ArticlePDF Available

Has China De-industrialized Other Developing Countries?

Authors:

Abstract

China’s opening to trade is interpreted as a shift in world average factor endowments, which altered the comparative advantage of other countries. In the rest of the world on average, this shift lowered the share of labour-intensive manufacturing in the sum of labour-intensive manufacturing and primary output by 1–3.5 percentage points, and the corresponding export share by 1.5–5 points. The de-industrialising effect varied among countries, and was clearest in East Asia. It was significant, but not big enough to be a serious threat to growth or equity in most other developing countries. KeywordsDevelopment–Heckscher-Ohlin theory–China–De-industrialisation
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
1
Working Paper Number 175
Has China de-industrialised other developing countries?
Adrian Wood* and Jörg Mayer**
1
adrian.wood@qeh.ox.ac.uk joerg.mayer@unctad.org
China’s opening to trade is interpreted as a shift in world average factor
endowments, which altered the comparative advantage of other countries. In the rest
of the world on average, this shift reduced the ratio of labour-intensive manufacturing
to primary production by 7-10% for output and 10-15% for exports. China’s impact
is clearest on East Asian countries: in other developing regions, it was swamped by
other causes of structural change. The de-industrialising effect was significant, but
not big enough to be a serious threat to growth or equity in most other developing
countries.
January 2009
* Department of International Development, Queen Elizabeth House, Oxford
** United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva
1
Mauro Caselli provided extensive and excellent research assistance in the compilation and analysis of
the data. Alicia Rapin also helped with the data. Useful comments on earlier versions and related
presentations were provided by seminar and conference audiences at Oxford, Sussex, Nottingham,
Manchester and WIDER.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
2
1. Introduction
The least disputable of China’s impacts on the world has been the explosion of studies
of China’s impact on the world. These range from broad analyses of global payments
imbalances and interest rates (e.g. Dooley et al., 2004) to detailed examination of the
exports of particular commodities by particular countries (e.g. Gallagher et al., 2008).
Most of them refer to the past, but some forecast the future (e.g. Yang, 2003; Mayer
and Fajarnes, 2008). They have used various methods, including inspection of trade
data (e.g. Lall et al. 2005; Mesquita Moreira, 2007; Kaplinsky and Morris, 2008),
revealed comparative advantage calculations (Lederman et al., 2008), gravity models
(e.g. Hanson and Robertson, 2007; Greenaway et al., 2008) and computable general
equilibrium (CGE) models (e.g. Dimaranan et al., 2006). To survey this literature
would require an entire paper, but good bibliographies are available in Goldstein et al
(2006), Winters and Yusuf (2006) and Broadman (2007).
The focus of the present paper is on how the entry of China into world markets over
the past three decades has affected the broad sectoral structures of other economies,
especially developing ones. It looks in particular at the balance between the two
broad traded sectors that matter most to developing countries, namely labour-intensive
manufacturing, which is often said to have been harmed by competition from China,
and primary production, which is often said to have gained from increased demand by
China. The effects of China on both these sectors in other developing countries have
aroused concerns and suspicions about retarded industrialisation, reduced employment
and increased inequality in Africa, Latin America and the rest of Asia.
The analysis in this paper goes beyond most other studies of the impact of China by
examining the sectoral structure not only of exports but also of output (in this respect
being similar to the CGE studies). It is also set in a more clearly specified theoretical
framework – that of Heckscher and Ohlin (H-O) – than most other studies. The
relevance of H-O is contested by Rodrik (2006), who finds China’s exports to be more
sophisticated than normal for its level of development, but his results are challenged
by Xu (2007), Amiti and Freund (2008) and Schott (2008). Our own earlier work
(Mayer and Wood, 2001) also suggests that China’s export structure is rather well
explained by its factor endowments.
Section 2 shows how, in H-O theory, the entry of China into world markets should
affect the sectoral structures of other countries. It also outlines the empirical method
to be applied in the rest of the paper. Section 3 describes the sources of our data, and
their strengths and weaknesses. Section 4 explains and applies our methods for
calculating the impact of China on world average endowments. Section 5 estimates
the effects of endowments on output and export structures. Section 6 combines the
results of the two previous sections into predictions of the impact of China on output
and export structures in other countries, and then compares the predictions with actual
changes in these structures. Section 7 concludes.
2. Theory and method
The impact of China on other countries can be interpreted in H-O theory as occurring
through a shift in world average factor endowments. The comparative advantage of a
country depends on its endowments not in isolation but relative to the endowments of
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
3
all other countries involved in trade. This comparator group was altered by China’s
emergence from near-autarky, because of its size and distinctive endowment structure,
and hence so was the comparative advantage of other countries.
More specifically, as will be documented later, China’s opening to trade effectively
lowered the world average land/labour ratio and increased the share of workers with a
basic education in the world labour force. The relative endowments of other countries
were thus shifted in the opposite directions, which tended to move their comparative
advantage away from labour-intensive manufacturing, which requires a lot of workers
with a basic education but not much land. The corresponding increase in comparative
advantage for developing countries was mainly in primary production, which uses a
lot of land; for developed countries, it was mainly in skill-intensive manufacturing
and services, which need workers with more than a basic education.
The mechanism by which this shift in world average endowments took effect was a
vast expansion of China’s exports, concentrated on labour-intensive manufactures, in
which its own endowments give it a comparative advantage, and of its imports, which
are concentrated on primary products and skill-intensive manufactures, in which it has
a comparative disadvantage. These changes in trade flows altered relative prices on
world markets and shifted the demand functions faced by producers in other countries
– inwards for labour-intensive manufactures, and outwards for primary commodities
and skill-intensive manufactures.
A formal model
The impact of China can be analysed more precisely by extending the H-O model in
Wood (2009), which refers to one country and holds world endowments constant, to
include the effects of changes in world average endowments. We begin by explaining
the single-country model, before turning to its extension.
Equation (1) shows how a country’s relative outputs of labour-intensive manufactures
(M) and primary products (P) are influenced by its endowments of three factors:
workers with a basic education (B), land or natural resources (N) and the total labour
force (L). The equation links proportional changes (denoted by hats) in relative sales
of M and P by country z in market ž,
zz
P
zz
M
qq
(
(
ˆˆ
, to proportional changes, and
, in two endowment ratios, B/L and N/L.
z
L
z
B
vv
ˆˆ
z
L
z
N
vv
ˆˆ
()
(
)
(
)
(
)
[
]
z
L
z
N
z
NLNPNM
z
L
z
B
z
BLBPBM
zz
MP
zz
P
zz
M
vvvvqq
ˆˆˆˆˆˆ
+=
ϕθθϕθθε
(
(
(
(1)
The terms in the square bracket specify how changes in endowments alter the relative
production costs of M and P. Changes in endowment ratios change the relative prices
of the factors concerned (in the opposite directions, via the φ’s, whose size depends
inversely on the scope for substitution among factors and goods).
2
The changes in
2
More precisely, on the scope both for substitution among factors in particular sectors in response to
changes in factor prices and for shifts in the sectoral structure of production in response to changes in
the prices of goods (across all the sectors of the economy, not only between M and P). The scope for
such sectoral shifts depends inversely on the level of the country’s trade costs. The negative sign on
the elasticity φ is cancelled in equation (1) by the negative sign on ε. In the standard Heckscher-Ohlin-
Samuelson model, with countries in a single cone of diversification, changes in endowments would not
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
4
factor prices alter the relative production costs of M and P via the (θθ) terms. Each
θ is the share of a factor in the cost of a good: for example, θ
NP
is the share of land in
the cost of primary production. The effects of changes in relative factor prices on the
relative production costs of the two goods depend on the differences between the cost
shares: for example, because θ
BM
θ
BP
is positive, a relative rise in the price of basic-
educated workers raises the relative cost of labour-intensive manufactures.
Changes in relative production costs and thus in relative producer prices (at the farm
gate or factory gate) alter the relative sales, and hence outputs, of M and P, to a degree
governed by the first term of equation (1),
zz
MP
(
ε
, which is the elasticity of relative
demand for country z’s varieties of M and P in market ž. As explained in Appendix A
and in Wood (2008), this elasticity can be written more fully as
()
zz
MP
MPMP
zz
MPMP
zz
MP
s
(
(
(
τ
γββ
ε
+
=
1
(2)
where γ
MP
is the elasticity of substitution in consumption between the two goods, β
MP
is the elasticity of substitution in consumption among different national varieties of M
and P (averaged across the two goods, and likely to be much larger than γ
MP
), and
zz
MP
s
(
is an average of country z’s shares of market ž for M and P. The numerator of (2) is a
weighted average of β
MP
and γ
MP
: the larger is country z’s share of market ž, the closer
to γ
MP
(and thus the lower) is its demand elasticity. The demand elasticity depends
also on trade costs, in two ways: they influence the market share; and they damp the
transmission of changes in relative producer prices into changes in relative purchaser
prices. This second channel is captured in equation (2) by
zz
MP
(
τ
, which is country z’s
average ratio of trade costs to production costs for M and P in market ž (excluding the
part of trade costs that varies strictly in proportion to production costs).
Equation (3) extends equation (1) to include the effects on country z’s relative sales of
M and P in market ž of changes in the endowments of the rest of the world (which is
identified by a * superscript instead of a z). Its first line is equivalent to equation (1),
but with
zz
MP
(
ε
replaced by (2) and with the square-bracketed term in (1) written more
compactly. It continues to show how a country’s relative sales are influenced by its
own endowments.
()
()
()
()
()
()
()
=
=
+
+
=
NBi
LiiLiPiM
z
MP
MPMP
zz
MP
z
L
z
i
z
iL
NBi
iPiM
zz
MP
MPMP
zz
MPMP
zz
P
zz
M
vv
s
vv
s
qq
,
***
*
,
ˆˆ
1
1
ˆˆ
1
ˆˆ
ϕθθ
τ
γβ
ϕθθ
τ
γββ
(
(
(
(
((
(3)
The second line of (3), which is derived in Appendix A, is similar in form to the first
line. The terms in the summation specify how changes in world endowment ratios
alter factor prices (since full adjustment of factor demands could be achieved by shifts in the sectoral
structure of production): φ would be infinite, as would be ε in equation (1), which would collapse back
into the standard Rybczynski relationship between relative outputs and relative endowments. The basic
difference between the present model and the standard model is that ε is less than infinite, as explained
in Wood (2008) and Wood (2009).
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
5
alter world relative producer prices, in the same sort of way as in an individual
country, namely by changing relative factor prices, whose effect on relative goods
prices depends on cost shares.
3
The cost shares can be assumed to be the same for the
world as for an individual country, but the effects of relative endowments on relative
factor prices tend to be larger for the world (φ
*
iL
), which is a closed economy, than for
an individual country open to trade (φ
z
iL
), which can respond to changes in its
endowments by altering exports and imports as well as by substitution among factors
in production and domestic consumption.
The second line of (3) is of opposite sign to the first line, which makes intuitive sense
(for example, a fall in country z’s relative price of M would raise its relative sales of
M, while a fall in the world relative price would reduce them). The double-decker
demand elasticity in the second line of (3) also differs from its counterpart in the first
line. The numerator is smaller in the second line, but in both lines is inversely related
to country z’s share of market ž. In the denominator, the world average ratio of trade
costs to production costs in market ž may differ from that of country z (though if z
were an average country, and ž were an export market, the two would be similar).
China’s entry into world trade affected the q
M
/q
P
ratios of other countries by altering
the v
*
terms in the second line of (3). The equation implies that the effect was always
in the same direction, but that its size varied, being smaller where market shares,
zz
MP
s
(
,
were larger and trade costs,
z
MP
(
*
τ
, were higher. The impact of China is thus likely to
have been less on bigger countries, which tend to have larger market shares. It is also
likely to have had less effect on sales in home markets, in which shares are raised by a
trade cost advantage, than in export markets, the difference being bigger for countries
whose home markets are more protected. The impact of China on countries’ relative
outputs of M and P is thus likely to have been smaller than the impact on their relative
exports, particularly for countries that export only small shares of their output.
In this sort of H-O model, the China impact is in the same direction as in the standard
Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model, but is different in magnitude and mechanism.
4
Another difference from the standard H-O model is that non-human capital plays no
part in the analysis – the factors in the present model are just land and different sorts
of labour. Our reason for omitting capital is that it is internationally mobile and thus
does not influence the comparative advantage of individual countries (as explained
more fully in Wood 1994: section 2.2).
Overview of method
Our estimates of the impact of China on the ratio of labour-intensive manufacturing to
primary production in other countries, which will be made separately for total output
and for exports, involve several steps, whose details and limitations will be discussed
3
If world endowments were held constant, the (v* – v*) terms would be zero and the second line would
thus vanish, reducing equation (3) back to the substance of equation (1).
4
In the standard model, China’s impact on the world market prices of goods causes changes in factor
prices in each country, inducing changes in the mix of factors used in each sector. The sectoral mix of
output then needs to alter to allow factor markets to clear. In the present model, because countries face
less-than-infinitely elastic demand curves as a result of product differentiation and trade costs (Wood,
2008), China’s impact on world market prices has more direct effects on other countries’ relative sales
and hence their production of the goods concerned.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
6
in the relevant sections below. But the general approach can be outlined on the basis
of equation (3), since what needs to be done is to estimate its second line.
A first step is to calculate (in section 4) the effect of China’s opening on world factor
endowments – the v
*
terms. However, there is no way of estimating directly the rest
of the second line, which would require long time series on endowments and sectoral
structures for the world as a whole. Instead, we estimate the corresponding part of the
first line of equation (3) – which is equivalent to equation (1) – using data on many
individual countries (in section 5). In section 6, we use the coefficients from section 5
and the world endowment effects from section 4 to predict the impact of China on
sectoral structures in other countries, and then compare these predictions with actual
changes in sectoral structures.
A limitation of this approach is that the non-v terms in the first line of equation (3)
differ from those in its second line. The trade cost ratios are different: for exports, our
estimates of the first line should capture world average
z
MP
(
*
τ
, but for output they may
understate it and thus overstate the impact of China.
5
The other two differences pull
in opposite directions. The elasticity of relative demand for a country’s goods with
respect to its own prices,
(
)
MPMP
zz
MPMP
s
γββ
(
, is larger than with respect to foreign
prices,
(
)
(
MPMP
zz
MP
s
γβ
)
(
1 . But as already mentioned, the elasticity of factor prices
with respect to endowments is smaller for an individual country (φ
z
iL
) than for the
world as a whole (φ*
iL
). There is no obvious reason to suppose that one of these two
effects is larger, so we assume that they roughly offset each other.
3. Data sources and problems
The data used in this paper are similar to those in our earlier work (for instance, Wood
and Jordan, 2000; Wood and Mayer, 2001; Mayer and Wood, 2001), and still exclude
countries with populations below one million, but with two improvements: we have
matching data on the sectoral structure of both exports and output; and at several
points in time, rather than a single cross-section. Our new data, however, have all the
problems of our previous data, and some extra ones, too.
Primary products, P, correspond to the category labelled BP in our earlier papers,
which includes both unprocessed and processed agricultural and mineral products (in
the International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC), processed primary products
are a part of manufacturing). Labour-intensive manufactures, M, covers the category
that was labelled NML in our earlier papers, including textiles, clothing, footwear,
leather and wood products (Mayer and Wood, 2001, table 1). In this paper, however,
we add to M electronics (ISIC Rev. 2 group 383 and Standard International Trade
Classification Rev. 2 divisions 75–77), though only for developing countries, because
labour-intensive assembly of such items is now an important export activity in many
of them. For developed countries, electronics stays in skill-intensive manufactures.
Classifying electronics as labour-intensive or skill-intensive simply on the basis of a
country’s developing or developed status is crude, but the best that can be done with
5
The trade costs relevant to the effect of world prices on output include international as well as internal
trade costs. For individual countries, however, trade cost ratios for output include home market sales
(as well as exports), on which countries do not need to pay international trade costs.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
7
the available data (and we will test the sensitivity of our results to omitting electronics
from M). This specific problem, moreover, illustrates a more general problem, which
is the internal heterogeneity of our product categories: the composition of M varies
across countries with their endowments (Schott, 2003); and for each country it differs
between exports and output (the former including more items with low trade costs).
Our export data are from the UNCTAD database. Our output data are derived by
combining UN national accounts statistics with UNIDO industrial output statistics
(whose country coverage is unfortunately rather limited). Sectoral shares of ISIC
manufacturing value added from UNIDO are used to split the value of manufacturing
output in the UN national accounts between processed primary products (whose value
is added to the UN agriculture and mining categories to generate P), labour-intensive
manufactures, and skill-intensive manufactures (for details, see Appendix B).
A weakness of both our output and our export data is that they are measured in terms
of values rather than of volumes, without matching price or unit value series. This is
a problem because the theory refers to volumes (q
M
and q
P
) and because the impact of
China has involved changes in prices. In addition, the output and export data are not
strictly comparable, because sectoral output is value added, while sectoral exports are
measured gross of intermediate inputs (and re-exports).
6
Imported intermediates grew
rapidly during the period of China’s entry into world markets, and are a large share of
the value of some export products, including electronics (though the domestic content
of non-assembly processing exports in China has risen – Aziz and Li, 2007: 8).
Two of the factor endowment variables are identical to those in our earlier work: land,
N, which is the surface area of the country concerned; and labour, L, which is its adult
(over-15) population, taken from Barro and Lee (2001). The number of workers with
a basic education, B, is also taken from Barro and Lee: it includes those with complete
primary schooling and with secondary (but not tertiary) schooling. We tried narrower
(omitting complete secondary) and broader (including incomplete primary) measures
of B, but these seem intuitively less appropriate and yielded worse statistical results.
The limitations of the skill and land variables were discussed in our earlier papers –
the main problem of both being that they fail to capture variation in the quality of the
endowments concerned – but are more serious in the present paper because it uses
time-series as well as cross-section data. Length of schooling is an acceptable cross-
country proxy for human capital, because it is correlated with variation in the quality
of schooling and non-school learning, but it is less reliable as a measure of changes
over time, for example because rises in school attendance may be associated with falls
in school quality.
7
The surface area measure of N not only fails to reflect differences
among countries in what is on or under their land, but also stays the same over time
for each country, regardless of (for example) oil discoveries or desertification.
8
6
Input-output tables can be used to separate off the value added content of exports, but do not exist for
enough countries, years and sectors (the best available data are those of Nicita and Olarreaga, 2007).
7
A debate on this issue started by Pritchett (2001) led to the development of a new data set by Cohen
and Soto (2007), with which we experimented as an alternative to Barro and Lee (2001).
8
Our earlier efforts (e.g. Wood and Mayer 2001) to improve on this measure with more detailed data
on natural resources were largely unsuccessful.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
8
4. Effect of China on world endowments
The task of this section is to estimate the impact of China’s opening on world factor
endowments. It requires a method of aggregating endowments across countries. In
principle, the right method is implicit in equation (3), namely to weight each country’s
endowments by the effect (per unit of the factors) that they have on world prices of M
and P. This effect must depend on how productively the country uses its factors, what
proportion of them is used to produce M and P, and how much the country is involved
in trade. In practice, we lack the data to apply this method, but its logic is helpful in
suggesting simpler approximations and in understanding their limitations.
The method implicit in a well-known paper by Freeman (2006) is to classify countries
as open or closed, and then simply to add up the endowments of the open ones. Thus,
for example, labelling for brevity the B/L ratio as b, its world average would be
=
=
=
=
=
=
==
Zz
z
z
t
z
t
Zz
z
z
t
Zz
z
z
tt
bwLBb
111
*
(4)
where
t is the year, and z indexes the Z open countries. The factor ratios of individual
countries, , are weighted by their shares, , of the open world’s total labour force.
The impact of China is the difference between with and without China included in
Z (and similarly for world average N/L, labelled for brevity below as n).
z
t
b
z
t
w
b
*
t
A concern about this method is its polarised categorisation of countries as either fully
integrated into the world economy or wholly detached from it, since all of them trade
to some extent. One possible variant, which we will use, is just to extend
Z to include
all countries for which endowment data exist, regardless of how much they trade. A
more radical alternative, which we will also use, and which follows Spilimbergo
et al.
(1999) and IMF (2007), is to adjust the weight of each country in the world average
by the extent of its involvement in trade. World average
b thus becomes
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
=
===
Zz
z
z
t
oz
t
Zz
z
z
t
z
t
z
t
z
t
z
t
Zz
z
z
t
z
t
Zz
z
z
t
z
t
o
t
bw
Lo
Lo
bLoBob
1111
*
(5)
where is the ratio of trade to GDP in country
z at time t, and Z covers all countries
with data. The world average, , is weighted by country shares, , of the world’s
openness-adjusted labour force. It can be calculated with and without China in
Z, and
the impact of China is the difference between the changes in these two estimates of
over the period during which China opened to trade.
z
t
o
*o
t
b
oz
t
w
*o
t
b
This approach, too, is open to criticism. The right measure of trade for this purpose is
its domestic value added content, reflecting factor inputs, but in practice, as already
mentioned, exports are measured gross of intermediate inputs and include re-exports,
which distorts the calculation by giving undue weight to countries with high gross-to-
value-added trade ratios. It can also be argued that what drives a country’s impact on
world prices is not just its exports and imports but its production and consumption of
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
9
tradable goods, so that equation (5) gives too little weight to large countries with low
trade-to-tradables ratios.
The methods in both equation (4) and equation (5) are vulnerable to another criticism,
which is that they fail to take account of differences among countries in efficiency or
factor productivity. A country which produces more output per unit of factor input
will tend to exert more influence on world prices, so its endowments should be given
more weight in calculating the effective world average. The important question is
how China’s efficiency compares with that of other countries: in particular, if China is
of below-world-average efficiency, equations (4) and (5) will overstate the impact of
its opening on effective world endowments.
There is currently no accurate and accepted answer to this question, partly because of
controversy about the undervaluation of China’s exchange rate and about the size of
its GDP at purchasing power parity (estimates of which were reduced substantially in
2007 by the International Comparisons Project).
9
Casual observation suggests that
China’s efficiency is well below that of most developed countries, but well above that
of most developing countries, especially in labour-intensive manufacturing, and hence
probably not far from the relevant world average (implying that this potential error in
applying equations (4) and (5) may not be serious).
Table 1 presents the results of our calculations by both methods. They include the 94
countries, including China, for which we have data (which accounted for 86% of the
world’s adult population in 1990), and they cover 1980-2000, the period during which
China opened to trade. The trade-to-GDP ratios in the openness-adjusted calculations
measure ‘trade’ as the mean of merchandise exports and merchandise imports, are at
official exchange rates, and are from the UNCTAD database. The table includes
information not only on the two endowment ratios discussed above (
B/L and N/L) but
also on average adult years of schooling, the skill-to-labour ratio that we used in our
earlier work. China’s own endowment ratios are shown at the bottom of the table.
Considering first the labour-force-weighted numbers in the upper panel, the top row
shows that world average endowments (with China included) changed in the expected
directions during 1980-2000: years of schooling rose by one-fifth; the share of basic-
educated workers in the labour force rose by one-tenth; and land per worker fell by
one-third (because of population growth). The second row shows world averages
without China, and the third row the proportional (log) effect of including China.
Including China hardly alters world average years of schooling in 2000, but it raises
the world average share of basic-educated workers in the labour force by 0.09 log
points (about 10%), which is one of our estimates of the impact of China on effective
world endowments. World average land per worker is reduced by including China: in
2000, this makes a difference of 0.19 log points (about 20%), which is another of our
estimates of the impact of China on effective world endowments.
The openness-adjusted numbers are in the lower panel of the table. In both years, the
openness adjustment somewhat increases both of the world average skill ratios: more
9
This controversy also affects the trade-to-GDP ratio for China used in our application of equation (5)
– the openness-adjusted world endowment calculations.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
10
educated countries tend to have higher trade-to-GDP ratios, though to a lesser extent
in 2000 than in 1980 because developing countries had become more open. The rise
in the openness-adjusted average share of basic-educated workers over the period is
almost entirely due to China. Including China causes the average to rise by 0.07 log
points more than if China is excluded (when it hardly alters).
10
This is another of our
estimates of China’s impact on effective world endowments.
The openness-adjusted world average of land per worker (including China) was above
the labour-force-weighted average in 1980, because land-abundant countries tended to
have higher trade-to-GDP ratios than land-scarce ones. This difference had vanished
by 2000, because of large increases in exports from land-scarce Asian countries, one
of which was China. Including China causes the world average to fall over the period
by 0.10 log points more than if China is excluded, which provides the last of our
estimates of its impact on effective world endowments.
11
In summary, we have two estimates of the impact of China’s opening on the effective
world
B/L ratio (+0.07 and +0.09 log points) and two estimates of its impact on the
effective world
N/L ratio (–0.10 and –0.19 log points). For each ratio, the openness-
adjusted estimate is, as expected, smaller than the labour-force-weighted one, the gap
being smaller for
B/L than for N/L. The impact on B/L is roughly half the size of that
on
N/L. Neither of these impacts is vast, but nor is either of them trivial.
5. Effects of endowments on structure
The task of this section is to estimate the effects of factor endowments on sectoral
structure. Its results are used in the next section to translate our estimates of China’s
impact on world endowments into estimates of China’s impact on the ratio of labour-
intensive manufacturing to primary production in other economies. We proceed, as
explained earlier, by estimating equation (1) as an approximation to what we should
ideally estimate, which are the non-
v terms in the second line of equation (3).
We use a panel of data on individual countries, with observations in three years (1980,
1990 and 2000) spanning the period of China’s opening.
12
Our dependent variable is
the ratio of labour-intensive manufacturing to primary production in each country and
year. We measure this ratio in terms of both output and exports: the former includes
sales in both home and foreign markets, the latter sales only in foreign markets. We
estimate the output regression for as many countries as possible (53), and the export
regression both for these 53 countries and for a larger set of 96 countries – the extra
43 being countries with data on exports and endowments but not on output. A list of
the countries is in Appendix C. China is excluded from the regressions.
The basic specification of the regression is
10
The rise appears roughly twice as large in the 1980s as in the 1990s, partly because China’s B/L rose
faster (from 0.46 in 1980 to 0.54 in 1990, and then to 0.58 in 2000), and partly because its trade/GDP
ratio rose faster (from 0.07 in 1980 to 0.15 in 1990, and then to 0.21 in 2000).
11
All of this fall appears to have occurred in the 1980s, partly because China’s N/L fell faster (from
1.45 in 1980 to 1.12 in 1990, and then to 0.98 in 2000), as a result of slowing population growth, and
partly because its trade/GDP ratio rose faster (see previous footnote for details).
12
In each year, variables are measured (where possible) as three-year centred averages.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
11
(
)
z
t
z
tn
z
tb
z
Pt
z
Mt
unbqq +++= lnlnln
ξξξ
(6)
in which
u is the error term, t indexes time periods and z as before indexes countries.
It relates proportional differences in sectoral structure to proportional differences in
endowment ratios, as in equation (1) but measured in (natural) logs. For example,
corresponds to in equation (1), and
z
t
bln
z
L
z
B
vv
ˆˆ
(
)
z
BLBPBM
zz
MPb
ϕθθεξ
=
(
. The main
aim of this section is to estimate
ξ
b
and ξ
n
, which we try by three methods: pooled
ordinary least squares (POLS), fixed effects (FE) and first differences (FD).
13
Because our interest is in China’s impact on other developing countries, we include an
intercept dummy
D
1
for developing countries (in all three years). Because we are also
interested in changes over time, we include time period dummies, too, separately for
developed countries (
A
1
and A
2
) and for developing countries (D
2
and D
3
). Table 2
defines the dummy variables (to be discussed further in the next section) and provides
summary statistics for the other variables. The full specification is thus
(
)
z
tAA
z
tn
z
tb
z
Pt
z
Mt
uDDDAAnbqq ++++++++=
3322112211
lnlnln
ξξξξξξξξ
(7)
The results are presented in table 3, whose three panels contain the output regressions,
the 53-country export regressions and the 96-country export regressions. Its columns
correspond to the variables in equation (7). In each panel, the top three rows show the
POLS, FE and FD results. The fourth row is a variant on the FD regression with only
the dummy variables included, to be discussed in the next section.
Consider first the three POLS regressions. In all of them, the coefficients on
b and n
are of the expected sign (positive for
ξ
b
, because of the sign of θ
BM
θ
BP
, and negative
for
ξ
n
, because of the sign of θ
NM
θ
NP
), statistically significant, and big enough to
matter.
14
The coefficients in the output regression are both (absolutely) smaller than
in the matching 53-country export regression.
15
The output regression also fits the
data a bit better than the 53-country export regression.
There is not much difference in the values of
ξ
b
and ξ
n
between the 53-country and 96-
country export regressions, nor in their goodness of fit. The extra 43 countries, almost
all developing, have a much lower average ratio of labour-intensive manufactured to
13
What we need to calculate the impact of China are world average time-series elasticities. The POLS
estimates of ξ
b
and ξ
n
, on which we will mainly rely, depend heavily on the cross-section dimension of
the data. For individual countries, as explained in Wood (2008), time-series elasticities can differ
greatly from cross-section elasticities, but the world average time-series elasticity is close to the world
average cross-section elasticity implied by the slope of a regression across all countries.
14
In these respects, they resemble the coefficients estimated in our earlier work (e.g. Wood and Berge,
1997; Wood and Jordan, 2000; Wood and Mayer, 2001; Mayer and Wood, 2001), though in most of
this earlier work we used a different measure of skill (average years of schooling). In all our work,
when the dependent variable is some ratio of manufactures to primary exports or output, the coefficient
on n is remarkably consistent in size (about 0.6 in export regressions and about 0.3 in output
regressions). The coefficients on skill variables are more sensitive to specification and country
coverage of the data.
15
Referring back to the first line of equation (3), this difference implies that the generally larger share
that a country has of its home market than of its export markets outweighs the generally lower level of
trade costs for home sales than for export sales. Part of the explanation is probably that our data refer
not to homogeneous goods but to broad sectoral aggregates, within which the mix of goods sold on the
home market includes more items with high trade costs than the mix of goods exported.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
12
primary exports (unlogged, it is 0.16, compared to 0.62 for the 53 countries). But this
is explained largely by their lower endowments of skill (
b, the share of basic-educated
workers in the labour force, is on average 24% for the 43 extra countries, compared to
44% for the 53 countries) and by their higher land/labour ratios (
n averaging about 4
km
2
per 100 workers, compared to 2 km
2
for the 53 countries).
16
The numbers cited
in this paragraph are derived from those in table 2.
In all three POLS regressions, the coefficient on the developing-country dummy,
D
1
,
is negative, significant and of similar size. Its value of -0.7 implies that the
M/P ratio
for both output and exports is on average in developing countries roughly half of what
would be predicted for developed countries with the same endowments of skill and
land. The inclusion of the
D
1
dummy also substantially lowers the value of ξ
b
(which
would otherwise be above unity in all three regressions). A plausible interpretation is
that developed countries are better endowed, relative to developing countries, with the
skills needed for labour-intensive manufacturing than is implied by comparing their
numbers of primary and secondary school graduates – as a result partly of better-
quality schooling and partly of more training and practical experience.
In the FE and FD regressions,
D
1
disappears. In all these regressions, moreover, all
the estimates of
ξ
b
and ξ
n
are insignificantly different from zero at conventional test
levels, and about half have the wrong sign (five out of six for
ξ
n
). The FE and FD
estimates thus differ radically from the POLS estimates, and are unusable for our
purpose of estimating the impact of China on other economies.
17
Specification tests give some support to the FE and FD results: Breusch-Pagan tests
suggest that, with our data, random-effects estimation would be preferable to POLS;
Hausman tests suggest that FE or FD estimates would be preferable to random-effects
estimates. It is hard to believe, however, that endowments have no effect on sectoral
structure. There are also plausible econometric reasons for the insignificance of the
FE and FD estimates. These two methods reduce the ratio of signal to noise, biasing
coefficients towards zero and raising standard errors; and this problem is particularly
serious with our data, partly because endowments change slowly over time, compared
to their cross-section variation, and partly because our measures of endowments are
subject to even more error in time-series than in cross-section.
In estimating the impact of China, we shall therefore rely on the POLS estimates of
ξ
b
and
ξ
n
. However, as a sensitivity test we re-ran the POLS regressions with electronics
excluded from labour-intensive manufacturing in developing countries. Electronics is
already excluded for developed countries, so this amendment enlarged the negative
coefficients on
D
1
. It hardly changed ξ
n
, but somewhat reduced ξ
b
, particularly in the
16
The coefficients ξ
b
and ξ
n
in the 96-country regression do differ slightly from those in the 53-country
regression. The lower ξ
b
implies that the 43 countries have somewhat higher M/P ratios than would be
predicted from their skill ratios using the 53-country coefficients. The absolutely larger ξ
n
implies that
the 43 countries have somewhat lower M/P ratios than would be predicted from their land/labour ratios
using the 53-country coefficients.
17
Although our model is, in theory, not dynamic (sectoral structure depends on current endowments),
there may in practice be lags, so we also tried four methods of GMM estimation (details on request).
This yielded more sensible signs: 8/12 estimates of ξ
b
were positive, no better than 4/6 for FE and FD;
but 11/12 estimates of ξ
n
were negative, compared to 1/6 for FE and FD. However, only two of the 24
coefficients were statistically significant at conventional levels.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
13
53-country export regression, because electronics exports are of most importance for
the well-educated developing countries of East Asia.
18
6. Predicted and actual impact of China
Table 4 contains our estimates of the impact of China’s opening on the ratio of labour-
intensive manufacturing to primary production in other countries. These estimates are
based on the formula
()
**
lnlnln nbqq
nbPM
ΔΔ=Δ
ξξ
(8)
where Δln
b* and Δln n* are our estimates of the impact of China on world average
endowments of
B/L and N/L from table 1, and ξ
b
and ξ
n
are our POLS estimates of the
effects of endowment ratios on the
M/P ratio from table 3. The terms have negative
signs because a change in the world average shifts the relative endowment ratios of
individual countries in the opposite direction (for example, since China’s opening
reduced world average
n, it made other countries relatively more land abundant).
We have two estimates of Δln
b* and Δln n* (one labour-force-weighted and the other
also openness-adjusted), and hence, in the two columns of table 4, two alternative sets
of estimates of the impact of China on
M/P ratios. We also calculate separately the
impact on the
M/P output ratio (in the upper panel of table 4) and the M/P export ratio
(in its lower panel). The lower panel has two rows, based on our 53-country and 96-
country estimates of
ξ
b
and ξ
n
for exports, though the results are almost the same (the
differences in the coefficients happen to offset one another).
The results suggest that China’s opening to trade reduced the ratio of labour-intensive
manufacturing to primary output in other countries by between 0.07 and 0.11 log
points (7-10%). The impact on the corresponding export ratio was a reduction of
between 0.10 and 0.16 log points (10-15%). In each case, the range of the estimates
arises mainly from the difference between our alternative estimates of China’s impact
on the world average land/labour ratio. The smaller estimated impact on output than
on exports is in line with the theoretical expectation that China’s opening would have
less effect on sales in countries’ home markets than in their export markets.
19
These predicted impacts are the same for all countries, but their economic significance
varies with the initial level of the
M/P ratio. Consider, for example, a 10% reduction,
holding the combined output of the two sectors constant. In a country whose initial
M/P ratio was 10, M would fall by only 1% and P would rise by 9%, whereas in a
country whose initial
M/P ratio was 1/10, M would fall by 9% and P would rise by
1%. In both cases, the effect on the share of
M in M+P would be tiny – a reduction of
under one percentage point. For a country whose initial
M/P ratio was unity, the fall
in
M and the rise in P would both be the same size (5%), and the effect on the share of
M in M+P would be larger – about 3 percentage points – but still small.
18
Excluding (including) electronics, ξ
b
is 0.51 (0.60) for output, 0.58 (0.77) for 53-country exports, and
0.54 (0.59) for 96-country exports.
19
This difference reflects the smaller estimated coefficients in the output regressions than in the export
regressions. The true difference may be larger than these numbers imply, since, as mentioned earlier,
the coefficients derived from individual-country data may exaggerate the output elasticity.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
14
How do these predicted changes in M/P ratios compare with actual changes? Did
M/P ratios in other countries fall, or did they rise less than would otherwise have been
expected, after China’s opening? Some answers to these questions can be obtained
from the coefficients on the time dummy variables in the regressions in table 3.
20
It is
assumed that the impact of China was concentrated in the 1990s (China’s trade policy
changed most in the second half of the 1980s, and the effects would have been felt in
other countries with some lag). It is also assumed that other forces causing changes in
M/P ratios during the 1980s continued in the 1990s, so that the impact of China can be
detected by comparing changes over the 1990s with changes over the 1980s.
21
For developed countries, the relevant comparison in the POLS regressions is between
A
1
, which measures any step change in 1990 relative to 1980, and A
2
, which measures
any further step change by 2000. In the FD regressions, from which
A
1
vanishes, A
2
measures the difference between changes in the 1990s and in the 1980s. None of the
results suggests that China had a negative impact: in all three POLS regressions, the
coefficients on
A
2
are larger than on A
1
, and in the FD regressions, the coefficients on
A
2
are positive (albeit insignificant), implying that M/P output and export ratios rose
more, not less, in the 1990s than in the 1980s. A possible explanation is that by 1990
most truly labour-intensive manufacturing in developed countries had ceased, and that
the rise in
M/P in the 1990s reflects the expansion of other, skill-intensive activities
within our coarse ‘labour-intensive’ aggregate.
In developing countries, the impact of China on which is the main focus of this paper,
there is, by contrast, some evidence of a downward shift in
M/P ratios. In the POLS
regressions,
D
2
, which measures any step change in 1990, has to be compared with
D
3
, which measures any further step change by 2000, while in the FD regressions, the
key variable is
D
3
, which shows the difference between changes in the 1990s and in
the 1980s. In the output regressions in the top panel of table 3, the POLS coefficient
on
D
3
is smaller than that on D
2
, by -0.05, which is also the size of the coefficient on
D
3
in the FD regression (though this is far from significant). The conclusion is that
the
M/P output ratio in developing countries in 2000 was roughly 5% lower than
would have been expected from its trend in the 1980s, which is consistent with our
predicted 7-10% reduction as a result of China’s opening.
Evidence of a China impact can be seen also in the export regressions in the middle
panel of table 3 (whose 53-country coverage matches that of the output regressions).
In the POLS regression, the coefficients on
D
2
and on D
3
are both positive, indicating
upward shifts in the
M/P export ratios of developing countries in both the 1980s and
the 1990s. But the shift in the 1990s is smaller than in the 1980s, by 0.20 log points.
The coefficient on
D
3
in the FD regression is similar, -0.22 (though insignificant).
The
M/P export ratio of developing countries was thus roughly 20% lower in 2000
than it would have been if its rise of the 1980s had continued at the same rate, which
20
We re-ran these regressions with individual-country endowment ratios normalised on without-China
world average endowments in the year concerned, to see whether some of the actual changes could be
explained by changes in the endowments or openness of countries other than China. This made almost
no difference to the results, other than to shift all the intercepts.
21
The period covered by these calculations could in principle be altered, for example by going further
back than 1980 and (when more data become available) further forward than 2000. This would have
some advantages (fuller capture of the post-1990 China impact) but also disadvantages (making it less
plausible to argue that other causes of change in M/P were the same before as after 1990).
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
15
again fits with our predicted reduction of 10-15% as a result of China’s opening – and
with the prediction of a larger China impact on exports than on output.
The coefficients on
D
2
and D
3
in the 96-country export regressions in the bottom
panel of table 3, which include 43 countries for which we lack data on the
M/P output
ratio, differ substantially from those in the middle panel. The coefficient on
D
2
in the
POLS regression is close to zero, implying no upward shift in the
M/P export ratio in
the 1980s on average for this larger group of developing countries, and the coefficient
on
D
3
is positive, albeit statistically insignificant, implying an upward shift in the
1990s. The coefficient on
D
3
in the FD regression is likewise positive, implying that
the
M/P export ratio rose by more in the 1990s than in the 1980s, counter to our
prediction of a reduction as a result of China’s opening.
Different outcomes in different groups of countries could in principle be explained by
them having been affected differently by China’s opening. This explanation is not
plausible, however, for these two groups of developing countries (the 33 that are part
of the 53-country set, and the 70 that are part of the 96-country set), because in theory,
as mentioned in section 2, the impact of China should be in the same direction on all
countries and vary only in magnitude. (Nor, more generally, were we able to capture
empirically the theoretically expected pattern of variation in magnitude.
22
)
The other possible explanation for the difference in export outcomes between these
two groups of developing countries is that non-China forces acted differently on them.
In particular, for the 37 extra developing countries in the larger group other influences
on
M/P export ratios might have been not, as our time-dummy method assumes, the
same in the 1990s as in the 1980s, but rather differed between the 1980s and 1990s in
ways that offset the impact of China. Examples of such differences would be policy
changes in these countries or in their trading partners that provided more incentives or
markets for their manufactured exports in the 1990s compared to the 1980s.
This explanation is fairly plausible. Of the 37 extra countries, 28 are in Latin America
or sub-Saharan Africa, regions in which there was widespread liberalisation of trade
regimes in the 1990s. Many countries in these regions lack comparative advantage in
manufacturing, so these policy changes would not have raised their
M/P export ratios
(and would have reduced their
M/P output ratios), but they stimulated manufactured
exports from some more densely populated countries. In Latin America, moreover,
many countries introduced structural policies to improve the competitiveness of their
manufactured exports (Melo, 2001) and there was an intensification in the 1990s of
regional trade schemes that are likely to have stimulated manufactured exports.
In table 5, to examine actual outcomes more closely, we divide developing countries
into five regional groups (East Asia, South Asia, Latin America, Middle East and sub-
Saharan Africa). For each group, and for China, the table shows the average changes
in
M/P ratios in the 1980s and 1990s and the differences between these decades, for
22
Equation (3) predicts that the size of the China impact will be smaller, the larger is the share of the
country concerned in the market concerned. We tried to measure this variation by interacting D
3
with
(a) each country’s size (measured by its PPP GDP in the mid-1990s), expecting a positive sign, and (b)
each country’s ratio of trade to GDP in the mid-1990s, expecting a negative sign. However, the size
interaction coefficients were all near zero, and the openness interaction coefficients were significant but
of the wrong sign (picking up rising M/P ratios in East Asian countries with high trade/GDP ratios).
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
1
6
output and for the two sets of export data (53 and 96 countries). The table also shows
the standard deviations within each group, which in almost all cases exceed the
averages, partly because of genuine differences among countries and partly because of
errors of measurement in the data, amplified by differencing and double-differencing.
To clarify the relationship between the averages in table 5 and the regressions in table
3, we show, in the fourth row of each panel of table 3, a variant on the FD regression
that excludes the (statistically insignificant) endowment variables and includes only
the dummy variables. For developed countries, the differences between decades in
table 5 (0.11, 0.03 and 0.03) are the same as the coefficients on
A
2
in the fourth-row
regressions (and close to those in the third-row regressions). For developing countries
as a group, these differences are the same as the coefficients on
D
3
in the fourth-row
regressions, which again are close to those in the third-row regressions.
23
The numbers for China in the ‘difference’ columns are positive: its output
M/P ratio
was constant in the 1980s, but rose in the 1990s; while its export
M/P ratio rose much
faster in the 1990s than in the 1980s. Two developing regions show a consistently
opposite pattern of negative differences. One is East Asia, where rapid rises in both
output and export
M/P ratios in the 1980s slowed in the 1990s. That this slowdown
was caused by China’s opening seems particularly plausible because of the similarity
of endowments and trade patterns in other East Asian countries to those of China, and
is consistent with most other studies.
24
The negative differences in East Asia are
larger if electronics is omitted from
M, probably because in the 1990s competition
from China was strongest in traditional labour-intensive manufactures.
25
The other developing region where all the differences are negative is the Middle East
and North Africa. Both output and export
M/P ratios rose in the 1980s, but for output
the rise slowed in the 1990s and for exports it was sharply reversed. It seems unlikely
that these changes were caused mainly by China’s opening. This region’s exports are
dominated by oil, and the
M/P ratio (since it is measured in value rather than volume)
is strongly affected by the oil price. China probably had only a small effect on the oil
price up to 2000, although labour-intensive manufacturing in the non-oil countries of
this region must have suffered from Chinese competition in the 1990s.
The difference between the two decades in the
M/P output change is negative also for
Latin America, where the ratio rose in the 1980s but fell in the 1990s. This pattern is
consistent with the widely-held view that labour-intensive manufacturing in the region
contracted as a result of greater competition from imports from China and other Asian
countries.
26
However, this rise in imports was caused as much by Latin America’s
liberalisation of its own trade policies as by China’s opening. Moreover, the region’s
M/P export ratio moved in the other direction, from little change in the 1980s to rapid
rise in the 1990s: the most likely cause is regional integration schemes, some of which
23
The 1980-90 averages for developed countries are the intercepts of the fourth-row regressions and for
developing countries as a group are the intercepts plus the coefficients on D
2
.
24
For example, Ianchovichina and Walmsley (2003) and Eichengreen et al. (2007). Greenaway et al.
(2008) by contrast conclude from a gravity model that China displaced manufactured exports from
other Asian countries only to a very limited extent (mainly in developed-country markets).
25
Excluding (including) electronics, for East Asia the output change difference is -0.29 (-0.19), the 53-
country export change difference is -0.82 (-0.45), and the 96-country export change difference is -0.62
(-0.34). For no other region does the exclusion of electronics much alter the results.
26
Lall et al. (2005), Devlin et al (2006), Freund and Ozden (2006), Lederman et al. (2008).
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
1
7
(e.g. Mercosur) fostered trade in manufactures among Latin American countries and
others of which (
e.g. NAFTA) opened North America to their manufactured exports.
In South Asia, the
M/P output ratio rose in the 1990s, after remaining constant in the
1980s. The reasons for this change must have been internal, because, although policy
barriers were lowered in some countries, the region remained largely closed to trade
because of the large size of its countries and their poor infrastructure, so that its output
structure could not have been greatly affected by China’s opening. South Asia’s
M/P
export ratio rose in both the 1980s and the 1990s, and at about the same speed. The
growth of China’s competing exports must have tended to slow this rise, but the effect
on South Asia, whose exports of
M were concentrated on clothing, was damped by the
Multi-Fibre Arrangement and was also offset by export-promoting policy changes.
27
The numbers for sub-Saharan Africa in table 5 suggest little change in the
M/P output
ratio in the 1980s or the 1990s, but are based on only 7 countries. There is no sign of
the shrinkage of manufacturing that is believed to have occurred in African countries
as a result of the reduction of policy barriers to imports, including those from China.
28
In the 96-country data, in which the number of African countries rises from 7 to 23,
the average
M/P export ratio is constant in the 1980s but rises in the 1990s, which is
contrary to the predicted impact of China (and is too early to be explained by AGOA
and EBA). However, little weight should be put on these numbers: the
M/P export
ratio is so low in most of these countries that the estimated changes, and especially the
differences in changes, are probably dominated by measurement errors.
7. Conclusions
This paper has attempted to measure the effects of China’s opening to the world on
the sectoral structures of other countries, especially developing ones and especially on
the balance between labour-intensive manufacturing and primary production, which
matters for overall economic progress, for income distribution and for employment.
Its method has been to apply Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory, treating China’s opening
as a shift in effective world average factor endowments which altered the relative
endowments and hence the comparative advantage of all other countries.
Subject to a variety of qualifications discussed in the paper, we estimate that China’s
opening lowered the ratio of labour-intensive manufacturing to primary output in
other countries by 7-10%, and the corresponding ratio of exports by 10-15%. These
are average effects. The theory predicts that China’s impact should have been larger
on smaller countries and in more open markets: this is consistent with the bigger
effect on exports than on output (which includes sales in less open home markets), but
we were unable to measure other aspects of this predicted pattern of variation.
The paper also compares these estimates of China’s impact with actual changes in the
relevant ratios in developing countries, controlling for other influences on these ratios
by a differences-in-differences approach. On average for the 33 developing countries
27
Yusuf et al. (2006) and Dimaranan et al (2007) emphasise that the effect of China on South Asia’s
manufactured exports varies among products, and conclude that the future evolution of these exports
will depend heavily on the speed at which China upgrades its own exports
28
E.g Goldstein et al. (2006), Broadman (2007). Kaplinsky and Morris (2008) argue that expansion of
African manufactured exports requires sustained preferential access to the US and EU markets.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
18
for which all the necessary data exist, the ratio of labour-intensive manufacturing to
primary production did tend to fall during the 1990s, for both output and exports, but
across a larger set of 70 developing countries, the average export ratio tended to rise,
contrary to what would have been predicted from the impact of China.
A closer examination, dividing these developing countries into regions, suggests that
the impact of China was clearest on the rest of East Asia, whose countries are similar
to China in terms of endowments and sectoral structure. In other regions, changes in
actual ratios of labour-intensive manufacturing to primary production, whether falls or
rises, appear to have been dominated by other, region-specific influences, with China
as just one determinant of the direction and size of the outcome.
The frequent dominance of other influences is partly because the impact of China was
fairly small. Despite China’s vast size and amazing growth, our estimates suggest that
its opening did not on average have a large effect on the broad sectoral structures of
other countries, and we can see no plausible modification of our approach that could
make this effect appear much larger. The impact is not trivial, and in some countries
and more narrowly defined sectors must have been much bigger than average, but our
estimates imply that the common view of China’s emergence as a threat to economic
progress and equity in the rest of the developing world is exaggerated.
China’s opening to the world was a one-off event, which caused a step change in the
comparative advantage of other countries. Its rapid growth, based on accumulation of
more skills, capital and modern technology, is by contrast a continuing event, and one
whose effects will change with the passage of time. Up to now, China’s growth has
mainly amplified the effects of its opening: raising both its supply of labour-intensive
manufactures and its demand for primary products. Over the longer-term future, this
rising demand for primary products will continue, but China’s accumulation of skills
will move it out of labour-intensive manufacturing, tending to increase rather than (as
initially) to reduce the size of this sector in other developing countries.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
19
References
Amiti, M., and C. Freund (2008). The anatomy of China’s export growth.
Policy
Research Working Paper
4628. World Bank. Washington DC.
Aziz, J., and X. Li (2007). China’s changing trade elasticities.
Working Paper 07/266.
International Monetary Fund. Washington DC.
Barro, R., and J.-W. Lee (2001). International data on educational attainment: updates
and implications.
Oxford Economic Papers. 53(3): 541–563.
Broadman, H. (2007).
Africa’s Silk Road: China and India’s New Economic Frontier.
Washington DC: World Bank.
Cohen, D., and M. Soto (2007). Growth and human capital: good data, good results.
Journal of Economic Growth. 12(1): 51–76.
Devlin, R., A. Estevadeordal and A. Rodriguez-Clare (eds) (2006).
The Emergence of
China. Opportunities and Challenges for Latin America and the Caribbean
.
Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
Dimaranan, B., E. Ianchovichina and W. Martin (2006). Competing with giants: who
wins, who loses? In L. Winters and S. Yusuf (eds),
Dancing with Giants. China,
India, and the Global Economy
. Washington DC: World Bank and Institute of Policy
Studies.
Dimaranan, B., E. Ianchovichina and W. Martin (2007). China, India, and the future
of the world economy: fierce competition or shared growth.
Policy Research Working
Paper
4304. World Bank. Washington DC.
Dooley, M., D. Folkerts-Landau and P. Garber (2004). The revived Bretton Woods
system: the effects of periphery intervention and reserve management on interest rates
and exchange rates in center countries.
Working Paper 10332. National Bureau of
Economic Research (NBER). Cambridge (Mass.).
Eichengreen, B., Y. Rhee and H. Tong (2007). China and the exports of other Asian
countries.
Review of World Economics. 143(2): 201–226.
Freeman, R. (2006). Labor market imbalances: shortages, or surpluses, or fish stories?
Paper presented at Boston Federal Reserve Conference. Available at
http://www.bos.frb.org/economic/conf/conf51/papers/freeman.pdf
Freund, C., and C. Ozden (2006). The effect of China’s exports on Latin American
trade with the world. Mimeo. Available at
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTLACOFFICEOFCE/Resources/IndustryLevelTradeFlows.pdf
Gallagher, K., J. Moreno-Brid and R. Porzecanski (2008). The dynamism of Mexican
exports: lost in (Chinese) translation?
World Development. 36(8): 1365–1380.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
20
Goldstein, A., N. Pinaud, H. Reisen and X. Chen (2006). The Rise of China and
India: What’s in it for Africa?
Paris: OECD Development Centre.
Greenaway, D., A. Mahabir and C. Milner (2008). Has China displaced other Asian
countries’ exports?
China Economic Review. 19(2): 152–169.
Hanson, G., and. R Robertson (2007). China and the manufacturing exports of other
developing countries. Forthcoming in R. Feenstra and S. Wei (eds),
China’s Growing
Role in World Trade
. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Available at
http://www.nber.org/books_in_progress/china07/cwt07/hanson.pdf
Ianchovichina, E., and T. Walmsley (2003). The impact of China’s WTO accession on
East Asia.
Policy Research Working Paper 3109. World Bank. Washington DC.
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2007). The globalisation of labor.
World
Economic Outlook
, April, Chapter 5. IMF. Washington DC.
Kaplinsky, R., and M. Morris (2008). Do the Asian drivers undermine export-oriented
industrialization in SSA?
World Development. 36(2): 254–273.
Lall, S., J. Weiss and H. Oikawa (2005). China’s competitive threat to Latin America:
an analysis for 1990-2002.
Oxford Development Studies. 33(2): 163–194.
Lederman, D., M. Olarreaga and E. Rubiano (2008). Trade specialization in Latin
America: the impact of China and India.
Review of World Economics. 144(2): 248–
271.
Mayer, J., and P. Fajarnes (2008). Tripling Africa’s primary exports: What? How?
Where?
Journal of Development Studies. 44(1): 80–102.
Mayer, J., and A. Wood (2001). South Asia’s export structure in a comparative
perspective.
Oxford Development Studies. 29(1): 5–29.
Melo, A. (2001). Industrial policy in Latin America and the Caribbean at the turn of
the century.
Working Paper 459. Inter-American Development Bank. Washington
DC.
Mesquita Moreira, M. (2007). Fear of China: is there a future for manufacturing in
Latin America?
World Development. 35(3): 355–376.
Nicita, A., and M. Olarreaga (2007). Trade, production and protection database,
1976–2004.
World Bank Economic Review. 21(1): 165–71.
Pritchett, L. (2001). Where has all the education gone?
World Bank Economic Review.
15(3): 367–91.
Rodrik, D. (2006). What’s so special about China’s exports?
China and World
Economy
. 14(5): 1–19.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
21
Schott, P. (2003). One Size Fits All? Heckscher-Ohlin specialisation in global
production.
American Economic Review. 93(3): 686–708.
Schott, P. (2008). The relative sophistication of Chinese exports.
Economic Policy.
January: 5–49.
Spilimbergo, A., J. Londono and M. Szekely (1999). Income distribution, factor
endowments, and trade openness.
Journal of Development Economics. 59(1): 77–101.
Winters, L., and S. Yusuf (eds) (2006).
Dancing with Giants. China, India, and the
Global Economy
. Washington DC: World Bank and Institute of Policy Studies.
Wood, A. (1994).
North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality. Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
Wood, A. (2008). Openness is a matter of degree: how trade costs reduce demand
elasticities.
Working Paper 169. Queen Elizabeth House, Oxford University.
Wood, A. (2009). Heckscher-Ohlin in theory and reality. In P. Arestis and J. Eatwell
(eds),
Issues in Economic Development and Globalisation, London: Palgrave
Macmillan. Longer version available as
Working Paper 157, Queen Elizabeth House,
Oxford University.
Wood, A., and K. Berge (1997). Exporting manufactures: human resources, natural
resources, and trade policy.
Journal of Development Studies. 34(1): 35–59.
Wood, A., and K. Jordan (2000). Why does Zimbabwe export manufactures, and
Uganda not?
Journal of Development Studies. 37(2): 91–116.
Wood, A., and J. Mayer (2001). Africa’s export structure in a comparative
perspective.
Cambridge Journal of Economics. 25(3): 369–94.
Xu B (2007). Measuring China’s export sophistication. Mimeo. Available at
http://www.ceibs.edu/faculty/xubin/Measuring.pdf
Yang, Y. (2003). China’s integration into the world economy: implications for
developing countries.
Working Paper 03/245. International Monetary Fund.
Washington DC.
Yusuf, S., K. Nabeshima and D. Perkins (2006). China and India reshape global
industrial geography. In L. Winters and S. Yusuf (eds),
Dancing with Giants. China,
India, and the Global Economy
. Washington DC: World Bank and Institute of Policy
Studies.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
22
Appendix A. Derivation of equations (2) and (3)
Following Wood (2008), the demand elasticity in equation (1), which measures the
response of country
z’s relative sales of M and P in market ž to changes in country z’s
relative producer price, can be expanded to
zz
MP
zz
MP
zz
MP
(
(
(
δεε
~
= (A1)
where
zz
MP
(
ε
~
is the elasticity of country z’s relative sales in market ž with respect to its
relative purchaser price, and
zz
MP
(
δ
is the elasticity of its relative purchaser price in that
market with respect to its relative producer price.
It is also shown in Wood (2008) that
zz
MP
(
ε
~
depends on the elasticities of substitution
among national varieties of goods
M and P (β
M
and β
P
) and between goods M and P
(
γ
MP
). More precisely,
zz
MP
(
ε
~
is a weighted harmonic mean of these three elasticities, in
which the key weights are country
z’s shares of market ž for the two goods. A more
tractable approximation for the present paper is the weighted arithmetic mean
(
)
(
)
MPMP
zz
MPMPMP
zz
MPMP
zz
MP
zz
MP
sss
γβββγε
=+
(
(
(
(
1
~
(A2)
where
β
MP
is an average of the two elasticities of substitution among national varieties
and
zz
MP
s
(
is an average of country z’s shares of market ž for M and P.
For changes in prices over time, which are what matter for the impact of China, it is
also shown in Wood (2008) that the price ratio elasticity
zz
MP
(
δ
can be written as
zz
MP
zz
MP
zz
MP
zz
MP
a
(
(
(
(
τ
τ
δ
+
+
1
1
(A3)
where
zz
MP
(
τ
is country z’s ratio of trade costs in market ž to producer prices, averaged
across goods
M and P, and
zz
MP
a
(
is the fraction of trade costs that are proportional to
producer prices. To simplify the algebra, the definition of trade costs can be restricted
to those that are independent of producer prices and the definition of producer prices
expanded to include proportional trade costs, so that (A3) becomes
zz
MP
zz
MP
(
(
τ
δ
+
1
1
(A4)
Equation (2) in the main text is obtained by substituting equations (A2) and (A4) into
equation (A1). Moving now towards deriving equation (3) in the main text, equations
(1) and (2) can be combined more compactly as
(
)
zz
P
zz
M
zz
MP
zz
P
zz
M
ppqq
(
(
(
(
(
ˆˆ
~
ˆˆ
=
ε
(A5)
being alert to the risk of confusion between lower-case
p (purchaser price) and upper-
case
P (primary products), where
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
23
()
()
()
zz
MP
z
L
z
i
z
iL
NBi
iPiM
zz
P
zz
M
vv
pp
(
((
τ
ϕθθ
+
=
=
1
ˆˆ
ˆˆ
,
(A6)
Everything so far holds constant the prices of foreign suppliers to market
ž. Allowing
foreign prices to change involves extending (A5) into an equation of the form
(
)
(
)
z
P
z
M
z
MP
zz
P
zz
M
zz
MP
zz
P
zz
M
ppppqq
(
(
(
(
(
(
(
(
***
ˆˆ
~
ˆˆ
~
ˆˆ
+=
εε
(A7)
where
z
MP
(
*
~
ε
is the elasticity of country z’s relative sales in market ž with respect to the
relative purchaser prices of foreign suppliers, changes in which are determined by an
equation of the same general form as (A6)
()
()
()
z
MP
NBi
LiiLiPiM
z
P
z
M
vv
pp
(
((
*
,
***
**
1
ˆˆ
ˆˆ
τ
ϕθθ
+
=
=
(A8)
in which the
z superscripts are replaced with *s. The sign of
z
MP
(
*
~
ε
in (A7) is opposite
to that of
zz
MP
(
ε
~
because a rise, say, in country z’s price would lower its sales whereas a
rise in the prices of foreign suppliers would raise its sales. Its size is determined by
MP
zz
MP
z
MP
γεε
=
((
~
~
*
(A9)
meaning that it is smaller than
zz
MP
(
ε
~
by the size of the elasticity of substitution between
the two goods.
The convenient relationship in (A9), which does not depend on the simplification of
using an arithmetic rather than a geometric average in (A2), exists because alterations
in relative prices (by country
z or by the rest of the world) have two different effects
on sales. The first effect is on relative market shares, by altering the prices of country
z’s varieties of the two goods relative to the prices of other countries’ varieties: a rise
in
zz
P
zz
M
pp
((
lowers country z’s share of market ž for M and raises it for P; while a rise
in
z
P
z
M
pp
((
**
has an opposite and symmetrical impact, raising country z’s share of this
market for
M and lowering its share for P. The second effect is on relative total sales
of
M and P in market ž, by altering the relative prices of (all varieties of) these goods,
with asymmetrical effects: a rise in
zz
P
zz
M
pp
(
(
shrinks the whole market for M relative
to
P and so compounds the market-share effect on country zs relative sales of M and
P; whereas a rise in
z
P
z
M
pp
((
**
, though also shrinking the whole market for M relative
to
P, tends to offset the market-share effect on country z’s relative sales of M and P.
The difference between the compounding and offsetting aspects of this second effect
is the change in the overall relative sales of the two goods caused by a change in their
overall relative prices, which depends on
γ
MP
. For example, if both its own and
foreign suppliers’ relative purchaser prices changed by an equal amount, country
z’s
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
24
share of market ž would remain constant and the change in its relative sales would be
determined entirely by the elasticity of substitution between the two goods. Hence,
substituting into (A9) for
zz
MP
(
ε
~
from (A2) and rearranging,
(
)
(
MPMP
zz
MP
z
MP
s
γβε
=
((
1
)
~
*
(A10)
Equation (3) in the main text is derived by expanding equation (A7), using equations
(A2), (A6), (A8) and (A10), and rearranging. The second line of equation (3) gets its
negative sign from that of equation (A8).
Appendix B. Derivation of the output data
This appendix explains how output data for primary products,
P, and labour-intensive
manufactures,
M, were derived by combining UN national accounts statistics with
UNIDO industrial output statistics.
Our primary category,
P, as in the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC),
includes processed primary products (
PP), which the International Standard Industrial
Classification (ISIC) treats as manufactures. That is:
P (broad or SITC primary) = NP (narrow or ISIC primary) + PP (processed primary)
NM (narrow or SITC manufacturing) = BM (broad or ISIC manufacturing) – PP.
We also need to divide the narrow SITC manufactures category into labour-intensive
manufactures (
NML), skill-intensive manufactures (NMH) and electronics (EL):
BM = PP + NM = PP + NML + NMH + EL.
The first step of the calculation was to use the UNIDO data to calculate four shares:
ψ
PPBM
= PP/BM; ψ
NMLBM
= NML/BM; ψ
NMHBM
= NMH/BM; and ψ
ELBM
= EL/BM.
The second step of the calculation was to convert National Accounts sectoral output
data for agriculture (
NPA), mining (NPM) and ISIC manufacturing (BM
NA
) into P and
NM, as follows:
P = NPA + NPM + (ψ
PPBM
*BM
NA
)
NM
NA
= (1 – ψ
PPBM
)*BM
NA
The third step of the calculation was to split up
NM, as follows
NML
NA
= ψ
NMLBM
*NM
NA
;
NMH
NA
= ψ
NMHBM
*NM
NA
;
EL
NA
= ψ
ELBM
*NM
NA
.
Our category
M was then defined for developing countries as NML
NA
+ EL
NA,
and for
developed countries simply as
NML
NA
, for reasons explained in the main text.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
25
The ISIC (Revision 2) 3-digit groups included in each of the categories into which we
split broad manufacturing were as follows:
PP: 311, 313, 314, 353, 354, 372
NML: 321, 322, 323, 324, 331, 332, 341, 342, 355, 356, 361, 362, 369, 371, 381, 390
NMH: 351, 352, 382, 384, 385.
EL: 383
We encountered four problems in deriving the required output data from the UNIDO
Industrial Statistics Database 2006.
1) For some countries and years, some data were aggregated across 3-digit groups.
To disaggregate them, we applied the shares of the relevant groups in the aggregate in
the previous three years for which disaggregated data were available. Countries for
which there were no disaggregated data for any year were excluded.
2) Missing data for some groups and years. Such gaps were filled (i) by calculating an
average value if the missing observation was between two available ones, or (ii) by
calculating the percentage change for the three previous or following years, depending
on whether the observations were missing at the end or at the beginning of a period.
Countries for which these calculations could not be made were excluded.
3) Data for some countries had to be combined to obtain consistent time series. Data
for West Germany (available up to 1993) were combined with data (available from
1998) for Germany (which includes the former East Germany). Data for Belgium and
Luxembourg were combined to match the only available trade data. Data for Ethiopia
were combined with data for Eritrea, using the dollar exchange rates in the UNIDO
dataset to convert the data for Eritrea into Ethiopian Birr.
4) Part of the data for Burundi and for Trinidad and Tobago appear to be misreported.
We thus assumed that for Burundi group 383 had been wrongly placed in group 390
from 1986 to 1991, and that for Trinidad and Tobago groups 382 and 383 had been
wrongly aggregated into group 383 between 1982 and 1987.
Appendix C. Country coverage of the data sets
The 53-country data set contains:
Developed countries (20 countries): Australia, Austria, Belgium and Luxembourg,
Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan,
Norway, Poland, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom, United States.
East Asia (6 countries): Hong Kong (China SAR), Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines,
Republic of Korea, Singapore.
South Asia (3 countries): Bangladesh, India, Sri Lanka.
Latin America (10 countries): Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, El
Salvador, Mexico, Trinidad and Tobago, Uruguay, Venezuela.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
2
6
Middle East and North Africa (7 countries): Egypt, Iran, Jordan, Kuwait, Syrian Arab
Republic, Tunisia, Turkey.
Sub-Saharan Africa (7 countries): Cameroon, Kenya, Malawi, Mauritius, Senegal,
South Africa, United Republic of Tanzania.
The 96-country data set contains the following additional countries:
Developed countries (6 countries): Bulgaria, Denmark, Netherlands, New Zealand,
Romania, Switzerland.
East Asia (3 countries): Papua New Guinea, Taiwan (Province of China), Thailand.
South Asia (4 countries): Afghanistan, Myanmar, Nepal, Pakistan.
Latin America (12 countries): Argentina, Brazil, Cuba, Dominican Republic,
Guatemala, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru.
Middle East and North Africa (2 countries): Algeria, Iraq.
Sub-Saharan Africa (16 countries): Benin, Central African Republic, Democratic
Republic of the Congo, Ghana, Guinea-Bissau, Liberia, Mali, Mozambique, Niger,
Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Togo, Uganda, Zambia, Zimbabwe.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
2
7
Table 1. Impact of China on world average endowment ratios
Log
e
Log
e
Log
e
1980 2000 change 1980 2000 change 1980 2000 change
Labour-force-weighted average
Including China 5.34 6.50 0.20 0.42 0.47 0.10 3.58 2.40 -0.40
Excluding China 5.53 6.54 0.17 0.41 0.43 0.04 4.34 2.90 -0.40
Log
e
difference -0.04 -0.01 0.03 0.03 0.09 0.06 -0.19 -0.19 0.00
Openness-adjusted average
Including China 5.75 6.65 0.15 0.46 0.50 0.07 4.24 2.43 -0.56
Excluding China 5.89 6.74 0.14 0.46 0.47 0.01 4.65 2.96 -0.45
Log
e
difference -0.02 -0.01 0.01 0.00 0.06 0.07 -0.09 -0.20 -0.10
China's endowment ratios 4.80 6.40 0.29 0.46 0.58 0.24 1.45 0.98 -0.39
Note: sources and methods explained in text; our estimates of the impact of China's opening to trade are indicated with bold font. The 'world'
in this table covers 93 countries (plus China), three fewer than for the 96-country export regressions in later tables: Liberia is omitted because
its recorded trade/GDP ratio in 2000 of over 4 is not credible; Egypt and Guinea-Bissau are omitted because of incomplete endowment data.
Their omission has a negligible effect on the averages.
Adult years of
schooling
Basic-educated share of
labour force (B /L )
Land (km
2
) per 100
workers (N /L )
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
28
Table 2. Details of variables used in regressions
Mean Std dev Max Min
Dependent variable (log
e
M /P )
Output (53 countries) -0.83 1.04 2.24 -3.48
Exports (53 countries) -0.48 1.52 2.54 -4.18
Exports (96 countries) -1.08 1.87 2.78 -7.31
Endowment ratios (logged)
b = B /L (53 countries)
-0.83 0.47 -0.14 -2.26
b = B /L (96 countries)
-1.09 0.70 -0.14 -4.34
n = N /L (53 countries)
-3.98 1.51 -0.35 -8.57
n = N /L (96 countries)
-3.66 1.46 -0.35 -8.57
Dummy variables
A
1
1 for developed countries in 1990 and 2000, 0 otherwise
A
2
1 for developed countries in 2000, 0 otherwise
D
1
1 for developing countries in all three years, 0 otherwise
D
2
1 for developing countries in 1990 and 2000, 0 otherwise
D
3
1 for developing countries in 2000, 0 otherwise
Note: Eastern Europe included in 'developed' for purposes of defining
coverage of dummy variables. On this basis, developed countries are 38%
of the 53-country data and 27% of the 96-country data. China is omitted
from all the regressions.
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
29
Method Intercept
R
2
log
e
b
log
e
n
A
1
A
2
D
1
D
2
D
3
Output ratio (53 countries, 3 years)
POLS
-1.06 0.60 -0.30 0.00 0.14 -0.75 0.00 -0.05 0.57
(0.00) (0.01) (0.00) (0.97) (0.02) (0.01) (0.97) (0.59)
FE
0.58 0.32 0.32 0.21 0.20 0.14 0.12
(0.70) (0.19) (0.41) (0.04) (0.13) (0.28)
FD
0.01 0.05 -0.14 0.11 0.09 -0.05 0.02
(0.90) (0.83) (0.80) (0.15) (0.56) (0.63)
FD
0.02 0.11 0.12 -0.06 0.01
(0.62) (0.15) (0.17) (0.61)
Export ratio (53 countries, 3 years)
POLS
-1.60 0.77 -0.50 0.14 0.20 -0.72 0.30 0.10 0.48
(0.00) (0.07) (0.00) (0.13) (0.05) (0.13) (0.14) (0.62)
FE
2.98 -0.28 1.06 0.40 0.83 0.60 0.33
(0.42) (0.63) (0.27) (0.10) (0.01) (0.05)
FD
0.24 0.21 0.82 0.04 0.48 -0.22 0.03
(0.05) (0.74) (0.52) (0.78) (0.18) (0.42)
FD
0.17 0.03 0.34 -0.21 0.02
(0.03) (0.83) (0.09) (0.46)
Export ratio (96 countries, 3 years)
POLS
-2.14 0.59 -0.58 0.14 0.21 -0.71 0.02 0.15 0.45
(0.00) (0.03) (0.00) (0.06) (0.02) (0.04) (0.88) (0.33)
FE
2.82 -0.22 1.28 0.45 0.68 0.72 0.35
(0.32) (0.51) (0.11) (0.04) (0.01) (0.00)
FD
0.30 0.06 1.27 0.02 0.33 0.07 0.01
(0.00) (0.86) (0.22) (0.86) (0.17) (0.74)
FD
0.19 0.03 0.11 0.07 0.00
(0.01) (0.79) (0.42) (0.72)
Note. All regressions exclude China. P values in parentheses.
Coefficients on independent variables
Table 3. Regression results 1980-2000 (dependent variable in all rows is log
e
q
M
/
q
P
)
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
30
Table 4. Predicted impact of China's opening on ratio of labour-
intensive manufacturing to primary production in other countries
Labour-force- Openness-
weighted adjusted
Impact on log
e
M /P output ratio -0.11 -0.07
Impact on log
e
M /P export ratio
53-country coefficients -0.16 -0.10
96-country coefficients -0.16 -0.10
Note. Calculations explained in text, using data from tables 1 and 3
on world endowment ratios
Alternative estimates of impact
QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS175
31
Table 5. Changes in logged ratios of labour-intensive-manufacturing to primary output and exports, 1980-2000, regional averages
Region (number
of countries in 53- 1980- 1990- Differ- 1980- 1990- Differ- Extra 1980- 1990- Differ-
country data) 1990 2000 ence 1990 2000 ence countries 1990 2000 ence
China -0.02 0.24 0.26 0.34 1.13 0.79 0.34 1.13 0.79
Developed (20) 0.02 0.13 0.11 0.17 0.20 0.03 6 0.19 0.21 0.03
Developing (33) 0.14 0.08 -0.06 0.51 0.30 -0.21 0.29 0.37 0.07
East Asia (6) 0.43 0.24 -0.19 1.20 0.75 -0.45 3 0.88 0.54 -0.34
Standard deviation 0.480.370.28 1.070.761.03 1.170.770.88
South Asia (3) 0.00 0.29 0.29 0.77 0.81 0.04 4 0.73 0.68 -0.05
Standard deviation 0.150.230.25 0.790.490.71 0.831.051.21
Latin America (10) 0.10 -0.07 -0.17 0.04 0.73 0.69 12 0.08 0.47 0.39
Standard deviation 0.380.570.64 1.010.761.23 0.890.641.10
Middle East (7) 0.21 0.07 -0.14 0.57 -0.43 -1.00 2 0.46 -0.73 -1.19
Standard deviation 0.420.510.86 1.241.792.42 1.381.712.17
Sub-Saharan Africa (7) -0.08 0.08 0.16 0.40 -0.19 -0.59 16 0.07 0.53 0.45
Standard deviation 0.500.360.68 0.720.861.26 0.771.592.02
Notes: regional averages are unweighted; Eastern Europe included in 'developed' group (Hungary and Poland in 53-country data; plus Bulgaria
and Romania in 96-country data); East Asia excludes China; Latin America includes Caribbean; Middle East includes North Africa.
Output (53 countries) Exports (53 countries) Exports (96 countries)
... China's contribution did not merely add to global totals: structural change in other countries over this period would have been different if it had remained a closed nonmarket economy. Because of its vast size, China's opening to trade effectively lowered the global land/labor ratio and raised the share of workers with a basic education in the global labor force, shifting the comparative advantage of other developing countries from manufacturing to primary production, though in most cases not by much (Wood and Mayer 2011). Had China remained closed, in short, other developing countries would have become more industrialized. ...
... Other land-scarce developing countries will occupy the labor-intensive manufacturing space vacated by China (Wood and Mayer 2011). Their sectoral shares of manufacturing will rise, relative to those of primary activities, for both output and employment, particularly formal employment (and if the relative world price of labor-intensive manufactures rises, so will the relative wages of their unskilled workers). ...
... I simply couldn't answer his question, but neither could I forget it. When I came back to academia in the UK in 1985at the Institute of Development Studies at Sussexit turned into the question I decided to pursue in my research: how was the expansion of labour-intensive exports to developed countries by developing countries going to affect both sorts of countriesincluding, in the case of China, not just developed countries, but also other developing countries (Mayer/Wood 2011)? It took me a long time to provide an initial answer in that book, after which I went on to do a lot more work. ...
... 23-25). According to Adrian Wood, Chinese exporters lowered the ratio of labour-intensive manufacturing to primary output in other countries by 7-10% and the ratio of exports by 10-15% (Wood and Mayer 2009). Only neighbours close to China are integrated in its manufacturing production chains. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
Forging sustainable development must explicitly commit to gender issues in the management of enterprises in Africa. However, advancing both gender equality and creating sustainable pathways present pressing problems. This book chapter examines the need to address gender equality and sustainable development jointly and outlines the moral, ethical, and practical justifications. It was found that the sustainability issues in Africa include overusing and non-renewal of our natural resources (depletion of natural resources), environmental degradation, and high-income inequality. Gender inequality in Africa was found in work and industrialisation, demographics and procreation, agriculture and food production, water, sanitation, and energy, among others. The main drivers of gender inequality in Africa were revealed as unequal access to social protection, and economic, and legal power. Other factors that were found to prevent gender equality and sustainability were uneven distribution of the costs of extreme poverty, education, skill disparities, and gender stereotypes. Realistic solutions suggested are fostering the development of women as they formed the majority of a marginalised group and improving equal access to school, and leadership positions, and, abolishing cultural practices that discriminate against women.
... At QEH, he extended this analysis to show how cheaper communication and travel, by assisting highly skilled workers in the North to cooperate with workers in the South, had widened the wage gap in the North between highly skilled and other workers while narrowing the North-South gap in the wages of other workers (Anderson et al. 2006). He proposed improvements to Heckscher-Ohlin theory (Wood 2011) and estimated the size of the shift in the comparative advantage of the rest of the South away from manufacturing and towards primary production as a result of China's entry into world markets (Wood and Mayer 2011). In another work, Wood showed how the impact of aid on world poverty could be increased by allocating it in a way that took account of differences among developing countries not only in terms of current poverty levels but also in probable rates of poverty decline in the absence of aid (Wood 2008). ...
Chapter
This chapter reviews Oxford economists’ contributions to development economics from around 1950 to the 2010s. It shows the enormous range of contributions to analysis and policy by Oxford development economists, evolving with the changes in the global and developing country context. Throughout, there were broad two schools of thought, one tending to favour a neoclassical approach using traditional economic concepts, and the other more critical of these concepts and more multidisciplinary. Both were firmly grounded in empirical research and each made important contributions and influenced policy, interacting with national and global development institutions. By the end of the period, the role of development economics was diminishing with the increasing heterogeneity in the developing world while problems, constraints and opportunities became more universal, encompassing developed as well as developing countries. Oxford economists are moving towards a more universal approach, but institutions have yet to catch up.
... In the same vein, a multi-country comparative analysis showed that labour-intensive manufacturing was lower in 33 countries, owing to increased exposure to Chinese imports. The effect was larger in developing economies that produced goods similar to those produced in China (Wood & Mayer, 2011). Import competition from China could, therefore, have led to a decline in employment across Latin America, and, in certain cases, to an increase in informality, with little evidence of significant changes in wages (Moreira & Stein, 2019). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper explores the effects of import competition on the manufacturing sector in Chile following the implementation of the country’s two largest Free Trade Agreements (FTA) (with the USA and China). Exploiting cross-industry variation in import exposure, we analyse the effects on manufacturing sales, employment and labour productivity at the finest level of industrial classification (4 digit ISIC level). We detect an overall negative effect of increased Chinese import penetration, owing to substitution effects from low and medium tech imports and a less pronounced effect from USA imports. By introducing interaction effects, we find that the levels of foreign ownership and the export intensity of the domestic industries reverse the negative effect due to the opportunities offered via participation in global value chains. An IV strategy is applied to address standard endogeneity concerns and confirm the robustness of our estimates.
Article
The Oxford Handbook of Economic Imperialism examines unequal commercial, trade, and investment gains at the international level and explores how countries and nations can have exploitative relations. The book contains thirty-four chapters written by academics and experts in the field of international political economy. The chapters in the Handbook look at the history of economic imperialism from the early modern age to the present. They demonstrate the persistence of economic imperialism in today’s postcolonial world and the enduring control wielded by great powers even after the end of formal empire. The book reveals how emerging powers are expanding economic control in new geographic and geopolitical contexts. The Handbook highlights the significance of economic imperialism in the structures, relations, processes, and ideas that help sustain poverty and conflict worldwide.
Article
Informal labour relations and underemployed persons abound in many formerly colonized countries. The abundance of persons offering their labour power in relationship to the limited demand for their labour stems from the insufficient absorption of peasants set free from their land. In many late industrializing countries, most of those who are leaving agriculture do not find gainful employment. In fact, many of the late industrializers are prematurely de-industrializing. Based on a comparison between the conditions prevalent among the early industrializers and present-day latecomers to industry and advanced services, this chapter highlights how the generally violent passage from an agrarian-rural to a capitalist industrial-urban economy is aggravated by imperialist legacies and current post-imperialist practices for many countries of the Global South.
Article
Full-text available
This paper studies the empirical links among factor endowments, trade, and personal income distribution. The motivation is that many developing countries have implemented radical trade reforms in recent years. These reforms have changed relative prices, induced a reallocation of resources, and may have led to the introduction of new production techniques. These changes are quite complex and their final effect on income distribution is theoretically unclear. The author`s aim is to present the stylized empirical facts on the relations between income distribution, factor endowments, and trade.
Article
Full-text available
Cross-country econometric analysis informed by Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory suggests that the concentration of Africa's exports on unprocessed primary products is caused largely by the region's combination of low levels of education and abundant natural resources. In some African countries, the share of manufactures in exports could be raised by improving infrastructure and policies. For most of Africa, however, the highest priority is to raise the absolute level of exports in all sectors, and particularly in sectors based on natural resources, following a development path more like that of land-abundant America than of land-scarce Asia.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we examine the impact of China's growth on developing countries that specialize in manufacturing. Over 2000-2005, manufacturing accounted for 32% of China's GDP and 89% of its merchandise exports, making it more specialized in the sector than any other large developing economy. Using the gravity model of trade, we decompose bilateral trade into components associated with demand conditions in importing countries, supply conditions in exporting countries, and bilateral trade costs. We identify 10 developing economies for which manufacturing represents more than 75% of merchandise exports (Hungary, Malaysia, Mexico, Pakistan, the Philippines, Poland, Romania, Sri Lanka, Thailand, and Turkey), which are in theory the countries most exposed to the adverse consequences of China's export growth. Our results suggest that had China's export supply capacity been constant over the 1995-2005 period, demand for exports would have been 0.8% to 1.6% higher in the 10 countries studied. Thus, even for the developing countries most specialized in export manufacturing, China's expansion has represented only a modest negative shock.
Article
Full-text available
This paper formalises the enduring insights of Heckscher and Ohlin in a way that avoids the two least satisfactory features of the standard Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model, namely that in an open economy factor prices are unaffected by endowments or demand and that outcomes vary drastically with the assumed numbers of goods and factors. Its main innovation is to recognise that (and describe simply how) trade costs diminish the economic impact of differences between places in relative production costs, a point relevant also to other models of trade. The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model is a special case of the more general model.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyses the impact of China's exports on the prices of exports from other countries using disaggregated import data in the US, EU and Japan over the 1989-2006 period. Findings from this study suggest that China's exports have affected not just those countries whose competitiveness is largely based on low wages but all country groups in certain products sectors, destination markets and during different time periods. The middle income countries are the most affected by China's export expansion through price competition particularly after the late 1990s as a consequence of China's market expansion, its WTO entry and exchange rate variation. The influence on high-income countries is only in low-technology product sectors and appears to lose its significance in the post-1997 period. The impact on low-income countries is only significant in the medium- and high-tech sectors mostly in the pre-1997 period and this effect weakened over time.
Article
Full-text available
Although both China and India are labor-abundant and dependant on manufactures, the two rely on very different export mixes. Only one product—refined petroleum—appears in the top 25 products for both, and services exports are roughly twice as important for India as for China, which is much more strongly integrated into global production networks. Even assuming India also begins to integrate into global production chains and expands exports of manufactures, there seems to be opportunity for rapid growth in both. Accelerated growth through efficiency improvements in China and India, especially in their high-tech industries, will intensify competition in global markets leading to contraction of the manufacturing sectors in many countries. Improvement in the range and quality of exports from both countries has the potential to create substantial welfare benefits to the world, and to each other, and to act as a powerful offset to the terms-of-trade losses otherwise associated with rapid export growth. However, without efforts to keep up with China and India, some countries may see further erosion of their export shares and high-tech manufacturing sectors.
Book
China's size, rapid growth, external openness, and trade performance have led to varying perceptions among the countries of Latin America: Is China a potential new market, a potent new competitor, or both? This book assesses the near-term strategic implications of China's economic performance for growth and development in Latin America.
Chapter
IntroductionA Brief Summary of International Trade TheoryA Brief Summary of China's Relative EndowmentsProduct-Level Trade DataAcross-Product SophisticationWithin-Product SophisticationInterpretation of Results: How Close is China to the OECD?Caveats: Does Price Equal Quality?Conclusion References
Article
China's meteoric climb since the mid 1990s, as an exporter of manufactures, and India's ability, over the past six years to claim a sizable fraction of the global market for tradable IT enabled services1 have contributed to the changing pattern and the volume of global trade. Some of the implications of these are modeled and described in chapter 3. In 2004, China's share of the world's merchandise exports was close to 7 percent, that of India was a little less than 1 percent. The two countries' shares of global imports were 6.1 percent and 1 percent respectively. China's manufacturing sector accounts for over 41 percent of GDP and manufactured goods constituted 93 percent of exports in 2005 or almost one quarter of the gross value of industrial output. Machinery and transport equipment accounted for 45.2 percent of total exports. These statistics reflect the large gains in manufacturing capability facilitated by heavy investment in plant and equipment embodying the latest technologies and the codification of knowledge on production processes. Relative to China, India's formal manufacturing sector accounts for a far smaller share of GDP—less than 16 percent. Investment in new industrial capacity and industrial growth since 1990 has been slower and exports of manufactures are a fraction of China's in absolute terms and also a smaller fraction of total exports. Undoubtedly, India has achieved competitiveness in a few manufacturing subsectors and some of those are technologically quite advanced, as we will discuss below; however, on balance manufacturing capability has lagged. As described later, India's breakthrough is in the exports of certain business process services and software the tradability of which has been greatly enhanced by advances in telecommunications and the advent of the Internet.2 These developments point to ongoing and impending shifts in worldwide industrial geography. In this chapter we explore the likelihood of a continuing concentration of major industrial activities in China and India and the implications of such trends, were they to materialize, for other economies. The balance of this chapter is divided as follows: Section II describes the size of the domestic markets in China and India, especially for the relevant manufacturing products. Section III focuses on the overall strategy and patterns of development in the two countries. In section IV, we briefly examine the development of a few of the leading industrial and service sectors in both