ArticlePDF Available

Pre-positioning strategies for relief supplies in a relief supply chain

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

It is vital to pre-position a certain amount of relief supplies at pre-disaster. But governments are often confronted with a dilemma of coordinating inventory cost and stock-out cost in pre-positioning relief supplies. Pre-positioning strategies for relief supplies depend on the natural characteristic of relief supplies and the most urgent needs at post-disaster. Therefore, we classify relief supplies by their natural characteristic and priority, and introduce an option contract into relief supplies pre-positioning system which consists of a single government and an agreement enterprise. Specially, a consumable and relatively urgent relief supplies pre-positioning (C-RUP) model and a non-consumable and urgent relief supplies pre-positioning (NC-UP) model are established. The optimal decisions of the government and the enterprise are derived, respectively. The relief supply chain coordination is achieved with the option contract. Under channel coordination, the two models can not only improve the government’s emergency ability and support capacity, but also reduce the government’s inventory risk when compared to the government single pre-positioning model. Moreover, we give out the conditions that the two sides can reach a win-win situation. Lastly, we propose important managerial insights for pre-positioning strategies related to different types of relief supplies.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=tjor20
Journal of the Operational Research Society
ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/tjor20
Pre-positioning strategies for relief supplies in a
relief supply chain
Yang Liu, Jun Tian & Gengzhong Feng
To cite this article: Yang Liu, Jun Tian & Gengzhong Feng (2022) Pre-positioning strategies
for relief supplies in a relief supply chain, Journal of the Operational Research Society, 73:7,
1457-1473, DOI: 10.1080/01605682.2021.1920343
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2021.1920343
Published online: 26 Jun 2021.
Submit your article to this journal
Article views: 336
View related articles
View Crossmark data
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Pre-positioning strategies for relief supplies in a relief supply chain
Yang Liu, Jun Tian and Gengzhong Feng
School of Management, Xian Jiaotong University, Xian, China
ABSTRACT
It is vital to pre-position a certain amount of relief supplies at pre-disaster. But governments
are often confronted with a dilemma of coordinating inventory cost and stock-out cost in
pre-positioning relief supplies. Pre-positioning strategies for relief supplies depend on the
natural characteristic of relief supplies and the most urgent needs at post-disaster.
Therefore, we classify relief supplies by their natural characteristic and priority, and introduce
an option contract into relief supplies pre-positioning system which consists of a single gov-
ernment and an agreement enterprise. Specially, a consumable and relatively urgent relief
supplies pre-positioning (C-RUP) model and a non-consumable and urgent relief supplies
pre-positioning (NC-UP) model are established. The optimal decisions of the government
and the enterprise are derived, respectively. The relief supply chain coordination is achieved
with the option contract. Under channel coordination, the two models can not only improve
the governments emergency ability and support capacity, but also reduce the governments
inventory risk when compared to the government single pre-positioning model. Moreover,
we give out the conditions that the two sides can reach a win-win situation. Lastly, we pro-
pose important managerial insights for pre-positioning strategies related to different types
of relief supplies.
ARTICLE HISTORY
Received 23 September 2019
Accepted 14 April 2021
KEYWORDS
Game theory; government;
inventory; purchasing;
supply chain
1. Introduction
All corners of the whole world are frequently
affected by sudden disaster events such as earth-
quakes, hurricanes and tsunamis and so forth, which
pose disastrous threats and destructions to peoples
health, life and property security. As described in
the 2018 natural disasters report launched by the
Centre for Research on the Epidemiology of
Disasters, there were 315 natural disaster events
recorded with 11,804 deaths, over 68 million people
affected, and 131.7 billion dollars in economic losses
across the whole world. Disaster management as a
hedge against disaster events has drawn great public
attention over the past several decades, including
four sequential stages: mitigation, preparedness,
response and recovery (Altay & Green, 2006).
National governments are the primary relief organi-
zations responsible for pre-disaster mitigation and
preparedness and post-disaster responsiveness and
recovery. Taking China, for example, the Chinese
government has built 24 central warehouses and
more than 1000 local warehouses to reserve a cer-
tain amount of relief supplies before a disaster
strikes. But governments are often confronted with
a dilemma with respect to how many relief supplies
should be pre-positioned (Chakravarty, 2014;Hu
et al., 2019; Liang et al., 2012). In practice, pre-posi-
tioning adequate relief supplies can not only shorten
response time for disaster relief, but also signifi-
cantly improve the efficiency of relief activities
(Galindo & Batta, 2013; Rawls & Turnquist, 2012).
If no disaster occurs before the pre-positioned relief
supplies expire, governments will entail too much
inventory risk. On the other hand, stock-out risk
will occur if the pre-positioned relief supplies can-
not meet the sudden-onset demand. In view of this,
this paper is to present rational strategies of coordi-
nating inventory cost and stock-out cost in pre-posi-
tioning relief supplies.
From literature review, we find that many schol-
ars have proposed various methods to solve the pre-
positioning problem of relief supplies (see Sec. 2).
However, some research shortcomings still exist. In
practice, governments usually buy some kinds of
relief supplies and pre-position them in a warehouse
before a disaster strikes, while retailers in a com-
mercial supply chain usually apply zero inventory
management. But few studies have examined the
influences of regular relief supplies pre-positioned
by governments at pre-disaster, which is the start of
our paper. In addition to pre-position relief supplies
at pre-disaster, governments also can buy the
required relief supplies from agreement enterprises
(Ding & Huang, 2012; Nikkhoo et al., 2018; Wang
et al., 2015) or/and the spot market (Hu et al.,
2019) and receive in-kind donations (Chen et al.,
2017,2018; Holgu
ın-Veras et al., 2014). However,
CONTACT Yang Liu fanxipingly@163.com Xian Jiaotong University, Xianning West Road 28, Beilin, Xian, Shaanxi, China.
ßOperational Research Society 2021
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY
2022, VOL. 73, NO. 7, 14571473
https://doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2021.1920343
most existing studies only focus on the procurement
of relief supplies from the enterprises or/and spot
market at post-disaster, and ignore the importance
of in-kind donations which are donated by humani-
tarian organizations (HOs) or individuals. This is
mainly because this spontaneous flow of relief sup-
plies may bring much-needed relief and major com-
plications to the operations (Holgu
ın-Veras et al.,
2014). Different from previous research, this paper
considers that if the pre-positioned relief supplies
cannot satisfy the sudden-onset demand at post-dis-
aster, governments can not only buy the needed
relief supplies from the agreement enterprise and
spot market, but also receive in-kind donations. For
example, after the outbreak of the 2008 Wenchuan
earthquake, Pakistan donated more than 22 thou-
sand tents to disaster-affected areas. Under this
hypothesis, we intend to examine the influences of
in-kind donations on pre-positioning strategies for
relief supplies. Last but not least, relief supplies
cover an enormous spectrum, from food, drugs and
clothing to rescue equipment, electric generators
and construction materials. Some scholars divide
relief supplies into two categories: perishable prod-
ucts and non-perishable commodities, and propose
different strategies (outsourcing and insourcing) to
pre-position the two kinds of relief supplies (Wang
et al., 2016; Yao et al., 2018). Many researchers pay
attention to the pre-positioning problem of a certain
type of relief supplies such as food (Zhang et al.,
2019) and vaccine (Shamsi et al., 2018) because
these relief supplies are critical products which are
in great demand in the early post-disaster. It can be
seen that the classification of relief supplies largely
determines pre-positioning strategies for different
types of relief supplies. However, there is no univer-
sal standard for how to classify relief supplies at
present. For instance, relief supplies can be catego-
rized as consumable and non-consumable based on
their natural characteristic (Duran et al., 2012;
Wang et al., 2015; Yao et al., 2018). On the other
hand, they can be classified into three types based
on the most urgent needs (by priority): urgent, rela-
tively urgent, non-urgent (Goyet, 2001). In order to
solve the pre-positioning dilemma of governments,
this paper first intends to classify relief supplies with
the combination of their natural characteristic
and priority.
Since non-urgent relief supplies can be purchased
from the existing spot market at post-disaster, there
is no need to pre-position them at pre-disaster. So
purchasing non-urgent relief supplies is not the
focus of this paper. Considering their natural char-
acteristic and priority, relief supplies are classified
into four types: consumable and urgent (C-U), con-
sumable and relatively urgent (C-RU), non-
consumable and urgent (NC-U), non-consumable
and relatively urgent (NC-RU). C-U relief supplies
are mainly drugs, blood and vaccines and so on,
which require a rather rigorous storage condition
on temperature and moisture as well as high inven-
tory cost (Wang et al., 2016). In practice, we rarely
see blood plasma pre-positioned by commercial
enterprises. NC-RU relief supplies are mainly rescue
equipment, first-aid equipment and communication
equipment and so on, which are usually possessed
by public security fire control institutions, national
hospitals and military organizations. For instance, in
the 2008 Wenchuan earthquake in China, the
needed C-U and C-RU relief supplies were directly
transported to disaster-affected areas without pro-
curement. C-RU relief supplies are mainly drinking
water, fast food and packer milk, and NC-U relief
supplies are mainly tents, blankets and clothing.
Both C-RU and NC-U relief supplies are particularly
suitable for storage in advance of disasters because
they are pre-positioned in a relatively undemanding
storage condition and many enterprises are willing
to store relief supplies for the sake of themselves.
Accordingly, this paper focuses on the pre-position-
ing problem of both C-RU and NC-U
relief supplies.
Since option contract has overwhelming advan-
tages in supply elasticity, supply chain coordination
and risk reduction (Barnes-Schuster et al., 2002;
Gastaldi et al., 2006), we introduce an option con-
tract into relief supplies pre-positioning system
which consists of a single government and an enter-
prise, and build a C-RU relief supplies pre-position-
ing (C-RUP) model and a NC-U relief supplies pre-
positioning (NC-UP) model. Next, our research is
intended to address the following critical questions:
1. What are the pre-positioning frameworks for
both C-RU and NC-U relief supplies?
2. What are optimal decision strategies of the gov-
ernment and the enterprise under the two mod-
els, respectively?
3. Under what condition will the government and
the enterprise are willing to conduct the
option contract?
There are several key findings associated with our
analysis. First of all, we propose different pre-posi-
tioning frameworks for both C-RU and NC-U relief
supplies. The main difference is that C-RU relief
supplies are pre-positioned by the enterprise in
form of real products, while NC-U relief supplies
are pre-positioned by real products and production
capacity. Moreover, compared with the government
single pre-positioning model, it is necessary for the
government to develop both the C-RUP model and
1458 Y. LIU ET AL.
the NC-UP model. This is because the two models
can not only improve the governments emergency
ability and support capacity, but also reduce the
governments inventory risk. Third, we present the
conditions that the government and the enterprise
can achieve a win-win situation. Lastly, we propose
managerial insights for pre-positioning strategies
related to different types of relief supplies.
The remainder of this paper is organized as fol-
lows. Section 2 presents a brief literature review.
Section 3 is problem descriptions. Section 4 includes
two benchmark models. Section 5 builds the C-RUP
model and Sec. 6 builds the NC-UP model. Section
7concludes this paper and provides important man-
agerial insights. All proofs of Propositions are given
in the Appendix.
2. Literature review
Given that this work intends to build pre-position-
ing models for different types of relief supplies, the
research is related to three streams of literature.
The first stream is with regard to pre-positioning
relief supplies. Pre-positioning is defined as
stockpiling of equipment and supplies at, or near
the point of planned use(Lodree et al., 2012). The
mathematical programming methods are often
employed to address the pre-positioning problem of
relief supplies. Balcik and Beamon (2008) proposed
a mixed-integer programming model to determine
the number and location of distribution centers, and
the amount of relief items to be stockpiled at each
distribution center. Rawls and Turnquist (2010)
developed an optimization model that determined
the location and amount of relief supplies to be pre-
positioned. The model was validated by hurricanes
happened in the Gulf Coast area of the US.
Campbell and Jones (2011) established a news-
vendor-based model and examined the decision of
where to pre-position relief supplies prior to a disas-
ter, and how many to pre-position as stock at a cen-
ter. Galindo and Batta (2013) offered an integer
programming model for pre-positioning relief sup-
plies in preparation for disasters. The location and
level of storage for pre-positioned relief supplies
were yielded. Davis et al. (2013) proposed a stochas-
tic programming model that determined how many
global relief supplies from external suppliers, and
how many local relief supplies from internal suppli-
ers. Charles et al. (2016) proposed a deterministic
mixed integer linear programming to help humani-
tarian practitioners improve their supply networks.
The model identified the optimal number and loca-
tion of warehouses on a regional scale. Pacheco and
Batta (2016) put forward a forecast-driven dynamic
model for pre-positioning relief supplies. The
location of supply points and the optimal amount of
pre-positioned relief supplies at each supply point
were determined. The models outcomes can be eas-
ily understood by humanitarian practitioners.
Mohammadi et al. (2016) presented a novel multi-
objective stochastic programming model with regard
to pre-position and distribute relief supplies. The
optimal amount and location of supply centers, the
optimal inventory level of relief supplies and the
optimal flow amount of relief supplies were attained.
Klibi et al. (2018) proposed a multi-phase modelling
framework which was applied for humanitarian
relief network design. The framework could deter-
mine the number and location of distribution cen-
ters, each centers capacity, and the amount of relief
supplies to keep as stock. Ni et al. (2018) proposed
a min-max robust model that can optimize the deci-
sion of facility location and inventory level. The
earthquake happened at Yushu County in China
was used to evaluate the models performance.
The second stream is related to pricing relief sup-
plies. The supply chain contracts are often employed
to deal with the pricing problem. Balcik and Ak
(2014) introduced a quantity flexibility contract
(QFC) into the procurement of relief supplies, and
built a stochastic programming model to minimize
the relief organizations procurement and agreement
costs. Similar to Balcik and Ak (2014), Nikkhoo
et al. (2018) utilized a QFC between a relief organ-
ization and a supplier to coordinate inventory man-
agement. The results showed that the proposed QFC
could improve the demand satisfaction of disaster-
affected areas. Liang et al. (2012) introduced an
option contract into relief supplies management,
and established an option pricing model with
binominal lattice. There was a feasible price interval
in which the members in the relief supply chain
were willing to conduct the option contract.
Rabbani et al. (2015) developed an option pricing
model based on binomial trees. The option and exe-
cution prices in four different conditions were opti-
mized by the proposed model. The results showed
that the members in the relief supply chain were
willing to engage in the option transaction. Wang
et al. (2015) proposed a relief supplies purchasing
mechanism with an option contract, which is super-
ior to both pre-purchasing with a buyback contract
and instant-purchasing with a return policy. Hu
et al. (2019) proposed a relief supplies procurement
model based on a put option contract. The condi-
tions that the government and the supplier con-
ducted transactions and achieved a win-win
situation were derived. On the basis of Hu et al.
(2019), Liu et al. (2019) applied option contracts
into relief supplies management system which con-
sists of a single government and multiple suppliers.
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1459
The conditions that the government and all suppli-
ers achieved a multi-win situation were
also attained.
The last stream relates to the classification of
relief supplies. As stated by PAHO, relief supplies
can be classified into 10 different categories. From
Duran et al. (2012), they are divided into two types:
consumable and non-consumable. Consumable relief
supplies such as water and fast food are transferred
continuously into disaster-affected areas. Non-con-
sumable relief supplies are delivered to disaster-
affected areas once, and they are further classified as
operational and non-operational. Wang et al. (2015)
divided relief supplies into two categories: imperish-
able commodities and perishable products, and pro-
posed proactive insourcing strategies for pre-
positioning imperishable relief supplies and pro-
active outsourcing strategy for perishable relief sup-
plies. Similar results can be seen in Yao et al.
(2018). Shamsi et al. (2018) presented an option
contract between the buyer and two competing sup-
pliers and determined the optimal amount of the
required vaccine doses provided by the two suppli-
ers. Zhang et al. (2019) built a quantity commitment
contract framework where there was a government
authority and an agreement supplier. The results
showed that the government should actively cooper-
ate with the supplier to co-reserve perishable
relief materials.
We intend to design pre-positioning models for
different types of relief supplies. Such consideration
is different from the existing literature in the follow-
ing ways. First of all, relief supplies are sorted by
their natural characteristic and priority. Specially,
we build a C-RUP model for pre-positioning C-RU
relief supplies and a NC-UP model for NC-U relief
supplies. Second, the government can pre-position a
certain amount of a kind of relief supplies before a
disaster strikes, which is consistent with the charac-
teristic of the relief supply chain. This not only
increases the possibility that the enterprise conducts
the contract, but also timely transports the needed
relief supplies to disaster-affected areas. Third, in
addition to pre-position relief supplies at pre-disas-
ter and buy the needed relief supplies at post-disas-
ter, the government can also receive in-kind
donations which are collected and delivered by the
HO. Therefore, we investigate the influences of in-
kind donations on the interest game between the
government and the enterprise. We give out the
conditions that the relief supply chain coordination
can be achieved and the two sides can reach a win-
win situation. Compared with previous models
developed in the literature, our study is more closely
aligned with reality. And we propose important
managerial insights for the government to adopt a
reasonable pre-positioning model and strategies
related to different types of relief supplies.
3. Problem descriptions
3.1. The pre-positioning framework of
relief supplies
We will propose the pre-positioning frameworks of
both C-RU and NC-U relief supplies in this section.
We introduce an option contract into C-RU relief
supplies pre-positioning system and NC-U relief
supplies pre-positioning system, respectively. Each
system consists of a single government and an
agreement enterprise. It is a Stackelberg game where
the government is a leader and the enterprise is a
follower. The government can pre-position a certain
amount of a kind of relief supplies before a disaster
suddenly strikes. C-RU relief supplies are consum-
able products with high priority such as bottled
water and fast food. The production and inventory
costs of C-RU relief supplies are relatively low and
the sudden-onset demand of C-RU relief supplies in
the aftermath of a disaster is huge. If C-RU relief
supplies are pre-positioned by semi-products, the
shelf-life of such semi-products is relatively short.
So we consider that the enterprise will pre-position
C-RU relief supplies by real products. NC-U relief
supplies are such non-consumable products with
top priority such as tents, blankets and clothing.
The production and inventory costs of NC-U relief
supplies are high. Pre-positioning NC-U relief sup-
plies totally by real products will take up an enor-
mous amount of the enterprises money. If the
option contract is not triggered, the enterprise has
to dispose of the unused (unsold) relief supplies,
which leads to the reduction of his profit. So we
consider that the enterprise will pre-position NC-U
relief supplies with the combination of real products
and production capacity. If needed, the enterprise
will convert the prepared production capacity into
real products and deliver them to the government
before the deadline agreed in the contract. This
increases the enterprises production flexibility. The
enterprise can certainly convert production capacity
into real products before the default deadline. So
the time of converting production capacity into real
products is not taken into the modelling. In add-
ition to pre-position relief supplies at pre-disaster
and purchase the needed relief supplies from the
enterprise at post-disaster, the government can also
receive in-kind donations. We consider that if the
option contract is triggered, the government first
will buy the need relief supplies from the enterprise.
The enterprise is more likely to accept the option
contract under this schedule. If the sum of the gov-
ernments and the enterprises pre-positioned relief
1460 Y. LIU ET AL.
supplies cannot meet the sudden-onset demand, the
government will turn to receive in-kind donations
because the collection and disposal of in-kind dona-
tions have been basically completed. If the sum of
the governments and the enterprises pre-positioned
relief supplies plus in-kind donations cannot meet
the sudden-onset demand, the government will buy
the needed relief supplies from spot market. The
remaining unmet demand will lead to shortage cost.
3.2. Assumptions
To ensure that the C-RUP model and the NC-UP
model make sense, some rational assumptions are
presented without loss of generality. The first
assumption is that the government and the enter-
prise are both risk neutral and completely rational
following traditional economics. Next, we assume
that the needed relief supplies cannot be urgently
requisitioned by the government through mandatory
measures. This assumption is to fully depict the
effectiveness of pre-positioning strategies for differ-
ent types of relief supplies in advance of disasters by
an option contract. Similar assumptions could be
found in Zhang et al. (2019) and Liu et al. (2019).
The third assumption is that the government tends
to buy the needed relief supplies at a low price if
the option contract is triggered, which is consistent
with Hu et al. (2019). That is, if the execution price
is less than the spot market price, the government
will buy the needed relief supplies at the execution
price; if not, the government will buy them at the
spot market price. The fourth assumption is that if
the sum of the governments and the enterprises
pre-positioned relief supplies plus in-kind donations
cannot meet the sudden-onset demand, the prob-
ability that the government can buy all the needed
relief supplies from the existing spot market is a
constant (Hu et al., 2019). Lastly, we assume that
after the disaster, the government will commit to
subsidize the HO at a fixed subsidy level. This is
because the HO makes a huge effort in the collec-
tion and delivery of in-kind donations.
3.3. Notations and constraints
The notations are given in Table 1.
4. The benchmark models
This section analyzes two benchmark models: the
government single pre-positioning (GSP) model and
the centralized relief supply chain (CRSC) system.
4.1. The GSP model
We use Qdto denote the governments pre-posi-
tioned quantity of a kind of relief supplies under
the GSP model. Before a disaster strikes, the govern-
ment buys Qdunits relief supplies at x:Once a dis-
aster happens, if 0 xQd, the government does
not purchase additional relief supplies; if Qd<x
QdþS, the government needs to receive in-kind
donations; if xexceeds QdþS, the government
needs to procure the required relief supplies from
spot market. The remaining unsatisfied demand will
Table 1. Notations.
Variables Explanations
xThe actual demand of a kind of relief supplies that follows a random
distribution. The probability density and cumulative distribution
functions are fðxÞand FðxÞ:FðxÞand F1ðxÞare
increasing functions.
UThe maximal sudden-onset demand of a kind of relief
supplies, FðUÞ¼1:
hThe probability that a disaster occurs.
cUnit production cost.
hUnit inventory cost.
vUnit salvage value, h<v:
MUnit shortage cost.
xUnit wholesale price, x>c:
oOption price, oþv<cþh:
eExecution price, xþh<eþo:
pSpot market price, xþh<p:
uThe probability that the execution price is greater than the spot
market price.
kThe probability that the government can buy all the needed relief
supplies from spot market.
QaThe governments pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief supplies.
QbThe governments pre-positioned quantity of NC-U relief supplies.
qThe amount of C-RU relief supplies that the enterprise stockpiles.
q0The amount of real NC-U relief supplies that the enterprise stockpiles.
q1The amount of production capacity of NC-U relief supplies that the
enterprise stores.
SThe amount of in-kind donations.
mUnit preparation cost of NC-U relief supplies.
c0Unit urgent production cost of NC-U relief supplies, v<c0:
aThe subsidy level that the government offers to the HO.
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1461
yield stock-out cost. After the disaster, the govern-
ment needs to pay subsidies to the HO. So the gov-
ernments expected cost under the GSP model can
be formulated as
Cd¼xþh
ðÞ
Qdv1h
ðÞ
QdþhðQd
0
vQ
dx
ðÞ
fx
ðÞ
dx
þðU
QdþS
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M

xQdS
ðÞ
fx
ðÞ
dxþaS(1)
where the first term is the governments wholesale
cost and inventory cost, the second term is the sal-
vage profit if no disaster occurs, the last term is the
sum of profit and cost when a disaster occurs. The
first-order and the second-order derivatives of Cd
with respect to Qdare
@Cd
@Qd
¼xþhvhv1FQ
d
ðÞðÞð
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M

1FQ
dþSðÞðÞÞ
(2)
@2Cd
@Q2
d
¼hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M

fQ
dþSðÞvf Qd
ðÞ

(3)
In practice, many studies assume that the sud-
den-onset demand of a kind of relief supplies fol-
lows an uniform distribution (Liu et al., 2019;
Nikkhoo et al., 2018). This paper follows this
assumption and gets @2Cd
@Q2
d
¼hkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
U:Owing to
M>p>v, we have @2Cd
@Q2
d
>0:So Cdis convex in
Qd:By the first-order optimality condition, we
obtain the governments optimal pre-positioned
quantity of a kind of relief supplies under the GSP
model:
Q
d¼UUxþhv
ðÞ
þhSkpþ1k
ðÞ
M

hkp þ1k
ðÞ
Mv

(4)
4.2. The CRSC system
We use Qsto denote the systems pre-positioned
quantity of a kind of relief supplies under the CRSC
system in which the government is a central deci-
sion-maker (Ding & Huang, 2012). According to the
sudden-onset demand of a kind of relief supplies,
the systems expected cost under the CRSC system
can be formulated as
Cs¼cþh
ðÞ
Qsv1h
ðÞ
QsþhÐQs
0vQ
sx
ðÞ
fx
ðÞ
dx
þðU
QsþS
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M

xQsS
ðÞ
fx
ðÞ
dxþaS
(5)
where the first term is the systems production cost
and inventory cost, the second term is the salvage
profit if no disaster occurs, the last term is the sum
of profit and cost when a disaster occurs. The first-
order and the second-order derivatives of Cdwith
respect to Qsare
@Cs
@Qs
¼cþhvhv1FQ
s
ðÞðÞð
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M

1FQ
sþS
ðÞðÞÞ
(6)
@2Cs
@Q2
s
¼hkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv

U(7)
Owing to M>p>v, we have @2Cs
@Q2
s
>0:So the
first-order optimality condition works. By solving
@Cs
@Qs¼0, we obtain the systems optimal pre-posi-
tioned quantity of a kind of relief supplies under
the CRSC system:
Q
s¼UUcþhv
ðÞ
þhSkpþ1k
ðÞ
M

hkp þ1k
ðÞ
Mv

(8)
Owing to x>c, we have Q
d<Q
s:It shows that
the GSP model cannot coordinate the relief supply
chain. Therefore, we introduce an option contract
Figure 1. The timing of the interest game under the C-RUP model.
1462 Y. LIU ET AL.
into relief supplies pre-positioning system, and build
the C-RUP model and the NC-UP model in Secs. 5
and 6. Meanwhile, the GSP model is compared with
the two models.
5. The C-RUP model
In this section we intend to build the C-RUP model.
Figure 1 shows the timing of the interest game
between the government and the enterprise under
the C-RUP model. Prior to a disaster, the govern-
ment buys a certain amount of C-RU relief supplies
(the primary order) at the wholesale price, and sim-
ultaneously offers an option contract to the enter-
prise. The enterprise decides whether to accept this
option contract or reject it. If the enterprise accepts
this contract, he delivers the primary order quantity
of C-RU relief supplies to the government, and sim-
ultaneously decides how many real C-RU relief sup-
plies to pre-position at his own warehouse. If a
disaster occurs, according to the sudden-onset
demand of C-RU relief supplies, the governments
and the enterprises response actions include the fol-
lowing situations: if 0 <x<Qa, the government
will deliver his pre-positioned C-RU relief supplies
to disaster-affected areas and the enterprise will dis-
pose of the unsold C-RU relief supplies; if Qa<x<
Qaþq, the government will buy xQaunits C-
RU relief supplies from the enterprise and the enter-
prise will deliver them to the government and dis-
pose of the unsold C-RU relief supplies; if
Qaþq<x<QaþqþS, the government will buy
qunits C-RU relief supplies from the enterprise and
receive in-kind donations from the HO; if Qaþqþ
S<x<U, the government will buy the needed C-
RU relief supplies from spot market and the unmet
demand will lead to stock-out cost.
5.1. The enterprises optimal decisions
After accepting the option contract, the enterprise is
to determine his pre-positioned quantity of C-RU
relief supplies so as to maximize his expected profit.
From Figure 1, the enterprises expected profit can
be formulated as
Qa¼xc
ðÞ
Qacþho
ðÞ
qþ1h
ðÞ
vq
þhðQa
0
vqf ðxÞdx þðQaþq
Qa
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
xQa
ðÞ
þvðQaþqxÞÞfðxÞdx
þðU
Qaþq1u
ðÞ
eþupÞqf ðxÞdx(9)
where the first and second terms are the enterprises
fixed profit, the third term is the salvage profit if no
disaster occurs, the last term is the portfolio of
profits when a disaster occurs. The first-order
and the second-order derivatives of Qawith respect
to qare
@Qa
@q¼chþoþv
þh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
1FQ
aþq
ðÞðÞ
(10)
@2Qa
@q2¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
fQ
aþq
ðÞ
(11)
Owing to fQ
aþq
ðÞ
>0, p>vand e>v,we
have @2Qa
@q2<0:So Qais concave in q:So we obtain
the enterprises optimal pre-positioned quantity of
C-RU relief supplies:
q¼F11cþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

Qa(12)
5.2. The governments optimal decisions
Different from the retailer in a commercial supply
chain, the government as the buyer in the relief sup-
ply chain is to reduce the injuries, fatalities, and
damages caused by disasters, as well as to minimize
his expected cost. After all, the governments input
is always limited. However, the social benefit result-
ing from pre-positioning relief supplies cannot be
easily measured. Therefore, we assume that the
objective of the government is to minimize his
expected cost. Similar assumptions could be found
in Muggy and Jessica (2014), Hu et al. (2019) and
Liu et al. (2019). From Figure 1, the governments
expected cost can be formulated as
Ca¼xþh
ðÞ
QaþoqvQa1h
ðÞ
þhðQa
0
vðQaxÞfðxÞdx
þðQaþq
Qa
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
xQa
ðÞ
fðxÞdx
þÐU
Qaþq1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
qf x
ðÞ
dx
þðU
QaþqþS
kpþ1u
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
xQaqS
ðÞ
fx
ðÞ
dxþaS
(13)
where the first and second terms are the govern-
ments fixed cost, the third term is the salvage profit
if no disaster occurs, the last term is the portfolio of
costs when a disaster occurs. From the definition of
supply chain coordination, when the sum of the
governments pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief
supplies plus the enterprises pre-positioned quantity
of C-RU relief supplies is equal to the total pre-posi-
tioned quantity of C-RU relief supplies under the
CRSC system (i.e., Qaþq¼Q
s), the coordination of
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1463
the relief supply chain will be achieved (Liu
et al., 2019;Luoetal.,2015;Zhaoetal.,2013).
By substituting Qaþq¼Q
sinto Eq. (13),weget
the expression of the governmentsexpected
cost:
Ca¼xþh
ðÞ
QaþoQ
sQa
ðÞ
þhvQ
aÐQa
0Fx
ðÞ
dx

þ1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
Q
sQaðQ
s
Qa
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkpþ1k
ðÞ
M

UQ
sSðU
Q
sþS
FðxÞdx
!
þaSÞ(14)
The first-order and the second-order derivatives
of Cawith respect to Qaare
@Ca
@Qa
¼xþhovh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
1FQ
a
ðÞðÞ
(15)
@2Ca
@Q2
a
¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
fQ
a
ðÞ (16)
Owing to fQ
a
ðÞ
>0, p>vand e>v, we have
@2Ca
@Q2
a
>0:So Cais convex in Qa:We obtain the gov-
ernments optimal pre-positioned quantity of C-RU
relief supplies:
Q
a¼F11xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

(17)
Proposition 1. Under the C-RUP model, the govern-
ments optimal pre-positioned quantity and the enter-
prises optimal pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief
supplies are
Q
a¼U1xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

q¼Uxc
ðÞ
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
(18)
From Proposition 1, we can see that when h>
xþhov
1u
ðÞ
eþupv, the C-RUP model makes sense. That is,
the occurrence probability of a potential disaster
should be more than a certain value, rather than a
once-in-a-century disaster.
5.3. The relief supply chain coordination
We introduce an option contract into C-RU relief
supplies pre-positioning system and intend to
coordinate the relief supply chain with the
option contract.
Proposition 2. Under the C-RUP model, the relief
supply chain coordination can be achieved
when e ¼1
1uvupþUcþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S

:
Proposition 2 shows the condition that the relief
supply chain coordination is achieved. By solving
the first-order derivatives of oþewith respect to o
and S, we get @2oþeðÞ
@o<11
h1u
ðÞ
<0 and @2oþeðÞ
@S<0:
That is, the unit purchasing price of C-RU relief
supplies negatively correlates with the option price.
The higher the option price is, the lower the unit
purchasing price is. It indicates that the enterprise
faces a trade-off: a certain income from premium
and an uncertain gain because of demand uncer-
tainty. The unit purchasing price also negatively
correlates with the amount of in-kind donations.
The increase of in-kind donations leads to the
reduction of the unit purchasing price. When the
unit purchasing price oþeis less than xþh, the
cooperative relationship between the two sides will
be stopped. Therefore, the government should
receive an appropriate quantity of in-kind dona-
tions. To make Proposition 2 clearly, we illustrate
it with a numerical example. The setting of related
parameters is: U¼30, 000, h¼0:5, c¼40, h¼
0:1, v¼20, o¼5, p¼300, M¼500, x¼70,
u¼0:1, k¼0:8, S¼1000, a¼5:After calcula-
tion, when e¼197:2546, the relief supply chain
coordination can be achieved. The government
should receive up to 8885 units C-RU
relief supplies.
Proposition 3. Under C-RUP model, the govern-
ments optimal pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief
supplies Q
adecreases with o and S, while the enter-
prises optimal pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief
supplies qincreases with o and S:
Proposition 3 shows that the government can buy
the needed C-RU relief supplies at a low price with
an increasing option price. So the government tends
to reduce his pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief
supplies. Since the sum of the governments optimal
pre-positioned quantity plus the enterprises optimal
pre-positioned quantity under coordination is a con-
stant, the enterprises optimal pre-positioned quan-
tity of C-RU relief supplies will increase with the
option price. As the amount of in-kind donations
increases, the government reduces his pre-positioned
quantity of C-RU relief supplies. Since @Q
a
@S<@Q
s
@S<
0, the enterprises optimal pre-positioned quantity
of C-RU relief supplies will increase with in-
kind donations.
Proposition 4. Under C-RUP model, the enterprises
expected profit Q
aand the governments expected
cost C
adecrease with o; the enterprises expected
profit Q
adecreases with S; the governments expected
cost C
adecreases with S when 0<a<
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
2þUxþhv
ðÞ
22oU xþhv
ðÞ
þ2hSv cþhov
ðÞ
ðÞ
2hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ ,but
increases with S when
a>kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
2þUxþhv
ðÞ
22oU xþhv
ðÞ
þ2hSv cþhov
ðÞ
ðÞ
2hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ :
1464 Y. LIU ET AL.
Proposition 4 shows that the increase of the option
price leads to the reduction of the enterprises
expected profit and the governments expected cost.
The influence of in-kind donations on the enterprises
expected profit is different from that on the govern-
ments expected cost. This is because after the disas-
ter, the government needs to pay subsidies to the HO.
If ais at a low level, the governments expected cost
decreases with the amount of in-kind donations.
Once aexcels a certain value, the governments
expected cost increases with the amount of in-kind
donations. So the government should set a proper
subsidy level for the HO. We illustrate it with the
above example. The governments maximal subsidy
level is up to 170.4986.
5.4. Comparisons between the C-RUP model and
the GSP model
When the relief supply chain is coordinated, is it
necessary for the government to adopt the C-
RUP model to pre-position C-RU relief supplies?
By the comparisons between the C-RUP model
and the GSP model, Propositions 5 and 6
are presented.
Proposition 5. Compared to the GSP model, the C-
RUP model can improve the total pre-positioned
quantity of C-RU relief supplies (Q
aþq>Q
dÞand
reduce the governments inventory risk (Q
a<Q
d).
Proposition 5 shows that the C-RUP model is
superior to the GSP model. The increase of the total
pre-positioned quantity of C-RU relief supplies
improves the governments emergency ability and
support capacity at pre-disaster and in the early
post-disaster. The decrease of the governments pre-
positioned quantity of C-RU relief supplies means
that the government shifts some of inventory risk to
the enterprise.
From rational decision-making, the government
and the enterprise should be better off under the C-
RUP model than under the GSR model, satisfying
the inequation:
Q
a>Q
d
C
a<C
d
(19)
Proposition 6. Under the C-RUP model, when 0<
o<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
2Uand 0<S<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
,
the government and the enterprise will be better off.
Proposition 6 presents the condition that the C-
RUP model can achieve Pareto improvement. The
first condition is that the option price should be
controlled in a proper range after bargaining
between the government and the enterprise. The
second condition is that the government should
receive a proper quantity of in-kind donations.
To make Proposition 6 clearly, we illustrate it
with the above example. Since S¼1000 <
Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
¼3547, substituting S¼1000 into
Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
2U, we can get o¼7:2167:The
governments expected cost and the enterprises
expected profit are depicted as in Figure 2. From
Figure 2, when 0 <o<7:2167 and 0 <S<3547,
both the government and the enterprise are willing
to conduct the option contract.
Figure 2. The governments expected cost and the enterprises expected profit.
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1465
6. The NC-UP model
Figure 3 shows the timing of the interest game
between the government and the enterprise under
the NC-UP model. Prior to a disaster, the govern-
ment buys Qbunits NC-U relief supplies at x, and
simultaneously offers an option contract to the
enterprise. The enterprise decides whether to accept
it. If the enterprise accepts it, he delivers the pri-
mary order quantity of NC-U relief supplies to the
government, and decides how many real products
and production capacity to pre-position. If a disaster
occurs, according to the sudden-onset demand of
NC-U relief supplies, the governments and the
enterprises response actions include the following
situations: if 0 <x<Qb, the government will
deliver his pre-positioned NC-U relief supplies to
disaster-affected areas and the enterprise will dispose
of the unsold NC-U relief supplies; if Qb<x<
Qbþq0, the government will buy xQbunits NC-
U relief supplies from the enterprise and the enter-
prise will deliver them and dispose of the unsold
real products; if Qbþq0<x<Qbþq0þq1, the
government will buy q0units real products and the
enterprise will convert xQbq0units production
capacity into real products and deliver them to the
government before the deadline agreed in the con-
tract; if Qbþq0þq1<x<Qbþq0þq1þS, the
government will buy q0þq1units NC-U relief sup-
plies from the enterprise and receive in-kind dona-
tions; if Qbþq0þq1<x<U, the government will
buy the needed NC-U relief supplies from spot mar-
ket and the unmet demand will lead to stock-
out cost.
6.1. The enterprises optimal decisions
After accepting the option contract, the enterprise is
to determine how many real products and produc-
tion capacity to pre-position so as to maximize his
expected profit. From Figure 3, the enterprises
expected profit can be formulated as
where the first and second terms are the enterprises
fixed profit, the third term is the option premium
of real products and preparation cost of production
capacity, the fourth term is the salvage profit if no
disaster occurs, the last term is the portfolio of prof-
its when a disaster occurs. The first-order and the
second-order derivatives of Qbwith respect to q0
and q1are
Figure 3. The timing of the interest game under the NC-UP model.
Qb¼xc
ðÞ
Qbcþho
ðÞ
q0þom
ðÞ
q1þ1h
ðÞ
vq0þhÐQb
0vq0fx
ðÞ
dx
þðQbþq0
Qb
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
xQb
ðÞþvQ
bþq0x
ðÞ

fx
ðÞ
dx
þðQbþq0þq1
Qbþq0
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
q0þ1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
xQbq0
ðÞ

fx
ðÞ
dx
þðU
Qbþq0þq1
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
q0þ1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
c0
ðÞ
q1Þfðxdx

(20)
1466 Y. LIU ET AL.
We get H¼
@2Qb
@q2
0
@2Qb
@q0@q1
@2Qb
@q1@q0
@2Qb
@q2
1
¼h2c0v
ðÞ
1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
U2>0:
By solving @Qb
@q0¼0 and @Qb
@q1¼0, we attain the
enterprises optimal pre-positioned quantities of real
products and production capacity:
q
0¼U1cþhmv
hc0v
ðÞ
!
Qb(22)
q
1¼U1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
cþhmv
ðÞ
þc0v
ðÞ
om
ðÞ

hc0v
ðÞ
1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
(23)
6.2. The governments decision analysis
The governments expected cost can be formulated as
Cb¼xþh
ðÞ
Qbþoq
0þq1
ðÞ
vQb1h
ðÞ
þhðQb
0
vðQbxÞfðxÞdx
þðQbþq0þq1
Qb
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
xQb
ðÞfðxÞdx
þðU
Qbþq0þq1
1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
q0þq1
ðÞ
fx
ðÞ
dx
þðU
Qbþq0þq1þS
kp þ1u
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
xQbq0
ð
q1SÞfx
ðÞ
dx þaSÞ(24)
where the first term is the governments wholesale
cost and inventory cost, the second term is the
option cost, the third term is the salvage profit if no
disaster occurs, the last term is the portfolio of costs
when a disaster occurs. When the relief supply chain
coordination is achieved, Qbþq
0þq
1is equal to
Q
s:After transformation, we get
Cb¼xþhv
ðÞ
QbþoQ
sQb
ðÞ
þhvQ
bÐQb
0Fx
ðÞ
dx

þ1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
Q
sQbðQ
s
Qb
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkpþ1k
ðÞ
M

UQ
sSðU
Q
sþS
FðxÞdx
!
þaS
(25)
The first-order and the second-order derivatives
of Cbwith respect to Qbare
@Cb
@Qb
¼xþhovh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
1FQ
b
ðÞðÞ
(26)
@2Cb
@Q2
b
¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
fQ
b
ðÞ (27)
Owing to fQ
b
ðÞ>0, p>vand e>v, we have
@2Cb
@Q2
b
>0:So Cbis convex in Qb:The governments
optimal pre-positioned quantity of NC-U relief sup-
plies:
Q
b¼U1xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

(28)
Proposition 7. Under the NC-UP model, the govern-
ments optimal pre-positioned quantity of NC-U relief
supplies and the enterprises optimal pre-positioned
quantities of real products and production capacity of
NC-U relief supplies are
@Qb
@q0
¼cþhov
ðÞ
þh1u
ðÞ
eþupvþvc0
ðÞ
FQ
bþq0
ðÞ
1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
FQ
bþq0þq1
ðÞ
!
@2Qb
@q2
0
¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
U<0
@2Qb
@q0@q1
¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
U
@Qb
@q1
¼mþoþh1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
1FQþq0þq1
ðÞðÞ
@2Qb
@q2
1
¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
U<0
@2Qb
@q1@q0
¼h1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
U
8
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
:
(21)
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1467
Q
b¼U1xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

q
0¼Uxþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
cþhmv
hc0v
ðÞ
!
q
1¼U1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
cþhmv
ðÞ
þc0v
ðÞ
om
ðÞ

hc0v
ðÞ
1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
8
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
:(29)
From Proposition 7, the first condition that the
NC-UP model makes sense is h>xþhov
1u
ðÞ
eþupv:
By solving q
0>0 and q
1>0, the unit urgent pro-
duction cost should meet 1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
cþhmv
ðÞ
xþhov
þv<c0<1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
cþhmv
ðÞ
cþhovþv:
Proposition 8. Under the RC-UP model, the relief
supply chain coordination can be achieved
when e ¼1
1u
Umo
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Sþc0up

:
Proposition 8 shows the condition that the relief
supply chain coordination is achieved. By solving the
first-order derivatives of oþewith respect to oand
S, we get @2oþe
ðÞ
@o<11
h1u
ðÞ
<0 and @2oþe
ðÞ
@S<0:The
unit purchasing price of NC-U relief supplies nega-
tively correlates with the option price and the quan-
tity of in-kind donations.
Proposition 9. Under the RC-UP model, the govern-
ments optimal pre-positioned quantity of NC-U relief
supplies Q
bdecreases with o and S; the enterprises
optimal pre-positioned quantity of real NC-U relief
supplies q
0increases with o and S; the enterprises
optimal pre-positioned quantity of production cap-
acity q
1has no concern with o, but decreases with S:
Proposition 9. shows the relationships between Q
b,
q
0,q
1and o,S:To make Proposition 9 clearly, we
illustrate it with a numerical example. The setting of
related parameters is: U¼30, 000, h¼0:5, c¼40,
h¼0:1, v¼20, o¼5, p¼300, M¼500, x¼
70, u¼0:1, k¼0:8, S¼1000, a¼5, m¼18,
c0¼30:First, assume S¼1000 and plot the
changes of Q
b,q
0and q
1with an increasing o
(0 <o<10) (see Figure 4a). Then assume o¼5
and plot the changes of Q
b,q
0and q
1with an
increasing S(0 <S<3000) (see Figure 4b).
Proposition 10. Under the RC-UP model, the enter-
prises expected profit Q
bdecreases with o and S; the
governments expected cost C
bdecreases with o; the
governments expected cost C
bdecreases with S when
0<a<ab, but increases with S when a>ab:
In Proposition 10,abis the value that makes
@C
b
@S¼0:Proposition 10 shows that as the option
price increases, the government can buy the needed
NC-U relief supplies from the enterprise at a lower
price. So the enterprises expected profit and the
governments expected cost decrease with the
increase of the option price. The increase of in-kind
donations leads to the reduction of the probability
that the government purchases the needed NC-U
relief supplies. So the enterprises expected profit
decreases with an increasing quantity of in-kind
donations. Since the government has to pay subsi-
dies to the HO because of his effort in the collection
and delivery of in-kind donations. If the subsidy
level is at a low level, the governments expected
Figure 4. The pre-positioned quantity of NC-U relief supplies with oand S:
1468 Y. LIU ET AL.
cost decreases with the amount of in-kind donations
because the subsidy cost is relatively low. If the sub-
sidy level excels a certain value, the sharp increase
of the subsidy cost that the government must pay
leads to the increase of the governments expected
cost. Therefore, the government should set a proper
subsidy level for the HO. We illustrate it with the
above example. The governments maximal subsidy
level is up to 174.2711.
Proposition 11. Compared to the GSP model, the
NC-UP model also can improve the total pre-posi-
tioned quantity of NC-U relief supplies
(Q
bþq
0þq
1>Q
dÞand reduce the governments
inventory risk (Q
b<Q
d).
Proposition 11 shows that the NC-UP model
have an advantage over the GSP model because it
can greatly not only improve the governments
emergency ability and support capacity, but also
shift some of the governments inventory risk to
the enterprise.
Proposition 12. Under the RC-UP model, when 0<
o<oband 0<S<Sb, the government and the
enterprise will be better off.
In Proposition 12,obis the value that makes
Q
b¼Q
d, which is related with S:Since obshould
be more than 0, we can get the value that makes
ob¼0, which is recorded as Sb:To make
Proposition 12 clearly, we illustrate it with the above
example. The setting of related parameters is the
same as the above. We can get Sb¼2900:Since S¼
1000 <Sb¼2900, we get ob¼5:1915:The govern-
ments expected cost and the enterprises expected
profit are depicted as in Figure 5. when 0 <o<
5:1915 and 0 <S<2900, the government and the
enterprise will be better off.
7. Conclusions
In order to solve the governments pre-positioning
dilemma, we first classify relief supplies according to
their natural characteristic and the most urgent
needs at post-disaster, and then introduce an option
contract into relief supplies pre-positioning system.
Specially, we build the C-RUP model for pre-posi-
tioning consumable, relatively urgent relief supplies,
determining the decision of how many C-RU relief
supplies to be pre-positioned by the government
and the enterprise, and simultaneously build the
NC-UP model for non-consumable, urgent relief
supplies which is used to determine the decision of
how many NC-U relief supplies to be pre-positioned
by the government, and how many real products
and production capacity to be pre-positioned by the
enterprise. The relief supply chain coordination
could be achieved with the option contract. Under
channel coordination, the C-RUP model and the
NC-UP model are superior to the GSP model
because they cannot only improve the governments
emergency ability and support capacity, but also
reduce the governments inventory risk. Moreover,
we give out the conditions that the government and
the enterprise are willing to conduct the option con-
tract. Lastly, we propose important managerial
insights with numerical examples and sensitivity
analysis, as follows: First of all, the C-RUP model
and the NC-UP model are superior to the GSP
Figure 5. The governments expected cost and the enterprises expected profit.
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1469
model. So it is beneficial for the decision-makers to
adopt the two models to pre-position a kind of relief
supplies. Moreover, pre-positioning a kind of relief
supplies depends on the natural characteristic of
relief supplies and the most urgent needs at post-
disaster. Specifically, the C-RUP model is mainly
designed to pre-position consumable, relatively
urgent relief supplies such as bottled water, while
the NC-UP model is mainly designed to pre-pos-
ition non-consumable, urgent relief supplies such as
tents. Third, the government should negotiate with
the enterprise for an appropriate option price, not
too big. Eventually, the government should receive
an appropriate quantity of in-kind donations, and
set a proper subsidy level for the HO.
This paper also has such disadvantages. First, the
quantity of in-kind donations is still regarded as an
exogenous variable. In the future research we will
extend our model by considering it as an endogen-
ous variable. Second, the proposed models are sin-
gle-period. We will furthermore extend them to
multiple-period models.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank the associate editor and
referees for their valuable suggestions and comments,
which help us to improve this paper greatly.
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by
the authors.
Funding
This work was supported by the Humanities and Social
Sciences Foundation of Ministry of Education of China
under Grant 19YJA630068 and the Key Soft Science
Research Projects in Shaanxi Province of China under
Grant 2019KRZ012.
References
Altay, N., & Green, W. G. (2006). OR/MS research in dis-
aster operations management. European Journal of
Operational Research,175(1), 475493. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.ejor.2005.05.016
Balcik, B., & Ak, D. (2014). Supplier selection for frame-
work agreements in humanitarian relief. Production
and Operations Management,23(6), 10281041. https://
doi.org/10.1111/poms.12098
Balcik, B., & Beamon, B. M. (2008). Facility location in
humanitarian relief. International Journal of Logistics
Research and Applications,11(2), 101121. https://doi.
org/10.1080/13675560701561789
Barnes-Schuster, D., Bassok, Y., & Anupindi, R. (2002).
Coordination and flexibility in supply contracts with
options. Manufacturing & Service Operations
Management,4(3), 171207. https://doi.org/10.1287/
msom.4.3.171.7754
Campbell, A. M., & Jones, P. C. (2011). Prepositioning
supplies in preparation for disasters. European Journal
of Operational Research,209(2), 156165. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.ejor.2010.08.029
Chakravarty, A. K. (2014). Humanitarian relief chain:
Rapid response under uncertainty. International
Journal of Production Economics,151, 146157. https://
doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2013.10.007
Charles, A., Lauras, M., Van Wassenhove, L. N., &
Dupont, L. (2016). Designing an efficient humanitarian
supply network. Journal of Operations Management,
4748(1), 5870. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jom.2016.05.
012
Chen, J. X., Liang, L., & Yao, D. Q. (2017). Pre-position-
ing of relief inventories for non-profit organizations: A
newsvendor approach. Annals of Operations Research,
259(12), 3563. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-
2521-4
Chen, J. X., Liang, L., & Yao, D. Q. (2018). Pre-position-
ing of relief inventories: A multi-product newsvendor
approach. International Journal of Production Research,
56(18), 62946313. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.
2018.1470342
Davis, L. B., Samanlioglu, F., Qu, X., & Root, S. (2013).
Inventory planning and coordination in disaster
relief efforts. International Journal of Production
Economics,141(2), 561573. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ijpe.2012.09.012
Ding, B., & Huang, Y. F. (2012). Emergency materials
supply chain coordination by the joint mechanism
between government and enterprises. Asian Social
Science,8(8), 1527. https://doi.org/10.5539/ass.
v8n8p15
Duran, S., Ergun, O., Keskinocak, P., & Swann, J. (2012).
Humanitarian logistics: Advanced purchasing and
prepositioning of relief items. In H. B. James (Ed.),
Handbook of global logistics: Transportation in inter-
national supply chains (pp. 447462). Springer.
Galindo, G., & Batta, R. (2013). Prepositioning of supplies
in preparation for a hurricane under potential destruc-
tion of prepositioned supplies. Socio-Economic Planning
Sciences,47(1), 2037. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.
2012.11.002
Gastaldi, M., Ketikidis, P. H., & Cucchiella, F. (2006).
Risk management in supply chain: A real option
approach. Journal of Manufacturing Technology
Management,17(6), 700720. https://doi.org/10.1108/
17410380610678756
Goyet, C. V. (2001). Humanitarian supply management
and logistics in the health sector. Pan American Health
Organization (PAHO).
Holgu
ın-Veras, J., Jaller, M., Wassenhove, L. N., P
erez,
N., & Wachtendorf, T. (2014). Material convergence:
Important and understudied disaster phenomenon.
Natural Hazards Review,15(1), 112. https://doi.org/
10.1061/(ASCE)NH.1527-6996.0000113
Hu, Z. Q., Tian, J., & Feng, G. Z. (2019). A relief supplies
purchasing model based on a put option contract.
Computers & Industrial Engineering,127, 253262.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2018.12.015
Klibi, W., Ichoua, S., & Martel, A. (2018). Prepositioning
emergency supplies to support disaster relief: A case
study using stochastic programming. INFOR:
Information Systems and Operational Research,56(1),
5081. https://doi.org/10.1080/03155986.2017.1335045
1470 Y. LIU ET AL.
Liang, L., Wang, X. H., & Gao, J. G. (2012). An option
contract pricing model of relief material supply chain.
Omega,40(5), 594600. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.
2011.11.004
Liu, Y., Tian, J., Feng, G. Z., & Hu, Z. Q. (2019). A relief
supplies purchasing model via option contracts.
Computers & Industrial Engineering,137, 106009.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2019.106009
Lodree, E. J., Ballard, K. N., & Song, C. H. (2012). Pre-
positioning hurricane supplies in a commercial supply
chain. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences,46(4),
291305. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2012.03.003
Luo, M. L., Li, G., Wan, C. L., Qu, R., & Ji, P. (2015).
Supply chain coordination with dual procurement
sources via real-option contract. Computers &
Industrial Engineering,80, 274283. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.cie.2014.12.019
Mohammadi, R., Ghomi, S., & Jolai, F. (2016).
Prepositioning emergency earthquake response sup-
plies: A new multi-objective particle swarm optimiza-
tion algorithm. Applied Mathematical Modelling,
40(910), 51835199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apm.
2015.10.022
Muggy, L., & Jessica, L. H. S. (2014). Game theory appli-
cations in humanitarian operations: A review. Journal
of Humanitarian Logistics and Supply Chain
Management,4(1), 423. https://doi.org/10.1108/
JHLSCM-07-2013-0026
Ni, W., Shu, J., & Song, M. (2018). Location and emer-
gency inventory pre-positioning for disaster response
operations: Min-max robust model and a case study of
Yushu earthquake. Production and Operations
Management,27(1), 160183. https://doi.org/10.1111/
poms.12789
Nikkhoo, F., Bozorgi-Amiri, A., & Heydari, J. (2018).
Coordination of relief items procurement in humani-
tarian logistic based on quantity flexibility contract.
International Journal of Disaster Risk Reduction,31,
331340. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijdrr.2018.05.024
Pacheco, G., & Batta, R. (2016). Forecast-driven model
for prepositioning supplies in preparation for a fore-
seen hurricane. Journal of the Operational Research
Society,67(1), 98113. https://doi.org/10.1057/jors.2015.
54
Rabbani, M., Arani, H., & Rafiei, H. (2015). Option con-
tract application in emergency supply chains.
International Journal of Services and Operations
Management,20(4), 385397. https://doi.org/10.1504/
IJSOM.2015.068523
Rawls, C. G., & Turnquist, M. A. (2010). Pre-positioning
of emergency supplies for disaster response.
Transportation Research Part B: Methodological,44(4),
521534. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.trb.2009.08.003
Rawls, C. G., & Turnquist, M. A. (2012). Pre-positioning
and dynamic delivery planning for short-term response
following a natural disaster. Socio-Economic Planning
Sciences,46(1), 4654. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.
2011.10.002
Shamsi, G., Torabi, A. S., & Shakouri, G. H. (2018). An
option contract for vaccine procurement using the SIR
epidemic model. European Journal of Operational
Research,267(3), 11221140. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ejor.2017.12.013
Wang, X. H., Li, F., Liang, L., Huang, Z. M., & Ashley, A.
(2015). Pre-purchasing with option contract and coord-
ination in a relief supply chain. International Journal of
Production Economics,167, 170176. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.ijpe.2015.05.031
Wang, X. H., Wu, Y., Liang, L., & Huang, Z. (2016).
Service outsourcing and disaster response methods in a
relief supply chain. Annals of Operations Research,
240(2), 471487. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-014-
1646-y
Yao, X., Huang, R., Song, M., & Mishra, N. (2018). Pre-
positioning inventory and service outsourcing of relief
material supply chain. International Journal of
Production Research,56(21), 68596871. https://doi.org/
10.1080/00207543.2018.1495853
Zhang, L., Tian, J., Fung, Y. K., & Dang, C. Y. (2019).
Materials procurement and reserves policies for
humanitarian logistics with recycling and replenish-
ment mechanisms. Computers & Industrial Engineering,
127, 709721. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2018.11.013
Zhao,Y.,Ma,L.,Xie,G.,&Cheng,T.C.E.(2013).
Coordination of supply chains with bidirectional
option contracts. European Journal of Operational
Research,229(2), 375381. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ejor.2013.03.020
Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1. See Secs. 5.1 and 5.2.
Proof of Proposition 2. From Proposition 1, we get
qþQ
a¼U1xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

and Q
s¼U
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhSkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
. By solving qþQ
a¼Q
s, we can
obtain e¼1
1uvupþUcþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S

:
Proof of Proposition 3. By substituting einto Eq.
(18), the first-order derivatives of Q
aand qwith respect
to oand Sare: @Q
a
@o¼ xc
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
ðÞ
hcþhov
ðÞ
2kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
<0,
@q
@o¼xc
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
ðÞ
hcþhoc
ðÞ
2kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
>0, @Q
a
@S¼
xþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
<0, @q
@S¼xc
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
>0.
Proof of Proposition 4. The enterprises expected
profit is
Q
a¼xc
ðÞ
Q
acþhov
ðÞ
q
þh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
qÐQ
aþq
Q
aFðxÞdx

(A.1)
The first-order derivative of Q
awith respect to ois
@Q
a
@o¼qþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oqðQ
aþq
Q
a
FðxÞdx
!
(A.2)
We have qþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
ðÐQ
aþq
Q
aFðxÞdxÞ<
qþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq1FQ
aþq

¼q1þh1u
ðÞð
@e
@o1
ðFQ
s
ðÞ
ÞÞ ¼ 0, i.e., @Q
a
@o<0. Due to C
s¼C
aQ
a,
we have @C
a
@o¼@Q
a
@o<0.
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1471
The first-order derivative of Q
awith respect to Sis
@Q
a
@S¼h1u
ðÞ
@e
@SqðQ
aþq
Q
a
FðxÞdx
!
(A.3)
We have h1u
ðÞ
@e
@SqÐQ
aþq
Q
aFðxÞdx

<h1
ð
uÞ@e
@Sq1FQ
aþq
ðÞðÞ
¼h1u
ðÞ
@e
@Sq1FQ
s
ðÞðÞ
<0,
i.e., @Q
a
@S<0.
The first-order derivative of C
awith respect to Sis
@C
a
@S¼ xc
ðÞ
kp þ1k
ðÞ
M

xþcþ2h2o2v
ðÞ
2hcþhov
ðÞ
kp þ1k
ðÞ
Mv

Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhvS
ðÞ
kp þ1k
ðÞ
M

hUakp þ1k
ðÞ
Mv

Ukpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv

(A.4)
We get a¼kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
2þUxþhv
ðÞ
22oU xþhv
ðÞ
þ2hSv cþhov
ðÞ
ðÞ
2hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ by
@C
a
@S¼0. When 0<a<kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
2þUxþhv
ðÞ
22oU xþhv
ðÞ
þ2hSv cþhov
ðÞ
ðÞ
2hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ ,
the governments expected cost decreases with the donated
quantity of relief supplies S; The governments expected
cost increases with the donated quantity of relief supplies
Swhen akpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
2þUxþhv
ðÞ
22oU xþhv
ðÞ
þ2hSv cþhov
ðÞ
ðÞ
2hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ .
Proof of Proposition 5. The total pre-positioned quan-
tity of C-RU relief supplies under the C-RUP model is
Q
aþq¼U1Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ

; the pre-positioned
quantity of C-RU relief supplies under the GSP model is
Q
d¼U1Uxþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ

. Since x>cand Fx
ðÞ
and F1x
ðÞare increasing functions, we get Q
aþq>Q
d.
The governments pre-positioned quantity of C-RU
relief supplies under the C-RUP model is
Q
a¼U1xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

. Due to Q
dQ
a¼
xc
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
SþoU
ðÞ
hcþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
>0, i.e., Q
a<Q
d.
Proof of Proposition 6. Assume Q
ad ¼Q
aQ
dand
we obtain:
Q
ad ¼xc
ðÞ
Q
aQ
d
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ
q
þh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
qÐQ
aþq
Q
aFðxÞdx

(A.5)
By solving Q
ad >0, we have
o<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

S
2U(A.6)
Since Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
2Ushould be more than 0, we
have 0 <S<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
.If0<o<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
2U
and 0 <S<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
, the enterprises expected profit
will be better off.
Assume C
ad ¼C
aC
dand we obtain:
C
ad ¼xþhv
ðÞ
Q
aQ
d
ðÞ
þoq
þhvQ
aQ
dðQ
a
Q
d
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

ðQ
sþS
Q
dþS
Fx
ðÞ
dx Q
sþQ
d
!
þ1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
ðqðQ
s
Q
a
Fx
ðÞ
dxÞÞ (A.7)
The first-order derivative of C
ad with respect to ois
@C
ad
@o¼qþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oqðQ
s
Q
a
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
(A.8)
Since qþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
ðÐQ
s
Q
aFx
ðÞ
dxÞ<q1þh1
ðð
uÞ@e
@o1FQ
s
ðÞðÞ
Þ¼ 0, we have @C
ad
@o<0. Hence when
o¼0, the governments expected cost is maximal, as follows:
C
ad ¼xþhv
ðÞ
Q
aQ
d
ðÞ
þoq
þhvQ
aQ
dðQ
a
Q
d
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

ðQ
sþS
Q
dþS
Fx
ðÞ
dx Q
sþQ
d
!
þvþUcþhv
ðÞ
kp þ1k
ðÞ
Mv

Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

S
!
qðQ
s
Q
a
FðxÞdxÞ
! (A.9)
Due to @C
admax
@S<0, S¼0 maximizes C
admax. So we get
C
admax <xþhv
ðÞ
Q
aQ
d
ðÞ
þhvkp 1k
ðÞ
M

Q
aQ
dþÐQ
d
Q
aFx
ðÞ
dx

¼0, i.e., C
admax <0. To sum up,
when 0 <o<Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
2Uand 0 <S<
Ucþhv
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
, the enterprise and the government will be
better off.
Proof of Proposition 7. See Secs. 6.1 and 6.2.
Proof of Proposition 8. Given q
0þq
1þQ
b¼
U1mo
h1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ

and Q
s¼UUcþhv
ðÞ
þhSkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
.By
solving q
0þq
1þQ
b¼Q
s, we can obtain
e¼1
1u
ðÞ
Umo
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Sþc0up

:
Proof of Proposition 9. The first-order derivatives of
Q
b,q
0, and q
1with respect to oand Sare: @Q
b
@o¼
Uc
0v
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
ðÞ
U2kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
xþhmv
ðÞ
hvc0Umo
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S

2
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
ðÞ
<
U2kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
xc
ðÞ
hvc0Umo
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S

2
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
ðÞ
<0,
@q
0
@o¼
@Q
b
@o>0, @Q
b
@S¼ Ukpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
mo
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
xþhov
ðÞ
hvc0Umo
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S

2
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
ðÞ
<0,
@q
0
@S¼
@Q
b
@S>0, @q
1
@o¼0, @q
1
@S¼ kpþ1k
ðÞ
M
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv<0.
Proof of Proposition 10. The enterprises expected
profit is
Y
b¼xc
ðÞ
Q
bcþhov
ðÞ
q
0þom
ðÞ
q
1
þh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
q
0ðQ
bþq
0
Q
b
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þ1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
q
1ðQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
bþq
0
FðxÞdx
!
(A.10)
1472 Y. LIU ET AL.
The first-order derivative of Q
bwith respect to ois
@Q
b
@o¼q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1ðQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
b
FðxÞdx
!
(A.11)
We then have q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1
ð
ÐQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
bFðxÞdxÞ<q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1
ðÞ
1
ð
FQ
bþq
0þq
1
ðÞ
Þ¼ q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1
ðÞ
1FQ
s
ðÞðÞ
¼0 i.e., @Q
b
@o<0.
The first-order derivative of Q
bwith respect to Sis
@Q
b
@S¼h1u
ðÞ
@e
@Sq
0þq
1ðQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
b
FðxÞdx
!
(A.12)
Similarly, we have h1u
ðÞ
@e
@Sq
0þq
1ÐQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
b
FðxÞdxÞ<h1u
ðÞ
@e
@Sq
0þq
1
ðÞ
1FQ
bþq
0þq
1
ðÞðÞ
¼h1u
ðÞ
@e
@Sq
0þq
1
ðÞ
1FQ
s
ðÞðÞ
<0, i.e., @Q
b
@S<0.
The first-order derivative of C
bwith respect to ois
@C
b
@o¼q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1ðQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
b
FðxÞdx
!
(A.13)
We then have q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1
ð
ÐQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
bFðxÞdxÞ<q
0þq
1þh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oq
0þq
1
ðÞ
1
ð
FQ
b
ðþq
0þq
1ÞÞ¼ 0, i.e., @C
b
@o<0.
The first-order derivative of C
bwith respect to Sis @Cb
@S.
By solving @Cb
@S¼0, we can get the analytic expression of
a. Since it is extremely complicated, we use abto denote
it. When 0 <a<ab,@Cb
@S<0, the governments expected
cost decreases with S. When a>ab,@Cb
@S>0, the govern-
ments expected cost increases with S.
Proof of Proposition 11. The total pre-positioned
quantity of NC-U relief supplies under the NC-UP model
is Q
bþq
0þq
1¼U1Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ

; the pre-posi-
tioned quantity of NC-U relief supplies under the GSP
model is Q
d¼U1Uxþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ

. Since x>c
and Fx
ðÞ and F1x
ðÞ are increasing functions, we get
Q
bþq
0þq
1>Q
d. The governments pre-positioned
quantity under the NC-UP model is
Q
b¼U1xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ

. Due to Q
dQ
b¼
xþhov
h1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
Uxþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
S
hUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
>xc
ðÞ
hkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
SþoU
ðÞ
hcþhov
ðÞ
kpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
>0,
i.e., Q
b<Q
d.
Proof of Proposition 12. Assume Q
bd ¼Q
bQ
d
and we obtain:
Q
bd ¼xc
ðÞ
Q
aQ
d
ðÞ
cþhov
ðÞ
q
0þom
ðÞ
q
1
þh1u
ðÞ
eþupv
ðÞ
q
0ðQ
bþq
0
Q
b
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þ1u
ðÞ
eþupc0
ðÞ
q
1ðQ
bþq
0þq
1
Q
bþq
0
FðxÞdx
!
(A.14)
By solving Q
bd >0, we can get the analytic expression
of o. Since it is extremely complicated, we use obto
denote it. Since obshould be more than 0, we can get the
value that makes ob¼0, which is recorded as Sb.Soif
0<o<oband 0 <S<Sb, we have Q
bd >0.
AssumeC
bd ¼C
bC
dand we obtain:
C
bd ¼xþhv
ðÞ
Q
bQ
d
ðÞ
þoq
0þq
1
ðÞ
þhvQ
bQ
dðQ
b
Q
d
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

ðQ
sþS
Q
dþS
Fx
ðÞ
dx Q
sþQ
d
!
þ1u
ðÞ
eþup
ðÞ
q
0þq
1ðQ
s
Q
b
FðxÞdx
!
(A.15)
The first-order derivative of C
bd with respect to ois
@C
bd
@o¼Q
sQ
bþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oQ
sQ
bðQ
s
Q
b
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
(A.16)
Owing to Q
sQ
bþh1u
ðÞ
@e
@oQ
sQ
b
ðÐQ
s
Q
b
Fx
ðÞ
dxÞ<0, we have @C
bd
@o<0. Hence when o¼0, the gov-
ernments expected cost is maximal, as follows:
C
bd ¼xþhv
ðÞ
Q
bQ
d
ðÞ
þoq
0þq
1
ðÞ
þhvQ
bQ
dðQ
b
Q
d
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

ðQ
sþS
Q
dþS
Fx
ðÞ
dx Q
sþQ
d
!
þc0þUmo
ðÞ
kp þ1k
ðÞ
Mv

Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

S
!
q
0þq
1ðQ
s
Q
b
FðxÞdx
!
(A.17)
By substituting c0¼Ukpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv
ðÞ
cþhvm
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M
ðÞ
Sþvinto
Eq. (A. 17), we get
C
bdmax ¼xþhv
ðÞ
Q
bQ
d
ðÞ
þoq
0þq
1
ðÞ
þhvQ
bQ
dðQ
b
Q
d
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
þkp þ1k
ðÞ
M

ÐQ
sþS
Q
dþSFx
ðÞ
dx Q
sþQ
d

þUkpþ1k
ðÞ
Mv

cþhv
ðÞ
Ucþhv
ðÞ
þhkpþ1k
ðÞ
M

Sþv
!
q
0þq
1ðQ
s
Q
b
Fx
ðÞ
dx
!
(A.18)
Owing to @C
bdmax
@S<0, S¼0 maximizes C
bdmax.Sowe
get: C
bdmax <xþhv
ðÞ
Q
bQ
d
ðÞ
þhvkp
ð
1k
ðÞ
MÞQ
bQ
dþÐQ
d
Q
bFx
ðÞ
dx

¼0, i.e., C
bdmax <0.
To sum up, when 0 <o<oband 0 <S<Sb, the enter-
prise and the government will be better off.
JOURNAL OF THE OPERATIONAL RESEARCH SOCIETY 1473
... The option contract is an economics program that is often used in supply chain management for trading parties to enter into uncertain demand product supply due to its characteristics such as risk management, flexibility, and no need to physically hold the asset [35,36]. For example, Hu verified the effectiveness of option contracts in the supply chain coordination process under demand uncertainty [37]; Aghajani et al. used option contracts to derive the optimal production and purchasing quantities for supply chain decision makers under output and demand uncertainty [38]; Liu et al. suggested that option contracts can increase the level of joint government-enterprise physical and production capacity stockpiles of emergency supplies and improve the response level of disaster relief [39]. However, while existing research confirms that option pacts can coordinate governmententerprise cooperation to carry out physical and production capacity stockpiling of emergency supplies, drugs in shortage belong to special emergency supplies, and the primary prerequisite for promoting the security of supply of medicines through enterprise production capacity stockpiling is an adequate stockpile of APIs [40,41]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Drug shortage is a global problem, and the development of government-enterprise cooperative stockpiles of drugs in shortage, combining physical and production capacity, has become one of the most important means of coping with drug shortages. However, existing studies have tended to overlook the fact that shortages of Active Pharmaceutical Ingredients (APIs) have become an important constraint on production capacity stockpiling and that the lack of incentives and provisions for coordination of benefits have led to a double marginal effect of joint stockpiling by government and enterprises of drugs in shortage. Accordingly, this study introduced the option contract to the drug supply system composed of government and pharmaceutical enterprises and used the subsidy of API storage in lieu as an important initiative to incentivize the reserve of APIs, to construct a model of shortage drug reserve under the government’s leadership. This study aims to improve the effect of government-enterprise joint stockpiling of drugs in shortage, which is of great theoretical and practical significance. According to the classification of production license types of pharmaceutical enterprises, this study established a three-level supply chain decentralized decision-making model consisting of the government, formulation enterprises, and API enterprises, and a two-level supply chain centralized decision-making model consisting of the government and API Formulation (API-F) integrated enterprises, respectively. By solving the inverse order derivation, the government-enterprise option cooperation conditions and optimal decision-making strategy were derived. The study results showed that: (i) The addition of enterprise API stockpiling mode can help the government conventional reserves, and enterprise production capacity reserves, broaden the way of drug reserves, and improve the effect of government-enterprise option cooperation; (ii) when the probability of drug shortages is high, the government should prefer the cooperation of API-F integrated enterprises, which is conducive to reducing intermediate links and government costs and improving the supply responsiveness to shortages of medicines; (iii) Setting appropriate government subsidies for API storage can incentivize enterprises to stockpile APIs and improve drug production capacity and physical supply response capability. This study took the problem of socialized stockpiling of drugs in shortage as an entry point and explored the problems and solution strategies in the government-enterprise cooperative stockpiling of drugs in shortage, which not only made some theoretical contributions to the application of options contract in the government-enterprise cooperative stockpiling of drugs in shortage but also provided new ideas and theoretical basis for the improvement of the stockpiling work of drugs in shortage.
... In relief supply pre-positioning systems, to reduce the wastage of expired resources and address shortages, governments worldwide have encouraged emergency management departments or humanitarian organizations to collaborate with businesses in stockpiling relief supplies. This collaboration integrates the physical storage capabilities and production capacities of businesses [1,3,4]. For instance, the Chinese government has implemented a series of policies such as the "National Natural Disaster Relief Emergency Plan (2016)", which emphasize the diversification of rescue and disaster relief material reserves and promote a socialized storage mechanism for emergency supplies [1,2,5]. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper delves into optimizing the rotation of relief supplies within the relief supply chain system, concentrating on reserve quantity decisions for governments and humanitarian organizations involved in disaster response. By integrating a trade-in strategy with suppliers, it ensures a precise and timely response to the fluctuating demand for relief supplies post-disaster. Utilizing the newsvendor model, optimization theory, and supply chain coordination principles, we developed a comprehensive model that calculates optimal reserve quantities for pre-positioning demanders. It also outlines the expected profit function for suppliers and a robust supply chain coordination model. The findings highlight that optimal stockpiling decisions for relief supplies are heavily influenced by cost parameters, material characteristics, and the relationship between trade-in pricing and market resale values. Notably, higher trade-in prices generally reduce the government’s optimal reserve quantities, impacting strategic decisions within supply chain coordination. This research adds to disaster management literature by offering strategic insights into how coordination and pricing strategies can improve disaster preparedness and response efficiency and effectiveness.
... Pu et al. (2023) have optimized railway routes by calculating carbon emissions during railway construction, operation, and maintenance. The existing research on post-fire rescue is more based on efficiency and cost, focusing on the optimization of transportation routes (Zhang et al. 2020), vehicle layout (Akbari et al. 2023), material allocation (Liu et al. 2021), and firefighting methods (Han et al. 2022) but neglect the calculation of carbon emissions during rescue. ...
Article
Full-text available
In the context of global high temperature, the harm of greenhouse gases (GHG) emissions caused by frequent forest fires to the environment cannot be ignored. Existing research only calculates the GHG generated by the burning of forest vegetation, ignoring the GHG generated by the fire-driven social rescue activities. Taking the forest fire in Beibei District, Chongqing City, China, as an example, this paper studies and establishes the GHG emission accounting method for the whole process of forest fire from ignition to fire extinguishing through three processes: vegetation burning, rescue transportation, and on-site fire extinguishing. It covers three GHG calculation types: biomass burning, traffic activity level comprehensive energy consumption, and machine energy consumption. Among them, the CO2 produced by the burning of coniferous forest, the support transportation of rescue teams in Yunnan province, and the motorcycle transportation at the fire extinguishing site accounted for a relatively high proportion in the corresponding processes, reaching 12,761.445 t, 118.750 t, and 1056.980 t, respectively. Finally, through data analysis, suggestions on GHG emission reduction related to forest tree regulation and optimization of rescue and fire extinguishing management are put forward, which provides a direction for future research on carbon reduction in the whole process of forest fire events. Graphical abstract
... Hu et al. [5] establish a put option to overcome the huge cost of government in relief supply and make comparison between the put option contract, wholesale price contract and buyback contract. In order to solve the dilemma faced by the government in the pre-positioning of disaster relief materials, Liu et al. [6] design an option contract to establish the pre positioning (C-RUP) model of consumables and relative emergency relief materials and the pre positioning (NC-UP) model of non consumables and emergency relief materials. Ghavamifar et al. [7] present a hybrid contract composed of quantity flexible contract and option contract to coordinate the relief supply chain. ...
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we study option contracts for emergency material reserves due to unexpected events. Contingencies occur randomly and the amount of realization cannot be known until it breaks out. Therefore, it is important to stockpile some necessary supplies in advance. However, a large advance stockpile on the demand side would incur low-carbon disposal costs, which are not economical. Also, the supplier will have no incentive to stockpile for the demander due to low carbon disposal costs and production costs. Therefore, we propose a contractual approach with option to stimulate supplier to stockpile for his client. Three models are discussed based on the consideration of low-carbon disposal costs: a centralized decision case, a non-option decentralized case, and a decentralized case with option. The outcomes demonstrate that the number of first orders under the decentralized case without option is less than the order quantity under the centralized case. Moreover, the size of the first purchase volume in all three cases depends on the both parties’ practical factors. Meanwhile, the reasonable interval of option fee is obtained by analysis.
Article
Purpose Pre-positioning and distributing relief items are important parts of disaster management as it simultaneously considers activities from both pre- and post-disaster stages. This study aims to address this problem with a novel mathematical model. Design/methodology/approach In this research, a bi-objective mixed-integer linear programming model is developed to tackle pre-positioning and distributing relief items, and it is formulated as an integrated location-allocation-routing problem with uncertain parameters. The humanitarian supply chain consists of relief facilities (RFs) and demand points (DPs). Perishable and imperishable relief commodities (RCs), different types of vehicles, different transportation modes, a time window for delivering perishable commodities and the occurrence of unmet demand are considered. A scenario-based game theory is applied for purchasing RCs from different suppliers and an integrated best-worst method-technique for order of preference by similarity to ideal solution technique is implemented to determine the importance of DPs. The proposed model is used to solve several random test problems for verification, and to validate the model, Iran’s flood in 2019 is investigated as a case study for which useful managerial insights are provided. Findings Managers can effectively adjust their preferences towards response time and total cost of the network and use sensitivity analysis results in their decisions. Originality/value The model locates RFs, allocates DPs to RFs in the pre-disaster stage, and determines the routing of RCs from RFs to DPs in the post-disaster stage with respect to minimizing total costs and response time of the humanitarian logistics network.
Article
Full-text available
Inventory pre-positioning is critical to quickly and efficiently responding to potential disasters. This paper considers a NPO (a relief agent) that requires stockpiling multiple products for responding multiple potential disaster events. By employing the multi-product newsvendor (MPNV) approach, this paper establishes a multiple relief materials’ storage model that aims to minimise the expected total cost of the NPO. Our model acknowledges that the occurrence of a disaster, the demand after a disaster and the donation after a disaster are uncertain. Given the no-budget constraint, this paper shows the implicit conditions that determine the optimal solutions; for the case with a budget constraint, the paper develops a two-binary iterative approach to solve the model with a budget constraint. Numerical examples are conducted to investigate the impacts of model parameters. The paper further proposes a flexible storage policy, in which the NPO and the supplier jointly stockpile relief materials. The optimal solution of the case with the flexible stockpiling policy is also characterised. Moreover, this paper shows the policy implementation can simultaneously increase the performance of the NPO and the supplier; and both players of the supply chain prefer that the supplier solely holds all inventory.
Article
Full-text available
Developing an efficient policy to determine the inventory a non-profit organization (NPO) should stockpile to respond to potential disasters plays a vital role in humanitarian relief. Incorporating social donation and emergency spot purchasing, this paper develops a (generalized) two-stage delivery process model to characterize relief materials’ delivery after a disaster. We propose an analytical model that aims to minimize the total costs when all demands incurred by an unexpected disaster need to be fully satisfied. Moreover, we determine that the optimal solution uniquely exists and characterize the effects of key parameters. Last, this paper also develops a risk-sharing scheme, in which the NPO and the supplier jointly stockpile relief materials. Under some mild conditions, we show that implementing the scheme could increase the storage quantity and decrease the total costs simultaneously. Several numerical examples are employed to validate the model, as well as the value of the proposed risk-sharing scheme.
Article
The demand for relief supplies after sudden disasters strike is growing at an explosive rate. Because of high uncertainty and time urgency, governments usually stockpile a certain amount of relief supplies in advance of potential disasters. Hence governments face inventory risk and stock-out risk in the relief supply management. The stored relief supplies by governments are wasted if no disaster happens. If the quantity of stored relief supplies is not sufficient, stock-out risk will occur. In reality, governments may purchase relief supplies from multiple suppliers, rather than from a supplier. However, few studies have been undertaken with respect to the decision of what quantity of relief supplies should be stockpiled by governments, and how much inventory to pre-position at each supplier. To solve the problem, we introduce option contracts into relief supply management by considering this system as a relief supply chain with one government and multiple suppliers. A relief supplies purchasing (RSP) model via option contracts is established. The government’s optimal order quantity of relief supplies and each supplier’s pre-positioning quantity of relief supplies are derived. We uncover the condition that the relief supply chain coordination is achieved. Under channel coordination, the RSP model can improve the total quantity of relief supplies stockpiled for sudden disasters, and reduce the government’s inventory risk when compared to the government single pre-positioning model. Meanwhile, we give the condition that the government and all suppliers achieve a multi-win situation. Finally, we broaden our model and attain a common interval in which both supplier 1 and supplier 2 are willing to engage. The research findings provide some managerial insights for government’s purchasing strategies.
Article
Relief supply management is one of the most important parts in emergency management. Because of high uncertainty and time urgency, relief supplies should be purchased in advance as stock before disasters occurs. The purchasers of relief supplies are mainly governments. As in commercial supply management, governments face inventory risk and stock-out risk in their management of relief supplies. Stock-out risk can be solved by spot markets and in-kind donations, while there is no good solution to inventory risk. It is highly possible that pre-reserved relief supplies are not used within their validity periods because of the low frequency of disasters, which causes huge losses to governments. To solve the problem, we introduce a put option contract into relief supply management by considering the system as a relief supply chain. We explore the characteristics of the put option contract and prove that it can provide coordination of the relief supply chain. Furthermore, we make comparison between the put option contract, wholesale price contract and buyback contract under the same conditions to show the superiority of the put option contract. Meanwhile, we also present the condition that both a government and a supplier conduct transactions and achieve a win-win situation based on the put option contract.
Article
Physical reserves, being one of the most important resources in humanitarian rescue operations, should ideally be in adequate quantity and in good quality to meet sudden-onset demands. However, given the uncertainties in demand quantity and timing, reserves (i.e., medicines, drugs, compressed food) can expire if they are not used in a timely manner, resulting in a huge wastage or the expired reserves being consumed. Considering factors of uncertain demand, resource wastage and cost efficiency together, this paper focuses on procurement and reserves cooperation between a given government authority and a strategic supplier in a framework of quantity commitment contract. Under some plausible assumptions, the optimal recycling and replenishment policies, and the government's optimal payment strategies are formulated. Through a numerical example and sensitivity analyses, the practical applicability of the proposed model to the procurement and reserves management for humanitarian logistics, underlining managerial insights, is examined. Specially, this paper suggests that the government should actively cooperate with suppliers to co-reserve perishable or consumable materials, and give priority to suppliers whose operational costs are low and market shares are big. Moreover, factors, including materials’ shelf-life, customers’ perception and consumption rate, etc., should be carefully evaluated when the government selects perishable materials as reserves and corresponding suppliers as partners.
Article
Service outsourcing is very common in a commercial supply chain, and in humanitarian relief area, the transportation service is usually outsourced. To practice relief supply more effectively, it seems essential to enlarge outsourcing from shipping to more areas, and private enterprises could play a vital role. This paper examines the optimal pre-disaster order quantity of a certain relief commodity, based on a two-stage coordinated approach. Our findings show that the delay cost, shortage penalty cost, risk of supply shortage, salvage value, expected perishable rate, unit inventory cost and reactive price have significant impacts on the optimal amount of propositioned inventory. Moreover, the outsourcing strategies differ by types of relief commodities. For perishable supplies, proactive or reactive outsourcing would improve the benefits of buyer and supplier simultaneously. As for imperishable supplies, it is better to combine proactive insourcing approach and reactive outsourcing strategy. In view of some supplies whose monitoring cost is high, the insourcing approach is much better than the outsourcing approach.
Article
Nowadays, coordination of relief items procurement in humanitarian logistics has become one of the main challenges of disaster management. In this paper, we utilize a quantity flexibility contract (QFC) to coordinate ordering activities in a three-echelon relief chain. This multi-echelon supply chain consists of a relief organization (i.e., NGO), one relief item supplier, and affected areas. In the proposed QFC, initially, the relief organization places an order before the disaster strikes and is committed to purchasing the initial quantity no less than a previously agreed amount. On the other hand, the supplier is committed to providing up to a certain amount above the initial order, if needed. Expected profit functions of relief chain members include transportation cost, inventory cost, the manufacturing cost of relief items, shortage cost, salvage value, and satisfaction level of affected areas. Our findings show that, under demand uncertainty, the proposed QFC not only prevents significant losses at relief organization but also enhances satisfaction level of the affected areas. Finally, the performance of the proposed coordination model is examined via various numerical experiments and managerial insights are extracted.
Article
Timely and adequate supply of vaccines in disastrous situations has a key role in controlling communicable diseases. This paper develops a specific option contract for proactively provisioning required vaccine doses from two suppliers (a main and a backup). The model aims to minimize the procurement and social costs using the SIR epidemic model. A novel hybrid solution procedure is developed using the optimal control theory, Stackelberg game model and nonlinear programming approaches. To evaluate the performance of the developed solution method, a number of numerical examples are presented and their results are discussed.
Article
Pre-positioning emergency inventory in selected facilities is commonly adopted to prepare for potential disaster threat. In this paper, we simultaneously optimize the decisions of facility location, emergency inventory pre-positioning, and relief delivery operations within a single- commodity disaster relief network. A min-max robust model is proposed to capture the un-certainties in both the left- and right-hand-side parameters in the constraints. The former corresponds to the proportions of the pre-positioned inventories usable after a disaster attack, while the latter represents the demands of the inventories and the road capacities in the disaster-affected areas. We study how to solve the robust model effciently and analyze a special case that minimizes the deprivation cost. The application of the model is illustrated by a case study of the 2010 earthquake attack at Yushu County in Qinghai Province of PR China. The advantage of the min-max robust model is demonstrated through comparison with the deterministic model and the two-stage stochastic model for the same problem. Experiment variants also show that the robust model outperforms the other two approaches for instances with significantly larger scales.
Article
This paper studies the strategic problem of designing emergency supply networks to support disaster relief over a planning horizon. The problem addresses decisions on the location and number of distribution centres needed, their capacity, and the quantity of each emergency item to keep in stock. It builds on a case study inspired by real-world data obtained from the North Carolina Emergency Management Division (NCEM) and the Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA). To tackle the problem, a scenario-based approach is proposed involving three phases: disaster scenario generation, design generation and design evaluation. Disasters are modelled as stochastic processes and a Monte Carlo procedure is derived to generate plausible catastrophic scenarios. Based on this detailed representation of disasters, a multi-phase modelling framework is proposed to design the emergency supply network. The two-stage stochastic programming model proposed is solved using a sample average approximation method. This scenario-based solution approach is applied to the case study to generate plausible scenarios, to produce alternative designs and to evaluate them on a set of performance measures in order to select the best design.