalez, Clarke, & O'Dell,1998), indicating that backlash is unlikely. Likewise, Grover and Crocker (1995)
found that employees in general are more attached to organizations that offer workfamily benets, regardless of whether or not
they personally gain from them; however, employees who could take advantage of childcare services (e.g., those who had young
children) were more committed than employees who could not.
Sinclair, Hannigan and Tetrick (1995) argued that social exchange theory provides a logical theoretical framework for
understanding the relationship between workfamily benets and employee attitudes and behaviorsregardless of whether or
not an employee is a user of a particular set of benets. They proposed that organizations and employees reciprocate
demonstrations of commitment, and that positive attitudes and behaviors are exchanged for supportive family-friendly benets.
Proposition 17. Workfamily benets are positively related to employee attitudes such as job satisfaction regardless of whether they
are applicable to all employees or not.
6. Conclusion
The potential for HRM research in employee benets is extensive. Our discussion has been limited to a handful of the most
common or costly benet programs. While other employer-sponsored benets exist (e.g., non-health insurance benets, executive
perquisites, educational tuition reimbursement), because of their salience, we feel that the areas and issues related to health care,
retirement benets, and work and family benets offer HRM the greatest research opportunities to contribute to management
15J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
concern and close the research practitioner gap. We also noted from our review that much of the research related to benets,
especially health care and retirement plans, has been performed from an economics perspective, which has left many managerial
and organizational behavior questions and perspectives unexamined. For example, the research questions we asked and
propositions we developed brought forth issues of individual differences, attitudes and dispositions.
Due to the general dearth of normative benets management research, practitioners are making their way by trial and error.
Prescriptive guidelines are developed through conventional wisdom and hard earned experience, but lack evidence-based
research support or guidance.
Practitioners have not had the luxury to wait on HRM researchers to catch up, because the cost of not making decisions relative
to potentially cost saving programs like consumer-driven health care or dened contribution retirement plans is too high.
However, the other side of the coin is that the cost of making poor decisions in healthcare and retirement benets because of the
lack of supporting HRM research is also potentially high. The propositions we have delineated throughout this article represent
starting points for future research.
References
Adams, G. (1999). Career-related variables and planned retirement age: An extension of Beehr's model. Journal of Vocational Behavior,55,221235.
Agnew, J., Balduzzi, P., & Sunden, A. (2000). Portfolio choice, trading, and returns in a large 401(k) plan.Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston
College CRR WP 2000-06.
Ajzen, I. (1988). Attitudes, personality and behavior. Chicago, IL: Dorsey.
Ajzen, I. (1991). The theory of planned behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,50,179211.
Ajzen, I. (2001). Nature and operation of attitudes. Annual Review of Psychology,52,2758.
Albarracin, D., Fishbein, M., & Godestein, E. (1997). Seeking social support in old age as reasoned action: Structural and volitional determinants in a middle-aged
sample of Argentinean women. Journal of Applied Social Psychology,27, 463476.
Allen, T. D. (2001). Family-supportive work environments: The role of organizational perceptions. Journal of Vocational Behavior,58, 414435.
Allen, H., & Sullivan, S. (2006). Seeing the health in health care costs. Harvard Business Review,84(2), 4856.
Aon Consulting (2007). Spring 2007 Health Care Trend Survey. Retrieved March 8, 2008, from http://www.aon.com/us/busi/hc_consulting/employee_benets_cons/
health_welfare/healthcare_trend_survey_spring07.pdf
Baicker, K. & Levy, H. (2007). Employer health insurance mandates and the risk of unemployment. NBER Working Paper No. 13528.
Baird, I. S., & Thomas, H. (1985). Toward a contingency model of strategic risk taking. Academy of Management Review,10(2), 230243.
Baltes, B., Briggs, T. E., Huff, J. E., Wright, J. A., & Neuman, G. A. (1999). Flexible and compressed workweek schedules: A meta-analysis of their effects on work-
related criteria. Journal of Applied Psychology,84(4), 496513.
Barrick, M. R., & Mount, M. K. (1991). The big ve personality dimensions and job performance: A meta-analysis. Personnel Psychology,44(1), 126.
Barro, J., & Beaulieu, N. (2003). Selection and improvement: Physician responses to nancial incentives. (10017). National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper.
Beehr, T. (1986). The process of retirement: A review and recommendations for future investigation.
Beehr, T., Glazer, S., Nielson, N., & Farmer, S. (2000). Work and nonwork predictors of employees' retirement ages. Journal of Vocational Behavior,57,206225.
Beehr, T., & Newman, J. (1978). Job stress, employee health, and organizational effectiveness: A facet analysis, model, and literature review. Personnel Psych ology,31(4),
665699.
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. (1999). Risk aversion or myopia? Choices in repeated gambles and retirement investments. Management Science,45(3), 364381.
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. (2001). Naïve diversication strategies in retirement saving plans. American Economic Review,91,7998.
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. (2002). How much is investor autonomy worth? Journal of Finance,57, 15931616.
Bernasek, A., & Shwiff, S. (2001). Gender, risk, and retirement. Journal of Economic Issues,35(2), 345356.
Bodie, Z., & Merton, R. C. (1993). Pension benet guarantees in the United States: A functional analysis. In R. Schmitt(Ed.), The future of pensions in the United States
Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Bond, J., Thompson, C., Galinsky, E., & Prottas, D. (2003). Highlights of the National Study of the Changing Workforce. Washington, D.C.: Families and Work Institute.
Boudreau, J. W., & Ramstad, P. M. (2007). Beyond HR: Extending the paradigm through a talent decision science. In J. Storey, D. Ulrich & P. Wright (Eds.), Routledge
companion to strategic human resource management London, UK: Routledge.
Bowen, D., & Ostroff, C. (2004). Understanding HRMemployer performance linkages: The role of the strengthof the HRM system. Academy of Management
Review,29(2), 203221.
Bromiley, P., & Curley, S. P. (1992). Individual differences in risk taking. In F. J. Yates (Ed.), Risk Taking Behavior (pp. 87132). New York: John Wiley.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (2000). National Compensation Survey. U.S. Department of Labor.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (2005). Employee benets in private industry. U.S. Department of Labor.
Burtless, G. (2003). What do we know about the risk of individual account pensions? Evidence from industrial countries. AEA Papers and Proceedings,93(2),
354359.
Chernew, M., Cutler, D. M., & Keenan, P. S. (2005). Increasing health insurance costs and the decline in insurance coverage. Health Services Research,40(4),
1021 1039.
Choi, J., Laibson, D., Madiran, B. & Metrick, A. (2001). For better or for worse: Default effects and 401(k) savings behavior. (8651, 2001) NBER Working Paper 8651.
Christensen, K. E., & Staines, G. L. (1990). A viable solution to work/family conict? Journal of Family Issues,11 (4), 455467.
Clark, R., Harper, L., & Pitts, M. (1997). Faculty pension choices in a public institution: Dened benetanddened contribution plans. TIAA-CREF Research Dialogues,vol. 50.
Clark, R. L., & McDermed, A. (1990). The choice of pension plans in a changing regulatory environment. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute.
Conference Board (2007). Employee benets: Second generation wellness and productivity. New York: Conference Board Institute.
Dalton, D., & Mesch, D. (1990). The impact of exible scheduling on employee attendance and turnover. Administrative Science Quarterly,35,370387.
Danna, K., & Grifn, R. W. (1999). Health and well-being in the workplace: A review and synthesis of the literature. Journal of Management,25,357384.
Davis, M. M. (1934). The American approach to health insurance. Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly,12,201217.
Davis, M. M., & Rorem, C. R. (1932). The crisis in hospital nance and other studies in hospital economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Deadrick, D. L., & Gibson, P. A. (2007). An examination of the research-practice gap in HR: Comparing topics of interest to HR academics and HR professionals.
Human Resource Management Review,17,131139.
Dencker, J. C., Joshi, A., & Martocchio, J. J. (2007). Employee benets as context for intergenerational conict. Human Resource Management Review,17, 208220.
Dreher, G. F., Ash, R. A., & Bretz, R. D. (1988). Benet coverage and employee cost: Critical factors in explaining compensation satisfaction. Personnel Psychology,41,
237254.
Dulebohn, J. H. (2002). An investigation of the determinants of investment risk behavior in dened contribution pension plans. Journal of Management,42(1), 125.
Dulebohn, J. H., & Murray, B. (2007). Retirement savings behavior of higher education employees. Research in Higher Education,48(5), 45582.
Dulebohn, J. H. , Murray, B., & Sun, M. (2000). Selection among employer-sponsored pension plans: The role of individual differences. Personnel Psychology,53(2),
405432.
Dulebohn, J. H., & Werling, S. (2007). Compensation research: Yesterday, today, and tomorrow. Human Resource Management Review,17,191207.
16 J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
Eaton, S. C. (2003). If you can use them: Flexibility policies, organizational commitment, and perceived performance. Industrial Relations,42(2), 145167.
Ellis, R. P., & Manning, W. G. (2007). Optimal health insurance for prevention and treatment. Journal of Health Economics,26(6), 11281150.
Employee Benet Plan Review (2001). Investment options in 401(k) plans continue to expand. Employee Benet Plan Review,56(2), 36.
EBRI (Employee Benet Research Institute) (2008). EBRI databook on employee benets.Washington, D.C.: Employee Benet Research Institute (Chapter 1).
Falk, I. S., Rorem, C. R., & Ring, M. D. (1933). The cost of medical care. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Faulkner, E. J. (1960). Health insurance. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Freidberg, L. (2007). The recent trend towards later retirement.: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College Series 9.
Friedman, D. E. (1990). Child care makes it work: A guide to employer support for child care. Washington, D.C: National Association for the Education of Young
Children.
Funk, S. G., Rapoport, A., & Jones, L. V. (1979). Investing capital on safe and risky alternatives: An experimental study. Journal of Experimental Psychology,108,
415550.
Galinsky, E., & Stein, P. J. (1990). The impact of human resource policies on employees: Balancing work/family life. Journal of Family Issues,8,368383.
Gaynor, M., Hass-Wilson, D., & Vogt, W. B. (1999). Change, consolidation, and competition in health care markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives,13(1), 141164.
Gaynor, M., Rebitzer, J. B., & Taylor, L. J. (2004). Physician incentives in health maintenance employers. Journal of Political Economy,112(4), 915931.
Gerhart, B. A., & Milkovich, G. T. (1992). Employee compensation: research and practice. In M. D. Dunnette & L.M. Hough (Eds.), Handbook of industrial and employer
psychology, (2nd ed.) Palo Alto, CA: Consulting Psychologists Press.
Glass, J. (2004). Blessing or curse: Workfamily policies and mother's wage growth over time. Work and Occupations,31, 367394.
Glass, J., & Fujimoto, T. (1995). Employer characteristics and the provision of family responsive policies. Work and Occupations,22(4), 380411.
Goldsmith, J. (2001). The new health-cost crisis. Harvard Business Review,79(10), 2021.
Goodstein, J. D. (1994). Institutional pressures and strategic responsiveness: Employer involvement in workfamily issues. Academy of Management Journal,37(2),
350382.
Grover, S. L., & Crocker, K. J. (1995). Who appreciates family-responsive human resource policies: the impact of family-friendly policies on the organizational
attachment of parents and non-parents. Personnel Psychology,48,271287.
Gustman, A. L., & Steinmeier, T. L. (1992). The stampede toward dened contribution pension plans: Fact or ction? Industrial Relations,31(2), 361369.
Harris, M., & Fink, L. (1994). Employee benet programs and attitudinal and behavioral outcomes. A preliminary model. Human Resource Management Review,4,
117129.
Henderson, J. W. (2002). Health economics and policy (2nd ed.). Cincinnati: South-Western.
Heneman, R., Greenberger, D., & Strasser, S. (1988). The relationship between pay-for performance perceptions and pay satisfaction. Personnel Psychology,41,
745 761.
Heneman, H., III, & Schwab, D. (1985). Pay satisfaction: Its multidimensional nature and measurement. International Journal of Psychology,20,129141.
Hewitt Associates (2002). Archival records and benet communications. IL: Lincolnshire.
Hewitt Associates (2005). Microhistory of employee benets and compensation 17942005. Retrieved March 8, 2008 from http://www.hewittassociates.com/
_MetaBasicCMAssetCache_/Assets/Articles/microhistory.pdf
Hewitt Associates (2007). Survey ndings: Global viewpoint health and productivity 2007. Retrieved March 8, 2008 http://www.hewittassociates.com/
_MetaBasicCMAssetCache_/Assets/Articles/Global_Viewpoint_Health_Productivity_2007.pdf
Hiles, A., Hogg, B., Tapia, A., & Winkler, J. (2007). Personal responsibility in benets. Benets Quarterly,23(2), 2532.
Holden, S., & VanDerhei, J. (2006). 401(k) participant account balances. Journal of Financial Service Professionals, 60,5,7989.
Ingram, P., & Simons, T. (1995). Institutional and resource dependence determinants of responsiveness to workfamily issues. Academy of Management Journal,38
(5), 14661482.
Institutional Investor (2001). Option overload? Institutional Investor,35(12), 121.
Jacobs-Lawson, J. M., & Hershey, D. A. (2005). Inuence of future time perspective, nancial knowledge, and nancial risk tolerance on retirement saving behaviors.
Financial Services Review,14(4), 331344.
Jacoby, S. (1997). Modern manors: Welfare capitalism since the new deal. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Jianakoplos, N. A., & Bernasek, A. (1998). Are women more risk averse? Economic Inquiry,36(4), 620630.
Judge, T. A., Cable, D. M., Boudreau, J. W., & Bretz, R. D., Jr. (1995). An empirical investigation of the predictors of executive career success. Personnel Psychology,48,
485519.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica,47, 263290.
Kahn, A., & Kamerman, S. (1987). Child care: Facing the hard choices. Dover, MA: Auburn House.
Kaiser/HRET (2007). Kaiser/HRET employer health benets survey. Retrieved on March 5, 2008 from http://www.kff.org/insurance/7672/
Kaufman, B. (2004). Theoretical perspectives on the employment relationship. Ithaca, NY: Industrial and Labor Relations Press.
Kelley, B. C. (2003). Restraining trend in plan payments: Disease management of six conditions may be the key. Compensation & Benets Review,35(4), 1317.
Kelly, E. L. (2006). Workfamily policies: The United States in international perspective. In M. Pitt-Catsouphes, E. E. Kossek & S. Sweet (Eds.), The Work and Family
Handbook: Multidisciplinary Perspectives and Approaches.
Kessler, R., & Stang, P. (2006). Health and work productivity: Making the business case for quality health care. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Kim, S., & Feldman, D. (2000). Working in retirement: The antecedents of bridge employment and its consequences for quality of life in retirement. Academy of
Management Journal,43(6), 11951210.
Konrad, A. M., & Mangel, R. (2000). The impact of work-life programs on rm productivity. Strategic Management Journal,21, 12251237.
Kossek,E. E., & Pichler, S.(2006). EEO and the management of diversity. In P. Boxell, J.Purcell & P. Wright (Eds.),Handbook of human resource management(pp. 251272).
Oxford Press.
Kossek, E.E., Pichler, S., Hammer, L., & Bodner, T. (2007). Contextualizing workplace supports for family: An integrative meta-analysis of direct and moderating
linkages to workfamily conict. In J. Cleveland (Chair) Social support, leadership, and workfamily outcomes. Society or IndustrialOrganizational Psychology
(SIOP) Conference, New York, NY.
Kossek, E.E., Pichler, S., Ryan, A.M., & Lee, M.D. (2006). Exploring linkages between SHRM, work life strategy, and implementing new ways of working for
professionals. In G.N. Powell (Chair) The opt-out revolt: Uncovering the truth about the media hype about women exiting the workforce. Academy of
Management Meeting, Atlanta, GA.
Kramerich, L. B. (1999). Statement Leslie B. Kramerich, Deputy Assistant Secretary For Policy Pension And Welfare Benets Administration, Before the Subcommittee on
Oversight Ways And Means Committee, U.S. House Of Representatives March 23, 1999. Washington DC: Pension and Welfare Benets Administration.
Levinson, D. (1986). A conception of adult development. American Psychologist,41,313.
Lyons, A. C., & Yilmazer, T. (2004). How does marriage affect the allocation of assets in women's dened contribution plans? CRR WP, Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for
Retirement Research at Boston College.
Mackenzie, K. D. (1998). A framework for managing risky situations. International Journal of Organizational Analysis,6(1), 531.
Madrian, B. C., & Shea, D. F. (2001). The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) participation and savings behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,116 (4),
114 91188.
Maier, T. (2004). On phenomenology and classication of hoarding: A review. Acta Psychiatrica Scandinavica,110 (5), 323337.
Manning, M. R., Jackson, C. N., & Fusilier, M. R. (1996).Occupati onalstress, soci alsupport, and the costs of health care. Academy of Management Journal,39,738750.
Martin, A. (2006). Risk taking behaviours within sexual health. Primary Health Care,16 (10), 3134.
Martocchio, J. J. (2003). Employee benets. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
McGoldrick, M., & Carter, B. (1982). The family life cycle. In Froma Walsh (Ed.), Normal family processes New York: Guilford Publications.
Micelli, M., & Lane, M. (1991). Antecedents of pay satisfaction: A review and extension. In K. Rowland & G. Ferris (Eds.), Research in personnel and human resources
management (pp. 235309). Greenwich, CT: JAI.
17J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
Milliken, F. J., Martins, L. L., & Morgan, H. (1998). Explaining organizational responsiveness to workfamily issues: The role of human resource executives as issue
interpreters. Academy of Management Journal,41, 580592.
Mitchell, O. S., & Moore, J. F. (1998). Can Americans afford to retire? New evidence on retirement saving adequacy. The Journal of Risk and Insurance,65(3), 371400.
Mitchell, O. S., & Rappaport, A. M. (1993). Innovations and trends in pension plan coverage,type, and design. In Ray Schmitt (Ed.), The future of pensions in the United
States (pp. 5391). Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania.
Munnell, A., Sass, S., & Aubry, J. (2006). Employer survey: 1 of 4 boomers won't retire because they can't. An issue in brief: Center for Retirement Research at Boston
College Series 6.
Munnell, A., & Sunden, A. (2006). 401(k) plans are still coming up short. An Issue in Brief: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College,vol. 43.
Munnell, A. H., Sunden, A., & Taylor, C. (2000). What determines 401(k) participation and contributions? CRR WP, Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research
at Boston College.
Nishii, L. H., & Wright, P. (2008). Variability at multiple levels of analysis: Implications for strategic human resource management. In D. B. Smith (Ed.), The people
make the place (pp. 225248). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
Oliver, C. (1991). Strategic responses to institutional processes. Academy of Management Review,16,145179.
Osterman, P. (1995). Work/family programs and the employment relationship. Administrative Science Quarterly,40(4), 681701.
Parker, D., Manstead, A. S. R., Stradling, S. G., & Reason, J. T. (1992). Intention to commit driving violations: An application of the theory of planned behavior. Journal
of Applied Psychology,77(1), 94101.
Patterson, M. P. (2004). Dened contribution health plan to consumer driven health benets: Evolution and experience. Benets Quarterly,20(2), 4959.
Perry, V., & Morris, M. (2005). Who is in control? The role of self-perception, knowledge, and income in explaining consumer nancial behavior. Journal of Consumer
Affairs,39(2), 299313.
Porterba, J. M. (2004). Portfolio risk and self-directed retirement saving programmes. The Economic Journal,11 4(494), 2653.
Reinecke, J., Schmidt, P., & Ajzen, I. (1997). Birth control versus AIDS prevention: A hierarchical model of condom use among young people. Journal of Applied Social
Psychology,27(9), 743759.
Rivis, A., & Sheeran, P. (2003). Descriptive norms as an additional predictor in the theory of planned behavior: A meta-analysis. Current Psychology: Developmental,
Learning, Personality, Social,22(3), 218233.
Rothausen, T. J., Gonzalez, J. A., Clarke, N. E., & O'Dell, L. L. (1998). Family-friendly backlashFact or ction? The case of organizations' onsite child care centers.
Personnel Psychology,51,685705.
Sahibzada, K., Hammer, L. B., Neal, M. B., & Kuang, D. C. (2005). The moderating effects of work-family role Combinations and Work-Family Organizational Culture
on the Relationship between family-friendly workplace supports and job satisfaction. Journal of Family Issues,26,120.
Salas, E., & Cannon-Bowers, J. (2001). The science of training: A decade of progress. Annual Review of Psychology,52,471499.
Scofea, L. A. (1994). The development and growth of employer-provided health insurance. Monthly Labor Review,117,310.
Secret, M. (2000). Identifying the family, job, and workplace characteristics of employees who use workfamily benets. Family Relations: Interdisciplinary Journal
of Applied Family Studies,49(2), 217225.
Sethi-Iyengar, S., Huberman, G., & Jiang, W. (2004). How much choice is too much? Contributions to 401(k) retirement plans. In O. Mitchell & S. Utkus (Eds.), Pension
design and structure: New lessons from behavioral nance Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Seyler, D. L., Monroe, P. A., & Garand, J. C. (1995). Balancing work and family: The role of employer-supported child care benets. Journal of Family Issues,16,
170 194.
Shapira, Z. (1995). Risk taking: A managerial perspective. New York: Russell Sage.
Sharon, C., & Donahue, T. (2006). Consumer-driven health care: Lessons from the rst ve years. Benets Quarterly,22(2), 1822.
Sinclair, R., Hannigan, M., & Tetrick, L. (1995). Benet coverage and employee attitudes: A social exchange perspective. In L. E. Tetrick & J. Barling (Eds.), Changing
employment relations (pp. 163185). Washington, DC: American Psychological Association.
Sitkin, S. B., & Pablo, A. L. (1992). Reconceptualizing the determinants of risk behavior. Academy of Management Review,17(1), 938.
Slovic, P. (1972). Information processing, situation specicity and generality of risk taking behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,22,128134.
Sunden, A. E., & Surette, B. J. (1998). Gender differences in the allocation of assets in retirement savings plans. AEA Papers and Proceedings,88(2), 207211.
Thaler, R. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economic Letters,8,201207.
Thaler, R., & Shefrin, H. (1981). An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy,89, 392406.
Thomas, L. T., & Ganster, D. C. (1995). Impactof family-supportive work variables on workfamily conict and strain: A control perspective. Personnel Psychology,80(1),
615.
Thompson, C. A., Beauvais, L. L., & Lyness, K. S. (1999). When workfamily benets are not enough: The inuence of workfamily culture on benet utilization,
organizational attachment, and workfamily conict. Journal of Vocational Behavior,54, 392415.
Tsui, A. S., Pearce, J. L., Porter, L. W., & Tripoli, A. M. (1997). Alternative approaches to employeeorganization relationships: Does investment in employees pay off?
Academy of Management Journal,40, 10891121.
Williams, M. L. (1995). Antecedents of employee benet satisfaction: A test of a model. Journal of Management,21, 10971128.
Williams, M. L., & MacDermid, S. M. (1994). Linkages between employee benets and attitudinal and behavioral outcomes: A research review and agenda. Human
Resource Management Review,4,131160.
Williams, M. L., Malos, S. B., & Palmer, D. K. (2002). Benet system and benet level satisfaction: An expanded model of antecedents and consequences. Journal of
Management,28,195215.
Wilson, A. (2003). Bill Ford: Let's look at national health care. Automotive News (November, 24, 2003).
Wiseman, D., & Levin, I. (1996). Comparing risky decision-making under conditions of real and hypothetical consequences. Organizational Behavior and Human
Decision Processes,66(3), 241250.
Wolff, S. (2003). Employer health: Beyond integrated disability management. Compensation & Benets Review,35(4), 712.
18 J.H. Dulebohn et al. / Human Resource Management Review xxx (2008) xxxxxx
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Please cite this article as: Dulebohn, J. H., et al., Employee benets: Literature review and emerging issues, Human Resource
Management Review (2008), doi:10.1016/j.hrmr.2008.10.001
... Employee benefits represent a significant part of the total compensation offered by organizations (Dulebohn et al., 2009;Giancola, 2012;Lin et al., 2014). Organizations increasingly recognize the need to invest in employee benefits in order to attract, motivate and retain talented employees (Dulebohn et al., 2009;Adams & Artz, 2015;Blumen, 2015). ...
... Employee benefits represent a significant part of the total compensation offered by organizations (Dulebohn et al., 2009;Giancola, 2012;Lin et al., 2014). Organizations increasingly recognize the need to invest in employee benefits in order to attract, motivate and retain talented employees (Dulebohn et al., 2009;Adams & Artz, 2015;Blumen, 2015). The significance of benefits means that referring to them as "fringe" benefits as it were, is now a misnomer (Budd, 2004a). ...
... Employee benefits are inducements and services employers provide to employees aside the pay they receive for performance of their work (Dulebohn et al., 2009;Yanadori, 2015). Compensation therefore comprised "all forms of financial returns, intangible services and benefits employees receive as part of the employment relationship" (Milkovich et al., 2011, as in cited in Yanadori, 2015. ...
Article
Full-text available
Drawing upon the ability-motivation-opportunity (AMO) framework and social exchange theory, this study examined the effect of HR practices (training, employee benefits, and employee participation) on employee attitude (satisfaction, affective commitment, normative commitment and continuance commitment). Primary data was collected from 521 medical workers (excluding medical doctors) in a large public hospital in Makurdi through the use of questionnaire. Results of multiple regression analysis indicates a positive effect of HR practices on job satisfaction, affective commitment, and normative commitment. However, the effect of HR practices on continuance commitment was negative. This implies that respondents in the study have a social exchange relationship with their organization. The study recommends that managers of public hospitals should consider employees as important stakeholders and invest in HR practices that improves their skills and abilities, as well as motivate and provide opportunities for employees to contribute to workplace decisions. This will engender positive attitudes that benefit both employees and their organizations.
... Employee benefits, sometimes called fringe benefits, are defined as the non-wage components of remuneration (ABS, 2013a;Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2015). They are a significant component of compensation or 'total reward', representing an estimated 10-20 per cent of total compensation costs in Australia, the US and the UK (Shields and North-Samardzic, 2016;Dulebohn, et al., 2009;Tremblay, Sire and Pelchat, 1998). As is the case in financial planning, the Australian context for benefits is quite different to other developed economies. ...
... Rather, benefits may include special paid leave, health and wellbeing programs, career development such as training, and employee discounts. Employee benefits also differ between and within Australian industries, depending upon company and industry choice of 'best fit' or what may provide employers with a competitive advantage in attracting and retaining staff (Dulebohn, et al., 2009). Common benefits in the Australian financial services industry include salary sacrificing, share equity plans, and discounts on proprietary financial products. ...
Article
Full-text available
The Australian financial services industry has been a leader in offering flexible work policies, positioning them as a solution to the tensions between women’s dual work and family roles. While Australian legislation provides the right to request flexible work, this study uncovers how, in one finance organisation, flexible work is framed as an employee benefit within a suite of benefits. The study shows that employees using flexible work arrangements are less likely to understand and know how to access the full range of benefits, many of which have short- and longterm financial implications. This has consequences for the long-term financial security of women (as the heaviest users of flexible work arrangements) and for financial planners, both as employees of organisations in the Australian finance industry and as providers of advice to women working in this sector.
... But non-significant results are also reported, for example by Williams et al. (2002) and de la Torre-Ruiz et al. (2019). One possible explanation for insignificant results is that age-specific effects come into play (Cennamo and Gardner, 2008;Dulebohn et al., 2009;Gabrielova and Buchko, 2021;Martin et al., 2021). ...
... Dencker et al. (2007, p. 214) note: "Older workers are more likely to be concerned about sufficient retirement income and the rising costs of medical care and prescription drug costs". In contrast, younger employees do not care about economic and health security that much (Dulebohn et al., 2009;Hall et al., 2017). Although it is argued that studies on health benefits are scarce (Xavier, 2014) Intention to leave during no heterogeneous effects by age groups emerged in the studies by Veth et al. (2019), Miller (2016 and Eriksson and Kristensen (2014). ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose The study's objective is to estimate the association of specific perceived employer-provided benefits on employees' intention to leave in different age cohorts during coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19). Informed by the psychological theories of ageing, the authors propose three age-cohort-specific hypotheses in three motivational domains: security and health benefits, flexible work arrangement and education-related benefits. Design/methodology/approach The authors use a large survey of employees in Estonia (n = 7,209) conducted in 2020 and test the association of specific benefits and their interactions with age on employees' intention to leave. Findings The results show that older cohorts are generally less prone to leave their jobs. Benefits that employers could use during the COVID-19 crisis generally had negative associations with the intention to leave, but age-specific differences were negligible; only the perceived provision of flexible work arrangements reduced the younger cohort's intention to leave relatively more. Originality/value This study is one of the few that allows us to make inferences regarding the benefits preferences amongst the working population during an unprecedented health crisis.
... Providing benefits that correspond with the choices, needs, and values of employees can help firms improve employee happiness, commitment, and engagement. This demonstrates how crucial it is from a strategic standpoint to create and carry out successful benefit programs that promote company performance (Dulebohn et al., 2009). ...
Article
Full-text available
This research investigates the impact of various HR policies on millennial employee engagement.Through a comprehensive literature review and empirical analysis, the study identifies key factors that influence millennial engagement. Primary data was collected using a structured questionnaire from 232 working millennials in the city of New Delhi, NCR. Reliability and validity of the questionnaire have been tested. The results indicate a positive relationship between employee training, flexible work practices, digital orientation, and employee benefits with employee engagement. Conversely, employee decision-making and participation, as well as pay for performance management and pay for performance, show a negative relationship with employee engagement. These findings highlight the importance of aligning HR policies with the preferences and values of millennials to enhance their engagement and ultimately improve organizational performance. KEYWORDS: Millennials, Employee Engagement, HR practices
... Types of benefits could be different based on industry or organization. Benefits were also influenced by workforce or job market environment, including competition for talent, and management perceptions of what will produce favorable employee outcomes (Dulebohn, Molloy, Pichler, & Murray, 2009). Benefits, especially health benefits differ from one country to another country. ...
... Work-family benefits have a favorable impact on employee attitudes like job satisfaction. [23] This finding can be explained by the social exchange theory that companies and employees reciprocate dedication and commitment and that family-friendly benefits are traded for cooperative attitudes and behaviors. [24] Another example demonstrating the evolution of workforce preference and expectation beyond the traditional perks is employer-supported volunteering (ESV) benefits. ...
Article
Full-text available
Despite increasing awareness of employee benefits, there are still relatively few studies that provide a thorough examination of how employee benefits affect various performance measures organizations. This paper provides an overview of the definition and categories of employee benefits, important employee benefits from the employee's perspective, and the influencing factors, then analyze reasons contributing to the mismatch of employees' expectations and actual benefits offered and the impacts of benefits on four aspects of business performance, namely retention, engagement, commitment, motivation, and productivity. This systemic and comprehensive understanding of employee benefits and their impacts on business performance contribute to the managerial implication of human resource management to redesign the compensation package to meet the expectations of the workforce and, in return, achieve desired performance.
Article
Mental health has grown increasingly important as an aspect of employee well-being, with organizations expected to address these needs through offerings to support employee mental health. Broad societal forces like stigma and low levels of literacy surrounding mental health make it challenging for many people to understand these offerings. As the marketplace for these offerings grows to meet this demand, employees, HR professionals, and business leaders need better resources to understand, organize, and distinguish among their choices. The current research offers a 3-dimensional taxonomy for organizing these offerings, distinguishing them according to their (a). Primary Purpose-To Restore or Enrich; (b). Delivery Agent Location-External or Internal; (c). Latitude in Providing-Legally Required or Voluntary Provided. We provide theoretical approaches for scholars to consider these offerings’ impact in workplaces, and briefly demonstrate the taxonomy’s value in organizing some of the commonly available offerings in many modern workplaces. Finally, we provide two attainable research avenues for researchers to explore to inform organizational stakeholders on the (1). prevalence, costs, outcomes of these offerings in the workforce and (2). helpers and hurdles to employees' using these offerings.
Article
Employer-sponsored health insurance benefits are essential for employee productivity, performance and employee well-being. However, increasing health insurance costs are a primary concern for employers and employees alike. Despite its importance, there is a lack of research on employer-sponsored health insurance benefits from the perspective of employer attractiveness. To address this gap, we reviewed the literature on the importance of health insurance benefits in enhancing employer attractiveness. In addition, we discussed emerging issues related to health insurance benefits for future research. These issues involve increasing employee contribution to employer-sponsored health insurance benefits, customised health insurance benefits plans, health benefits communication and the issue of health benefits administration sludge which impacts employer attractiveness. We also proposed a model related to employer-sponsored health insurance benefits variables and employer attractiveness, which can be tested in future research.
Chapter
Full-text available
Human resource management of equal employment opportunity (EEO) and workforce diversity involves the development and implementation of employer policies and practices that not only create a diverse workplace, but foster a supportive culture to enable individuals from different backgrounds to be able to work together productively to achieve organizational goals. Ensuring EEO, and the creation of a work environment that capitalizes on the benefits of a diverse workforce, are of growing importance for organizational effectiveness. Most employees around the globe work in organizations with a diversity and multicultural dimension to their business. This article aims to discuss the HRM perspective regarding EEO and diversity. Towards this end, it defines core concepts, and then examines labor force shifts and other rationales for managing EEO/diversity. It concludes by discussing ‘how’ firms are managing these issues. Future research implications are integrated at the end of relevant sections.
Article
A model of strategic risk taking incorporating environmental, industrial, organizational, decision maker, and problem variables is presented. The model is intended to be both a preliminary conceptualization of strategic risk taking and a stimulant for future research on risk taking in strategic management decisions. Relevant research from a number of disciplines is summarized, and the potential impacts of particular variables on the propensity to take strategic risks are examined.
Article
Corporate health costs are again shooting up at double-digit rates. Employers need to take responsibility for that cost increase and redesign the structure of their health benefits.