ArticlePDF Available

Choices and the value of natural capital

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Sustainability requires maintaining opportunities for future generations, so they can meet their needs. Opportunities are passed to future generations through a set of capital assets. Nature provides an important class of these assets, but markets seldom reveal the marginal value of natural capital. Rather, the marginal social worth or asset price must be imputed based on intertemporal exchange. In the context of assessing whether intertemporal allocation rules lead to sustainable development, appropriate asset prices must be based on the actual allocations and trade-offs society makes. Therefore, measuring economic programmes that enable the measurement of asset prices is an important empirical task. We review the theory of measuring natural capital asset prices and discuss the key elements of measuring economic programmes that enable the measurement of natural capital asset prices. We place the measurement of economic programmes and natural capital asset prices in the context of wealth-based sustainability metrics.
Content may be subject to copyright.
doi:10.1093/oxrep/gry021
© The Author(s) 2019. Published by Oxford University Press.
For permissions please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com
Choices and the value of natural capital
Eli P.Fenichel* and YukikoHashida**
Abstract: Sustainability requires maintaining opportunities for future generations, so they can meet
their needs. Opportunities are passed to future generations through a set of capital assets. Nature
provides an important class of these assets, but markets seldom reveal the marginal value of nat-
ural capital. Rather, the marginal social worth or asset price must be imputed based on intertempo-
ral exchange. In the context of assessing whether intertemporal allocation rules lead to sustainable
development, appropriate asset prices must be based on the actual allocations and trade-offs society
makes. Therefore, measuring economic programmes that enable the measurement of asset prices is an
important empirical task. We review the theory of measuring natural capital asset prices and discuss
the key elements of measuring economic programmes that enable the measurement of natural capital
asset prices. We place the measurement of economic programmes and natural capital asset prices in the
context of wealth-based sustainability metrics.
Keywords: sustainability, wealth, natural capital, ecosystem services, green accounting
JEL classication: E01, Q01, Q56
I. Introduction
‘Sustainable’ cannot be a mere synonym for good; the sustainability concept must be
achievable and measurable. Asking whether society is sustainable without some clear
metric is not particularly useful (Solow, 1993). The World Commission on Environment
and Development (1987) added some precision by dening sustainable development as
meeting the needs of present generations without compromising the ability of future
generations to meet their needs. Said differently, sustainable development requires that
society maintains an opportunity set. Therefore, whether society is on a sustainable
path is a question of intertemporal allocation of resources: how much is consumed
and how much is saved, invested, or conserved? The majority of economic research on
intertemporal allocation has focused on optimal and efcient allocation. Sustainability,
however, only requires preserving an opportunity set, which does not ensure nor require
optimal or efcient allocation. Indeed, Dasgupta and Heal (1974) established that
* Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies; e-mail: eli.fenichel@yale.edu
** Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies; e-mail: yukiko.hashida@yale.edu
This research was supported by the Knobloch Family Foundations and beneted from discussions with
Joshua Abbott, Dieter Helm, Alexander Teytelboym, and the notes of an anonymous reviewer.
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Volume 35, Number 1, 2019, pp. 120–137
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
optimal intertemporal allocation of essential resource stocks might not lead to sus-
tainable consumption.1 Therefore, it is helpful to be able to discuss sustainability in a
world where intertemporal allocation is not optimal nor even efcient (Dasgupta, 2007;
Dasgupta and Maler, 2000). To address this challenge, Dasgupta and Maler (2000)
introduced the concept of a forecastable economic programme where economies or
governments may not allocate resources optimally or efciently.2 They call the map-
ping from a set of current capital assets levels to a future set of ows and stocks a
resource allocation mechanism.3 The policy question is whether the observed or likely
economic programme maintains opportunities for future generations, which is ultim-
ately an empirical question.
A quantitative measure to evaluate whether an economic programme sustains an
opportunity set is the change in the value of a portfolio of capital stocks conditional on
following a specic economic programme (Maler, 1991; Hamilton and Clemens, 1999;
Dasgupta and Maler, 2000; Dasgupta, 2007; Barbier, 2011; Helm, 2015). This port-
folio, comprising 123,,,
S stocks, indexed by
i
, including traditional reproducible
(built or manmade), natural, and human capital.4 The measure of the state of the broad
portfolio of capital stocks or assets is Inclusive or Comprehensive Wealth or Genuine
Savings (Arrow etal., 2004; World Bank, 2011; Hamilton and Hartwick, 2014; UNU-
IHDP and UNEP, 2014; Hanley et al., 2015). Dasgupta (2007) argues that if society
follows a sustainable economic programme then (inclusive, comprehensive, or genuine)
wealth, =
i
ii
ps , measured using ‘appropriate’ and constant accounting prices, pi,
applied to quantities of stocks, si, is non-declining, i.e.
∆∆
=≥
ps
ii 0 and approx-
imates changes in welfare.5 This measurement concept is increasingly embraced out-
side of economics (Matson et al., 2016). Though Irving Fisher (1906) and Theodore
Roosevelt (1910) expressed this idea over 100years ago. In 1910, Roosevelt comes close
to articulating the current denition of wealth-based sustainability, at least with respect
to natural resources:
The nation behaves well if it treats the natural resources as assets which it
must turn over to the next generation increased, and not impaired, in value;
and behaves badly if it leaves the land poorer to those who come after it. That
is all Imean by the phrase, Conservation of natural resources. Use them; but
use them so that as far as possible our children will be richer, and not poorer,
because we have lived.
1 Dasgupta and Heal (1974) focus on technological innovation. For recent treatments of this issue see
Groth (2007).
2 An efcient economic programme requires that intertemporal and Pareto improvement opportunities
are exhausted, so there is a unique efcient economic programme, conditional on initial conditions. It is
unlikely that there is a unique sustainable economic programme.
3 The distinction between economic programme and resource allocation mechanism is lost in the subse-
quent literature, and we use the terms interchangeably.
4 Fleurbaey and Blanchet (2013) provide a review of the development of sustainability metrics. Helm
(2015) provides a rich description of limits on substitution and aggregation rules discussed in the context of
sustainability.
5 Importantly, total wealth has no welfare theoretic interpretation.
Choices and the value of natural capital 121
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
Whether inclusive wealth is rising or falling is an empirical question. Physical scientists
are increasingly adept at measuring changes in stocks of natural resources. Economists
struggle to determine the appropriate prices,
p,
to use in change of wealth assessments
when the prices are not observable in markets. Smulders (2012) writes ‘The Achilles’
heel of the [wealth based] method [for measuring sustainability] is the determination
of the shadow prices’, where shadow prices refer to the appropriate natural capital
asset prices. Even if the price of stock i were known at time
t
and
t+∆
, the
p
in
must be constant and formed as a convex combination of the two measures of price
(Fenichel etal., 2016b; Fenichel etal., 2018). The challenge is determining ‘appropriate’
price functions to measure changes in wealth, particularly for assets that are subject to
thin, distorted, or missing markets—as is the case with many important forms of nat-
ural capital.6
Observed prices reveal the exchange ratios that society is accepting, even in ‘distorted’
economies. These prices reect political and non-market trade-offs, power dynamics,
institutional arrangements, and expected technological developments, in addition to
preference orderings. Prices capture the extent to which society behaves as if goods or
assets have substitutes or complements. Therefore, measured prices and shadow prices
are the best estimates of revealed opportunity costs and are the appropriate prices to
use in
. They inform the question of whether an observed economic programme can
be considered sustainable. Appropriate prices for sustainability accounting are revealed
shadow prices based on prevailing institutions and behaviours or in the case of pro-
spective analyses, feasible and realistic alternative institutions (Fenichel etal., 2018).7
There are three reasons why prices for sustainability assessment must be based on the
observed economic programme rather than a hypothetical optimal programme. First,
the optimal economic programme is one of many possible economic programmes, but
the observed programme is likely to be full of market failures. Second, analysis of opti-
mal allocation is important to make policy recommendations, but such counterfactual
economic programmes do not reect the actual trade-offs that society is currently mak-
ing. There is an analogue in the non-market demand literature—replacement costs are
only valid measures of the value for the lost capital stocks if people are actually willing
to make investments to replace the damaged or lost stocks (Freeman, 2003). If society
will never shift to an ‘optimal’ programme, then the marginal user cost associated with
the optimal programme is hardly the correct measure of opportunity cost for use in
sustainability assessment. Third, the economic programme describes how people are
using resources today versus saving for tomorrow, and therefore is central to under-
standing sustainability. In cases where the consensus is that current consumption is
excessive and asset management is poor, then the shadow price of a stock will be lower
than expected, all else equal. Improved management of an asset is expected to raise
the asset’s value, all else equal. Such changes would be important for the users of sus-
tainability assessments. Assuming that shadow prices were associated with an optimal
programme would obscure thesegains.
6 We focus on natural capital, but many other forms of capital may also suffer from distorted or missing
markets, and our exposition may be relevant to those capital stocks as well.
7 Realized shadow prices are also called accounting prices (Dasgupta and Maler, 2000) and exchange
prices (Obst and Vardon, 2014).
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
122
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
Society’s choice of economic programme is the only vehicle available to it to inuence
whether or not the future is sustainable, because the economic programme determines
how resources are allocated. Generating a forecastable economic programme requires
measurement, and a forecastable economic programme is imperative for measuring the
appropriate prices to use in the inclusive wealth index, especially for natural capital.
In this article we contribute to the literature on sustainability assessment and natural
capital valuation by focusing on the necessary steps to describe and measure prevail-
ing economic programmes, which complements prior work on deriving approximat-
ing approaches for natural capital asset prices conditional on measured economic
programmes.
II. Asset shadow prices and the measurement of
sustainability
It is helpful to review the connection between welfare, wealth, and capital asset prices in
order to understand the importance of the economic programme or resource allocation
mechanism, which is the feedback rule, xs
()
, that maps society’s current set of assets,
s
, into the uses of those assets
x
. Maler etal. (2008), Hamilton and Ruta (2009), and
Lange (2004) argue biophysical dynamics inuence the asset value of natural capital.
Fenichel and Abbott (2014b) extend these ideas and incorporate the importance of a
dynamic economic programme to develop a theory of measuring shadow prices that
generalizes Jorgenson’s (1963) approach to valuing invested capital assets.8 Fenichel
etal. (2016a), Yun etal. (2017b), Fenichel etal. (2018), and Abbott etal. (2018) extend
Fenichel and Abbott’s approach to address general equilibrium effects among real
assets and correlated stochastic stock dynamics. The principal insight from Fenichel
and Abbott (2014a), building off Dasgupta and Maler (2000), is that the Hamilton–
Jacobi–Bellman relationship does not depend on optimization, so long as the analyst
possesses an empirical forecastable economic programme. This opens a path to measur-
ing theoretically consistent revealed natural capital asset values or shadow prices condi-
tional on actual decisions rather than hypothetically optimal decisions. If capital stock
dynamics are deterministic and autonomous in time, then intertemporal welfare,
V
, as
a function of holding a set of stocks,
s
, at a point in time
t
(see Appendix for formal
description), is the present value of real net income or dividends from those stocks con-
ditional on how they are used (Fisher, 1906).9
Wealth-based sustainability theory focuses on changes in wealth and intertemporal
welfare. The change in intertemporal welfare over time is
()
()
∂=Vt t
sp
s/¢, where
p
¢
is the transpose of the vector of constant prices. Part of the challenge emerges in
a theory of measurement because measurement is always over time periods where the
8 Maler etal. (2008) and Hamilton and Ruta (2009) note the importance of institutional arrangements.
9 We use Fisher’s rather than Hicks’s (1939) concept of income because Fisher’s income concept allows a
decomposition of welfare changes and the connection between income and capital, whereas Hicks’s income
concept combines current period income ows with future potential ows so that capital disappears as a con-
cept. Weitzman (2016) provides further discussion about the relationship between Hicksian and Fisherian
income.
Choices and the value of natural capital 123
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
change in time is non-trivial. Once the time interval is not trivially small, then there can
be meaningful changes in the stock of capital and the price. In the capital accounts of
price-taking rms, the rm’s own level of capital would not inuence the price for the
asset, and constant prices are a reasonable assumption. However, changes in the value
of society’s aggregate stock of a capital asset can affect the price. Aweighted aver-
age of prices at time
t
and
tt+∆
exists to make the accounting notion of a change
in wealth and the economic concept of a change in intertemporal welfare identical
(Figure1). This interpretation is similar to Harberger’s (1971) argument that change in
net national product is a rst-order approximation of a welfare change.
Markets implicitly (or explicitly) forecast changes in assetallocation and scarcity.
If the dynamics of
s
can be forecast using ex ante knowledge of the economic pro-
gramme xs
()
for non-market assets, then the asset price is marginal net real income
or marginal net dividends plus own and cross-price capital gains terms, and a cross-
stock capital gains term all divided by the discount rate plus the marginal physical net
appreciation rate of the asset (see Appendix for a formal description). The cross-price
and cross-stock capital gains terms reect general equilibrium interactions between real
assets, and in the case of natural capital these can occur through ecological interactions
or interactions created by the economic programme (Fenichel etal., 2018).
Figure1: The connection between change in welfare, change in wealth, and shadow prices
Notes: Consider the change from stock s1 to stock s2. Panel Ashows the change in welfare, vertically hashed
area. The difference between the grey region and checked region in Panel B shows ps ps
11
22
, which is not
the change in wealth. Panel C shows the correct change in wealth using the arithmetic mean of p1 and p2
at the constant asset price as the vertically hashed region plus the checked region. If the checked region
equalled the horizontally hashed region, then change in wealth would equal change in welfare. Panel D illus-
trates that aweighted mean of p1 and p2 can be chosen to make the checked region equivalent to the hori-
zontally hashed region, aligning changes in wealth and changes in welfare.
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
124
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
The intertemporal welfare function
V()
s and its nth order derivatives are not revealed
through data. Fenichel etal. (2018) and Yun etal. (2017a) describe how asset prices and
changes in intertemporal welfare can be approximated to arbitrary precision, assuming
the stock dynamics, conditional on the economic programme, are bounded. Yun et al.
(2017a) provide an R package, capital asset pricing for nature, capn (https://cran.r-project.
org/web/packages/capn/index.html), for conducting the functional approximation.
Once measured, the price and intertemporal welfare functions, pi
()
s and
V
s
()
,
provide two paths towards resolving the challenge of selecting the appropriate set of
prices to use to measure
. First, it is possible to exploit the fundamental theorem
of calculus and integrate under the recovered pi functions (Fenichel et al., 2016b).
However, for a bounded system it is often possible to recover
Vt
s
()
()
, which is help-
ful when
s
is more than one stock. If the intent is to measure changes in wealth as a
proxy for changes in intertemporal welfare, then changes in wealth can reasonably be
redened as
∆∆
=+
()
()
()
()
Vt
Vtss
, and there is a convex combination of
pt
s
()
()
and pts+
()
()
that can make this true (Figure1). These measures reect the trade-
offs society is currently making, when based on the forecastable economic programme,
but say nothing about what society should do. Rather, they provide a mirror that helps
society to confront trade-offs that are often obscured by complex institutional arrange-
ments. That is because realized natural capital asset prices do not directly drive the eco-
nomic programme, but are reected by the prevailing economic programme.
III. Measuring the economic programme
The economic programme, xs
()
, sits at the core of wealth-based sustainability theory
(Dasgupta, 2007; Hamilton and Hartwick, 2014). The economic programme encapsu-
lates the decisions and policy choices that people make with respect to using resources
today or saving them for the future—realized intertemporal exchange.
(i) Conceptualissues
The economic programme may be thought of as a model of behavioural ‘inputs’ into
the production of service ows. In some cases the economic programme may be con-
sidered similar to input factor demands. However, it is not clear that these ‘demands’
satisfy the duality properties of a demand function. The economic programme may
include decisions that do not lead directly to stock changes. Three cases, sheries,
groundwater use, and emissions of stock pollutants, illustrate this point. Units must be
dened for the stocks. The sheries case provides an example where the economic pro-
gramme could be a single composite input called ‘effort’ (Squires, 1987). In this case,
the economic programme is closely related to input demand that results in gross natural
capital depreciation. Asingle stock of groundwater provides a more complicated case
(Fenichel etal., 2016a). In the groundwater case the economic programme may include
a crop choice, eld size choice, and water withdrawal choice. Only water withdrawal is a
direct demand for the resource, but is not separable from the other choices. This means
that a transformation of the economic programme enters the stock dynamic equation
Choices and the value of natural capital 125
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
and the economic programme is broader than factor input demand. The third case of
emission of a stock pollutant is more complicated still. In this case, an incidental bad is
produced to create a liability, along with the intended good. This model of the system
suggests that the economic programme related to the stock pollutant is not an input
demand. However, an alternative model of the system expands the set of ‘services’ to
include waste storage. In this expanded model, there would be an input demand for the
services of the pollutedasset.
Determining what is part of the economic programme and what is part of the set
of stocks is an important choice in analysing the sustainability of a given economic
programme. Implicit in the theory of natural capital asset pricing is the existence of
a behavioural equilibrium (Fenichel et al., 2018). A behavioural equilibrium implies
that people adjust choices within the economic programme quickly compared to the
dynamics of the stocks, and stock dynamics evolve slowly relative to the human deci-
sions captured by the economic programme. Substituting an equilibrating economic
programme provides the expected and average long-run dynamics. The assertion of a
behavioural equilibrium may require explicitly modelling stocks of capital aside from
natural capital. Two prominent types of capital stocks that might merit consideration
alongside natural capital are ‘social or institutional capital’ and reproducible, built, or
man-made capital (which may change as a function of human capital investment).10
There is substantial evidence that institutional change can lag environmental change
(Greif and Laitin, 2004). In such cases, it may be important to explicitly model insti-
tutional dynamics as a function of ‘institutional stocks’ or institutional state varia-
bles, sometimes called ‘social capital’. Yet, dening institution stocks may be fraught
with ill-dened units and measurement problems (Dasgupta, 2007). One could think
of political paradigms or administrative rule sets as determining institutional stocks,
but general models of institutional change remain aspirational and an area of import-
ant research. In reviewing the literature on social capital, Dasgupta (2007) argues that
institutions are the rules for allocating capital—they are the fabric of the economic pro-
gramme. Nevertheless, theory suggests that, like the economic programme, institutional
arrangements have a strong impact on asset values and prices. Libecap (1994) provides
examples where strengthening property rights enhanced productivity in the context
of ranching, farming, mining, and shing, and Besley (1995) establishes foundations
for linking property rights and investment incentives in agriculture. Melesse and Bulte
(2015) argue that land titling programmes have been instrumental to development. Yet,
a direct link between asset prices and strength of property rights is difcult to establish
because when property rights are weak there are seldom markets to observe asset prices.
Grainger and Costello (2014) use tradable permits in sheries, with varying levels of
security to conclude, ‘stronger property rights lead to greater quota asset values’. While
human relationships are an important part of institutional arrangements, Dasgupta
(2007) points out that some features of human networks can be thought of as human
capital.
Capital stock frictions and dynamics associated with reproducible capital may
require explicit modelling and are likely more tractable than modelling stocks of insti-
tutional or social capital. Clark et al. (1979) and Fenichel et al. (in press) provide
10 It may also be important to consider changes in human capital.
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
126
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
theoretical models where the optimal economic programme with respect to natural
capital is a jointly determined economic decision along with investment in capital
stocks of machines and nancial capital, which are traded in imperfect capital markets.
When these additional stocks materially impact the economic programme, then the
ecological-economic system model must be rich enough to include these non-natural
capital stocks. We expect similar effects arise in non-optimizing systems. Fenichel etal.
(2016a) suggest that a connection between the economic programme of groundwater
use and investment in irrigation technology could impact the implied shadow price of
groundwater. Connections between natural and other forms of capital are critical for
sustainability assessment because substitution and complementarity relationships sit at
the core of wealth-based sustainability metrics (Quaas etal., 2013; Fenichel and Zhao,
2015; Drupp, 2018). To date, however, theoretical and empirical modelling in natural
resource economics has focused mostly on natural resource dynamics, holding allo-
cation of other capital stocks xed, with the exception of the macroeconomic growth
literature that incorporates non-renewable resources (reviewed by Groth (2007)).
Allowing other capital stocks to evolve dynamically, as inuenced by the economic
programme, may be important for improved forecasts of natural capital asset dynamics
and prices. This is particularly important because technological innovation is import-
ant in a world with a growing human population and nite stocks of important non-
renewable resources (Groth, 2007). When reproducible capital is traded in markets, it
may provide identifying conditions for the asset value of natural capital, because the
reproducible asset prices will constrain cross-derivatives of the intertemporal welfare
function,
V()
s.
Additional questions include the scope of feedbacks and shocks and the spatial
extent of the ecological-economic system. Yun etal. (2017b) allow for general equilib-
rium effects between modelled capital stocks. This observation, coupled with the inn-
ite horizon nature of the asset pricing approach, makes it somewhat strange to assume
away other long-run changes in the economy, e.g. other input prices.
A challenge is that price dynamics for other inputs or dynamics of other capital
stocks may be non-autonomous with respect to time from the standpoint of the nat-
ural resource system. For example, from the standpoint of most local natural resource
management decisions, climate change is exogenous. To the extent that climate change
degrades or enhances local natural capital and to the extent that economic programmes
anticipate these changes, the effects likely manifest as pure time effects. Another import-
ant source of non-autonomous dynamics is exogenous technological change or tech-
nology spill-overs. Allowing time to enter directly and creating a total factor production
measure is theoretically sound (Arrow et al., 2003), but a practical challenge remains
for recovering asset prices in such a system because time cannot be placed on a bounded
interval. Resolving this challenge is an open question.
In some cases the localized nature of the services provided by natural capital stocks
may ameliorate general equilibrium concerns, but determining the spatial extent at
which to measure the economic programme is challenging. Interactions between seem-
ingly distinct natural capital stocks connected by human behaviours may be an espe-
cially large challenge for natural capital stocks that support recreational services at
distinct recreational sites (Post et al., 2008). The broader landscape may impact the
value and the way people interact with natural resource stocks, as juxtaposition may
Choices and the value of natural capital 127
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
drive complementarity and substitute relationships (Kopits et al., 2007; Abbott and
Klaiber, 2010).
Spatial aggregation raises questions as to the units of the stock and whether
locally sustainable economic programmes can aggregate to nationally sustainable
economic programmes. Implicitly, if all units of a natural capital stock are com-
bined into a single stock for measurement and valuations, then heterogeneities in
the stocks or local economic programmes are eliminated. Potentially heterogeneous
stocks or stocks subject to localized heterogeneous economic programmes appear
as if they are perfect substitutes, when they may not be. One reason for this is that
many forms of natural capital are difcult or impossible to arbitrage in space. So, it
is not possible to appeal to a law of one price for natural capital. Local variation in
stocks matters for asset prices, and local variation in the economic programme can
shift the pricecurve.
The economic programme itself may vary spatially and at sub-national scales for
idiosyncratic reasons that are not directly linked to the natural capital stock in ques-
tion. If the focus is on an iconic ecosystem or region, e.g. the Goulburn–Broken
Catchment in Australia, it is reasonable to focus on the economic programme within
that region (Pearson etal., 2013). Addicott (2017) shows that, even within the seem-
ingly homogeneous system of Kansas irrigated row crop agriculture, the economic pro-
gramme guiding resource use, e.g. groundwater withdrawal, may respond to resource
changes differently because of local institutional variation. He argues that aggregation
can induce a sort of omitted variables bias when local institutions drive the economic
programme. In federated systems that devolve control of resources, the economic pro-
gramme needs to be measured locally.
(ii) Empirical and dataissues
Measuring natural capital asset prices requires empirical measurement of the economic
programme. Measurement requires data and a model for organizing and interpreting
those data. Expanding data availability and modelling techniques are facilitating meas-
uring economic programmes as an input into natural capital asset prices. However,
challenges and necessary modelling decisions persist. With the pace of development,
data availability, and techniques, it may not be long before it will be possible to populate
local wealth accounts with many natural capital asset prices, enabling society to track
the change in a fair number of critical natural capital assets. However, this will not
be the case for all natural capital assets, leading to partial accounts. The assets that will
be the hardest to include in accounts are those that are hardest to dene in quantitative
terms. The lack of data is ceasing to be a reasonable excuse for not coordinating on the
measurement of, and accounting for, changes in natural capital asset values.
Data availability and computational approaches for handling data are developing
rapidly in environmental and ecological science (Willig and Walker, 2016) and econom-
ics (Einav and Levin, 2014). Unfortunately, the ecological and economic data are sel-
dom collected in tandem, leading to spatial and temporal scale mismatches. Afurther
challenge with measuring economic programmes is that for many important stocks of
natural capital, market transactions data are often weak complementary goods, which
presents well-known challenges for estimating demand (Phaneuf and Requate, 2017),
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
128
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
including valuation and behaviour. Nevertheless, time-use data, scanner data, and
social media data are all providing new digital records of human decisions.
Increasing data availability only facilitates measuring the economic programme; the
challenge is to estimate an economic programme across the domain of stocks for which
asset prices are desired. The challenge is greater than recovering rst-order marginal
effects at the current level of stock, as is common in programme evaluation. The goal is
to predict behaviour under foreseeable and likely institutional arrangements. The task
of rst-order importance is dening the appropriate future scenarios, which are likely
best treated as hypotheticals, and identication of material parameters is a secondary
concern (Heckman, 2010). In many cases, the economic programme of today, as a state
varying feedback rule, may be the best predictor of the economic programme of tomor-
row. When the goal is to measure the economic programme under prevailing institu-
tions, then the material parameters to identify are the parameters that explain human
responses to changes in stock, which may or may not be an out-of-sample counterfactual.
In cases where relevant stock levels have been visited or nearly visited within the range
of the historic data, machine learning may be a viable alternative to traditional econo-
metric approaches (Friedman et al., 2001; Varian, 2014). The identication challenge
increases in importance when states far from observed conditions are expected or there is
an effort to forecast alternative economic programmes ex ante and assess natural capital
asset values under novel institutional arrangements. However, in these cases, structural
identifying assumptions sufciently capable of producing observable moments in the
data are likely preferred to relying on strong local identifying assumptions that provide
average (linear) treatment effects and are motivated solely through an appeal to replicat-
ing randomization, rather than predicting behaviour (Manski, 2007; Heckman, 2010).
This is particularly true because ecological-economics systems are notoriously nonlinear
(Barbier etal., 2008; Smith, 2008; Koch etal., 2009). An alternative to relying on struc-
tural assumptions might be greater reliance on stated choice surveys structured under
novel scenarios. Stated choice surveys can elicit likely behaviour under novel states of the
world, including novel institutional arrangements. Stated choice data collection methods
come with their own well-known challenges (Johnston etal., 2017).
IV. Connecting the economic programme to social
realincome
The actions encapsulated in the economic programme generate real income, so the eco-
nomic programme is the result of prevailing incentives, constraints, and expectations.
Aggregate net real income is a money denominated social welfare index that includes
monetized net benets acquired outside of market transactions (Fenichel etal., 2018).11
Fisher (1906) described real income as ‘enjoyable commodities and services’, includ-
ing ‘the supplementary elements which we found lacking under the head of money-
income.... for it [real income] recognizes that money is only an intermediary, and seeks
to discover the real elements for which that money-income stands’. Krutilla (1967)
11 See Weitzman (2016) for a discussion of economic income concepts.
Choices and the value of natural capital 129
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
writes, ‘When the existence of a grand scenic wonder or a unique and fragile ecosystem
is involved, its preservation and continued availability are a signicant part of the real
income of many individuals.’ Theory provides no guidance about the shares of market
and non-market contributions to real income.
The challenge with measuring the real income component associated with service
ows from natural capital (what Fenichel et al. (2018) call ecosystem income) is that
the ecological contributions are unlikely to be additively separable (Boyd and Banzhaf,
2007). However, there is a marginal income or marginal dividend associated with changes
in quantity of the natural capital asset. The focus on the marginal impact on net real
income from a change in asset quantities overcomes the additive separability assump-
tions, but requires the production process embedded in the economic programme.
Capital stocks inuence the economic programme, which in turn affects real income
through three pathways: market production, household production, and direct services
(Fenichel et al., 2018). To date, research connecting the economic programmes and
natural capital dynamics to produce realized natural capital asset prices has focused
primarily on market production, where the real income contributions are ultimately
measured through market exchange (e.g. Fenichel and Abbott, 2014b; Fenichel etal.,
2016a; Bond, 2017; Yun etal., 2017b). However, this does not mean that all the services
provided by natural capital must enter directly into the market. Bond (2017) and Yun
etal. (2017b) capture intermediate, within-ecosystem, production contribution within
the natural capital asset prices, but the asset values are based on nal services.
Decisions captured in the economic programme also direct services ows from nat-
ural capital into real income through household production, production consumed dir-
ectly within the household, but that requires active inputs or actions (Bockstael and
McConnell, 2007). Household production income appears to be what concerned Fisher
(1906). Recreational and amenity services that are often weak complements to market
consumption are chief examples of household production in industrialized countries.
In developing countries, the set of household production service ows may be greater,
particularly in the case of subsistence agriculture, shing, or fuel wood collection.
Direct services seemingly leave no trace via the economic programme. The traditional
approach to valuation of direct services is through stated preference techniques. This
is because there is not a direct behaviour that can be observed or stated that yields the
real income, e.g. enhanced wellbeing from the knowledge of the existence of more of
an iconic species. This is the real income contribution that concerned Krutilla (1967).
The purpose of many attempts to measure direct services is benet–cost analysis with
respect to how society should conserve species or places (e.g. Loomis and White, 1996).
Our goal is different; it is to determine how society is currently valuing these stocks,
and how the valuation changes through time, given society’s observed behaviours. We
start by recognizing that changes in the ability of natural capital to provide such ser-
vices likely occur because of opposing demands, e.g. development pressure within the
habitat of an iconic species. The opposing demands are also subject to an economic
programme. When natural capital provides direct services, there are often restrictions
within these economic programmes for the market services associated with reducing
natural capital that may be tied to the stock of natural capital of interest. For example,
land-use regulations or social pressure may exist because of an iconic species. That
iconic species may provide existence value to people, but the land-use restrictions imply
that society is willing to forgo a development path sans restrictions in order to conserve
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
130
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
the species. This provides the realized exchange made to protect the iconic species. In
these cases, it is important to measure the economic programme associated with the
countervailing use of the capital stock. Then, the marginal value of the stock can be
measured by measuring what the user cost of conservation is to the users who would
draw down the stock. This can provide a lower bound on the implied marginal value,
asset price, of the protected species. There are two reasons the measure might be a
lower bound. First, the behavioural equilibrium captured in the feedback rule of the
economic programme may have been formed with substantial free-riding from the ben-
eciaries given the non-excludability of existence value. Second, in a pure conservation
case, the equilibrium may be a corner solution. For example, when a particular forest
will never be harvested, all that is known is the minimum asset price of standing forest
that prevents harvest.
Decisions about which feature of real income to include are interconnected with nor-
mative decisions about the boundaries of who counts and what feature of the eco-
nomic programme to include when aggregating individual real income into social real
income. This is relatively easy for ex post evaluation of marketed services. The challenge
increases when household production and direct services are included. In the valuation
of environmental services, the extent of the market is often more important than per
capita marginal values (Smith, 1993). Importantly, those who value services provided
by natural capital may not make decisions about the allocation of natural capital or
direct the economic programme. In these cases, or in cases where there are sufcient
heterogeneity and a lack of market-based allocation, the average behaviour captured
by the economic programme will not produce the average contribution to aggregate real
income (Fenichel and Abbott, 2014a).
V. Examples
We review published efforts to price natural capital assets conditional on observed
economic programmes to focus on the measurement of the economic programme.
We exclude efforts to measure natural capital asset price that assume the economic
programme comes from a competitive optimizing market (e.g. Halvorsen and Smith,
1984), or that the system is in equilibrium so that the net present value of a constant
ow of resource rents provides the value of the asset (e.g. Lange, 2004). Examples of
measuring economic programmes in order to measure asset price for natural capital
tend to be data intensive. Requirements to measure economic programmes and natural
capital asset prices are that quantities of stocks have well dened units, actions within
the economic programme have well dened units, and there are available data. These
requirements have led to applications that are seemingly narrow. However, we expect
researchers to apply the approach to increasingly complex systems in the future.
Fenichel et al. (2016a) use a 10-year panel of the universe of Kansas groundwater
withdrawal and crop choice data to estimate a linear selection model (Pfeiffer and Lin,
2014) for water withdrawal as a function of crop choice, stock of groundwater, and
other observables. Crop choice is also a function of stock of groundwater. Fenichel
etal. (2016a) estimate a multinomial logit model for crop choices as a function of water
stock and other observables. They model unirrigated elds as a ‘crop’ choice thereby
Choices and the value of natural capital 131
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
including information about extensive margin planting decisions. The authors imply
that xs
()
is the water withdrawal function, but the economic programme also impli-
citly contains the crop choice response to the waterstock.
Yun etal. (2017b) develop the economic programme needed to measure natural capi-
tal asset prices for sh stocks in the Baltic Sea based on Hutniczak’s (2015) model of
harvester behaviour. The authors develop an effort index as a function of three sh
stocks. The empirical approach uses a production framework, a multi-product distance
function that takes advantage of detailed landing and effort data for all 411 vessels
in the Polish shing eet. The modelling approach yielded vessel specic parameters,
which Yun et al. (2017b) simulate at the individual vessel level to measure harvester
response to changing sh stock and management regimes.
Fenichel and Abbott (2014b) use a seemingly simple economic programme that
denes aggregate effort for the US commercial Gulf of Mexico reef shing eet. They
summarize Zhang’s (2011) empirical estimates into xs ys
()
=
γ
, where
y
and
γ
are
scale and elasticity parameters averaged from Zhang (2011). However, Zhang’s (2011)
underlying count data model was estimated using 126,131 shing trip records and
included gear specic effort. Furthermore, the shing production model in Fenichel
and Abbott (2014b) is an aggregation of the generalized Schaefer function developed
by Zhang and Smith (2011) that makes use of the same dataset as Zhang and accounts
for gear and spatial variation along with other observables. The generalized Schaefer
harvest function implies that the impact of the economic programme on the capital
stock is non-linear, with harvest dened as qs txs
() ()
()
α
, where
q
is a catchability par-
ameter and
α
is an elasticity parameter. Bond (2017) uses a similar economic pro-
gramme, but he conditions the production of sh on an exogenously declining stock
of wetlands. He considers the asset value of wetlands that provide sh nursery habitat
and storm protection. Bond uses an ad hoc economic programme that yields constant
wetland loss for illustrative purposes.
To illustrate the sensitivity of natural capital asset prices to changes in the economic
programme, consider the economic programme used by Fenichel and Abbott (2014b)
to recover the shadow price function for the Gulf of Mexico reef sh stock between
the mid-1990s and 2005. To illustrate how the natural capital asset prices are depend-
ent on the economic programme, consider a change to the elasticity parameter
γ
in
the economic programme.12 Figure2(a) shows a 2 per cent decrease in the behavioural
elasticity relative to the base case. Such a response could occur because of increased
outside opportunities or barriers to entry, slowing the rate shers enter the shery when
stocks rise (or xed cost slowing the rate of exit as the stock falls). Figure2(b) shows
how making shers less responsive to an increase in the stock increases the asset price
at low stocks, but lowers the asset prices at high stocks.
VI. Discussion and conclusion
The theory of sustainability must be a theory of measurement. Measuring the value of
natural capital assets requires empirically measuring changes in stocks and valuation,
12 Parameters and functions for this example are included in the ‘GOM’ example of the capn package
forR.
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
132
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
but it is the measurement of economic programmes that often provides the bottleneck
to reliable natural capital asset prices. Resolving the challenges of measuring economic
programmes requires balancing theory and data and developing sufcient structure to
enable forecasts of economic decisions as the state of the world changes.
Sustainability assessment using the wealth framework will be most useful when mul-
tiple stocks are considered and the economic programme is vector valued. Multiple
stocks create the possibility of substitute and complementarity relationships among
assets (Yun etal., 2017b). Whether or not assets can be substitutes is at the core of the
sustainability question. Helm (2015) and Barbier (2011) review the weak versus strong
sustainability debate. Helm (2015) specically argues for careful consideration of aggre-
gation rules. We argue that state varying shadow prices reect the current implicit aggre-
gation rules because they reect substitute and complementary relationships. As stocks
increase in scarcity the degree of substitutability may weaken. It is even possible that
stocks become complements. In order to measure complementarity or substitute rela-
tionships, natural capital must be valued within the context of a broader system. The
degree of substitutability or complementarity is inuenced by the scope of decisions
people make—the economic programme. Failing to consider vector-valued economic
programmes, when multiple decision margins are possible, seems likely to make a single
resource appear scarcer than it is, overvaluing the asset and, all else equal, making it
appear as if society is less likely to preserve the opportunity set for future generations.
This could lead to fewer members of the current generation having their needs met.
However, the reverse may be true if multiple assets are aggregated into a singleasset.
Beyond the aggregation–disaggregation challenge, is the challenge of coordinating
data collections at appropriate scales. Measuring economic programmes and valuing
natural capital is an inherently interdisciplinary endeavour. Economists and natural
scientists need to continue to expand collaborative efforts to collect data so that envir-
onmental dynamics and the economic programme articulate.
Figure2: Illustration of how changes in the economic programme can affect the shadow price of nat-
ural capital
0
200000
400000
600000
(a)(b)
0 100000000 200000000 300000000
stock
effort
0
5
10
15
0 100000000 200000000 300000000
stock
shadow price
Notes: Panel (a)shows the change in the economic programme. Panel (b) shows the resulting change in stock.
Solid curve is the parameterization from Fenichel and Abbott (2014b). Dashed curve is a 2 per cent decrease
in the elasticity parameter.
Choices and the value of natural capital 133
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
GDP and national accounts have had an outsized impact on policy because they
produce a measurement. Kuznets (1934) argues that, ‘there is considerable value, how-
ever, in checking the unarmed observation of even a careful student by the light of a
quantitative picture’. Kuznets also acknowledged the simplications necessary and data
challenges inherent in measurement.13 It is not sufcient for sustainable development
or sustainability more broadly to be an abstract unachievable goal. Sustainability must
be measurable, and early attempts to measure sustainability suggest it is also achievable
(Arrow etal., 2004; UNU-IHDP and UNEP, 2014; Lange etal., 2018). Measurement
of economic programmes that inform natural capital asset prices is an essential element
in providing actionable sustainability measurements.
Appendix
The present value of real net income can be formally writtenas
Vt
WedW V
t
t
s
ssxs sxss s
()
()
=
()
()
=
()
()
+∇
()
()
−−
()
,,
,
δτ
τδ
1¢ (1)
where
W
is a real net income index,
s
is
S
-length vector of capital stocks,
x
is
X
-
length vector of feedback rules that comprise the economic programme,
δ
is a discount
rate,
s¢
is the transpose of the vector of differential equations dening stock dynamics
conditional on the economic programme, and
s is the gradient operator with respect
to the vector of stocks. The nal equality connects the Fisherian (Fisher, 1906) and
Hicksian (Hicks, 1939) income concepts.
Taking the derivative of Eq (1) with respect to the stock provides the asset price,
which is formally written
pV
Wp
ssp
s
sp
i
s
s
i
i
i
ji
j
i
j
ji
j
i
i
s
sx s
()
==
()
()
+
+
+
≠≠
∑∑
,
()
()
s
s
s
j
i
s
i
i
δ
(sxs (2)
where
ji.
Abbott et al. (2018) show that stochastic process adds endogenous risk
and prudence capital gains terms to the numerator. If the asset is depreciating,
ss
<
0
as Jorgenson (1963) assumes, then depreciation effectively increases the rate of discount.
References
Abbott, J. K., and Klaiber, H. A. (2010), ‘Is All Space Created Equal? Uncovering the Relationship
between Competing Land Uses in Subdivisions’, Ecological Economics, 70, 296–307.
Fenichel, E. P., and Yun, S. D. (2018), ‘Valuing Multiple Natural Capital Stocks Under Correlated
Volatility’, World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economics, Arizona State University,
Yale University, and Mississippi State University, Gothenburg, Sweden.
13 Kuznets (1973) recognized that heavy reliance on the environment or natural resources could make
GDP very misleading.
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
134
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
Addicott, E. T. (2017), ‘Spatial Aggregation of Natural Capital: The Value of Groundwater Across
Management Districts’, School of Forestry and Environmental Studies, New Haven, CT, Yale
University.
Arrow, K. J., Dasgupta, P., and Maler, K.-G. (2003), ‘Evaluating Projects and Assessing Sustainable
Development in Imperfect Economies’, Environmental and Resource Economics, 26, 647–85.
— — Goulder, L., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P., Heal, G., Levin, S., Maler, K.-G., Schneider, S., Starrett,
D., and Walker, B. (2004), ‘Are We Consuming Too Much?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18,
147–72.
Barbier, E. B. (2011), Capitalizing on Nature, New York, Cambridge University Press.
— Koch, E. W., Silliman, B. R., Hacker, S. D., Wolanski, E., Primavera, J., Granek, E. F., Polasky,
S., Aswani, S., Cramer, L. A., Stoms, D. M., Kennedy, C. J., Bael David, Kappel, C. V., Perillo, G.
M.E., and Reed, D. J. (2008), ‘Coastal Ecosystem-based Management with Nonlinear Ecological
Functions and Values’, Science, 319, 321–3.
Besley, T. (1995), ‘Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence from Ghana’,
Journal of Political Economy, 103, 903–37.
Bockstael, N. E., and McConnell, K. J. (2007), Environmental and Resource Valuation with Revealed
Preferences: ATheoretical Guide to Empirical Models, Dordrecht, Springer.
Bond, C. A. (2017), ‘Valuing Coastal Natural Capital in a Bioeconomic Framework’, Water Economics
and Policy, 3(2).
Boyd, J., and Banzhaf, S. (2007), ‘What are Ecosystem Services? The Need for Standardized
Environmental Accounting Units’, Ecological Economics, 63(2–3), 616–26.
Clark, C. W., Clarke, F. H., and Munro, G. R. (1979), ‘The Optimal Exploitation of Renewable
Resource Stocks: Problems of Irreversible Investment’, Econometrica, 47, 25–47.
Dasgupta, P. (2007), Human Well-being and the Natural Environment, New York, Oxford University
Press.
Heal, G. (1974), ‘The Optimal Depletion of Exhaustible Resources’, Review of Economic Studies,
41, 3–28.
— Maler, K.-G. (2000), ‘Net National Product, Wealth, and Social Well-being’, Environmental and
Development Economics, 5, 69–93.
Drupp, M. (2018), ‘Limits to Substitution between Ecosystem Services and Manufactured Goods and
Implications for Social Discounting’, Environmental and Resource Economics, 69, 135–58.
Einav, L., and Levin, J. (2014), ‘Economics in the Age of Big Data’, Science, 346(6210).
Fenichel, E. P., and Abbott, J. K. (2014a), ‘Heterogeneity and the Fragility of the First Best: Putting
the ‘Micro’ in Bioeconomic Models of Recreational Resources’, Resource and Energy Economics,
36, 351–69.
— — (2014b), ‘Natural Capital from Metaphor to Measurement’, Journal of the Association of
Environmental and Resource Economists, 1, 1–27.
Zhao, J. (2015), ‘Sustainability and Substitutability’, Bulletin of Mathematical Biology, 77, 348–67.
— Abbott, J. K., and Yun, S. D. (2018), ‘The Nature of Natural Capital and Ecosystem Income’,
in V. K. Smith, P.Dasgupta, and S. Pattanayak (eds), Handbook of Environmental Economics,
Amsterdam, North Holland.
Adamowicz, W. L. V., Ashton, M. S., and Hall, J. S. (in press), ‘Incentive Systems for Forest-
based Ecosystem Services with Missing Financial Service Markets’, Journal of the Association of
Environmental and Resource Economists.
Abbott, J. K., Bayham, J., Boone, W., Haacker, E. M.K., and Pfeiffer, L. (2016a), ‘Measuring the
Value of Groundwater and Other Forms of Natural Capital’, Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences, 113, 2382–7.
Levin, S., McCay, B. J., St Martin, K., Abbott, J. K., and Pinsky, M. (2016b), ‘Wealth Reallocation
and Sustainability under Climate Change’, Nature Climate Change, 6, 237–44.
Fisher, I. (1906), The Nature of Capital and Income, Norwood, MA, Norwood Press.
Fleurbaey, M., and Blanchet, D. (2013), Beyond GDP: Measuring Welfare and Assessing Sustainability,
New York, Oxford University Press.
Freeman, A. M. I. (2003), The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and
Methods, 2nd edn, Washington, DC, Resources For the Future.
Choices and the value of natural capital 135
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
Friedman, J., Hastie, T., and Tibshirani, R. (2001), The Elements of Statistical Learning, Berlin,
Springer.
Grainger, C. A., and Costello, C. J. (2014), ‘Capitalizing Property Rights Insecurity in Natural Resource
Assets’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 67(2), 224–40.
Greif, A., and Laitin, D. D. (2004), ‘A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change’, American Political
Science Review, 98, 633–52.
Groth, C. (2007), ‘A New-growth Perspective on Non-renewable Resources’, in L.Bretschger and S.
Smulders (eds), Sustainable Resource Use and Economic Dynamics, Dordrecht, Springer.
Halvorsen, R., and Smith, T. R. (1984), ‘On Measuring Natural Resource Scarcity’, Journal of Political
Economy, 92, 954–64.
Hamilton, K., and Clemens, M. (1999), ‘Genuine Savings Rates in Developing Countries’, The World
Bank Economic Review, 13, 333–56.
Hartwick, J. M. (2014), ‘Wealth and Sustainability’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(1),
170–87.
— Ruta, G. (2009), ‘Wealth Accounting, Exhaustible Resources and Social Welfare’, Environmental
and Resource Economics, 43, 53–64.
Hanley, N., Dupuy, L., and McLaughlin, E. (2015), ‘Genuine Savings and Sustainability’, Journal of
Economic Surveys, 29, 779–806.
Harberger, A. C. (1971), ‘Three Basic Postulates for Applied Welfare Economics: An Interpretive
Essay’, Journal of Economic Literature, 9, 785–97.
Heckman, J. J. (2010), ‘Building Bridges between Structural and Program Evaluation Approaches to
Evaluating Policy’, Journal of Economic Literature, 48, 356–98.
Helm, D. (2015), Natural Capital: Valuing the Planet, New Haven, CT, Yale University Press.
Hicks, J. R. (1939), Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic
Theory, New York, Oxford University Press.
Hutniczak, B. (2015), ‘Modeling Heterogeneous Fleet in an Ecosystem Based Management Context’,
Ecological Economics, 120, 203–14.
Johnston, R. J., Boyle, K. J., Adamowicz, W. V.L., Bennett, J., Brouwer, R., Cameron, T. A., Hanemann,
W. M., Hanley, N., Ryan, M., Scarpa, R., Tourangeau, R., and Vossler, C. A. (2017), ‘Contemporary
Guidance for Stated Preference Studies’, Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists, 4, 319–405.
Jorgenson, D. W. (1963), ‘Capital Theory and Investment Behavior’, American Economic Review, 53,
247–59.
Koch, E. W., Barbier, E. B., Silliman, B. R., Reed, D. J., Perillo, G. M., Hacker, S. D., Granek, E.
F., Primavera, J. H., Muthiga, N., Polasky, S., Halpern, B. S., Kennedy, C. J., Kappel, C., and
Wolanski, E. (2009), ‘Non-linearity in Ecosystem Services: Temporal and Spatial Variability in
Coastal Protection’, Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 7, 29–37.
Kopits, E., McConnell, V., and Walls, M. (2007), ‘The Trade-off between Private Lots and Public Open
Space in Subdivisions at the Urban–Rural Fringe’, Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89, 1191–7.
Krutilla, J. V. (1967), ‘Conservation Reconsidered’, American Economic Review, 57, 777–86.
Kuznets, S. (1934), National Income. 1929–1932, National Bureau of Economic Research.
— (1973), ‘Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reections’, American Economic Review, 63,
247–58.
Lange, G.-M. (2004), ‘Wealth, Natural Capital, and Sustainable Development: Contrasting Examples
from Botswana and Namibia’, Environmental and Resource Economics, 29, 257–83.
— Wondon, Q., and Carey, K. (2018), The Changing Wealth of Nations 2018: Building a Sustainable
Future, Washington, DC, World Bank.
Libecap, G. D. (1994), Contracting for Property Rights, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Loomis, J. B., and White, D. S. (1996), ‘Economic Benets of Rare and Endangered Species: Summary
and Meta-analysis’, Ecological Economics, 18, 197–206.
Maler, K.-G. (1991), ‘National Accounts and Environmental Resources’, Environmental and Resource
Economics, 1, 1–15.
Aniyar, S., and Jansson, A. (2008), ‘Accounting for Ecoystem Services as a Way to Understand the
Requirements for Sustainable Development’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences,
105, 9501–6.
Eli P. Fenichel and Yukiko Hashida
136
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
Manski, C. F. (2007), Identication for Prediction and Decision, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Matson, P., Clark, W. C., and Andersson, K. (2016), Pursuing Sustainability: AGuide to the Science and
Practice, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.
Melesse, M. B., and Bulte, E. (2015), ‘Does Land Registration and Certication Boost Farm
Productivity? Evidence from Ethiopia’, Agricultural Economics, 46, 757–68.
Obst, C., and Vardon, M. (2014), ‘Recording Environmental Assets in the National Accounts’, Oxford
Review of Economic Policy, 30(1), 126–44.
Pearson, L. J., Biggs, R., Harris, M., and Walker, B. (2013), ‘Measuring Sustainable Development: The
Promise and Difculties of Implementing Inclusive Wealth in the Goulburn–Broken Catchment,
Australia’, Sustainability: Science, Practice, and Policy, 9, 16–27.
Pfeiffer, L., and Lin, C.-Y. C. (2014), ‘The Effects of Energy Prices on Agricultural Groundwater
Extraction from the High Plains Aquifer’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96,
1349–62.
Phaneuf, D. J., and Requate, T. (2017), A Course in Environmental Economics Theory, Policy, and
Practice, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Post, J. R., Persson, L., Parkinson, E. A., and van Kooten, T. (2008), ‘Angler Numerical Response
across Landscapes and the Collapse of Freshwater Fisheries’, Ecological Applications, 18, 1038–49.
Quaas, M. F., van Soest, D., and Baumgartner, S. (2013), ‘Complementarity, Impatience, and the
Resilience of Natural-resource-dependent Economies’, Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 66, 15–32.
Roosevelt, T. (1910), ‘Conservation: Speech at Denver before the Colorado Live Stock Association’, in
A. H. Lewis (ed.), Compilation of the Messages and Speeches of Theodore Roosevelt.
Smith, M. D. (2008), ‘Bioeconometrics: Empirical Modeling of Bioeconomic Systems’, Marine
Resource Economics, 23, 1–23.
Smith, V. K. (1993), ‘Nonmarket Valuation of Environmental Resources: An Interpretive Appraisal’,
Land Economics, 69, 1–26.
Smulders, S. (2012), ‘An Arrow in the Achilles’ Heel of Sustainability and Wealth Accounting’,
Environmental and Development Economics, 17, 368–72.
Solow, R. (1993), ‘An Almost Practical Step towards Sustainability’, Resource Policy, 19, 162–72.
Squires, D. (1987), ‘Fishing Effort: Its Testing, Specication, and Internal Structure in Fisheries
Economics and Management’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 14, 268–82.
UNU-IHDP and UNEP (2014), Inclusive Wealth Report 2014, Measuring Progress toward Sustainability,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Varian, H. R. (2014), ‘Big Data: New Tricks for Econometrics’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28,
3–28.
Weitzman, M. L. (2016), ‘Some Theoretical Connections among Wealth, Income, Sustainability, and
Accounting’, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 22060.
Willig, M. R., and Walker, L. R. (2016), Long-term Ecological Research: Changing the Nature of
Scientists, New York, Oxford University Press.
World Bank (2011), The Changing Wealth of Nations, Washington, DC, World Bank.
World Commission on Environment and Development (1987), Our Common Future, New York,
Oxford University Press.
Yun, S. D., Fenichel, E. P., and Abbott, J. K. (2017a), ‘capn: Capital Asset Pricing for Nature’, available
at https://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/capn/index.html.
Hutniczak, B., Abbott, J. K., and Fenichel, E. P. (2017b), ‘Ecosystem Based Management and the
Wealth of Ecosystems’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 114, 6539–44.
Zhang, J. (2011), ‘Behavioral Response to Stock Abundance in Exploiting Common-pool Resources’,
The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 11, article 52.
Smith, M. D. (2011), ‘Estimation of a Generalized Fishery Model: ATwo-stage Approach’, Review
of Economics and Statistics, 93, 690–9.
Choices and the value of natural capital 137
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article-abstract/35/1/120/5267892 by Yale University user on 08 January 2019
... Furthermore, natural capital approaches utilize many natural capital data, statistics, and indicators (GGKP, 2020;UNSD, 2021). For example, measures of biophysical flows and economic valuation of ecosystem services (Guerry et al., 2015) and natural assets (Fenichel & Hashida, 2019) and production of environmental statistics (United Nations Statistical Division, 2017). Finally, international indicator initiatives on sustainable development (e.g., sustainable development goals (United Nations, 2021b)), national wealth (e.g., World Bank Changing Wealth of Nations; Lange, 2019), and green growth (e.g., Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Green Growth Indicators; OECD, 2017) catalyze the production of natural capital-relevant indicators. ...
Article
Full-text available
The natural capital indicator framework (NCIF) offers an entry‐level approach to natural capital reporting using existing data sources and indicators. Here, we test the NCIF for the first time in the megadiverse Pantanal biome in Brazil. We compile publicly available indicators on the cattle, soy, fishing, and nature‐based tourism industries alongside indicators on the state of the biome and its ecosystem services. We show that the NCIF is quick to implement using existing environmental and socioeconomic indicators produced by public and NGO statistics communities. However, we identify significant gaps in indicators on the condition and economic value of the biome, the human investment required to derive benefits from the biome, emissions produced by the industries that exploit the biome, and the ecosystem services that maintain the functioning of the biome, such as nutrient cycling and biodiversity. Existing initiatives in Brazil could fill natural capital reporting gaps, including Brazil's experimental natural capital accounts. The NCIF provides a structured approach to highlight gaps in natural capital reporting and guide decision‐makers to prioritize investment in filling data and reporting gaps. Systematic, transnational monitoring must fill gaps in natural capital data to inform decision‐making in the megadiverse Pantanal biome.
... Therefore, the question arises as to whether traditional measures besides being able to improve water classification can deliver benefits to society. Natural capital accounts have the potential to contribute to the answer to this question, as the obtained economic value incorporates information about the structure of the institutional setting, the intensity of ecosystem services harvesting, and the extent and condition of natural resources (Mullin et al., 2018;Fenichel and Hashida, 2019). They can provide information on trends across time and allow for comparability among river basins, measure the effects of policy interventions on water resources, and give an indication of the cost-efficiency of policies aiming to improve the health of the environment (Russi and Brick, 2013 This study involved the development of accounts of the asset value of two ecosystem services in two areas in Europe that are managed under the Water Framework Directive. ...
... This means care must be taken not to use hypothetical changes in management to compute potential changes in value. It is unreasonable to assume 'optimal' management that is inconsistent with prevailing institutions (Fenichel and Hashida 2019). There is a need to map into actual situations existing valuation methods that focus on potential changes, and to develop benefitstransfer libraries (Boyle et al. 2010). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
Realising the goal of the High Level Panel for a Sustainable Ocean Economy (Ocean Panel) to catalyse the transition to a sustainable ocean economy depends on coordinating and managing humanity’s relationship with the ocean and the broader environment. This task requires organising information that currently is often disorganised, spread across multiple government agencies or in a few cases not yet available. National ocean accounts would provide countries with the information needed to guide ambitious and broad- based plans to develop ocean economies and to capitalise on marine opportunities (European Union Directorate-General of Maritime Affairs and Fisheries and Joint Research Centre 2018; Economist Intelligence Unit 2015), while protecting the ocean for generations to come in accordance with the Sustainable Development Goals, most notably SDG 14, ‘Life below Water’. The ‘blue-ing’ of the ocean economy—or making the ocean economy sustainable—requires ensuring that the ocean continues to provide at least the current levels of opportunity; ‘measuring the ocean economy gives a country a first-order understanding of the economic importance of the seas’ (Economist Intelligence Unit 2015). The old adage goes that ‘what gets measured, gets managed’, or more accurately, that ‘if you cannot measure it, you cannot improve it’. Sound decision- making requires organised information.
... Unlike other forms of wealth, natural resources are harder and more costly to restore. Crucially, climate change can also reallocate natural capital within the society in unpredictable ways; such a reallocation may turn out to be disruptive from the perspective of distributive justice, particularly in terms of maintaining an opportunity set for future generations (Fenichel and Hashida, 2019). Therefore, research into the effects of rising temperature and climate change on inclusive wealth calls for more interdisciplinary research methods that combine biophysical and social measurements. ...
Article
We shed new light on the macroeconomic and financial effects of rising temperatures. In the data, a shock to global temperature dampens research and development (R&D) expenditure growth. This novel empirical evidence is rationalized within a stochastic endogenous growth model. In the model, temperature shocks undermine economic growth via a drop in R&D expenditure. We examine three theoretical channels of the negative R&D expenditure effect of rising temperatures: the patent obsolescence channel, the labor productivity channel, and the capital quality channel. Temperature risk generates welfare costs of 93.14% of lifetime utility in this benchmark model. Moreover, the government can offset these welfare costs by subsidizing investment with 7.04% or R&D expenditure with 3.81% of total public spending, respectively. Alternatively, it can levy a lump-sum tax on households which finances 6.90% of total public spending, reduce corporate taxes by 3.62 percentage points, or increase labor taxes by 2.80 percentage points.
... Therefore, the question arises as to whether traditional measures besides being able to improve water classification can deliver benefits to society. Natural capital accounts have the potential to contribute to the answering of this question, as the obtained economic value incorporates information about the structure of the institutional setting, the intensity of ecosystem services harvesting, and the extent and condition of natural resources [157,158]. They can provide information on trends across time and allow for comparability among river basins, measure effects of policy interventions on water resources, and give an indication of the cost-efficiency of policies aiming to improve the health of the environment [159]. ...
Article
Full-text available
In the European Union, the Water Framework Directive provides a roadmap for achieving good water status and sustainable water usage, and a framework for the information, types of analysis, and interventions required by the Member States. Lack of previous knowledge in, and understanding of, interdisciplinary approaches across European countries has led to applications of corrective measures that have yielded less than favourable results. The natural capital paradigm, the assessment and monitoring of the value of natural capital, has the potential to convey information on the use of water resources and improve the connection between implemented measures and changes in the status of the resources, thus enhancing the effectiveness of policy interventions. In this paper, we present the natural capital accounting methodology, adapted to the requirements of the Directive, and demonstrate its application in two European catchments. Using economic methods, the asset value of two ecosystem services was estimated and associated with changes in water status due to policy instruments. Findings demonstrate that the asset value of water for residential consumption and recreational purposes fluctuates from year to year, influenced by current and future uses. Consequently, managing authorities should consider both current and emerging pressures when designing interventions to manage water resource sustainably.
Article
Natural capital accounting provides a systematic framework through which to quantify the benefits of natural assets. National-scale applications have demonstrated the feasibility of developing such accounts and their value as a tool to support environmental policy and management decisions. Building on that success, there have been increasing calls for sub-national organisations (for example, protected area authorities and water companies) to develop their own natural capital accounts. As we document in this paper, recent efforts by local organisations in the UK to produce such accounts have tended to rely on a set of 'standard practice' methods, many borrowed directly from national natural capital accounting exercises. In this paper, we review those methods and apply them in producing natural capital accounts for two UK National Parks. Working with the National Park Authorities, we critically assess the usefulness of those accounts to inform local land management. On account of data gaps and significant sensitivity to methodological assumptions, our research shows that these local accounts are considered of limited practical use for land management decision making at a local scale. Through specific illustrative examples, we show that natural capital accounts for local decision-making can be improved through: the inclusion of fit-for-purpose data and valuation methods, the consideration of uncertainties, and the incorporation of ecological information and spatial aspects. We also highlight the need for the development of both standardised guidelines and readily-available tools to quantify and value ecosystem services.
Article
Full-text available
Trong những năm gần đây, khu vực ven biển Hà Tĩnh thường xuyên chịu ảnh hưởng mạnh từ lũ lụt, đặc biệt đợt mưa lũ lịch sử năm 2020 gây ra thiệt hại lớn về gười và tài sản. Nghiên cứu đặt mục tiêu đánh giá tính dễ bị tổn thương lũ lụt nhằm giảm nhẹ thiệt hại tới đời sống dân cư ven biển. Tính dễ bị tổn thương được đánh giá theo khung các yếu tố mức độ phơi bày, mức độ nhạy cảm và khả năng chống chịu với sự tham gia của 14 chỉ số đánh giá. Trên cơ sở các dữ liệu thu thập, đặc biệt từ ảnh vệ tinh, điều tra xã hội học, nghiên cứu cho thấy phần lớn các xã của các huyện Kỳ Anh (14/20 xã), Cẩm Xuyên (17/27 xã) và Lộc Hà (10/13 xã) có mức độ tổn thương với lũ lụt ở mức cao và rất cao. Kết quả đánh giá tính dễ bị tổn thương cụ thể đến cấp xã. Đồng thời, với cách thức đánh giá mang tính tổng thể, bài báo cung cấp cơ sở cho các cấp chính quyền xây dựng kịch bản ứng phó với lũ lụt kết hợp cơ sở khoa học và thực tiễn hiệu quả.
Article
Concerns for fossil fuel price volatility, environmental pollution and energy inefficiency drive the formulation of energy policies aimed at attaining energy security. We use a theoretical framework which integrates key elements of energy security into the context of natural capital theory to investigate the causal relationship between Nasdaq clean energy stock price and a range of variables including oil price, natural gas prices, carbon price and energy efficiency. Our autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) results reveal that clean energy stock price is jointly and individually explained by the variables representing some elements of energy security. Carbon price and energy efficiency emerged as the most important elements of energy security driving the ongoing transition from conventional to clean energy sources. Consequently, governments should take environmental sustainability and energy efficiency very seriously when formulating energy policies in the pursuit of energy security and the way they stimulate substitutions between clean energy sources and hydrocarbons. ARTICLE HISTORY
Article
Full-text available
Valuing natural assets is important for tracking the performance of management, for sustainability assessments based on wealth accounting, for environmental income and product accounting, and for benefit–cost analysis of specific projects. Developments in valuing natural capital have focused on implicit intertemporal exchange revealed by resource management behavior that maps the state of the natural system in a continuous fashion onto a management response. However, the management of many real assets, including many natural assets, is best described as inaction with punctuated adjustment. We develop natural asset valuation theory and approximation methods for such cases. We illustrate the theory and methods for the case of forests managed through even‐aged management, that is, clear cuts. These forests may provide “passive” or “inaction” value while standing and timber benefits at harvest. We find that the passive flow value of the forests can be positive and depend on site class, and that wealth held in private industrial Oregon Douglas‐fir forests increased over the first decade of the twenty‐first century.
Article
Full-text available
The Long-Term Ecological Research (LTER) Program is, in a sense, an experiment to transform the nature of science, and represents one of the most effective mechanisms for catalyzing comprehensive site-based research that is collaborative, multidisciplinary, and long-term in nature. The scientific contributions of the Program are prodigious, but the broader impacts of participation have not been examined in a formal way. This book captures the consequences of participation in the Program on the perspectives, attitudes, and practices of environmental scientists. The edited volume comprises three sections. The first section includes two chapters that provide an overview of the history, goals, mission, and inner workings of the LTER network of sites. The second section comprises three dozen retrospective essays by scientists, data managers or educators who represent a broad spectrum of LTER sites from deserts to tropical forests and from arctic to marine ecosystems. Each essay addresses the same series of probing questions to uncover the extent to which participation has affected the ways that scientists conduct research, educate students, or provide outreach to the public. The final section encompasses 5 chapters, whose authors are biophysical scientists, historians, behavioral scientists, or social scientists. This section analyzes, integrates, or synthesizes the content of the previous chapters from multiple perspectives and uncovers emergent themes and future directions.
Article
Full-text available
Significance Ecosystems store vast quantities of wealth, but difficulties measuring wealth held in ecosystems prevent its inclusion in accounting systems. Ecosystem-based management endeavors to manage ecosystems holistically. However, ecosystem-based management lacks headline indicators to evaluate performance. We unify the inclusive wealth and ecosystem-based management paradigms, allowing apples-to-apples comparisons between the wealth of the ecosystem and other forms of wealth, while providing a headline performance index for evaluating the performance of ecosystem-based management. We project that the Baltic Sea fishery ecosystem yields increasing stores of wealth over the next 50 y under the ecosystem-based management-inspired multispecies maximum sustainable yield management beginning in 2017, whereas the previous single-species management generally results in declining wealth.
Article
Full-text available
This paper examines implications of limits to substitution for estimating substitutability between ecosystem services and manufactured goods and for social discounting. Based on a model that accounts for a subsistence requirement in the consumption of ecosystem services, we provide empirical evidence on substitution elasticities. We find an initial mean elasticity of substitution of two, which declines over time towards complementarity. We subsequently extend the theory of dual discounting by introducing a subsistence requirement. The relative price of ecosystem services is non-constant and grows without bound as the consumption of ecosystem services declines towards the subsistence level. An application suggests that the initial discount rate for ecosystem services is more than a percentage-point lower as compared to manufactured goods. This difference increases by a further half percentage-point over a 300-year time horizon. The results underscore the importance of considering limited substitutability in long-term public project appraisal.
Chapter
From the outside looking in, scientists are often characterized as old men in white laboratory coats, working in splendid isolation, usually within the confines of rather sterile looking laboratories. Of course, this image was never quite accurate for ecologists, who abandoned white laboratory coats for more field-appropriate boots and khaki pants, but who nonetheless typically worked alone or with the benefit of a faithful field assistant (Figure 1.1a). The late 1900s was a time of rapid change in the way in which ecological research was conducted, in part because of opportunities for support from governmental agencies. Especially critical in effecting these changes was grant support that would allow scientists to comprehensively investigate the intricate and complex ecological interactions between organisms and their environment from a long-term and site-based perspective. Such efforts often involved large and diverse groups of scientists representing multiple disciplinary perspectives and investigative approaches (Figure 1.1b). The US Long-Term Ecological Research (LTER) program, with support from the National Science Foundation (NSF), was one of the first governmental programs to catalyze long-term, site-based, multidisciplinary, and collaborative research. The scientific research arising from such support has been broad and deep, resulting in thousands of publications. The research insights have been integrated into a number of synthetic books, each dedicated to long-term research at a particular site in the LTER program (Knapp et al. 1998; Bowman and Seastedt 2001; Greenland, Goodin, and Smith 2003; Schachak et al. 2005; Magnuson, Kratz, and Henson 2005; Foster and Aber 2006; Chapin et al. 2006; Havstad, Huenneke, and Schlesinger 2006; Redman and Foster 2008; Lauenroth and Burke 2008; Brokaw et al. 2012). In contrast, the effects of the LTER program’s many innovations on the participating scientists have not been explored in a comprehensive or systematic fashion. This book provides a window into how scientists have changed as a consequence of participation in the LTER program. The LTER network of sites, begun in 1980, effectively implemented the first effort by the NSF to systematically fund long-term, site-based environmental research.
Article
This article proposes contemporary best-practice recommendations for stated preference (SP) studies used to inform decision making, grounded in the accumulated body of peer-reviewed literature. These recommendations consider the use of SP methods to estimate both use and non-use (passive-use) values, and cover the broad SP domain, including contingent valuation and discrete choice experiments. We focus on applications to public goods in the context of the environment and human health but also consider ways in which the proposed recommendations might apply to other common areas of application. The recommendations recognize that SP results may be used and reused (benefit transfers) by governmental agencies and nongovernmental organizations, and that all such applications must be considered. The intended result is a set of guidelines for SP studies that is more comprehensive than that of the original National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) Blue Ribbon Panel on contingent valuation, is more germane to contemporary applications, and reflects the two decades of research since that time. We also distinguish between practices for which accumulated research is sufficient to support recommendations and those for which greater uncertainty remains. The goal of this article is to raise the quality of SP studies used to support decision making and promote research that will further enhance the practice of these studies worldwide.
Article
Payments for ecosystem services (PES) is a popular paradigm to address underprovision of ecosystem services in developing economies. Potential PES recipients often experience other market imperfections, which can influence PES uptake and environmental performance. These include poorly functioning financial services markets. We develop a model of nonindustrial timber production with poorly functioning financial service markets and PES. We calibrate the model to the Panama Canal Watershed and solve the dynamic allocation decision using dynamic programming. The results of our model show that improving financial services markets, including improved access to borrowing and savings, can reduce the costs of acquiring ecosystem services. Nonenvironmental market frictions can influence the incentive properties of PES payment vehicles. Our model predicts that wealthier individuals are likely to provide the desired land uses at least cost if incentivized land uses involve production. In these cases cost-effective PES is unlikely to advance development objectives. © 2019 by The Association of Environmental and Resource Economists.
Book
Environmental and Resource Valuation with Revealed Preferences: A Theoretical Guide to Empirical Models provides a systematic review of those economic approaches for valuing the environment and natural resources that use information on what people do, not what they say. The authors have worked on models of revealed preferences for valuing environmental and natural resources for several decades and authored some of the seminal papers in the field. The book is a natural outcome of their conceptual contributions and their many years of experience in empirical policy research, natural resource damage litigation and teaching on the topic. The chief purpose of Environmental and Resource Valuation with Revealed Preferences is to collect in one place current thought on the various revealed preference approaches to environmental valuation and to subject these approaches to consistent theoretical critique. The unique features of Environmental and Resource Valuation with Revealed Preferences include: • a development of the theory from the simplest ideas of economic preferences, based on microeconomics and welfare theory, extended to show how these ideas can be used empirically; • coherent theoretical and practical treatment of the approaches developed to value the environment and public goods, from travel cost to wage and housing hedonics to averting behavior and cost of illness; • a candid review of the major conceptual challenges and an exploration of neglected issues in the literature; • connections between theory and empirical research for real world problems. Environmental Valuation with Revealed Preferences is an exceptionally useful tool for economists and graduate students working in the area of environmental and resource economics at universities, research institutes, government agencies, non-governmental environmental organizations, multi-lateral banks.
Article
The wetlands of the Gulf Coast region of the United States are under pressure from relative sea level rise and subsidence pressures that threaten to alter fishery breeding grounds and increase expected damage from stochastic storm events, among other issues. Barrier islands, marshes, and swamps are thus forms of natural capital that serve an intermediate role in supporting fishery stocks, as well as a final demand role in providing direct protection to infrastructure. In order to make good policy choices related to land loss, the values associated with these interacting stocks must be estimated. In this paper, the numerical approach of Fenichel and Abbott (2014) is extended as a proof of concept in order to illustrate the valuation of fish and wetlands stocks, allowing for the recovery of final demand and intermediate service values, and taking into account the scarcity value of each resource. Examples of policies which, when implemented, will change the subsequent valuation of each resource are also presented.
Conference Paper
We are interested in three related questions: ( 1) How should accounting prices be estimated? ( 2) How should we evaluate policy change in an imperfect economy? ( 3) How can we check whether intergenerational well-being will be sustained along a projected economic programme? We do not presume that the economy is convex, nor do we assume that the government optimizes on behalf of its citizens. We show that the same set of accounting prices should be used both for policy evaluation and for assessing whether or not intergenerational welfare along a given economic path will be sustained. We also show that a comprehensive measure of wealth, computed in terms of the accounting prices, can be used as an index for problems ( 2) and ( 3) above. The remainder of the paper is concerned with rules for estimating the accounting prices of several specific environmental natural resources, transacted in a few well known economic institutions.