ArticlePDF Available

Contextualization and Value-in-Context: How Context Frames Exchange

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The purpose of this paper is to explore the role of context in service provision and, more broadly, in market co-creation. We oscillate foci from an individual actor at the micro level to a market at the macro level to make the scaleable influence of context more salient. This reveals the meso level, which is nestled between the micro and macro levels. We discuss how these market levels influence one another. We conceptualize markets as simultaneous, continuous exchanges that are bounded by each of these levels of context.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Contextualization and
value-in-context: How
context frames exchange
Jennifer D. Chandler
University of Hawaii at Manoa
Stephen L. Vargo
University of Hawaii at Manoa
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to explore the role of context in service provision and, more broadly,
in market co-creation. We oscillate foci from an individual actor at the micro level to a market at the
macro level to make the scaleable influence of context more salient. This reveals the meso level,
which is nestled between the micro and macro levels. We discuss how these market levels influ-
ence one another. We conceptualize markets as simultaneous, continuous exchanges that are
bounded by each of these levels of context.
Keywords
service-dominant logic, value-in-context, value-in-use, value networks
Most contemporary marketing scholars (e.g. Bagozzi, 1975; Hunt 1991; Vargo and Lusch, 2004a)
consider the study of marketing and, by implication, markets to be concerned with exchange. The
purpose of exchange is to access resources that have value potential – that is, that provide benefit –
to actors from within their own particular contexts. However, marketing scholars disagree about
where and how value is created through exchange and, thus, about the role of exchange in the
value-creation process itself.
One perspective views value creation as the joint integration of resources by the multiple actors
associated with an exchange. Specifically, service-dominant logic (Vargo and Lusch, 2004, 2008)
emphasizes value as co-created by multiple actors (Prahalad and Ramaswamy, 2004), rather than
viewing value as created by a single actor. In this way, the simultaneous exchange processes that
occur across actors during service provision – which Vargo and Lusch (2004) define as resources
Corresponding author:
Jennifer D. Chandler, Shidler College of Business, University of Hawaii at Manoa, 2500 Campus Road, Honolulu, HI 96822
Email: jenc@hawaii.edu
Marketing Theory
11(1) 35–49
ªThe Author(s) 2011
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/1470593110393713
mtq.sagepub.com
applied for the benefit of another actor – can be seen as service-for-service exchanges. This
process orientation emphasizes how multiple actors exchange service, which contrasts with the
output orientation of the ‘neoclassical economics research tradition’ (e.g. Hunt, 2000), which
emphasizes how multiple actors exchange output units. The latter orientation has also been
referred to as ‘manufacturing logic’ (e.g. Normann, 2001); ‘old enterprise logic’ (Zuboff and
Maxmin, 2002); ‘marketing management’ (Webster Jr, 1992); or ‘goods-dominant (G-D) logic’
(Vargo and Lusch, 2004a; 2008).
The purpose of this paper is to further explore how actors ‘come together’ through exchange
within a specific context and to explore the role that context plays in framing exchange. Arguably,
making salient the influence of context is relatively isomorphic with those conceptualizations of
markets that are, at least intuitively, interactive (e.g. Gronroos, 2006); networked, or contextual (e.g.
Collon, 1998). Similarly, the proposed emphasis takes a network perspective of markets, one that is
most extensively found in marketing within the work of the IMP group (e.g. Hakansson and Snehota,
1995). The proposed emphasis differs slightly, however, from the IMP group work because there the
emphasis is more on relationship than value creation. Additional insights can also be found in the
approach of the Nordic School of service marketing (e.g. Gronroos, 2006), especially in the ‘many-
to-many marketing’ approach of Gummesson (2006), but there too the emphasis is on interactions
and relationships, rather than value creation. However, all of this work, along with the proposed
framework, converge in their shared external perspectives on processes outside of actors and in their
implication that value is emergent at intersections of resource networks (Normann, 2001; Vargo and
Lusch, 2004a, 2008; Gronroos, 2006).
The purpose of the proposed framework is to extend this literature by making salient and
explicit how context, markets, and value co-creation are theoretically related. It seems that for the
study of markets and value co-creation, one should be able to call on academic marketing’s knowl-
edge of markets to better understand both the value-co-creation process and the embedded, con-
textual nature of value. Ironically, this not the case, or, at least it is only so to a limited extent.
As Venkatesh et al. (2006) indicate, ‘the market is everywhere and nowhere in marketing.’ That
is, marketing has no real theory of markets. It might be argued that the reason for this is that it
inherited one from economics but, as Vargo (2007) has suggested, to the extent that there is a
positive theory of the market in economics, it is based on a normative theory of national wealth
creation rather than a more general theory of value creation and exchange. Perhaps even more tell-
ing is the indictment of Nobel Laureate in Economics Douglass C. North (1977): ‘It is a peculiar
fact that the literature on economics ... contains so little discussion of the central institution that
underlies neoclassical economics – the market.’
We build on the aforementioned studies by conceptualizing how context frames markets such that
exchange between two actors can be seen simultaneously as exchange within and among service
ecosystems, for example, and vice versa. This is important because exchanges across different
contexts together constitute markets. To this end, we propose a multi-level perspective of context that
is based on social network theory, economic sociology, and the general management literature. We
integrate this with the service-dominant logic perspective of value co-creation and markets.
We propose three levels of context – micro, meso, and macro – that coincide with fundamental
processes of value co-creation. By conceptualizing a layer – the meta layer – that ‘covers’ each of
these levels, it is more salient how these levels evolve simultaneously. We begin building this frame-
work by exploring the role of resources as articulated in various market and network theories. Then
we explain how the recently reframed role of service, as articulated in the service-dominant logic,
36 Marketing Theory 11(1)
pushes the notion of context to the forefront of marketing thought and theory. Based on this, we discuss
how context frames exchange by making salient the simultaneous, interactive processes at each level.
The service-dominant logic perspective
Service-dominant (S-D) logic (Vargo and Lusch, 2004a, 2008) represents a broader perspective
of markets compared with traditional perspectives of markets that focus on the exchange of
goods (referred to as goods-dominant, or G-D, logic). The S-D logic emphasis on service – the
application of resources for the benefit of other actors – looks beyond goods as the basis of eco-
nomic and social exchange. That is, S-D logic emphasizes knowledge and skills (operant
resources) as primary resources of economic and social exchange, as opposed to G-D logic,
which emphasizes physical resources (operand resources). Based on this, exchange processes
that integrate knowledge and skills are focal when viewing exchange as value co-creation. To
explorethismorefully,webeginwithareview and conceptual extension of the notions of
resource and service, each of which is detailed below.
Toward understanding resources in context
Marketing scholars have traditionally focused on goods as resources and, complementary to that
view, asserted marketing processes as supplemental to the core production processes of the firm
(Prahalad and Ramaswamy, 2004). In this sense, marketing processes are traditionally seen as
‘adding value’ to goods that are already inherently valuable. Most other similar resource con-
ceptualizations stem from the resource-based view of the firm in which resources are seen mostly
as goods ‘owned by the firm’ or as ‘inputs to production processes’ (Penrose, 1959; Barney, 1991;
Peteraf, 1993; Barney et al., 2001).
However, Hunt and Morgan (1995) begin to discuss resources as owned or accessible by
multiple actors. They further describe how actors seek access to resources and, as a result, interact
with one another to gain such access. Resources thus connect actors to one another (and vice versa)
and are valuable because of this. Together, the connected actors influence the ‘expansion and
contraction’ of a resource (Constantin and Lusch, 1994). Zimmerman (1951: 15) affirms that
resources ‘are not, they become; they are not static but expand and contract in response to human
actions.’ As a result, when disparate actors access resources that they do not own or unilaterally
control, they become connected because of their joint access to a resource.
For example brand knowledge refers to the differential effect of consumer response to a firm’s
marketing efforts with regard to an offering that is known or ‘branded’ (Keller, 1993). From
Zimmerman’s perspective, brand knowledge is a resource that evolves in response to the behaviors
of actors. Together, actors that maintain favorable, strong, and unique brand associations expand
the potential of brand knowledge as a resource, while actors that do not form favorable brand
associations contract the potential of brand knowledge as a resource. For most actors, brand
knowledge is a resource that cannot be controlled because it is neither owned nor is it unilaterally
controlled. As a resource, brand knowledge can provide, among other things, benefits such as
product familiarity, uncertainty reduction, or higher price premiums (for firms).
Actors further enhance or detract from brand knowledge as a resource when they partner or
build networks that center on a brand in communities (Mun
˜iz Jr and Schau, 2002) or in alliances
(Srivastava et al., 1998; Kotler and Pfoertsch, 2006; Pfoertsch et al., 2007). Accessible to these
types of groups are other externally-based resources such as shared information or knowledge that
Chandler and Vargo 37
can also be jointly influenced by multiple actors (Rindfleisch and Moorman, 2001). For example
actors can choose to build upon one another’s knowledge in either a collaborative or competitive
fashion (Johnson et al., 2004).
Each of these – brand or information – is an example of a resource that is externally-based and
dynamically determined in the context; that is, they are resources that cannot be owned or controlled
by a single actor. As such, they are resources that represent indirect exchange, or service-for-service
exchanges that occur through service intermediaries. Often, these service intermediaries take form
within institutions (e.g. monetary systems). In fact, various types of institutions can govern indirect
exchange; for example, ownership systems draw on property rights to facilitate exchange.
Because actors are traditionally emphasized as ‘owning’ resources, actors have traditionally
been viewed as separate and unique from the resources and contexts within which they are
embedded. But often, because of their past service efforts and also because of their rights to future
service (e.g., money), they become connected within these contexts to other resources and other
actors. For this reason, many scholars emphasize the use of governance mechanisms for managing
ownership, and thus control, of resources within their contexts (for example see Wathne and Heide,
2004). However, because of resources that cannot be uniquely owned or controlled, as discussed,
we further develop the emphasis of Ford and colleagues (2003) on actors themselves as resources
within a particular context. This refers to firms whose competences and connectedness to resources
can act as resources to other actors (Bagozzi, 1975; Achrol and Kotler, 1999; Kogut, 2000; White,
2002; Araujo and Easton, 2005). This occurs when, for example, actors indirectly connect actors
with other actors (Hakansson and Snehota, 1995; Gronroos, 2006; Gummesson, 2006).
An example of this might be a brand. For example if a college student is looking to do laundry
and is unfamiliar with laundry detergents, a familiar brand may serve as a resource because it
connects the student with a firm that is reputable for providing quality laundry detergent. Or, in
another example, two fans of a popular band (e.g. the Beatles) may become acquainted on a
website such as Facebook because they seek an association with the Beatles music brand. As a
result of their individual efforts, these actors come to be in one another’s contexts. Inadvertently,
through their individual efforts, they reciprocate benefit to one another. Their access to one another
is a fundamental aspect of how they resolve their situations because they draw upon one another as
resources (Wilkinson and Young, 2005).
How actors draw upon one another as resources is critically dependent on the contexts in which
they are embedded. For this reason, actors can be said to be partially defined by their contexts
while’their contexts can be said to be partially defined by them (the actors). In other words, actors
and’their contexts are mutually constitutive, or partially defined by one another (Giddens, 1979).
Each actor brings a unique quality to the context that affects other actors in the context, as well as
the’context as a whole. Because each actor in the context is always integrating and exchanging
resources with other actors and thereby serving other actors, there is continuous change in the
context.
This continuous change highlights a market fluidity that has been understudied in the man-
agement and marketing literature. The dynamic and living fluidity of markets is framed, or formed,
because of context. Contexts frame markets as interactions or exchanges that we can ‘‘see’’ and
‘understand’’. But essentially markets have no beginning or end; they are continuous. Contexts
give markets form and function in time and space, whereas markets themselves transcend time and
space because market exchanges simultaneously represent past and future service-for-service
exchanges among different actors. Markets are, in fact, simultaneous exchange – whether
exchange occurs between two people, among three companies, in New York, or on websites such
38 Marketing Theory 11(1)
as ebay.com. Markets exist when two people exchange, and markets exist when twenty countries
exchange. Markets exist in geographic spaces and virtual places. But the ability to place para-
meters on exchange occurs because of contexts.
This points to a fundamental need to differentiate among contexts. This is especially important
because actors may be drawn upon as resources in particular contexts, but act as deterrents in other
contexts. Simultaneously, a particular context may act as a resource for an individual actor but act
as a deterrent for a different actor (Emirbayer and Mische, 1998). In this way, resources ‘become’
resources largely as a function of the contexts in which they are embedded; that is, the potential of
resources to be drawn upon for service depends on the context in which they are embedded. And, as
a result, resources can be more valuable in one context, but less valuable in other contexts. How
context influences the value of a resource is one way through which contexts frame exchange and
the co-creation of markets.
Toward service in context
As described above, context influences value co-creation and markets through its influence on
resources. Context also influences value co-creation through its influence on service. This is dis-
cussed below.
One of the seminal works that addresses resources and service together within a context is
Theory of the Growth of the Firm, in which Penrose (1959) describes how resources yield services.
According to the Penrosian perspective, this occurs through many steps, the first of which is firms
competing for and acquiring resources. This process continues when resources are used to offer
‘service streams’ that ultimately fill and replace the context with service outputs. Service outputs
are then chosen from the context. To illustrate this further, consider two firms that competitively
seek coal to fuel their rail transportation systems. The amount of coal is limited, and the ability to
own and thereby control coal is seen as a fundamental driver of the firm’s service provision and,
ultimately, the firm’s performance. As a result of their varying ownership and control of coal, the
two transportation firms may offer heterogeneous service outputs, each of which become woven
together, along with other firms’ service outputs, into a context that is characterized by
competition.
This Penrosian emphasis on competition and its foundation on the competitive ownership of
goods has been the basis for many subsequent management and marketing studies that address
service and context together. To summarize, the Penrosian perspective articulates that successful
firms are those that own and control the resources that yield more service outputs in the context and
‘grow’ to dominate the context. Accordingly, the focus of Penrose was to write a Theory of the
Growth of the Firm that aimed to explain the growth of multinational corporations in the 1940s to
1950s, rather than to write a theory of service, context, and value creation.
Penrose did however advance the notion that resources are distinguishable from context
because they are bundles of potential service. Recent emphasis on service in marketing has
begun to examine this more deeply by focusing on service within particular contexts. Increas-
ingly, service has been viewed as a process, situated beyond traditional firm boundaries that links
actors together, that is ‘controlled bilaterally’ with other actors (Gadde et al., 2003: 359). Such
studies explain that, within each context, each actor serves other actors when it draws upon its
resources in its own context as a benefit (Kogut, 2000; White, 2002; Araujo and Easton, 2005).
That is, when different actors connect with one another, they ultimately join their different
networks together. The newly joined actors – through their service-for-service exchanges –
Chandler and Vargo 39
constitute a context, a phenomenon studied in new institutional economics (e.g. Menard, 1995);
the IMP Group (e.g. Hakansson and Snehota, 1995); the embeddedness of markets (e.g. Grano-
vetter, 1985; Collon, 1998); and the environment of exchange (Bagozzi 1975; Achrol et al.,
1983).
Extending this further, actors come to occupy unique positions in their contexts and, from those
positions, draw on resources for service-for-service exchanges, both direct and indirect. To
explain, consider two children at the same school who trade baseball cards at recess time. When
they return to their respective classrooms, they might trade the cards with the child seated to the left
side of their desks and then in turn trade again with the child to the right side of their desks. Each of
the children with whom they subsequently exchange may offer different ‘trades’ because of what
the child can access within his or her own unique network of exchanges. As a result, the two chil-
dren in the initial trade scenario may likely end up with unique exchange experiences, as well as a
very different combination of resources (e.g. baseball cards, candy, or stickers). The children, or
actors, differ in part because of the varied nature of their interactions, including direct exchanges
with children that are ‘close-by’ and indirect exchanges with their friends’ friends that are indirect
or ‘further away’ (Granovetter, 1985).
In this way, each actor’s context affects its ability to directly access and leverage resources, and
also affects its ability to indirectly access and leverage resources beyond its immediate context
(Uzzi, 1997). Stated differently, each actor’s service provision depends on its context. Each
instance of service, or each ‘unique application of uniquely integrated resources,’ is value creation
in a particular context that is enabled by direct and indirect access to various types of resources
(Lusch and Vargo, 2006: 284). Most important, as resources are drawn upon for service across
varying contexts, each context provides conditions ‘under which different resources will and will
not be valuable’ (Barney et al., 2001: 43). This is the focus of the following section.
Rethinking context
Given the discussion above, it is necessary to deepen our understanding of context. We begin by
acknowledging the heterogeneous and distinctive nature of context, and define a particular context
as a set of unique actors with unique reciprocal links among them (Wasserman and Faust, 1994;
Sheth and Uslay, 1997; Carrington et al., 2005). The ability to define context uniquely is important
because context heterogeneity affects how resources can be drawn upon for service.
As proposed in this framework, the notion of context and its influence on markets and exchange
draws heavily from the sociology of markets literature, as well as the social networks analysis
literature. Whereas the sociology of markets literature generally explores the emergence,
dynamics, and decline of markets, the social networks analysis literature generally advances the
methodology and theory of social structures (Fligstein and Dauter, 2007). Sociologists and
anthropologists consider the study of markets and exchange to be ‘one of the most vibrant fields’ in
the past 25 years, and have made significant progress in exploring context as the ‘origins, oper-
ations, and dynamics of markets as social structures’ (Fligstein and Dauter, 2007: 106). The
proposed conceptualization of context is thus based on work originating from sociology (Freeman,
1977; Granovetter, 1985; Friedkin, 1991; White, 2002); anthropology (Emirbayer and Mische,
1998; Nakano and White, 2008); and management (Uzzi, 1997; Uzzi and Lancaster, 2003).
Social network analysis, in particular, can assist in making salient the heterogeneous nature of
context (Wasserman and Faust, 1994) when it is viewed as a set of unique actors and unique
reciprocal links among them. Social networks analysis can help to precisely and formally specify
40 Marketing Theory 11(1)
service-for-service exchanges as reciprocal links among actors by representing them as either
sociograms, sociomatrices or algebraic equations (Wasserman and Faust, 1994). These representa-
tions are precisely and formally equivalent such that context can be explored empirically.
For empirical work, many network studies begin with qualitative approaches, including primary
data collection by way of participant observation or long interview techniques. But there are also
many network studies that are quantitative in nature, including agent-based modeling, predictive
modeling techniques, and survey-based research designs, as well as secondary data model estima-
tions and simulation techniques. Visualization is also a key aspect of social networks analysis
because it enables researchers to ‘see’ context and the scaleable influence of context within market
structures (Homan, 1950; Marsden, 1982).
By defining context as a unique set of actors and the unique reciprocal links among them, it is
possible to see how hundreds of actors and links may constitute one specific context, while two
actors and links may constitute another context. Understandably, resources and service in each of
these contexts will likely vary. Furthermore, these actors, links, and contexts are complex because
links between the two actors can affect other actors or links throughout the context and vice versa.
This occurs because every actor is itself connected to many other actors (Freeman, 1977; Barney
et al., 2001; Madhavaram and Hunt, 2008). As a result, direct service-for-service exchanges
between two actors may manifest in and influence indirect exchanges throughout and beyond a
particular context (McFarland et al., 2008).
To explore how this occurs, we propose a multi-level conceptualization of context based on
three levels: (1) micro level; (2) meso level; and (3) macro level (Kjellberg and Helgesson,
2006). Above each of these three levels, there is a meta layer that helps to make salient how these
levels evolve over time. Each level of context frames service-for-service exchange in a way that
informs value co-creation uniquely at that level (Dopfer et al., 2004; Andersson et al., 2008;
Storbacka et al., 2009). And the meta layer represents evolution of these levels, which occurs
simultaneously. Capturing these various aspects requires oscillating foci to each level or layer,
as shown in Figures 1 and 2. Each level is discussed below.
Micro-context: Framing exchange among actors as dyads
Context at the micro or individual level frames exchange as it occurs among individual actors. The
important process of exchange at this level is direct service-for-service exchange. That is, each
actor draws on its resources and competences to directly serve another actor. The context of this
service-for-service exchange is a dyad, which consists of two actors and the service-for-service
exchange between them. More important, this is a reciprocal dyad because both actors serve each
other, which is an important aspect of value co-creation because both actors are active participants
in the exchange process. This is shown in Figure 2a and on the first line of Figure 1: two unique
actors (aand b) are joined by a service-for-service exchange link (s).
Meso-context: Framing exchange among dyads as triads
Context at the meso level frames exchange as it occurs among dyads. The important process of
exchange at this level is the indirect service-for-service exchange that occurs between actor aand
actor c, as shown in Figure 2b and on the second line of Figure 1. As can be seen, actor bdirectly
serves both actors aand c(and vice versa), but actors aand cindirectly serve one another through
actor b. That is, actor bdirectly serves two of the actors, while the other actors indirectly serve each
other through their service of actor b. Stated differently, two actors indirectly serve one another by
Chandler and Vargo 41
Multi-Levels
of Context
Unit of
Analysis
Service-for-
Service
Exchange
Among
Context Revealed Through
Contextual Framing
of Exchange
Static
Micro-Context
Dyads Actors Direct Service-for-Service Exchange
(Freeman 1977, Barney et al. 2001,
Madhvaram and Hunt 2008)
Static
Meso-Context
Triads Dyads
Indirect Service-for-Service Exchange
-includes direct service
(Hakansson and Snehota 1995,
Gronroos 2006, Gummesson 2006)
Static
Macro-
Context
Complex
Networks
Triads Complex Service
-includes direct and indirect service
(Bagozzi 1975; Achrol and Kotler 1999,
Araujo and Easton 2005,
Kogut 2000, White 2002)
Dynamic
Meta-Layer:
Service
Ecosystems
(Giddens
1979,
DiMaggio
and Powell
1983)
Figure 1. How Context Frames Exchange
Figure 1. How Context Frames Exchange
42 Marketing Theory 11(1)
a) Example of Micro-Context Level: Dyad
b) Example of Meso-Context Level: Triad
c) Example of Macro-Context Level: Complex Network
d) Meta-Layer of Context: Service Ecosystems
b
a
Sa
b
Actor
--- Service-for-Service Exchange
c
Evolution/
Replication
Figure 2. Rethinking context
Chandler and Vargo 43
serving the same actor. The prototypical context of this service-for-service exchange is a triad.
More specifically, this is an intransitive triad because the three actors are not all directly connected,
which is important because it is not necessary for actors to be directly connected to serve one
another and co-create value.
Macro-context: Framing exchange among triads as ecosystems
Context at the macro level frames exchange as it occurs among triads. The important process of
exchange at this level is complex service, or the synergies of multiple simultaneous direct and
indirect service-for-service exchanges that enable actors to serve in a particular context, as shown
in Figure 2c and on the third line of Figure 1. Each triad draws on its resources and competences,
and applies them for a beneficiary in a particular context. The context of service-for-service
exchanges at the macro context is a complex network. More important, the notion of a complex
network is a fundamental aspect of value co-creation because of how actors, dyads, and triads cre-
ate synergy among multiple simultaneous direct and indirect service-for-service exchanges.
Layer of meta-context: Framing exchange among complex networks as service
ecosystems
Context at the meta-layer frames exchange as it occurs among complex networks. At the meta-
level, the notions of time and replication are introduced (Giddens, 1979). Specifically, practices,
routines, activities, or processes may be replicated at any of the three levels of context. Based
on this, the important process of exchange at this level is institutionalization, or the process by
which various networks of actors become legitimized (or delegitimized) with respect to larger soci-
etal systems (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983). Included within this notion is replication, especially of
institutions, which paradoxically creates dynamically changing contexts at the same time that it
also introduces stability to the system.
As shown in Figure 2d and Figure 1, this occurs when complex networks are sustained by the
reciprocal service provision of multiple actors, dyads, triads, and complex networks that are
accessing multiple resources. As shown in Figure 2, this is a complex multi-dimensional evolution
that occurs simultaneously in three dimensions: across levels of context, over time, and through
replication. When complex networks successfully institutionalize resources, they become joined
together as a service ecosystem, or ‘a spontaneously sensing and responding spatial and temporal
structure of largely loosely coupled value proposing social and economic actors’ interactions
through institutions and technology, to (1) co-produce service offerings; (2) exchange service
offerings; and (3) co-create value’ (Lusch et al., 2010: 31). In other words, the meta layer covers
all the levels of service-for-service exchanges such that they together constitute service ecosys-
tems. The notion of a service ecosystem is a fundamental aspect of value co-creation because it
acknowledges how large-scale social structures and institutions evolve relative to the individual
service efforts of actors, dyads, triads, and complex networks.
How context frames markets
As discussed, because every actor itself integrates resources through service-for-service exchanges
with other actors, the value creation space extends well beyond direct actor-to-actor exchanges
(i.e.’firm–firm interactions or firm–customer interactions). Service directly and indirectly joins
actors together as dyads, triads, and complex networks into service ecosystems such that direct
44 Marketing Theory 11(1)
individual exchanges occur at each level and simultaneously in the ‘context’ or meta layer of
networks-with-networks and networks-within-networks. The exchange processes and the resulting
links among actors constitute markets, but they transcend space and time. Context frames these pro-
cesses and links, and begins to clarify how resources and service contribute to value co-creation and
the co-creation of markets.
How exchange is framed by context is a fundamental aspect in the study of markets and
value co-creation that requires further exploration. Viewing exchange at each level, as
embedded in the context of the other levels, can be a fruitful area of inquiry. For example value
co-creation can be viewed from both an actor’s unique individual perspective within a dyad, as
well as from an omniscient general perspective of service ecosystems. The actor perspective can
only be understood from within the actor’s direct context, while the service ecosystem perspec-
tive can only be understood from an ominiscient general perspective. However, neither perspec-
tive is mutually exclusive; rather, each perspective occurs and must be understood in the
context of the other perspectives.
As a result, the service activities of an actor – that is, an actor’s individual value co-creation
efforts – are a function of its simultaneous embeddedness within multiple dyads, triads, complex
networks and service ecosystems. Stated somewhat differently, an actor’s ability to serve is a func-
tion of its unique context which includes the micro, meso, and macro levels – as well as the
dynamic meta layer. Context is multidimensional in that it is level-specific while being embedded
in successive levels that are of a temporal nature. In this sense, practices and transformations are
temporal replications of rules, or institutions, that facilitate exchange processes. Thus, context is
an’important dimension of value co-creation because it frames exchange, service, and the potenti-
ality of resources from the unique perspective of each actor, and from the unique omniscient
perspective of the entire service ecosystem. It is for this reason that Vargo and Lusch revised the
somewhat G-D logic-oriented concept of ‘value-in-use’ to a more S-D logic-friendly concept of
‘value-in-context’ (Vargo, 2009; Vargo et al., 2009).
Conclusion
The Market is simultaneous, continuous exchange, while Markets emerge from simultaneous,
continuous processes at different levels and layers of context. As described above, Figure 1
demonstrates that each level is nested among the other levels and together they simultaneously
evolve in the meta layer. The work here suggests that markets are created when actors, dyads,
triads, complex networks, and service ecosystems evolve through unique service provision efforts.
Context frames these processes. This has been more broadly studied as the co-creation of markets.
The ability to deal with time (forward and backward) conceptually appears to be a unique
human trait that allows humans to evolve as a species not only through biological replication, but
also through conceptual or institutional replication. This occurs because humans are able to
integrate the past and present with the future. Further research is needed to distinguish empirically
among these levels and layers, and also to relate them more explicitly to one another.
The definition and measurement of value processes according to this framework requires further
empirical research. The micro level, meso level, macro level, and meta layer evolve in response to
and in synchronization with one another, but the evolutionary reactions may be different at each
level. Empirical research is needed, for example, to establish how triad counts (Skvoretz and Faust,
1999) can answer value-related questions from a marketing perspective: Which types of triads are
more prevalent in specific contexts? Why do these triads persist in these specific contexts? How
Chandler and Vargo 45
does the conceptualization of markets change when reciprocity is introduced at the complex
network level or at the dyadic level?
Most useful in this framework is the absence of the dichotomy between firms and their
‘customers’, which is replaced with a collective conceptualization of actor based on resources,
service efforts, and contexts (Vargo and Lusch 2011). This allows marketing scholars to think
more deeply about the interrelationships among different types of actors, along different levels and
layers of context – and relate them to one another within a unified framework. Such a framework
lays foundation for service-for-service exchange as the basis for a systems perspective of markets.
Within this, the notion of reciprocal service-as-resources-applied-for-benefit offers insight on
notions of power, ownership, control, and property rights in modern-day markets. Many actors
involved in service-for-service exchange have been understudied in their collective influence on
markets, marketing, and marketing theory.
Put simply, individual actors pursue value through service-for-service exchanges that are the
basis of dyads, triads, complex networks, and service ecosystems. Markets are simply collections
of individual actors reconciling tensions in their direct contexts with respect to indirect forces from
overlapping complex networks. Over time, these can be viewed as service ecosystems, within
which value lies at the tensions of micro and macro pulls. It is because of a need to reconcile these
tensions that markets evolve.
References
Achrol, R. and Kotler, P. (1999) ‘Marketing in the Network Economy’, Journal of Marketing 63 (2): 146–63.
Achrol, R.S., Reve, T. and Stern, L.W. (1983) ‘The Environment of Marketing Channel Dyads –
A’Framework for Comparative-Analysis’, Journal of Marketing 47(4): 55–67.
Andersson, P., Aspenberg, K. and Kjellberg, H. (2008) ‘The Configuration of Actors in Market Practice’,
Marketing Theory 8(1): 67–80.
Araujo, L. and Easton, G. (2005) ‘Investments, Positions and Strategy from a Network Perspective’, in
P.’Andersson, S. Hertz and S. Sweet (eds) Perspectives on Market Networks – Boundaries and New
Connection. Stockholm: Economic Research Institute.
Bagozzi, R. (1975) ‘Marketing as Exchange’, Journal of Marketing 39(4): 32–9.
Barney, J. (1991) ‘Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage’, Journal of Management 17: 99–120.
Barney, J., Wright, M. and Ketchen, D. Jr (2001) ‘Resource-based Theories of Competitive Advantage:
A’Ten-year Retrospective on the Resource-based View’, Journal of Management 27(6): 643–50.
Burt, R.S. (1992) Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Carrington, P.J., Scott, J. and Wasserman, S. (2005) Models and Methods in Social Network Analysis.
Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Collon, M. (ed.) (1998) The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell.
Constantin, J. and Lusch, R.F. (1994) Understanding Resource Management. Burr Ridge, IL: Irwin
Professional.
DiMaggio, P.J. and Powell, W.W. (1983) ‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective
Rationality in Organizational Fields’, American Sociological Review 48: 147–60.
Dopfer, K., Foster, J. and Potts, J. (2004) ‘Micro-Meso-Macro’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics14: 263–79.
Emirbayer, M. and Mische, A. (1998) ‘What is Agency?’, American Journal of Sociology 103(4): 962–1023.
Fligstein, N. and Dauter, L. (2007) ‘The Sociology of Markets’, Annual Review of Sociology 33: 105–28.
Ford, I.D., Gadde, L.E., Hakansson, H. and Snehota, I. (2003) Managing Business Networks. Chichester: John
Wiley & Sons.
Freeman, L.C. (1977) ‘Set of Measures of Centrality Based on Betweenness’, Sociometry 40(1): 35–41.
46 Marketing Theory 11(1)
Friedkin, N.E. (1991) ‘Theoretical Foundations for Centrality Measures’, American Journal of Sociology
96(6): 1478–504.
Gadde, L., Huemer, L. and Hakansson, H. (2003) ‘Strategizing in Industrial Networks’, Industrial Marketing
Management 32: 357–64.
Giddens, A. (1979) Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure and Contradiction in Social
Analysis. Berkeley and Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press.
Granovetter, M. (1973) ‘The Strength of Weak Ties’, American Journal of Sociology 78(6): 1360–80.
Granovetter, M. (1985) ‘Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness’, American
Journal of Sociology 91(3): 481–99.
Gronroos, C. (2006) What Can Service Logic Offer Marketing Theory?’, in R. F. Lusch and S. L Vargo (eds)
The Service-dominant Logic of Marketing: Dialog, Debate, and Directions, pp. 354–64. Armonk, NY:
M.E. Sharpe.
Gummesson, E. (2006) Many-to-Many Marketing as Grand Theory: A Nordic School Contribution, in
R.’F.’Lusch and S. L. Vargo (eds) The Service-dominant Logic of Marketing: Dialog, Debate, and Direc-
tions, pp. 339–53. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Hakansson, H. and Snehota, I. (eds) (1995) Developing Relationships in Business Networks. London:
Routledge.
Homan, G. (1950) The Human Group. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Co.
Hunt, S. (1991) Modern Marketing Theory:Critical Issues in the Philosophy of Marketing Science.
Cincinnati, OH: South-Western Publishing.
Hunt, S. and Morgan, R. (1995) ‘The Comparative Advantage Theory of Competition’, Journal of Marketing
59(April): 1–15.
Hunt, S.D. (2000) A General Theory of Competition: Resources, Competences, Productivity, and Economic
Growth. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Johnson, J., Sohi, R.S. and Grewal, R. (2004) ‘The Role of Relational Knowledge Stores in Interfirm Part-
nering’, Journal of Marketing 68(July): 21–36.
Keller, K.L. (1993) ‘Conceptualizing, Measuring and Managing Customer-based Brand Equity’, Journal of
Marketing 57(1): 1–22.
Kjellberg, H. and Helgesson, C-F. (2006) ‘Multiple Versions of Markets: Multiplicity and Performativity in
Market Practice’, Industrial Marketing Management 35(7): 839–55.
Kogut, B. (2000) ‘The Network as Knowledge: Generative Rules and the Emergence of Structure’, Strategic
Management Journal 21: 405–25.
Kotler, P. and Pfoertsch, W. ( 2006) B2B Brand Management. New York: Springer.
Kotler, P. and Pfoertsch, W. (2007) ‘Being Known or Being One of Many’, Journal of Business and Industrial
Marketing 22(6): 357–62.
Lusch, R.F. and Vargo, S.L. (2006) The Service-dominant Logic of Marketing: Dialog, Debate, and Direc-
tions. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Lusch, R., Vargo, S. and Tanniru, M. (2010) ‘Service, Value Networks and Learning’, Journal of the Aca-
damy of Marketing Science 38(1): 19–31.
McFarland, R., Bloodgood, J. and Payan, J. (2008) ‘Supply Chain Contagion’, Journal of Marketing 72(2):
63–79.
Madhavaram, S. and Hunt, S. (2008) ‘The Service Dominant Logic and a Hierarchy of Operant Resources:
Developing Masterful Operant Resources and Implications for Marketing Strategy’, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science 36: 67–82.
Marsden, P.V. (1982) ‘Brokerage Behavior in Restricted Exchange Networks’, in P. V. Marsden and
N.’Lin’(eds) Social Structure and Network Analysis. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Menard, C. (1995) ‘Markets as Institutions, versus Organizations as Markets? Disentangling Some Funda-
mental Concepts’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 28: 161–82.
Mun
˜iz, A.M. Jr and Schau, H.J. (2005) ‘Religiosity in the Abandoned Apple Newton Brand Community’,
Journal of Consumer Research 31(March): 737–47.
Chandler and Vargo 47
Nakano, T. and White, D.R. (2008) ‘The ‘‘Visible Hand’’ in a Production-chain Market: A Market Equilibrium
from Network Analytical Perspective’, Working Paper, Irvine, CA: University of California Press.
Normann, R. (2001) Reframing Business: When the Map Changes the Landscape. Chichester: Wiley.
North, D.C. (1977) ‘Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The Challenge of Karl Polanyi’,
Journal of Euopean Economic History 6: 703–16.
Penrose, E. (1959) The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: John Wiley.
Peteraf, M.A. (1993) ‘The Cornerstones of Competitive Advantage: A Resource-based View’, Strategic
Management Journal 14(3): 179–91.
Pfoertsch, W., Linder, C. and Chandler, J. (2007) ‘Measuring the Value of Ingredient Brand Equity at Multiple
Stages in the Supply Chain: A Component Supplier’s Perspective’, Interdisciplinary Management Research
4: 571 – 94.
Prahalad, C.K and Ramaswamy, V. (2004) ‘Co-creation Experiences: The Next Practice in Value Creation’,
Journal of Interactive Marketing 18(3): 5–14.
Rindfleisch, A. and Moorman, C. (2001) ‘The Acquisition and Utilization of Information in New Product
Alliances: A Strength-of-Ties Perspective’, Journal of Marketing 65(April): 1–18.
Sheth, J. and Uslay, C. (2007) ‘Implication of the Revised Definition of Marketing: from Exchange to Value
Creation’, Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 26(2): 302– 7.
Skvoretz, J. and Faust, K. (1999) ‘Logit Models for Affiliate Networks’, Sociological Methodology 29(1):
253–80.
Srivastava, R., Shervani, T. and Fahey, L. (1998) ‘Market-based Assets and Shareholder Value: A Framework
for Analysis’, Journal of Marketing 62(1): 2–18.
Storbacka, K., Nenonen, S. and Korkman, O. (2009) ‘Markets as Configurations: A Research Agenda for
Co-created Markets’, Working Paper, Breukelen (Netherlands): Nyenrode Business Universiteit.
Uzzi, B. (1997) ‘Social Structure and Competition in Interfirm Networks: The Paradox of Embeddedness’,
Administrative Science Quarterly 42(3): 35–67.
Uzzi, B. and Lancaster, R. (2003) ‘Relational Embeddedness and Learning: The Case of Bank Loan Managers
and Their Clients’, Management Science 49(4): 383– 99.
Vargo, S.L. (2007) ‘On a Theory of Markets and Marketing: From Positively Normative to Normatively
Positive’, Australasian Marketing Journal 15(1): 53–60.
Vargo, S.L. (2009) ‘Toward a Transcending Conceptualization of Relationship: A Service-dominant Logic
Perspective’, Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing 24(5): 373–78.
Vargo, S.L. and Lusch, R.L. (2004a) ‘Evolving to a New Dominant Logic for Marketing’, Journal of
Marketing 68(1): 1–17.
Vargo, S.L. and Lusch, R.L. (2004b) ‘The Four Services Marketing Myths: Remnants from a Manufacturing
Model’, Journal of Service Research (May): 324–35.
Vargo, S.L. and Lusch, R.L. (2008) ‘Service-dominant Logic: Continuing the Evolution’, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science 36(1): 1–12.
Vargo, Stephen L. and Robert F. Lusch (2011), ‘‘It’s all B2B and Beyond ...: Toward a Systems Perspective
of the Market,’’ Industrial Marketing Management, 40 (2) 181–187.
Vargo, S.L., Lusch, R.L., Akaka, M.A. and He, Y. (2009) Service-dominant Logic: A Review and Assess-
ment, Review of Marketing Research (in press).
Venkatesh, A., Penaloza, L. and Firat, A.F. (2006) ‘The Marketing as a Sign System and the Logic of the
Market’, in R. F. Lusch and S. L. Vargo (eds) The Service-dominant Logic of Marketing: Dialog, Debate,
and Directions, pp. 251–65. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
Wasserman, S. and Faust, K. (1994) Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Wathne, K. and Heide, J. (2004) ‘Relationship Governance in a Supply Chain Network’, Journal of Marketing
68(1): 73–89.
Webster, F.E. Jr (1992) ‘The Changing Role of Marketing in the Corporation’, Journal of Marketing
56(October): 1–17.
48 Marketing Theory 11(1)
White, H. (2002) ‘Businesses Mobilize Production through Markets: Parametric Modeling of Path-dependent
Outcomes in Oriented Network Flows’, Complexity 8(1): 87–95.
Wilkinson, I. and Young, L. (2005) ‘A Planning Framework for Relationship and Network Management’, in
P. Andersson, S. Hertz and S. Sweet (eds) Perspectives on Market Networks – Boundaries and New
Connections. Stockholm: Economic Research Institute.
Zimmerman, E.W. (1972) World Resources and Industries: A Functional Appraisal of the Availability of
Agricultural and Industrial Materials. New York: Harper & Row.
Zuboff, S. and Maxmin, J. (2002) The Support Economy. New York: Penguin.
Jennifer D. Chandler is an Assistant Professor at the University of Hawaii at Manoa Shidler College of Busi-
ness. She holds a BA from UCLA, an MBA from the University of Hawaii, and a PhD from the University of
California, Irvine. Before entering academia, Dr Chandler had a successful career in international marketing
and advertising. After working with media giants Clear Channel Communications and Raycom Media, she
began her own marketing agency working across various sectors including retailing, tourism, nonprofit, enter-
tainment, and manufacturing. Dr Chandler’s research interests include social networks analysis, strategy, ser-
vice, international marketing, organizational buying, business markets, design and collaborative innovation.
She takes a multi-method research approach that combines qualitative research and predictive modeling, as
based on resource-based theory and structuration theory. Dr. Chandler enjoys teaching and playing piano, is
an avid shopper, and is currently training for her first triathlon. Address: Shidler College of Business, Uni-
versity of Hawaii at Manoa, 2500 Campus Road, Honolulu, HI 96822. [email: jenc@hawaii.edu]
Stephen L. Vargo is a Shidler Distinguished Professor and Professor of Marketing at the University of
Hawai’i at Manoa. His primary research areas are marketing theory and thought and consumers’ evaluative
reference scales. He has had articles published in the Journal of Marketing, the Journal of the Academy of
Marketing Science, the Journal of Service Research, and other major marketing journals; he serves on six
editorial review boards, including the Journal of Marketing,Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science,
and the Journal of Service Research. Professor Vargo has been awarded the Harold H. Maynard Award by
the American Marketing Association for ‘significant contribution to marketing theory and thought.’ Address:
Shidler College of Business, University of Hawaii at Manoa, 2500 Campus Road, Honolulu, HI 96822.
[email: svargo@hawaii.edu]
Chandler and Vargo 49
... The study viewpoint is that sharing economy businesses (that we consider Snapp company in this research) should attention to the actors involved, lead to loyalty through service ecosystem perspective and, at the same time, communicate logically among them. Furthermore, since individuals do not provide value, it is essential to focus on the components based on the service ecosystem levels (Chandler and Vargo, 2011;Haase and Pick, 2015;Leung et al., 2019;Lusch and Vargo, 2014). This paper contributes to growing research on modeling customer loyalty in a sharing economy context through a service ecosystem perspective. ...
... This study is based on prior research mentioned by Lusch and Nambisan (2015), suggesting that the service ecosystem needs to develop a "shared worldview" among its actors in levels. While the microsystems' components focus on individuals, the mesosystems' components account for collective, intersections, or individual relationships (Chandler and Vargo, 2011;Leung et al., 2019). The relationships show the connections among components, contributing to customer loyalty in a sharing economy context through service ecosystem perspective. ...
Article
Understanding customers' behavioral components in sharing economy platforms is vital to policy-makers and marketers. Concerning behavioral components such as commitment, attitude, and trust, which lead to customer loyalty in sharing economy platforms, has less addressed. This paper aims to investigate/examine customers' behavioral components, increasing customer loyalty in sharing economy context through the service ecosystem. Data were collected from 405 respondents who have used a sharing economy platform through a semi-structured questionnaire and were analyzed using structural equation modeling. Behavioral components such as customers' attitudes, trust, and commitment lead to customer loyalty in a sharing economy platform. Moreover, the results revealed the positive moderating effect of trust perception and attitude towards using the platform on customers' loyalty. This paper contributes to growing research on modeling customer loyalty in a sharing economy context through a service ecosystem perspective and investigating each level, which has been seen as limited in previous research.
... Drawing from these foundational concepts, value creation transcends simple bilateral exchanges, necessitating a more comprehensive array of resources and the involvement of multiple actors within an intricate network (Normann and Ramirez 1993). The notion of micro-exchange within these vast ecosystems suggests that customers and providers represent just a fraction of the entire network, including numerous actors engaging in reciprocal resource exchange to create value (Chandler and Vargo 2011). Such complex dynamics require a level of coordination facilitated by endogenously created institutionscomprising rules, norms, symbols, and practices that aid collaboration-and institutional arrangements (Elo et al. 2024), which are interdependent collections of these institutions, manifesting even at a societal scale (Meynhardt et al. 2016). ...
... In such institutional technology-enabled networks, actors, including competitors, might choose to collaborate for mutual benefits, showcasing the voluntary nature of cooperation even among rivals (Chandler and Vargo 2011;. The deployment of both operant and operand technologies facilitates this co-operation through resource liquefaction and enhanced resource density, further cementing the institutionalization of networks into fully fledged service ecosystems (Lusch and Nambisan 2015;Jaakkola et al. 2024). ...
Article
Full-text available
In our rapidly globalizing and digitizing world, small and medium-sized manufacturing enterprises (SMEs) face significant challenges that compel them to adopt a co-opetition strategy—a blend of competition and collaboration. Despite their potential benefits, the high failure rates and unmet expectations of co-opetition networks highlight a significant gap in the empirical frameworks for establishing and maintaining these networks. This research seeks to address these gaps by developing a framework that enhances value cocreation in the Portuguese ornamental stone sector, integrating the latest developments in the Industrial Internet of Things (IIoT), Service-Dominant Logic (S-D Logic), and service science. Question: How can a framework integrating IIoT, S-D Logic, and service science enhance value cocreation and manage co-opetition among SMEs in the Portuguese ornamental stone sector? Methods: Theoretical insights and practical applications were synthesized to develop and validate a comprehensive co-opetition framework. This framework was tested through an experimental pilot project in the Portuguese ornamental stone sector, leveraging IIoT. Results: The implementation of the framework demonstrated significant operational efficiency, including enhanced performance, reduced production variance, and better resource utilization, indicating that integrating IIoT within co-opetition networks can effectively support SMEs. Conclusions: This study confirms the transformative impact of embedding IIoT in co-opetition networks, offering a replicable and scalable framework for other sectors. This framework addresses the empirical gap and aligns with broader socio-economic goals, setting the stage for further research into its applicability and potential across diverse industrial environments.
... At the macro level, multiple action development dynamics are reflected in the shared value created by action as a new resource, to reconceptualize the changed context, thus facilitating the transformation from community to the commonwealth. At the micro level, there is a need to amplify the focal design process (Chandler & Vargo, 2011;Manas, 2018), focusing on resources that play value in the actual context, continuously including people and knowledge from real-life experiences, avoiding innovation efforts that deviate from the user's context perception, and attracting new youth to the action. ...
... Manufacturing servitization transformation occurs not only in manufacturing firms but also involves their customers, suppliers, partners, and even competitors [2]. To better understand the value creation process behind servitization, an integration of the roles and relationships of the various players involved is needed [25]. Kohtamäki considered value co-creation by firms and their customers in the context of servitization [26]. ...
Article
Full-text available
With the increasingly fierce market competition, customers’ needs are gradually becoming more complicated, specialized, customized, and personalized. How manufacturing enterprises adopt innovation strategies to achieve value-added products as well as value co-creation with customers is an important initiative for enterprises to maintain differentiated advantages in market competition. Therefore, the creation of service value has gradually become more and more important. The related research on manufacturing servitization has attracted extensive attention in recent years. Manufacturing servitization is the evolution process of manufacturing enterprises gradually from product-dominant logic to service-dominant logic. The purpose of this study is to explore the dynamic evolution of manufacturing servitization from the perspective of innovation strategy and analyze the dynamic evolution mechanism. This study shows the latest research progress of theories related to manufacturing servitization and lays the theoretical foundation for research on the mechanism of the dynamic evolution of manufacturing servitization. This study proposes a three-stage dynamic evolution model of manufacturing servitization: product production, technological innovation, and service innovation. This study primarily employs the research methods of model construction and computer simulation. Based on the Nelson–Winter model, this study establishes a decision model for manufacturing servitization innovation strategy. This study conducts a computer simulation study on the dynamic evolution of manufacturing servitization from the perspective of innovation strategy and draws conclusions. This study is of great significance for manufacturing enterprises in making appropriate service-oriented innovation strategy decisions in the context of the service-oriented transformation occurring widely in the manufacturing industry.
... Examining the cluster branding through its nested interactions and could provide insights and a better understanding of how and why place branding in clusters occurs. These levels can be micro, meso and macro level (Chandler and Vargo, 2011). In the case of cluster brands, the micro level refers to interaction at the level of the individual firms with their direct customers (dyadic exchange). ...
Book
Full-text available
This book results from a PhD workshop held in Aix-en-Provence in June 2023. The workshop was organized conjointly by Aix-Marseille Université (France), the Université de Lausanne (Switzerland), and the Université libre de Bruxelles (Belgium). It provided PhD students from all over Europe with a great opportunity to present their thesis’ projects or their most recent papers. A special session, focusing specifically on place branding and marketing, gathered six contributions. These contributions then received particular attention from supervisors from all three universities, and underwent a revision process. They form the chapters presented in this book. The book consists in three parts: 1) emerging trends in place branding, especially in cities; 2) a focus on the dynamics that characterize the relationships between actors of a city or region; and 3) attractiveness for residents and tourists (especially when places are used as filming locations). The first part relates to a global phenomenon to which cities cannot escape: the general path towards sustainable transition in many places around the world. Numerous cities are participating in the development of a more sustainable planet. Sustainability is typically seen as a “catch-all” term, that covers many dimensions. Here, the two chapters dedicated to new trends in place branding, that accompany this transition to more sustainable places, focus on two main aspects: being “green” and “inclusive”.
... 3. In the intervening years, the micro-macro dichotomy has been replaced by multilevel analyses in many disciplines or approaches, including macromarketing studies (e.g., Akaka et al. 2023;Chandler and Vargo 2011;Domegan et al. 2020;Haase and Becker 2020;Hyman, Kostyk, and Shabbir 2021;Layton 2016;Saatcioglu and Corus 2019). 4. It is fair to say that the marketing systems approach has evolved through the work of Roger Layton (Shultz 2012) and others. ...
Article
Full-text available
Pressing global problems place demands on scientific communities in terms of responsibility and accountability that require a discipline to make use of its capacity to act and the policies that can be developed on the basis of scientific knowledge. With a particular focus on values, the paper examines four areas or dimensions that determine the scope for action in the scientific context and thus influence the way in which scientific communities can assume responsibility. The analysis is based on a model rooted in the values-in-science literature, which specifies steering, doing, using, and managing science as the main scientific processes in which values can relate to science. Using the example of the intra-disciplinary division between macromarketing and micromarketing, the paper compares scientific processes in a world given by the nexus of knowledge, action, and values with a world in which values are primarily seen as a threat to science. Against this background, the preconditions for a proper positioning of the marketing discipline and marketing policy are explained.
Article
The concept of public service ecosystem is gaining much interest in discourses concerning value co-destruction in public service delivery. We adopt public service ecosystem as a perspective to view value co-destruction within infrastructure industry through misintegration of resources. To us, value destruction represents a decline in individual, organizational or societal well-being. Our research identifies hybridity, temporality, interconnectedness, and interdependence as pivotal characteristics of the public service ecosystem leading to misintegration of resources. We argue that mitigating value co-destruction requires a focus on institutional arrangements, structures, and incentives to align value creation processes and bridge gaps in the public service ecosystem
Article
Full-text available
Building on the ontology of evolutionary realism recently proposed by Dopfer and Potts (forthcoming), we develop an analytical framework for evolutionary economics with a micro-meso-macro architecture. The motive for reconception is to make clear the highly complex and emergent nature of existence and change in economic evolution. For us, the central insight is that an economic system is a population of rules, a structure of rules, and a process of rules. The economic system is a rule-system contained in what we call the meso. From the evolutionary perspective, one cannot directly sum micro into macro. Instead, we conceive of an economic system as a set of meso units, where each meso consists of a rule and its population of actualizations. The proper analytical structure of evolutionary economics is in terms of micro-meso-macro. Micro refers to the individual carriers of rules and the systems they organize, and macro consists of the population structure of systems of meso. Micro structure is between the elements of the meso, and macro structure is between meso elements. The upshot is an ontologically coherent framework for analysis of economic evolution as change in the meso domain - in the form of what we call a meso trajectory - and a way of understanding the micro-processes and macro-consequences involved. We believe that the micro-meso-macro analytical framework can greatly enhance the focus, clarity, and, ultimately, power, of evolutionary economic theory. Copyright Springer-Verlag Berlin/Heidelberg 2004
Article
Full-text available
This research explores the grassroots brand community centered on the Apple Newton, a product that was abandoned by the marketer. Supernatural, religious, and magical motifs are common in the narratives of the Newton community, including the miraculous performance and survival of the brand, as well as the return of the brand creator. These motifs invest the brand with powerful meanings and perpetuate the brand and the community, its values, and its beliefs. These motifs also reflect and facilitate the many transformative and emancipatory aspects of consuming this brand. Our findings reveal important properties of brand communities and, at a deeper level, speak to the communal nature of religion and the enduring human need for religious affiliation.
Article
Full-text available
Marketing inherited a model of exchange from economics, which had a dominant logic based on the exchange of “goods,” which usually are manufactured output. The dominant logic focused on tangible resources, embedded value, and transactions. Over the past several decades, new perspectives have emerged that have a revised logic focused on intangible resources, the cocreation of value, and relationships. The authors believe that the new per- spectives are converging to form a new dominant logic for marketing, one in which service provision rather than goods is fundamental to economic exchange. The authors explore this evolving logic and the corresponding shift in perspective for marketing scholars, marketing practitioners, and marketing educators.
Article
Full-text available
Since the introductory article for what has become known as the “service-dominant (S-D) logic of marketing,” “Evolving to a New Dominant Logic for Marketing,” was published in the Journal of Marketing (Vargo, S. L., & Lusch, R. F. (2004a)), there has been considerable discussion and elaboration of its specifics. This article highlights and clarifies the salient issues associated with S-D logic and updates the original foundational premises (FPs) and adds an FP. Directions for future work are also discussed. KeywordsService-dominant logic-New-dominant logic-Service
Article
The authors develop a conceptual framework of the marketing–finance interface and discuss its implications for the theory and practice of marketing. The framework proposes that marketing is concerned with the task of developing and managing market-based assets, or assets that arise from the commingling of the firm with entities in its external environment. Examples of market-based assets include customer relationships, channel relationships, and partner relationships. Market-based assets, in turn, increase shareholder value by accelerating and enhancing cash flows, lowering the volatility and vulnerability of cash flows, and increasing the residual value of cash flows.
Article
The imputation problem is how to account for the sources of the value of the firm. I propose that part of the value of the firm derives from its participation in a network that emerges from the operation of generative rules that instruct the decision to cooperate. Whereas the value of firm-level capabilities is coincidental with the firm as the unit of accrual, ownership claims to the value of coordination in a network pit firms potentially in opposition with one another. We analyze the work on network structure to suggest two types of mechanisms by which rents are distributed. This approach is applied to an analysis of the Toyota Production System to show how a network emerged, the rents were divided to support network capabilities, and capabilities were transferred to the United States. Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Article
Understanding sources of sustained competitive advantage has become a major area of research in strategic management. Building on the assumptions that strategic resources are heterogeneously distributed across firms and that these differences are stable over time, this article examines the link between firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Four empirical indicators of the potential of firm resources to generate sustained competitive advantage-value, rareness, imitability, and substitutability are discussed. The model is applied by analyzing the potential of several firm resources for generating sustained competitive advantages. The article concludes by examining implications of this firm resource model of sustained competitive advantage for other business disciplines.
Article
The author presents a conceptual model of brand equity from the perspective of the individual consumer. Customer-based brand equity is defined as the differential effect of brand knowledge on consumer response to the marketing of the brand. A brand is said to have positive (negative) customer-based brand equity when consumers react more (less) favorably to an element of the marketing mix for the brand than they do to the same marketing mix element when it is attributed to a fictitiously named or unnamed version of the product or service. Brand knowledge is conceptualized according to an associative network memory model in terms of two components, brand awareness and brand image (i. e., a set of brand associations). Customer-based brand equity occurs when the consumer is familiar with the brand and holds some favorable, strong, and unique brand associations in memory. Issues in building, measuring, and managing customer-based brand equity are discussed, as well as areas for future research.