ArticlePDF Available

Technological Acquisitions and the Innovation Performance of Acquiring Firms: A Longitudinal Study

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper examines the impact of acquisitions on the subsequent innovation performance of acquiring firms in the chemicals industry. We distinguish between technological acquisitions, acquisitions in which technology is a component of the acquired firm's assets, and nontechnological acquisitions: acquisitions that do not involve a technological component. We develop a framework relating acquisitions to firm innovation performance and develop a set of measures for quantifying the technological inputs a firm obtains through acquisitions. We find that within technological acquisitions absolute size of the acquired knowledge base enhances innovation performance, while relative size of the acquired knowledge base reduces innovation output. The relatedness of acquired and acquiring knowledge bases has a nonlinear impact on innovation output. Nontechnological acquisitions do not have a significant effect on subsequent innovation output. Copyright © 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
TECHNOLOGICAL ACQUISITIONS AND THE
INNOVATION PERFORMANCE OF ACQUIRING
FIRMS: A LONGITUDINAL STUDY
GAUTAM AHUJA
1
* and RIITTA KATILA
2
1
College of Business Administration, University of Texas at Austin, Austin,
Texas, U.S.A.
2
Robert H. Smith School of Business, University of Maryland, College Park, Mary-
land, U.S.A.
This paper examines the impact of acquisitions on the subsequent innovation performance of
acquiring firms in the chemicals industry. We distinguish between technological acquisitions,
acquisitions in which technology is a component of the acquired firm’s assets, and nontechnologi-
cal acquisitions: acquisitions that do not involve a technological component. We develop a
framework relating acquisitions to firm innovation performance and develop a set of measures
for quantifying the technological inputs a firm obtains through acquisitions. We find that within
technological acquisitions absolute size of the acquired knowledge base enhances innovation
performance, while relative size of the acquired knowledge base reduces innovation output.
The relatedness of acquired and acquiring knowledge bases has a nonlinear impact on
innovation output. Nontechnological acquisitions do not have a significant effect on subsequent
innovation output. Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
In this paper we examine the impact of acqui-
sitions on the subsequent innovation performance
of acquiring firms. Studying the impact of acqui-
sitions on postacquisition innovation performance
is important from at least three perspectives. First,
this evaluation is important from the perspective
of organizational learning and innovation, and
helps us understand how organizations absorb and
use external knowledge. Firm-level theories of
technical change suggest that a firm’s inno-
vativeness is an outcome of increases in its
knowledge base (Griliches, 1984, 1990; Pakes
and Griliches, 1984; Henderson and Cockburn,
1996). While a firm’s knowledge base can grow
through a series of knowledge-enhancing invest-
ments by the company over time, firms can also
grow their knowledge through acquiring or ‘graft-
ing’ of external knowledge bases (Cohen and
Levinthal, 1989; Huber, 1991). Interestingly,
Key words: innovation; acquisitions; knowledge
*Correspondence to: Gautam Ahuja, College of Business
Administration, University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX
78712-1174, U.S.A.
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Received 27 August 1998
Final revision received 12 October 2000
while the relationship between firms’ investments
in knowledge and their innovation output has
been studied extensively (Hall, Griliches and
Hausman, 1986; Griliches, 1990), relatively little
research has focused on the role of acquisitions
in growing the firm’s knowledge base (Granstrand
and Sjolander, 1990; Huber, 1991; Gerpott, 1995).
This lacuna is all the more surprising given find-
ings which indicate that obtaining technological
know-how and developing technical capabilities
are increasingly important motives for acqui-
sitions (Link, 1988; Granstrand et al., 1992;
Chakrabarti, Hauschildt, and Suverkrup, 1994;
Wysocki, 1997a, 1997b).
Scholars studying the market for corporate con-
trol have also examined the relationship between
acquisitions and innovation output (Hitt et al.,
1991, 1996; Hoskisson, Hitt, and Ireland, 1994).
However, in contrast to the findings of the inno-
vation literature, studies in the corporate control
tradition have generally found that acquisitions
have a negative impact on the postacquisition
innovation output of acquiring firms. Agency
problems, reduction in managerial commitment to
198 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
innovation, and the absorption of managerial
energy in the acquisition integration process at
the expense of routine management have been
posited as possible explanations for these results
(Hitt et al., 1991, 1996). This conclusion, how-
ever, is puzzling since acquisitions continue to
be a popular strategy for corporate growth. In
recent years more dollars have been invested in
acquisition activity than in any other equivalent
time period in history (Curry, 1997). Evaluating
the postacquisition innovation output of acquiring
firms provides one indicator, albeit an indirect
one, of the returns to corporate investments in
acquisition activity.
A third reason for studying the impact of acqui-
sitions on the postacquisition performance of
acquiring firms comes from the growing literature
on the resource-based view of the firm. According
to this perspective acquisitions are an important
part of the business process of redeploying
resources into more productive uses (Anand and
Singh, 1997; Capron, Dussauge, and Mitchell,
1998; Capron, Mitchell, and Swaminathan, 1998).
Through acquisitions firm-specific assets housed
within one organization are merged with assets
in another organization to improve the productiv-
ity of the combined assets (Haspeslagh and Jemi-
son, 1991; Anand and Singh, 1997). Evaluating
the postacquisition performance of firms provides
evidence on the efficiency of this asset-matching
and combining process.
In this paper we draw upon theories of techno-
logical innovation, learning, and the resource-
based view to develop a theoretical model and
predictions relating acquisition characteristics to
the innovation performance of acquiring firms
(Cohen and Levinthal, 1989; Grant, 1996). Inno-
vation performance can be measured in terms of
innovative inputs such as R&D expenditures, or
innovation outputs such as patenting frequency
(Griliches, 1984; Henderson and Cockburn,
1996). Acquisitions can affect both innovative
inputs and innovative outputs (Hitt et al., 1991).
For instance, a firm’s R&D expenditures can
decrease after it conducts an acquisition as the
firm eliminates certain streams of research or as
managers become more risk averse (Hitt et al.,
1991). Yet, even while research efforts decrease,
the productivity of those efforts can increase as
the two hitherto separate research teams combine
their skills and knowledge. In this research we
focus on the impact of acquisitions on innovation
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
outputs as measured by the patenting frequency
of the acquiring firm. Accordingly, we adopt an
innovation production function framework and
model patenting frequency as the output of a
production function (Griliches, 1984). The
hypotheses of this study are statements about
the relationship between this patented knowledge
output and the firm’s stocks of owned and
acquired knowledge. In estimating the impact of
acquisitions on the innovative output of a firm
we statistically control for the levels of innovative
inputs such as R&D expenditures, but leave their
substantive examination to future work.
HYPOTHESES
In this research we focus on two contingencies
that may be critical to clarifying the relationship
between acquisitions and the postacquisition inno-
vation performance of acquiring firms. First, we
draw attention to the fact that technological
reasons do not motivate all acquisitions. For
example, acquisitions can be motivated by the
desire to obtain access to distribution channels,
to gain entry into new markets, or to obtain
financial synergies or market power (Lubatkin,
1983; Balakrishnan, 1988; Chatterjee, 1991; Has-
peslagh and Jemison, 1991; Capron, Dussauge,
and Mitchell, 1998). Such acquisitions may pro-
vide no technological inputs to the acquiring firm
and therefore cannot be expected to improve its
innovation output. Second, we note that even
among technologically motivated acquisitions the
impact of acquisitions may depend on the charac-
teristics of the relationship between the knowl-
edge of the acquired and acquiring firms
(Lubatkin, 1983; Singh and Montgomery, 1987;
Lane and Lubatkin, 1998).
In summary, we argue that the impact of acqui-
sitions on the acquiring firm’s innovation output
can be understood in the context of the techno-
logical inputs provided by the acquisition. We
argue that acquisitions that provide no technologi-
cal inputs cannot be expected to have a positive
impact on firm innovation output (Hypothesis
1). Second, within acquisitions that do provide
technological inputs, we predict that the impact
of an acquisition on the postacquisition innovation
output of the acquiring firms is likely to vary
positively with the absolute size of the acquired
firm’s knowledge base, negatively with the rela-
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 199
tive size of the acquired and acquiring knowledge
bases, and curvilinearly with the relatedness of
the acquired and acquiring knowledge bases
(Hypotheses 2, 3 and 4).
Technological vs. nontechnological
acquisitions
Acquisitions can affect the acquirer’s subsequent
innovation output through two possible mecha-
nisms. First, an acquisition of another firm can
be viewed as an absorption of the acquired firm’s
knowledge base into the acquiring firm’s knowl-
edge base. Such a union can potentially expand
the acquirer’s knowledge base and increase its
innovation output by providing economies of
scale and scope in research and by enhancing the
acquirer’s potential for inventive recombination
(Henderson and Cockburn, 1996; Fleming, 1999).
Since nontechnological acquisitions add less to
the knowledge base of the acquirer they are less
likely to lead to such innovation output-enhancing
effects.
1
However, an acquisition can also disrupt
the established routines of the acquiring firm and
those of its newly acquired component, and
thereby reduce productivity (Jemison and Sitkin,
1986; Haspeslagh and Jemison, 1991). Prior
research suggests that acquisition integration
entails far-reaching disruption, and involves sig-
nificant managerial attention and transactions
costs (Pritchett, 1985; Haspeslagh and Jemison,
1991; Hitt et al., 1991, 1996; Hoskisson et al.,
1994). However, whether this disruption related
to nontechnological acquisitions will produce a
negative impact on innovative productivity is not
clear, a priori. On one hand it is possible that
as management focuses more on acquisitions and
their integration, decision making on routine tech-
nological matters can be delayed, activities such
as product championing can suffer, and a crisis
mentality on the management of the acquisition
can lead to only residual energies being supplied
to day-to-day operations even in the technological
core of the company (Thompson, 1967; Pritchett,
1985; Hitt et al., 1996). Alternately, it is pos-
sible that since such acquisitions do not
involve a technological component by definition,
they may not affect the technological subsystem
1
As suggested by one of the reviewers, in some cases
nontechnological acquisitions can increase innovation output,
for instance by providing contacts with new customers.
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
(Thompson, 1967) and innovation routines of the
firm, and therefore have no impact on innovation
output at all. The final impact of an acquisition
depends on the degree to which these effects
come into play.
Accordingly, we present the following base
hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1: Nontechnological acquisitions
will affect the postacquisition innovation output
of acquiring firms either negatively or nonsig-
nificantly.
Technological acquisitions and the absolute
size, relative size, and relatedness of
knowledge bases
Technological acquisitions are acquisitions that
provide technological inputs to the acquiring firm.
Thus, they potentially expand the acquirer’s
knowledge base and provide scale, scope, and
recombination benefits (Henderson and Cockburn,
1996; Fleming, 1999). However, technological
acquisitions can also entail a disruption in organi-
zational routines. Further, this disruption is most
likely in the set of routines that are closest to
the innovation arena, the technological subsystem
of the firm. Thus, technological acquisitions can
also have a negative impact on the innovation
output of the acquiring firm. On balance,
assessing whether technological acquisitions will
have a positive or negative impact on postacqui-
sition innovation output is likely to depend upon
the quantity and nature of knowledge elements
that they bring to the acquiring firm. To evaluate
whether the scale, scope, and inventive recombi-
nation benefits of acquisitions outweigh their
negative effects on organizational routines we
compare the knowledge bases of acquired and
acquiring firms along three key characteristics
that have also been prominently used in prior
acquisition research: absolute size, relative size,
and relatedness (Lubatkin, 1983). In the following
sections we examine and develop distinct hypoth-
eses for each of these characteristics.
Absolute size of acquired knowledge base
The absolute size of an acquired knowledge base
can affect the post acquisition innovation output
of the acquiring firm through at least two mecha-
nisms, both indicating a positive effect of larger
200 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
knowledge bases. First, the integration of the two
hitherto separate knowledge bases may enable
enhanced economies of scale and scope
(Henderson and Cockburn, 1996). For instance, a
long tradition of research in technology suggests
that new innovative outputs are often the result
of recombining existing elements of knowledge
into new syntheses (Schumpeter, 1934; Henderson
and Clark, 1990; Kogut and Zander, 1992; Tush-
man and Rosenkopf, 1992; Utterback, 1994;
Fleming, 1999). From this combinatorial perspec-
tive, the number of direct combinations that a
firm can create from its own knowledge elements
increases with the size of the acquired knowledge
base. While a firm with five units of knowledge
can generate 10 combinations using two elements
at a time, acquiring another firm with three units
of knowledge increases the number of combi-
nations that become available to 28. Similarly,
the merger of two knowledge bases can also
provide scale or scope economies by reducing
duplication in research efforts or by providing a
larger research base to defray costs.
Second, acquiring a larger knowledge base may
enhance a firm’s absorptive capacity. Prior
research indicates that as a firm expands its inter-
nal knowledge base and technological capability,
it also enhances its ability to absorb and utilize
external knowledge (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989;
Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Thus, when a firm
acquires a knowledge base it obtains access not
only to the acquired firm’s internally created
knowledge but also to a larger external domain
of knowledge that is understood and used by
the acquired firm. Thus, acquisitions increase the
number of elements of both internal and external
knowledge that are available to the acquiring firm
and hence increase its potential for inventive
recombination. Hence, we hypothesize:
Hypothesis 2: The greater the absolute size of
the acquired knowledge base, the greater the
subsequent innovation output of the acquiring
firm.
Relative size of acquired knowledge base
The arguments above focused on the increased
scale, scope, and recombination benefits possible
through the acquisition of a knowledge base. Yet,
several steps must be completed before newly
acquired knowledge can improve the acquirer’s
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
performance. The acquirer needs to recognize the
value and content of the acquired knowledge,
assimilate it, and apply it (Cohen and Levinthal,
1990). The degree to which these tasks can be
successfully accomplished is likely to vary with
the relative size of the acquiring and acquired
knowledge bases. The larger the relative size of
the knowledge base to be integrated, the more
difficult these stages are likely to be, and the
more negative the impact on postacquisition inno-
vation output.
Knowledge is primarily transferred through
interactions between the acquired and acquiring
units, and entails both teaching and learning on
both sides (Haspeslagh and Jemison, 1991). Inte-
gration teams, meetings within and between the
two R&D units, and extensive face-to-face com-
munication are integral parts of the process by
which the merging units learn about each other’s
technology and processes (Gerpott, 1995). Since
every communication needs both a sender and a
receiver, the relative size of the knowledge bases
in the merger becomes relevant. If the merged
knowledge bases are relatively equal in size, most
of the knowledge resources of the combined firm
will be devoted to the task of integrating the two
knowledge bases. As the two approximately equal
groups educate each other, fewer resources will
be available for conducting the actual business
of innovation. On the other hand, if the two
knowledge bases are relatively dissimilar in size,
the absorption and assimilation activity will
occupy only a part of the larger group’s resources
even if it entails the preoccupation of the smaller
of the two groups.
A second dimension of the relative size effect
is the disruption of existing organizational rou-
tines (Haspeslagh and Jemison, 1991; Singh and
Zollo, 1997). For successful assimilation and
application of the newly acquired knowledge,
many changes have to be introduced into the
functioning of the organization. Pathways of com-
munication, routing of work and authority, and
formal and informal organizational structures all
have to be adapted to incorporate the acquired
unit’s knowledge (Gerpott, 1995). If the acquired
firm’s knowledge base is small relative to the
acquirer the modifications required are likely to
be minor, and therefore not be very disruptive.
However, if the acquired firm’s knowledge base
is large relative to the acquiring firm, fairly major
changes would have to be made in the acquiring
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 201
firm, leading to a significant disruption of existing
processes. Accordingly, we predict:
Hypothesis 3: The greater the relative size
of the acquired knowledge base, the less the
subsequent innovation output of the acquiring
firm.
Relatedness of acquired and acquiring
knowledge bases
The third critical dimension in the unification of
two knowledge bases is their relatedness
(Lubatkin, 1983; Singh and Montgomery, 1987;
Lane and Lubatkin, 1998). While the previous
arguments concerned the magnitude of the
acquired and acquiring knowledge bases the
relatedness argument concerns the content of
these knowledge bases. We predict that
relatedness between the acquired and acquiring
knowledge bases is likely to have a nonmonotonic
influence on the subsequent innovation perfor-
mance of acquiring firms. Innovation output will
increase with increasing relatedness, but beyond
some optimum innovation output will decrease
with increasing relatedness.
The absorptive capacity argument suggests that
the ability to use new information to solve prob-
lems is enhanced when the new knowledge is
related to what is already known (Cohen and
Levinthal, 1990). Elements of similar knowledge
facilitate the integration of the acquired and
acquiring knowledge bases (Kogut and Zander,
1992; Grant, 1996). Common skills, shared lan-
guages, and similar cognitive structures enable
technical communication and learning (Cohen and
Levinthal, 1989; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998).
Further, the recipes for conducting research, or
the innovation routines of the acquired and
acquiring firms, are also likely to be different if
the firms come from distant realms of technology
(Kogut and Zander, 1992; Spender, 1989). In
such circumstances the integration of knowledge
bases can be resource consuming, or even
counterproductive as routines inappropriate to
either or both knowledge bases can be adopted
(Haspeslagh and Jemison, 1991; Singh and
Zollo, 1997).
On the other hand, an acquired knowledge base
that is too similar to the acquiring knowledge
base may also contribute little to subsequent inno-
vation performance. From an absorptive capacity
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
perspective acquired knowledge can help improve
performance through two effects. First, acquired
knowledge can provide a cross-fertilization effect
as old problems can be addressed through new
approaches, or by a combination of old and new
approaches (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Second,
new acquired knowledge can serve as the basis
for absorbing additional stimuli and information
from the external environment. If an acquisition
brings in knowledge that is too closely related to
the existing knowledge base of the acquiring firm,
both these benefits might be limited.
Knowledge bases with moderate degrees of
relatedness provide the benefits of enhancing the
variety of possible combinations that the firm can
use, while maintaining the elements of com-
monality that facilitate interaction between the
acquired and acquiring knowledge bases. Based
on the above arguments we suggest that acqui-
sitions that are characterized by a moderate
degree of overlap in the knowledge bases are
likely to provide the most significant positive
impact on the acquiring firm’s subsequent inno-
vation output. Accordingly, we predict:
Hypothesis 4: The relatedness of the acquired
knowledge base will be curvilinearly (inverted
U) related to the subsequent innovation output
of the acquiring firm.
DATA AND METHODS
Organizational knowledge base
In the previous section we argued that an acqui-
sition can be viewed as the union of two knowl-
edge bases. Measuring an organizational knowl-
edge base is then the key operational issue in
testing the hypotheses. Specifically, we need to
identify empirical measures that capture the abso-
lute size, relative size, and relatedness of knowl-
edge bases. In the arguments below we suggest
that an organization’s patent portfolio provides a
means for capturing these dimensions and map-
ping an organization’s knowledge.
A patent, by definition, represents a unique and
novel element of knowledge. A set of patents
then represents a collection of discrete, distinct
units of knowledge. Identifying a set of patents
that a firm has demonstrated familiarity with, or
mastery of, can be a basis for identifying the
‘revealed’ knowledge base of a firm, the distinct
202 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
elements of knowledge with which the firm has
revealed a relationship (Kim and Kogut, 1996).
The patents owned by a firm represent the
knowledge that the firm is acknowledged as hav-
ing created (Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson,
1993). Such patents are naturally elements of the
firm’s knowledge base. However, the firm’s pa-
tents also build on prior patents, the knowledge
created by the same firm in the past or by other
firms which have preceded it in that line of
inquiry. These prior patents are cited in the pa-
tents as recognition of their contribution to the
knowledge embodied in the focal patent. By cre-
ating a patent that builds on these prior patents,
the firm provides evidence that the knowledge
contained in those past patents is a part of the
firm’s knowledge set. Thus, the patents cited by
the firm should also be included in its knowledge
base. The Appendix describes in more detail the
logic underlying this approach to measuring
organizational knowledge bases.
Using patent data to measure organizational
knowledge bases corresponds closely to the con-
ceptual abstraction of a firm’s knowledge base as
a set of knowledge elements (Grant, 1996). The
number of cited and obtained patents provides a
measure of the size of the knowledge base. The
individual patents in the firm’s knowledge base
provide the basis for comparing the firm’s knowl-
edge base with other knowledge bases. Since
each patent number uniquely identifies a distinct
component of knowledge, the higher the number
of patents that are common across two knowledge
bases, the higher the relatedness between those
knowledge bases (see also Stuart and Podolny,
1996; Mowery, Oxley and Silverman, 1998).
Methods
A panel data design was used to test the hypoth-
eses. We selected a sample of firms from the
global chemicals industry independent of their
acquisition behavior, and traced the acquisition
behavior of these firms over a 12-year period,
from 1980 to 1991 (more details on the sample
are provided later). Several of the sample firms
were very active in the acquisitions arena, while
others conducted few or no acquisitions at all.
We attempted to collect data on every acquisition
conducted by these firms. The acquisition charac-
teristics of these firms were modeled as time-
varying influences on the subsequent innovation
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
performance of these firms. A distributed lag
analysis was used to identify the effects of an
acquisition on innovation performance in the 4
years succeeding the acquisition.
This approach addresses several methodological
problems that arise in evaluating the impact of
acquisitions on the postacquisition performance
of acquiring firms. First, examining a single
industry over a common period controls for
industry and period effects that have been cited
as a problem with prior acquisition research
(Fowler and Schmidt, 1988). Second, this research
design naturally includes both firms that are active
in acquisitions and those that are inactive. In the
absence of the latter group of firms it is difficult
to refute the argument that good or bad perfor-
mance by acquiring firms was not shared by
similar nonacquiring firms (Fowler and Schmidt,
1988). Third, this approach resolves the problem
of handling firms with multiple acquisitions. To
reduce the problem of confounding caused by
firms making several acquisitions over the study
period, some researchers have omitted such firms
from analyses (Fowler and Schmidt, 1988). How-
ever, omitting such firms may lead to biased
findings. With our research design such firms can
be retained in the analysis by including acqui-
sition and firm characteristics as time-varying
covariates in a panel regression. Finally, our panel
data set includes distributed lag effects. The dis-
tributed lag technique enables us to use multiple-
period lagged values of the independent variables
as additional regressors in the estimated equation
(Judge et al., 1988). By using this approach, we
can, in principle, trace the effects of the acqui-
sition on the performance of the acquiring firm
for several periods after the acquisition.
Model specification and econometric issues
We now describe our econometric approach, fol-
lowed by a discussion of the industry setting and
the variables used to test the hypotheses. The
dependent variable of the study, innovation out-
put, as measured by patent counts, is a count
variable and takes only non-negative integer
values. The linear regression model’s assumptions
of homoskedastic, normally distributed errors are
thus violated. A Poisson regression approach is
appropriate for such data (Hausman, Hall, and
Griliches, 1984; Henderson and Cockburn, 1996).
Accordingly, we specified the following Poisson
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 203
regression model:
P
it
=exp (X
it1
γ+A
it1
β
1
+A
it2
β
2
+A
it3
β
3
+A
it4
β
4
) (1)
where P
it
is the number of patents obtained by
firm iin year t,X
it1
is a vector of control
variables affecting P
it
, and A
it-year
is the lagged
vector of the acquisition variables for years t
1tot4.
Intuitively, this specification implies that the
number of patents obtained by any firm in any
year is randomly distributed following a Poisson
process, where the covariate vectors X
it1
and
A
it1
,A
it2
,A
it3
, and A
it4
determine the mean
of this process. Changes in the value of individual
covariates thus influence patenting frequency by
affecting the mean of the Poisson distribution
from which observations are drawn, in a manner
identical to an ordinary regression.
Since the impact of an acquisition is likely to
be felt over a number of years, rather than
entirely in any one year, we used a distributed
lag model (Judge et al., 1988). To capture the
lag effects, the one-period, two-period, three-
period, and four-period lagged values of all acqui-
sition related variables were included as covari-
ates in the above model. This distributed lag
model tests the impact of acquisitions for up to
4 years after the year the acquisition was orig-
inally made. Thus, illustratively speaking, in these
models the acquiring firm’s innovation perfor-
mance in 1986 is potentially influenced by acqui-
sitions made in 1982, 1983, 1984, and 1985. In
sensitivity tests (results available from the
authors), instead of using four lags we also esti-
mated the models using three and five lags and
found results substantively identical to those
reported here.
The use of distributed lags provides two bene-
fits. First, it enables us to examine the time
pattern of the impact of acquisitions on firm
innovation output. For instance, if an acquisition
contributes to improved performance for the first
2 years but thereafter leads to no further improve-
ment in innovation output, the 1- and 2-year
lagged acquisition variables will be positive and
significant, while the 3- and 4-year lagged acqui-
sition variables will be nonsignificant. Second,
since the total impact of an acquisition is likely
to be distributed over several periods following
the acquisition and may be statistically incon-
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
sequential in any one period, the regression coef-
ficients on the distributed lags can be summed to
obtain the total impact of an acquisition across
time (Gujarati, 1988: 507). By using the variances
and covariances of the individual lag coefficients
from the regression output the variance of the
summed coefficient can be calculated. The
summed coefficient can then be used for hypoth-
esis testing. For instance, the hypothesis that the
total impact of acquisitions summed across all
years is zero can be tested by computing the
following t-statistic and checking whether it is
statistically significant at the desired confidence
level (Greene, 1993; Gujarati, 1988).
t=(β
t1
+β
t2
+β
t3
+β
t4
)
/Variance (β
t1
+β
t2
+β
t3
+β
t4
)
where the β
ti
’s are the regression coefficients
for the ith period lagged acquisition variable
(Judge et al., 1988). The variance for the summed
coefficients can be computed using the following
relation (Gujarati, 1988: 507):
Variance (β
t1
t2
t3
t4
)
=[Var(β
t1
)+Var(β
t2
)
+Var(β
t3
)+Var(β
t4
) (2)
+2Cov(β
t1
β
t2
)+2Cov(β
t1
β
t3
)
+2Cov(β
t1
β
t-4
)+2Cov(β
t2
β
t3
)
+2Cov(β
t2
β
t4
)+2Cov(β
t3
β
t4
)]
The conditioning vector Xin Equation 1 helps
us to control for alternative explanations. For
instance, since an acquisition represents the
absorption of one firm by another, a simple expla-
nation for an increased postacquisition innovation
output would simply be increased innovative
inputs—the one postacquisition firm reflects the
combined efforts of the two preacquisition firms.
By including innovative inputs as time-varying
covariates in the conditioning vector X, we can
directly control for such effects. Other possible
determinants of innovation outputs such as firm
size, diversification, nationality, and time are also
controlled for through this vector.
This specification does not account for unob-
served heterogeneity, or the possibility that obser-
vationally equivalent firms may differ on unmeas-
ured characteristics. For instance, firms may enter
204 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
the sample with inherently different innovation
generating capabilities. Such unobserved hetero-
geneity, if present and not controlled for, can
cause estimation problems. First, it can lead to
overdispersion in the data. For the Poisson distri-
bution the variance is restricted to equal the
mean. If this restriction is false and the data are
overdispersed in that the variance exceeds the
mean, the computed standard errors in a Poisson
regression are understated. Second, unobserved
firm effects can lead to serial correlation among
the residuals of observations from the same firm.
Under overdispersion or serial correlation, com-
puted regression coefficients remain consistently
estimated; however, the standard errors are inac-
curate. Thus, hypothesis testing and inference can
be invalidated. To address the possibility of unob-
served heterogeneity we used the Presample Panel
Poisson approach (Blundell, Griffith, and Van
Reenen, 1995).
In the Presample approach, unobserved hetero-
geneity is modeled as an additional covariate in
the basic Poisson model. The values of the depen-
dent variable in the periods immediately preced-
ing the study period are used to construct an
instrumental variable. This instrumental variable
serves as a ‘fixed-effect’ for the firms in the
panel and helps to partial out unobservable differ-
ences across firms. Thus, presample information
on the firms provides the basis for controlling
for unobserved heterogeneity. In the context of
the current research the Presample variable can
be interpreted as a measure of the unobserved
differences in knowledge stocks between the sam-
ple firms.
Although the presample approach can help in
the reduction of overdispersion and serial corre-
lation, a more complete treatment of these poten-
tial problems would be to use an estimation
approach that accounts for any remaining over-
dispersion and serial correlation even after the
inclusion of a presample variable. The Gen-
eralized Estimating Equations (GEE) method-
ology provides a direct approach to modeling
longitudinal Poisson data with serial correlation
in a regression context (Liang and Zeger, 1986).
The GEE estimation procedure involves two
stages. In the first stage of the procedure beta
coefficients are estimated with the assumption of
independence across observations. This process
yields consistent estimates of the beta parameters
and the residuals from this regression provide an
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
estimate of the ‘working correlations’ between
the errors of different observations. This working
correlation matrix is then used as an input in a
second regression. The beta coefficients and stan-
dard errors from this second regression provide
consistent estimates of the underlying parameters
while accounting for the observed correlation
between observations. To ensure that all residual
correlation was accounted for, we used the GEE
procedure to estimate all models. Even for the
GEE approach instead of using the model-based
standard errors we used the more conservative
(i.e., larger) empirical standard errors. This
ensures that other potential misspecifications of
the variance function, such as any residual over-
dispersion, are also accounted for.
Sample and data
We tested the hypotheses on a longitudinal data
set comprising the acquisition and patenting
activities of 72 leading firms from the global
chemicals industry. Focusing on the largest firms
of the industry was necessary to ensure the avail-
ability and reliability of data. Obtaining infor-
mation on the key variables for smaller firms is
extremely difficult. This focus on large firms is
also consistent with prior research on acquisitions
(Hitt et al., 1991, 1996). We identified the 100
leading players in the chemicals industry from
lists of the largest chemicals firms that are pub-
lished annually by trade journals such as Chemi-
cal Week and C&E News. To avoid survivor bias,
the selected sample was drawn from the lists at
the beginning of the study period. In these pub-
lished lists subsidiaries were often listed sepa-
rately from parent firms. After combining subsidi-
aries with parent firms, a sample of 82
independent firms was identified for inclusion in
the sample. However, for 10 firms data could not
be reliably obtained and they were subsequently
dropped from the analysis. The remaining firms
include the key firms in the industry over the
study period and comprise of 30 European, 26
American, and 16 Japanese firms. The panel is
unbalanced as some of the firms were acquired
by other firms or restructured in a fashion that
made comparison difficult beyond a particular
year. Even though the sample was focused on
the largest firms in the chemicals industry the
inclusion of 72 firms provides significant depth
to the sample and ensures that there is consider-
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 205
able variety within the sample on the key vari-
ables of this study. For instance, the number of
employees for firms in the sample varies from a
minimum of 2300 to a maximum of more than
181,000. Similarly, the number of patents
obtained yearly varies from 0 to 760. Financial
figures and personnel data on these firms were
obtained from Compustat, Worldscope, Japan
Company Handbooks, Daiwa Institute Research
Guides, and trade publications and company
annual reports. For all firms, financial data were
converted to constant (1985) U.S. dollars to
ensure standardization within the sample. A full
list of the sample firms is available from the
authors.
The chemicals industry is an appropriate setting
for several reasons. First, technology-based acqui-
sitions have been a significant feature of this
industry (Chemical Week, 1983; Gibson, 1985).
Second, patents are generally regarded to be
effective, and used widely and consistently in the
chemicals industry (Levin et al., 1987; Arundel
and Kabla, 1998). For the firms in the sample
we obtained yearly patent counts from 1975 to
1992 and acquisition and firm attribute data for
the years 1980 to 1991. The need to use lagged
relationships between patent counts and the other
variables and to construct a control for unob-
served heterogeneity reduced the final panel for
regression analysis to 9 years. We describe the
data collection and coding procedures for the
three sets of variables in some detail below.
We used U.S. patent data for all firms, includ-
ing the foreign firms in the sample. This was
necessary to maintain consistency, reliability, and
comparability, as patenting systems across nations
differ in their application of standards, system of
granting patents, and value of protection granted.
The United States represents one of the largest
markets for chemicals, and firms desirous of com-
mercializing their inventions typically patent in
the United States if they patent anywhere. Studies
by Dosi, Pavitt and Suete (1990) and Basberg
(1983) show empirically that U.S. patent data
provide a good measure of foreign firms’ inno-
vativeness. Prior research using patent data on
international samples has also followed this strat-
egy of using U.S. patent data for international
firms (e.g., Stuart and Podolny, 1996; Patel and
Pavitt, 1997).
Data on acquisitions were obtained through
detailed archival research on the chemicals sec-
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
tor. Three main types of data sources were used
to identify acquisition activity and to collect
data on acquisition transactions: (1) commercial
data bases, including general business news
mediasuchastheDowJonesNewsRetrieval
Text Index, and chemicals sector-specific data
bases such as Metadex, (2) general business
print media such as the Frost and Sullivan Predi-
casts Index (United States, International, and
Europe), Mergers and Acquisitions Journal and
Moody’s Manuals, and industry-specific publi-
cations such as Chemical Week and Plastics
Technology, and, (3) government publications
and consultant reports for the chemicals indus-
try. We were able to identify 1287 acquisition
announcements for the sample firms over the
period of 1980 to 1991.
To identify the technological acquisitions
within this larger sample two approaches were
used. First, we obtained detailed news stories
associated with each acquisition announcement.
We were able to obtain news stories providing
details for 516 of the 1287 acquisitions identified
for the sample firms. For the remaining acqui-
sitions no further details, or inadequate details,
were available. Second, we searched the U.S.
Patents Data Base to determine if the acquired
firms had obtained any patents in the 5 years
preceding the acquisition. 165 of the acquired
firms had obtained patents during the 5 years
preceding their acquisition. For all subsequent
analyses we retained only those acquisitions for
which we were able to find either corroborating
news stories or patenting activity (534 acqui-
sitions in total). Acquisitions for which we were
able to obtain no further information were omit-
ted. The paucity of information on these acqui-
sitions suggests that these acquisitions were very
small or unimportant. Therefore, our analysis is
based on the 534 acquisitions for which we have
relatively complete information.
We used two criteria to distinguish technologi-
cal acquisitions from all other acquisitions. First,
we examined the news stories to establish if the
acquiring firm reported technology as a motivat-
ing factor for the acquisition or if technology
was a part of the transferred assets. We classified
the acquisition as technological if either of these
conditions was met. Second, we classified the
acquisition as technological if the acquired firm
had any patenting activity in the 5 years preced-
ing the acquisition. Of the 534 acquisitions on
206 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
which we had information, 283 met at least one
of the two above criteria and were classified
as technological acquisitions. The remaining 251
acquisitions were classified as nontechnological.
This classification scheme reflects a fairly
inclusive definition of technological acquisitions.
Firms need not have patented to be classified as
technology acquisitions. Further, acquired firms
obtaining even a single patent in the 5 years
prior to the acquisition are classified as techno-
logical acquisitions.
This classification scheme provides two bene-
fits. First, it uses two indicators to identify tech-
nological acquisitions and therefore enables more
complete identification of technological acqui-
sitions than either indicator by itself would. For
instance, our patent-based measures cannot be
computed if only a part of a firm is acquired,
rather than the complete entity, or if the tech-
nology has not been patented at all. In such
circumstances the news story could provide an
indication of whether the transaction entailed
technology or not. Similarly, if the acquisition
was motivated by multiple factors of which tech-
nology was not necessarily the one mentioned in
the news story, the patents measure provides an
indicator of whether technology was involved.
Thus, using the input from the news stories sup-
plements our patent-based measures.
Second, using this scheme of classification
makes our statistical tests more conservative.
With this scheme we are likely to capture any
acquisition that includes a technological compo-
nent. Further, we are more likely to err in the
direction of defining acquisitions as technological
even when they have a relatively small tech-
nology component. If such misclassifications
occur, we reduce our likelihood of finding
a positive impact of technological acquisitions
on the innovation performance of acquiring
firms.
Finally, we need to select a time period or
window for measuring a firm’s knowledge base.
At one extreme only the current year’s patents
could be considered relevant. At another extreme
any patent obtained by the firm in the past could
be included in computing its current knowledge
base. Prior research suggests that knowledge capi-
tal depreciates sharply, losing significant value
within 5 years (Griliches, 1979). Although the
depreciation rate for knowledge capital is likely
to vary across industries, a boundary of 5 or 6
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
years seems reasonable and has been used by
other researchers (Podolny and Stuart, 1995;
Henderson and Cockburn, 1996). In this research
we use the patents obtained by a firm in the
preceding 5 years to compute our knowledge
base measures. We also computed some of the
measures using patents for the preceding 6 years.
These measures were highly correlated with the
5-year measures, suggesting that the construct is
not unduly influenced by changes in the time
period used to compute it.
Variable definitions and operationalization
Dependent variable
Patents Innovation output, the dependent vari-
able, is measured through the patenting frequency
of firms, that is, the number of successful patent
applications by a firm in a given year. Patents
have both significant strengths and weaknesses as
measures of innovation output. First, patents are
directly related to inventiveness: they are granted
only for ‘nonobvious’ improvements or solutions
with discernible utility (Walker, 1995). Second,
they represent an externally validated measure of
technological novelty (Griliches, 1990). Third,
they confer property rights upon the assignee and
therefore have economic significance (Kamien and
Schwartz, 1982: 49; Scherer and Ross, 1990:
621).
Patents also correlate well with other measures
of innovative output. Empirical studies find that
patents are closely related to measures such as
new products (Comanor and Scherer, 1969), inno-
vation and invention counts (Achilladelis,
Schwarzkopf and Cines, 1987), and sales growth
(Scherer, 1965). Expert ratings of corporate tech-
nological strength are also highly correlated with
the number of patents held by corporations
(Narin, Noma, and Perry, 1987). Further, surveys
of patent holders indicate that the rate of utili-
zation of patents is reasonably high, with esti-
mates indicating that between 41 percent and 55
percent of all patents granted are put to commer-
cial use for at least a limited time (Griliches,
1990). Similarly, about 50 percent of all patents
granted are still being renewed and a renewal fee
is being paid 10 years after the patents had
originally been applied for (Griliches, 1990;
Schankerman and Pakes, 1986). Given a nonneg-
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 207
ligible renewal fee, this indicates a significant
usefulness for the majority of patents for a sig-
nificant time period.
However, the use of patents as a measure
of innovative output also has limitations. Some
inventions are not patentable, others are not pa-
tented, and the inventions that are patented differ
greatly in economic value (Cohen and Levin,
1989; Griliches, 1990; Trajtenberg, 1990).
Research, and the logic of appropriability, indi-
cate that the degree to which the first two of
these factors are a problem varies significantly
across industries (Cohen and Levin 1989; Levin
et al., 1987). Limiting the study to a single
industrial sector or a few closely related sectors
minimizes such problems as the factors that affect
patenting propensity are likely to be stable within
such a context (Basberg, 1987; Cohen and Levin,
1989; Griliches, 1990).
We measure Patents
it
, as the number of suc-
cessful patent applications, or granted patents, for
the acquiring firm iin year t. The granted patent
carries the date of the original application. We
use this date to assign a granted patent to the
particular year when it was originally applied
for. This procedure permits consistency in the
treatment of all patents and controls for differ-
ences in delays that may occur in granting patents
after the application is filed (Trajtenberg, 1990).
Note that the patent count for the dependent
variable is based on the patents of the acquiring
firm obtained 1–4 years after the acquisition in
all cases. These patents are therefore different
from the patents on which the independent vari-
ables are based. The independent variables
described below are based on patents obtained
by the acquired and acquiring firms, respectively,
in the 5 years before the acquisition.
Independent variables
Number of nontechnological acquisitions As
noted earlier, acquisitions were coded as techno-
logical acquisitions if either of the following two
criteria are met: first, if the acquiring firm
reported technology as a motivating factor for the
acquisition or if technology was reported as a
part of the transferred assets of the acquired firm;
second, if the acquired firm had any patenting
activity in the 5 years preceding the acquisition.
Acquisitions that did not meet either of the above
criteria were coded as nontechnological acqui-
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
sitions. We used four lagged versions of this and
all other acquisition related variables listed below.
Absolute size of acquired knowledge base To
obtain this variable we used the following pro-
cedure: for each acquiring firm for each year, we
prepared a list of the patents its acquisitions had
obtained in the preceding 5 years. These patents
were then combined with the patents cited by
them. Thereafter, all duplicates were removed to
ensure that a patent number appeared only once
on this list. The acquired knowledge base was
then computed as the number of patents (i.e.,
knowledge elements) on this list.
Relative size of acquired knowledge base This
variable was obtained by dividing Absolute
size of acquired knowledge base by the size of
the acquiring firm’s knowledge base. The size of
the acquiring firm’s knowledge base was
computed using the same procedure as the size
of the acquired firm’s knowledge base (see
above). In a few cases the acquired knowledge
base was larger than the acquiring knowledge
base. In these cases we used the larger number
as the denominator. Since our theoretical mech-
anism is concerned with the relative proportion
of the merged firms’ resources that are likely to
be occupied with integrative rather than inventive
activity, a number greater than 1 is not meaning-
ful.
Relatedness of acquired knowledge base To
measure the relatedness of the acquired knowl-
edge base, the following procedure was followed.
First, the list of patent numbers that appeared in
both the acquired firm’s knowledge base and in
the acquiring firm’s knowledge base was pre-
pared. Then, the number of elements on this
list was divided by Absolute size of acquired
knowledge base.
Number of technological acquisitions where pa-
tents unavailable This is the number of acqui-
sitions for which news stories indicated that tech-
nology was a component of the transferred assets
but where no patents could be identified with the
acquisition. This would occur if either the
acquired unit had obtained no patents or if the
acquired unit was a part of a larger parent firm
and patents were not assigned separately to the
acquired unit and therefore could not be separated
208 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
from the parent firm’s patents.
Controls
We included several control variables in the mod-
els. These control variables include yearly R&D
expenditures (R&D), firm size as measured by
natural log of number of employees
(Logemployees), firm diversification as measured
by entropy (Diversification), and a measure of
national cultural distance between the acquired
and acquiring firms (Foreign acquisitions). The
following formula was used to calculate the
Diversification measure: Entropy =P
j
ln(1/P
j
), where P
j
is defined as the percentage of
firm sales in segment jand ln(1/P
j
) is the weight
for each segment j(Palepu, 1985). Foreign acqui-
sitions was computed as
Foreign acquisitions =
4
i=1
{(I
ij
I
iu
)
2
/V
i
}/4 (3)
where I
i
stands for the index of the ith cultural
dimension, jand uare subscripts indicating the
countries jand u, and V
i
is the variance of the
index of the ith dimension (Hofstede, 1980). The
index thus indicates the cultural distance between
the acquirer’s country (j) and the acquired firm’s
country (u) (Kogut and Singh, 1988). We antici-
pate that foreign acquisitions might be more dif-
ficult to integrate than domestic acquisitions.
Finally, in all models we included the firm hetero-
geneity control variable Presample patents (the
sum of patents obtained by a firm in the 3 years
prior to the firm’s entry into the sample) and
dummy variables for acquirer nationality and cal-
endar year.
RESULTS
Table 1 provides descriptive statistics and corre-
lations. The table indicates the diversity of firms
included in the sample. Even though the sample
involves the prominent players in the industry,
there is considerable variance on all the key
variables such as Patents,R&D,Logemployees,
and the acquisition variables. The variables
reflecting the hypothesized effects are not very
highly correlated among themselves or with the
control variables. However, the correlations
between some of the control variables are high,
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
notably the correlation between R&D and Logem-
ployees (0.72), and the correlation of the firm
fixed-effect variable Presample patents with
R&D (0.89) and Logemployees (0.72). Robustness
tests (reported at the end of this section), how-
ever, indicate that the results on the hypothesized
effects were strong and unaffected by these high
correlations between some of the control vari-
ables.
Table 2 provides results for all models using
GEE Poisson estimators (reported with empirical
standard errors). The variables reflecting the
hypothesized effects were entered into the
regression individually and likelihood ratio tests
are reported for all models. Model 1 in Table
2 presents the base model with firm- and acqui-
sition-related control variables. Models 2–6
include the Number of nontechnological acqui-
sitions,Absolute size of acquired knowledge
base,Relative size of acquired knowledge base,
Relatedness of acquired knowledge base and
Relatedness of acquired knowledge base
2
vari-
ables entered successively. We use the full
model to discuss the results of the hypothesis
tests. The summed coefficients and the
associated standard errors for the lagged acqui-
sition variables for these models are given at
the bottom of the table.
In Hypothesis 1 we predicted a negative or
nonsignificant relationship between the number of
nontechnological acquisitions conducted in a year
and the subsequent innovation output of the
acquiring firm. The coefficients of Number of
non-technological acquisitions are nonsignificant
for all four periods individually. The summed
coefficient, which represents the total effect of
acquisitions across the 4 years, is not statistically
significantly different from zero. Thus, we do not
find an appreciable impact of acquisitions without
a technological component on the innovation out-
put of the acquirer for the four periods following
the acquisition.
The coefficients of the four Absolute size of
acquired knowledge base variables in Model 6 in
Table 2 are positive and significant, supporting
Hypothesis 2. The summed coefficient reflecting
the total impact of the acquisition is also positive
and significant. However, as the summed coef-
ficient indicates (0.0004), the absolute magnitude
of this effect is low. A one-unit increase in the
knowledge base of the acquired firm leads to a
0.04 percent increase in the acquirer’s innovation
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 209
Table 1. Means, standard deviations, minimum and maximum values and bivariate correlations for all variables
Variable Mean S.D. Min. Max. 1 2 3 45678910111213141516171819202122232425262728293031323334
1Patients
t
93.90 137.65 0.00 760.00
2No. of nontechnological 0.35 0.79 0.00 6.00 0.12
acquisitions
t1
3No. of nontechnological 0.34 0.78 0.00 6.00 0.12 0.26
acquisitions
t2
4No. of nontechnological 0.29 0.68 0.00 5.00 0.11 0.29 0.23
acquisitions
t3
5No. of nontechnological 0.25 0.69 0.00 7.00 0.12 0.21 0.29 0.30
acquisitions
t4
6Absolute size of acquired 26.08 275.94 0.00 6227.00 0.13 0.07 0.03 0.010.02
knowledge base
t1
7Absolute size of acquired 34.59 332.94 0.00 6227.00 0.150.03 0.05 0.03 0.00 0.02
knowledge base
t2
8Absolute size of acquired 34.83 338.80 0.00 6227.00 0.180.02 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.01
knowledge base
t3
9Absolute size of acquired 33.20 337.48 0.00 6227.00 0.19 0.00 0.020.03 0.02 0.51 0.03 0.01
knowledge base
t4
10 Relative size of acquired 0.02 0.08 0.00 0.90 0.04 0.12 0.00 0.000.05 0.440.01 0.00 0.16
knowledge base
t1
11 Relative size of acquired 0.02 0.09 0.00 0.90 0.010.01 0.12 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.56 0.01 0.00 0.02
knowledge base
t2
12 Relative size of acquired 0.02 0.09 0.00 0.90 0.01 0.04 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.55 0.01 0.05 0.02
knowledge base
t3
13 Relative size of acquired 0.02 0.08 0.00 0.90 0.020.02 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.37 0.03 0.00 0.56 0.12 0.05 0.00
knowledge base
t4
14 Relatedness of acquired 0.01 0.06 0.00 1.00 0.030.02 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.000.01 0.01 0.09 0.01 0.02 0.27
knowledge base
t1
15 Relatedness of acquired 0.01 0.06 0.00 1.00 0.04 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.08 0.00 0.01 0.02
knowledge base
t2
16 Relatedness of acquired 0.01 0.06 0.00 1.00 0.05 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.07 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.02 0.02
knowledge base
t3
17 Relatedness of acquired 0.01 0.06 0.00 1.00 0.06 0.02 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.09 0.06 0.01 0.03 0.02 0.06 0.00 0.07 0.04 0.01 0.01
knowledge base
t4
18 Relatedness of acquired 0.00 0.05 0.00 1.00 0.010.03 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.040.01 0.01 0.36 0.92 0.01 0.01 0.00
knowledge base
t12
19 Relatedness of acquired 0.00 0.05 0.00 1.00 0.000.02 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.00 0.000.01 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.92 0.01 0.01 0.01
knowledge base
t22
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
210 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
Table 1. Continued
Variable Mean S.D. Min. Max. 1 2 3 45678910111213141516171819202122232425262728293031323334
20 Relatedness of acquired 0.00 0.05 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.030.010.01 0.01 0.92 0.01 0.010.01
knowledge base
t32
21 Relatedness of acquired 0.00 0.05 0.00 1.00 0.010.01 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.04 0.02 0.010.01 0.93 0.00 0.01 0.01
knowledge base
t42
22 No. of technological 0.17 0.47 0.00 3.00 0.19 0.22 0.16 0.17 0.20 0.030.03 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.04 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.000.01 0.02 0.00 0.02
acquisitions where
patents unavailable
t1
23 No. of technological 0.16 0.46 0.00 3.00 0.21 0.10 0.23 0.18 0.170.01 0.01 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.050.03 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.03 0.010.01 0.00 0.28
acquisitions where
patents unavailable
t2
24 No. of technological 0.14 0.43 0.00 3.00 0.22 0.15 0.11 0.23 0.22 0.010.01 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.02 0.020.02 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.19 0.31
acquisitions where
patents unavailable
t3
25 No. of technological 0.13 0.41 0.00 3.00 0.19 0.15 0.15 0.08 0.200.02 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.06 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.030.020.01 0.14 0.21 0.31
acquisitions where
patents unavailable
t4
26 Foreign acquisitions
t1
0.20 0.86 0.00 14.66 0.02 0.23 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.150.02 0.00 0.01 0.33 0.03 0.11 0.01 0.12 0.02 0.170.01 0.08 0.02 0.09 0.01 0.39 0.14 0.12 0.04
27 Foreign acquisitions
t2
0.19 0.85 0.00 14.66 0.03 0.06 0.24 0.05 0.08 0.00 0.120.01 0.00 0.01 0.29 0.03 0.12 0.01 0.13 0.02 0.19 0.00 0.08 0.01 0.09 0.10 0.40 0.16 0.14 0.15
28 Foreign acquisitions
t3
0.15 0.60 0.00 6.86 0.04 0.24 0.10 0.15 0.10 0.08 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.11 0.00 0.150.020.01 0.02 0.19 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.12 0.02 0.18 0.17 0.41 0.22 0.42 0.23
29 Foreign acquisitions
t4
0.15 0.69 0.00 8.97 0.03 0.10 0.21 0.07 0.11 0.01 0.06 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.08 0.01 0.16 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.17 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.10 0.05 0.15 0.14 0.43 0.15 0.37 0.25
30 R&D
t1
19.32 30.24 0.23 161.25 0.89 0.18 0.19 0.16 0.16 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.11 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.24 0.30 0.30 0.26 0.07 0.11 0.15 0.12
31 Logemployees
t1
2.76 1.14 0.83 5.20 0.70 0.31 0.31 0.28 0.28 0.13 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.00 0.03 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.06 0.05 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.29 0.28 0.28 0.24 0.13 0.14 0.18 0.17 0.72
32 Diversification/Entropy
t1
0.53 0.41 0.00 1.60 0.04 0.10 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.10 0.12 0.11 0.10 0.05 0.09 0.10 0.10 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.07 0.08 0.12 0.01 0.000.06 0.08 0.05 0.14
33 U.S.A. 0.35 0.48 0.00 1.00 0.100.04 0.04 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.07 0.09 0.09 0.01 0.03 0.04 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.05 0.04 0.07 0.08 0.13 0.12 0.12 0.110.02 0.08 0.13
34 Japan 0.24 0.43 0.00 1.00 0.190.24 0.23 0.22 0.20 0.040.050.05 0.05 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.090.070.07 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.040.040.17 0.17 0.15 0.16 0.05 0.07 0.070.07 0.21 0.53 0.10 0.42
35 Presample patents
t1
2.28 3.26 0.01 15.80 0.94 0.11 0.12 0.09 0.10 0.07 0.08 0.11 0.11 0.07 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.20 0.21 0.21 0.18 0.00 0.02 0.05 0.04 0.89 0.72 0.02 0.10 0.20
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 211
Table 2. GEE presample Poisson regression with distributed lag analysis predicting patents
t
variable
Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6
Intercept 1.906*** 1.916*** 1.994*** 2.055*** 2.041*** 2.048***
[0.333] [0.334] [0.296] [0.293] [0.295] [0.292]
No. of 0.004 0.009 0.009 0.008 0.004
nontechnological [0.017] [0.017] [0.016] [0.016] [0.017]
acquisitions
t1
No. of 0.002 0.0003 0.004 0.005 0.004
nontechnological [0.018] [0.017] [0.016] [0.016] [0.016]
acquisitions
t2
No. of 0.001 0.006 0.002 0.003 0.002
nontechnological [0.023] [0.023] [0.023] [0.023] [0.024]
acquisitions
t3
No. of 0.010 0.012 0.008 0.010 0.008
nontechnological [0.014] [0.014] [0.013] [0.013] [0.012]
acquisitions
t4
Absolute size of 0.0001** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001***
acquired knowledge [0.00004] [0.00002] [0.00002] [0.00003]
base
t1
Absolute size of 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001***
acquired knowledge [0.00003] [0.00002] [0.00002] [0.00002]
base
t2
Absolute size of 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0002***
acquired knowledge [0.00002] [0.00002] [0.00002] [0.00002]
base
t3
Absolute size of 0.0000 0.0001** 0.0001** 0.0000*
acquired knowledge [0.0000] [0.00004] [0.00004] [0.0001]
base
t4
Relative size of 0.393** 0.387** 0.348*
acquired knowledge [0.165] [0.167] [0.156]
base
t1
Relative size of 0.447*** 0.442*** 0.455***
acquired knowledge [0.144] [0.142] [0.144]
base
t2
Relative size of 0.388*** 0.405*** 0.488***
acquired knowledge [0.125] [0.125] [0.121]
base
t3
Relative size of 0.479** 0.430* 0.369*
acquired knowledge [0.196] [0.198] [0.209]
base
t4
Relatedness of 0.207 0.221
acquired knowledge [0.176] [0.558]
base
t1
Relatedness of 0.002 0.821*
acquired knowledge [0.112] [0.384]
base
t2
Relatedness of 0.158 0.847*
acquired knowledge [0.111] [0.371]
base
t3
Relatedness of 0.151 0.836**
acquired knowledge [0.121] [0.335]
base
t4
Relatedness of 0.820
acquired knowledge [0.911]
base
2t1
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
212 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
Table 2. Continued
Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6
Relatedness of 1.580**
acquired knowledge [0.572]
base
2t2
Relatedness of 1.301*
acquired knowledge [0.572]
base
2t3
Relatedness of 1.251**
acquired knowledge [0.501]
base
2t4
No. of technological 0.023 0.034 0.016 0.018 0.009
acquisitions where [0.026] [0.024] [0.023] [0.023] [0.024]
patents
unavailable
t1
No. of technological 0.011 0.025 0.016 0.016 0.014
acquisitions where [0.024] [0.022] [0.021] [0.021] [0.022]
patents
unavailable
t2
No. of technological 0.039 0.053* 0.043 0.047 0.045
acquisitions where [0.030] [0.027] [0.026] [0.025] [0.025]
patents
unavailable
t3
No. of technological 0.063* 0.068* 0.066* 0.073** 0.077**
acquisitions where [0.020] [0.027] [0.026] [0.026] [0.027]
patents
unavailable
t4
Foreign 0.034** 0.031 0.026 0.035 0.038* 0.040*
acquisitions
t1
[0.012] [0.016] [0.017] [0.019] [0.017] [0.017]
Foreign 0.020* 0.019 0.014 0.023 0.022 0.024
acquisitions
t2
[0.010] [0.013] [0.012] [0.015] [0.015] [0.015]
Foreign 0.020 0.042* 0.051** 0.042* 0.046** 0.043*
acquisitions
t3
[0.013] [0.017] [0.016] [0.017] [0.016] [0.017]
Foreign 0.009 0.008 0.010 0.004 0.008 0.011
acquisitions
t4
[0.013] [0.015] [0.015] [0.017] [0.017] [0.017]
R&D
t1
0.0004 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
[0.001] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.001] [0.001]
Logemployees
t1
0.554*** 0.553*** 0.534*** 0.517*** 0.522*** 0.516***
[0.105] [0.109] [0.099] [0.097] [0.097] [0.096]
Diversification/ 0.176* 0.187* 0.217* 0.180* 0.183* 0.174*
Entropy
t1
[0.076] [0.083] [0.085] [0.080] [0.080] [0.076]
US firm 0.553*** 0.549*** 0.526*** 0.509*** 0.507*** 0.514***
[0.128] [0.130] [0.120] [0.118] [0.117] [0.114]
Japanese firm 0.997*** 1.006*** 0.991*** 0.942*** 0.950*** 0.951***
[0.233] [0.229] [0.219] [0.217] [0.217] [0.216]
Presample patents
t1
0.135*** 0.137*** 0.145*** 0.142*** 0.143*** 0.142***
[0.022] [0.024] [0.024] [0.023] [0.023] [0.022]
output. If we consider a hypothetical acquisition
in which the acquired firm has a knowledge
base with 50 elements (50 elements corresponds
approximately to a firm with 10 owned patents
plus 40 cited patents) then the above coefficient
suggests that this acquisition should lead to a 2
percent increase in innovation output (0.0004
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
50 =0.02) for the acquiring firm after the acqui-
sition, other things being equal.
In Hypothesis 3, a negative relationship was
proposed between the relative size of an acqui-
sition and the subsequent innovation performance
of the acquiring firm. This prediction was also
borne out. Specifically, the individual and
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 213
Table 2. Continued
Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6
N598 598 598 598 598 598
Pearson chi sq./d.f. 10570/579 10491/571 9923/567 9454/563 9448/559 9280/555
2 log-likelihood vis 158*** 1136*** 938*** 12*** 336***
a
`vis the preceding
model
Summed coefficients (Model 6)
No. of nontechnological 0.001
acquisitions [0.054]
Absolute size of 0.0004**
acquired knowledge [0.000]
base
Relative size of 1.660**
acquired knowledge [0.661]
base
Relatedness of 2.725**
acquired knowledge [1.332]
base
Relatedness of 4.951**
acquired knowledge [2.020]
base
2
No. of technological 0.145*
acquisitions where [0.081]
patents unavailable
Foreign acquisitions 0.011
[0.049]
*p0.05; **p0.01; ***p0.001 (one-tailed tests for hypothesized variables, two-tailed tests for controls)
The table gives parameter estimates; standard errors are in brackets. Year dummies are included, but not shown.
summed coefficients for Relative size of acquired
knowledge base are negative, indicating that
acquiring firms that are large relative to the
acquirer leads to a decline in postacquisition inno-
vation output for the acquirer. We also find sup-
port for Hypothesis 4. As shown in Model 6 of
Table 2, the coefficients for Relatedness of
acquired knowledge base are positive, and that
for its squared term, Relatedness of acquired
knowledge base
2
, are negative. These findings
support the argument that the relatedness of
acquisitions has a curvilinear impact on the sub-
sequent innovation output of acquiring firms. The
summed coefficients at the bottom of Table 2
support the same results.
Among the control variables, the coefficients
on Number of technological acquisitions where
patents unavailable for the 1-year, 2-year, and 3-
year lags are positive but not significant. How-
ever, the 4-year lag is positive and significant.
The summed coefficient is positive and signifi-
cant. Thus, technological acquisitions for which
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
we were unable to identify patents also improve
postacquisition innovation output.
Foreign acquisitions, which represents the cul-
tural distance between acquired and acquiring
firms, has a nonsignificant impact on innovation
output. Although the 1-year and 3-year lagged
variables are marginally significant but in
opposite directions (positive and negative,
respectively), the summed coefficient is positive
but not statistically significant (Table 2). Although
these results are not conclusive it appears that,
on balance, foreign acquisitions neither help nor
hurt innovation output. This finding is consistent
with recent research on international acquisitions,
which finds that acquisitions in which the acquirer
and the acquired are from different countries do
not result in greater postacquisition conflict, and,
in fact, often lead to superior postacquisition
performance (Weber, Shenkar, and Raveh, 1996;
Very et al., 1997). Nevertheless, further research
is required to understand this issue more com-
pletely.
214 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
Logemployees, the control measuring the size
of the acquirer, was found to be positively
associated with patenting frequency. Diversifi-
cation is negatively associated with patenting fre-
quency. Prior results on the impact of diversifi-
cation on innovative activity have been mixed;
studies find that diversification has both a positive
and a negative impact on innovation (Cohen and
Levin, 1989). Diversification can either encourage
innovation by providing a stimulus of multiple
knowledge bases within a single firm and by
leading to cross-fertilization of ideas, but it can
also imply a loss of focus in a given technological
area as research efforts are spread in multiple
directions. The results of this research support
the latter interpretation.
The Presample patents variable and several of
the year dummies (not reported) were also sig-
nificant in all the models. This indicates that it
was important to control for unobserved firm
effects as well as period effects in these data.
The Year dummies for 1983–86 were negative
and significant, while all the other year dummies
were nonsignificant, relative to the omitted cate-
gory—1991. These results indicate that patenting
had significantly increased for this set of firms
in the later years (1987–91), relative to the earlier
years (1983–86). The nation dummy variables
reflecting acquirer nationality, Japanese and U.S.,
were also positive and significant, indicating that
Japanese and U.S. firms were likely to obtain
more patents than European firms.
Sensitivity analyses
We also ran several sensitivity tests to check the
robustness of the results. We reconstructed all
the knowledge base measures after separating the
patents obtained by a firm (Own Patents) from
the patents cited by the firm (Cited Patents), and
ran two distinct sets of models. In the first set
we used knowledge-based measures for acquired
and acquiring firms based on only the Own Pat-
ents of the firm (i.e., we excluded Cited Patents).
In the second set we computed all knowledge-
based measures for acquired and acquiring firms
based on only the Cited Patents of the firms (i.e.,
we excluded Own Patents). The results of these
analyses are presented in Table 3. In the interest
of brevity, we only report the summed coef-
ficients and associated t-tests for the models (the
full regression table is available from the authors).
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
Table 3. GEE presample Poisson regression predicting
patents
t
. Own-cited patents measures. Summary of the
summed coefficient results for all lagged variables
Variable Own Cited
patents patents
12
No. of nontechnological 0.007 0.0006
acquisitions [0.057] [0.054]
Absolute size of acquired 0.002***
knowledge base (Own [0.001]
patents)
Relative size of acquired 1.632*
knowledge base (Own [0.708]
patents)
Relatedness of acquired 2.411
knowledge base (Own [3.562]
patents)
Relatedness of acquired 3.568
knowledge base
2
(Own [7.533]
patents)
Absolute size of acquired 0.0004***
knowledge base (Cited [0.000]
patents)
Relative size of acquired 1.653***
knowledge base (Cited [0.465]
patents)
Relatedness of acquired 2.752*
knowledge base (Cited [1.266]
patents)
Relatedness of acquired 4.759**
knowledge base
2
(Cited [1.865]
patents)
No. of technological 0.196* 0.141
acquisitions where patents [0.083] [0.081]
unavailable
Foreign acquisitions 0.003 0.011
[0.003] [0.048]
Reported coefficient estimates are the sum of the four lagged
coefficients (
t1
,
t2
,
t3
,
t4
) for each variable.
*p0.05; **p0.01; ***p0.001 (one-tailed tests for
hypothesized variables, two-tailed tests for controls)
The summed coefficients in Table 3 indicate that
with knowledge base measures based only on
Own Patents (Model 1), the hypotheses (2 and
3) on absolute size of acquired firm and relative
size of acquired firm were strongly supported.
However, the coefficients for the relatedness
hypothesis (4) carried the right signs (+for
relatedness and for its square term), but they
were statistically nonsignificant. In the analysis
based on Cited Patents only (Model 2) all hypoth-
eses (2, 3, and 4) were strongly supported. Thus,
using only patents, or only citations to measure
knowledge bases, provides rather similar results
to using both patents and citations for the absolute
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 215
size and relative size effects. However, in terms
of measuring relatedness, the patents-only meas-
ures do not appear to capture relatedness as well
as the citations-based measures. A comparison of
the results in Table 3 (based on Own Patents or
Cited Patents taken individually) with the results
in Table 2 (based on combining Own and Cited
patents to provide a single measure of knowledge
elements), however, suggests that the relatedness
measure based on both own and cited patents
collectively is more predictive than the measures
based on either Own Patents or Cited Patents
only.
In the results discussed above we used the
Presample Patents variable as a measure of unob-
served differences in the knowledge bases of
firms. The patent production function literature
provides several alternate approaches to construct
indices, reflecting differences in firms’ knowledge
stocks (Griliches, 1984; Hall et al., 1988; Hender-
son and Cockburn, 1996). We constructed several
such indices using different assumptions and input
data. First, we used capitalized historical R&D
expenditures to construct a knowledge stock index
(Hall et al., 1988).
2
Second, we constructed an
index based on the moving average sum of R&
D expenditures for the previous nyears. We
used a depreciation rate of 0.20 (consistent with
Henderson and Cockburn, 1996, and other studies
in this tradition) for the first approach and n=
5 years for the second approach, and estimated
models using these indices in lieu of the R&D
variable. We also computed the knowledge stock
index using cumulative lagged depreciated patent
stocks rather than cumulated lagged depreciated
R&D, and used this as a control variable in our
regression models in place of the Presample Pa-
tents measure. In additional estimation we used
the one period lagged values of the dependent
variable in lieu of the presample variable. The
results for all these approaches (available from
the authors) are very similar to the earlier
reported results.
As noted earlier, the correlations between the
2
Specifically, for the ith firm and tth period, knowledge stock
(K
it
) was computed using the formula K
it
=1δ(K
it1
)+R
it
,
where δstands for depreciation rate for knowledge capital,
and R
it
represents the current-period knowledge flow addition.
The initial stock of capital was computed by dividing the
first observed year’s flow by δ+g, where gis the firm’s
historic rate of growth of real expenditures on R&D
(Henderson and Cockburn, 1996).
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
three control variables, R&D,Logemployees and
Presample patents were high. Although this high
collinearity does not bias coefficient estimates, it
can affect the stability of the estimated coef-
ficients. Consequently, omitting even a few obser-
vations can change the sign or the significance
of the affected variables (Greene, 1993). To
ensure that our results were robust, we drew 50
random samples of 90 percent of the observations
and estimated the full model for each of these
samples. The results of this sensitivity analysis
indicated that the results of our hypothesis testing
were robust.
DISCUSSION
The results of the study indicate support for
our theoretical predictions. Specifically, separating
nontechnological acquisitions from technological
acquisitions and distinguishing between techno-
logical acquisitions on the basis of the absolute
size, relative size, and relatedness of the knowl-
edge bases of the acquired firm helps in predicting
postacquisition innovation output. We do not find
any statistically significant impact of nontechno-
logical acquisitions on subsequent innovation out-
put. Within technological acquisitions, absolute
size of the acquired knowledge base has a posi-
tive impact on innovation output, while relative
size of the acquired knowledge base reduces inno-
vation output. The relatedness of acquired and
acquiring knowledge bases has a nonlinear impact
on innovation output, with acquisition of firms
with high levels of relatedness and unrelatedness
both proving inferior to acquiring firms with mod-
erate levels of relatedness. These findings have
implications for theory, research, and practice.
We discuss these below.
Implications for theory and research
Recent research has highlighted the role of acqui-
sitions as a mechanism for the redeployment of
resources that are subject to market failure
(Anand and Singh, 1997; Capron, Dussauge, and
Mitchell, 1998). In this study we investigated the
effectiveness of such redeployment in the case of
one set of resources that are very susceptible to
market failure, knowledge-based or technological
resources. Our results provide both good and
bad news.
216 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
The positive outcome of this evaluation is that,
when the characteristics of acquisitions are
accounted for, acquisitions improve the techno-
logical performance of the acquiring firm.
Although prior research concluded that acqui-
sitions reduce innovative outputs, this study sug-
gests that under the appropriate circumstances,
even after controlling for innovative inputs such
as R&D, acquisitions can introduce a positive
shock onto innovation output. This finding is also
consistent with the sheer volume of acquisition
activity in the high-technology sector that sug-
gests that managers also view acquisitions as a
mechanism for accessing technology.
The results of this study are also important
from a broader economic perspective. The rapid
growth of technical knowledge in the past few
decades has meant that building and maintaining
expertise in multiple technologies is difficult for
even the largest corporations (Granstrand and Sjo-
lander, 1990; Arora and Gambardella, 1994). Yet,
bringing together different streams of knowledge
is becoming an important precondition to success-
ful innovation in many industries (Grant, 1996;
Powell, Koput, and Smith-Doerr, 1996). This
need for increased differentiation in the develop-
ment of knowledge and increased integration in
its application has given new importance to tech-
nology markets (Demsetz, 1991; Grant, 1996).
Our results indicate that the process of obtaining
technological assets from external sources and
matching them with internally developed assets
to enhance their productivity can work, at least
insofar as the frequency of innovation output
is concerned.
The above arguments highlighted the brighter
aspects of the results. Another perspective on
these results, however, draws attention to their
less positive facets. Prior research has identified
three kinds of deficiencies in the context of
organizational learning: hubris, or underestimating
the likelihood of failure or the difficulty of the
task at hand; overexploration, or venturing into
domains of completely new knowledge; and,
overexploitation, or focusing only on the immedi-
ate neighborhood of the well known and under-
stood and overlooking more distant options
(Levinthal and March, 1993). Our data and results
indicated evidence of all three kinds of errors. To
the extent that relative size serves as a measure of
the relative difficulty of integration, it appears
that underestimating the magnitude of the inte-
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
gration task is not uncommon. Further, the vari-
ation on relatedness, and the curvilinear relation-
ship that we identified between acquisition
relatedness and innovation output, suggests that
in selecting acquisitions managers err in both
directions, acquiring both businesses that are only
distantly related or unrelated to the existing busi-
ness, as well as those that are too closely related
to the current business. The problems of acquiring
unrelated businesses are well documented and our
results further reinforce those lessons (Singh and
Montgomery, 1987). Additionally, our findings
help to highlight errors in the opposite direction.
Managers do make mistakes in picking acqui-
sitions that are too closely related to their extant
domains, and these mistakes are penalized with
poorer performance. Thus, we find some empiri-
cal evidence of ‘competency traps’ (Levinthal and
March, 1993).
Implications for measurement
Our findings also have implications for the litera-
ture on acquisitions in general. Managerial hubris
and agency problems (Roll, 1986; Hayward and
Hambrick, 1997), imitation effects (Haunschild,
1993), inappropriate application of learning
(Haleblian and Finkelstein, 1999), and underesti-
mating the process impediments to postacquisition
integration (Jemison and Sitkin, 1986; Hitt et al.,
1996; Singh and Zollo, 1997) are all valid and
complementary explanations for why acquisitions
consistently fail to help the acquiring firm. The
findings of this paper suggest an additional expla-
nation, one that is perhaps more sympathetic to
managerial motivations and decisions. Evaluating
all acquisitions on the same performance metric,
for instance financial performance, may not be
appropriate. Acquisitions motivated by different
objectives may differ in their timing and mode
of impact on firm performance.
The recent literature has provided several excit-
ing ways of using patent data to measure the
construct of knowledge (Mowery, Oxley, and Sil-
verman, 1998; Jaffe et al., 1993; Stuart and
Podolny, 1996). We build on these studies by
presenting an additional set of measures and
applying them to the context of acquisitions. The
patent-based approach to knowledge measurement
used by this study, and similar approaches used
in prior studies (e.g., Stuart and Podolny, 1996),
have several strengths. A primary strength of
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 217
such approaches is that by using information on
individual elements of knowledge these
approaches make possible a fine-grained assess-
ment of a firm’s knowledge base. Research has
argued that a firm’s knowledge base should ide-
ally be reflected as an asset on its balance sheet
(Granstrand and Sjolander, 1990). Although that
remains unattainable at present, these kinds of
measures do provide some basis for quantifying
this asset and enabling further analysis. A second
strength of these approaches is that they enable
continuous, and highly informative and detailed,
measurement of difficult constructs such as tech-
nological relatedness. Finally, another virtue of
these approaches is that they permit quantification
of knowledge bases from publicly available data,
in a longitudinal context.
The use of distributed lags to study the dynam-
ics of postacquisition performance represents
another potential contribution of this study.
Although the distributed lag technique has been
used by economists, relatively few researchers in
the strategy area have used this methodology.
This approach could be extremely useful in a
variety of strategic contexts that entail studying
the impact of an event or strategy on the perfor-
mance of a unit across several periods.
Implications for managers
The findings of this study draw managers’ atten-
tion to several paradoxical aspects of the acqui-
sition selection and integration process. This study
indicates that larger absolute size and smaller
relative size of acquisitions are associated with
superior postacquisition performance for the
acquiring firm. Further, a moderate level of
relatedness is preferable to acquiring a firm that
is very closely related, or distant to the acquiring
firm. Thus, from the acquisition selection stand-
point this research suggests that a balance on both
size and relatedness of acquisitions is favored.
Limitations and future research
Several limitations of this study are worth noting.
The restriction of the sample to a single industrial
context reinforces the need for conducting the
study in other industries. Additionally, the rel-
evance and utility of the patent-based measures
of knowledge are likely to be limited to industries
in which patents are themselves meaningful indi-
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
cators of innovation. In addition to the chemicals
sector some of the other contexts in which these
measures could be applied include biotechnology,
semiconductors, industrial machinery, and
advanced materials.
Another limitation of this study that suggests
an area of future research is the use of patents
to measure innovative output. Although patents
are reasonably good indicators of innovative out-
put, they are best regarded as intermediate out-
comes between acquisitions and value creation.
While our results indicate that acquisitions accel-
erate the creation of technologically new combi-
nations and innovations, they do not allow us to
directly measure the value generated by these
innovations. Examining the economic value of
postacquisition innovations would be a natural
extension of the work in this study and would
enable a more complete assessment of the contri-
bution of technological acquisitions to technologi-
cal development.
Finally, in this paper we used only a simple
count measure for nontechnological acquisitions.
However, such acquisitions could themselves vary
on many dimensions and reflect many different
objectives. The development of a schema to mea-
sure the various dimensions of nontechnological
acquisitions and relating them to different types
of firm outcomes would be another fruitful direc-
tion of further research.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
We thank Jim Fredrickson, George Huber, Jim
Westphal, the editor, and two anonymous
reviewers for comments that helped us to refine
our thinking. We especially thank Risto Miikku-
lainen for assistance and advice on the computer
programs used to compute the patent citation
variables. We gratefully acknowledge the finan-
cial support of the University of Texas at Austin.
The first author also acknowledges the support
of the Center for International Business Education
and Research at the University of Michigan.
REFERENCES
Achilladelis B, Schwarzkopf A, Cines M. 1987. A
218 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
study of innovation in the pesticide industry: analysis
of the innovation record of an industrial sector.
Research Policy 16(2–4): 175–212.
Anand J, Singh H. 1997. Asset redeployment, acqui-
sitions and corporate strategy in declining industries.
Strategic Management Journal, Summer Special
Issue 18: 99–118.
Arora A, Gambardella A. 1994. Evaluating technologi-
cal information and utilizing it: scientific knowledge,
technological capability, and external linkages in
biotechnology. Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization 24(1): 91–114.
Arundel A, Kabla I. 1998. What percentage of inno-
vations are patented? Empirical estimates for Euro-
pean firms. Research Policy 27: 127–141.
Balakrishnan S. 1988. The prognostics of diversifying
acquisitions. Strategic Management Journal 9(2):
185–196.
Basberg B. 1983. Foreign patenting in the U.S. as a
technology indicator: the case of Norway. Research
Policy 12: 227–237.
Basberg B. 1987. Patents and the measurement of
technological change: a survey of the literature.
Research Policy 16(2–4): 131–141.
Blundell R, Griffith R, Van Reenen J. 1995. Dynamic
count data models of technological innovation. Eco-
nomic Journal 105(429): 333–344.
Capron L, Dussauge P, Mitchell W. 1998. Resource
redeployment following horizontal acquisitions in
Europe and North America, 1988–1992. Strategic
Management Journal 19(7): 631–661.
Capron L, Mitchell W, Swaminathan A. 1998. Resource
redeployment following horizontal acquisitions in
Europe and North America, 1988–1992. Strategic
Management Journal 19(7): 631–661.
Chakrabarti A, Hauschildt J, Suverkrup C. 1994. Does
it pay to acquire technological firms? R&D Manage-
ment 24(1): 47–56.
Chatterjee S. 1991. Gains in vertical acquisitions and
market power: theory and evidence. Academy of
Management Journal 34(2): 436–448.
Chemical Week. 1983. The push to buy technology.
134(Sept. 14): 44.
Cohen W, Levin R. 1989. Empirical studies of inno-
vation and market structure. In Handbook of Indus-
trial Organization (II). Schmalensee R, Willig RD
(eds). Elsevier: Amsterdam; 1059–1107.
Cohen WM, Levinthal D. 1989. Innovation and learn-
ing: the two faces of R&D. Economic Journal
99(397): 569–596.
Cohen W, Levinthal D. 1990. Absorptive capacity: a
new perspective on learning and innovation. Admin-
istrative Science Quarterly 35: 128–152.
Comanor W, Scherer F. 1969. Patent statistics as a
measure of technical change. Journal of Political
Economy 77(3): 392–398.
Curry S. 1997. The year of the very big deals. Fortune
Nov. 24: 36–37.
Demsetz H. 1991. The theory of the firm revisited. In
The Nature of the Firm, Williamson O, Winter S
(eds). Oxford University Press: New York; 159–178.
Dosi G, Pavitt K, Suete L. 1990. The Economics of
Technical Change and International Trade. New
York University Press: New York.
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
Fleming L. 1999. Recombinant uncertainty in techno-
logical search. working paper, Harvard Business
School.
Fowler KL, Schmidt DR. 1988. Tender offers, acqui-
sitions, and subsequent performance in manufactur-
ing firms. Academy of Management Journal 31(4):
962–974.
Gerpott T. 1995. Successful integration of R&D func-
tions after acquisitions: an exploratory empirical
study. R&D Management 25(2): 161–178.
Gibson WD. 1985. Tracking technology around the
globe. Chemical Week 136(24): 34.
Granstrand O, Bohlin E, Oskarsson C, Sjoberg N. 1992.
External technology acquisitions in large multi-tech-
nology corporations. R&D Management 22(2):
111–133.
Granstrand O, Sjolander S. 1990. The acquisition of
technology and small firms by large firms. Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization 13(3): 367–386.
Grant RM. 1996. Prospering in dynamically-competitive
environments: organizational capability as knowledge
integration. Organization Science 7(4): 375–387.
Greene W. 1993. Econometric Analysis. Macmillan:
New York.
Griliches Z. 1979. Issues in assessing the contribution
of research and development to productivity growth.
Bell Journal of Economics 10(Spring): 92–116.
Griliches Z. 1984. Introduction. In R&D, Patents and
Productivity, Griliches Z (ed). University of Chicago
Press: Chicago, IL; 1–20.
Griliches Z. 1990. Patent statistics as economic indi-
cators: a survey. Journal of Economic Literature
28(4): 1661–1707.
Gujarati D. 1988. Basic Econometrics. 2nd edn,
McGraw-Hill: New York.
Haleblian J, Finkelstein S. 1999. The influence of
organization acquisition experience on acquisition
performance. Administrative Science Quarterly
44(1): 29–56.
Hall B, Griliches Z, Hausman J. 1986. Patents and
RandD: is there a lag? International Economic
Review 27(2): 265–283.
Hall B, Cummins C, Laderman E, Mundy J. 1988. The
R&D master file documentation. NBER Technical
Working Paper Series, no. 72.
Haspeslagh PC, Jemison DB. 1991. Managing Acqui-
sitions: Creating Value Through Corporate Renewal.
Free Press: New York.
Haunschild PR. 1993. Interorganizational imitation: the
impact of interlocks on corporate acquisition activity.
Administrative Science Quarterly 38(4): 564–592.
Hausman J, Hall B, Griliches Z. 1984. Econometric
models for count data with an application to the
patents–R&D relationship. Econometrica 52: 909–
938.
Hayward MLA, Hambrick DC. 1997. Explaining the
premium paid for large acquisitions: evidence of
CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly 42(1):
103–127.
Henderson RM, Clark KB. 1990. Architectural inno-
vation: the reconfiguration of existing product
technologies and the failure of established firms.
Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 9–30.
Henderson R, Cockburn I. 1996. Scale, scope, and
Technological Acquisitions and Innovation 219
spillovers: the determinants of research productivity
in drug discovery. RAND Journal of Economics
27(1): 32–59.
Hitt MA, Hoskisson RE, Ireland RD, Harrison JS.
1991. Effects of acquisitions on R&D inputs and
outputs. Academy of Management Journal 34(3):
693–706.
Hitt MA, Hoskisson RE, Johnson RA, Moesel DD.
1996. The market for corporate control and firm
innovation. Academy of Management Journal 39(5):
1084–1119.
Hofstede G. 1980. Culture’s Consequences: Inter-
national Differences in Work-Related Values. Sage:
Beverly Hills, CA.
Hoskisson RA, Hitt MA, Ireland D. 1994. The effects
of acquisitions and restructuring (strategic
refocusing) strategies on innovation. In The Manage-
ment of Corporate Acquisitions: International Per-
spectives. Von Krogh G, Sinatra A, Singh H (eds).
Macmillan: Houndmills; 144–169.
Huber G. 1991. Organizational learning: the contribut-
ing processes and a review of the literatures. Organi-
zation Science 2(1): 88–117.
Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R. 1993. Geographic
localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced
by patent citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics
108: 577–598.
Jemison DB, Sitkin SB. 1986. Corporate acquisitions:
a process perspective. Academy of Management
Review 11(1): 145–163.
Judge GG, Hill RC, Griffiths WE, Lu
¨tkepohl HH, Lee
T. 1988. Introduction to the Theory and Practice of
Econometrics. 2nd edn, Wiley: New York.
Kamien M, Schwartz N. 1982. Market Structure and
Innovation. Cambridge University Press: New
York.
Kim D-J, Kogut B. 1996. Technological platforms and
diversification. Organization Science 7(3): 283–301.
Kogut B, Singh H. 1988. The effect of national culture
on the choice of entry mode. Journal of Inter-
national Business Studies 19(Fall): 411–432.
Kogut B, Zander U. 1992. Knowledge of the firm,
combinative capabilities, and the replication of tech-
nology. Organization Science 3(3): 383–397.
Lane PJ, Lubatkin M. 1998. Relative absorptive
capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic
Management Journal 19(5): 461–477.
Levin RC, Klevorick AK, Nelson RR, Winter SG,
Gilbert R, Griliches Z. 1987. Appropriating the
returns from industrial research and development:
comments and discussion. Brookings Papers on Eco-
nomic Activity 3: 783–831.
Levinthal D, March J. 1993. The myopia of learning.
Strategic Management Journal, Winter Special Issue
14: 95–112.
Liang K-Y, Zeger S. 1986. Longitudinal data analysis
using generalized linear models. Biometrika 73(1):
13–22.
Link A. 1988. Acquisitions as sources of technological
innovation. Mergers & Acquisitions 23(November/
December): 36–39.
Lubatkin M. 1983. Mergers and the performance of the
acquiring firm. Academy of Management Review
8(2): 218–225.
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
Mowery D, Oxley J, Silverman B. 1998. Technological
overlap and interfirm cooperation: implications for
the resource-based view of the firm. Research Policy
27(5): 507–523.
Narin F, Noma E, Perry R. 1987. Patents as indicators
of corporate technological strength. Research Policy
16(2–4): 143–155.
Pakes A, Griliches Z. 1984. Patents and R&D at the
firm level: a first look. In R&D, Patents and Pro-
ductivity, Griliches Z (ed). University of Chicago
Press: Chicago, IL.
Palepu K. 1985. Diversification strategy, profit perfor-
mance and the entropy measure. Strategic Manage-
ment Journal 6(3): 239–255.
Patel P, Pavitt K. 1997. The technological competencies
of the world’s largest firms: complex and path-
dependent, but not much variety. Research Policy
26: 141–156.
Podolny JM, Stuart TE. 1995. A role-based ecology of
technological change. American Journal of Sociology
100(5): 1224–1260.
Powell WW, Koput KW, Smith-Doerr L. 1996.
Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of
innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology.
Administrative Science Quarterly 41(1): 116–145.
Pritchett P. 1985. Managing people problems in deals
that don’t close. Journal of Buyouts & Acquisitions
3(7): 35–38.
Roll R. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate take-
overs. Journal of Business 59(2): 197–216.
Schankerman M, Pakes A. 1986. Estimates of the value
of patent rights in European countries during the
post-1950 period. Economic Journal 96: 1052–1077.
Scherer F. 1965. Corporate inventive output, prof-
itability and sales growth. Journal of Political Econ-
omy 73(3): 290–297.
Scherer F, Ross D. 1990. Industrial Market Structure
and Economic Performance. Houghton Mifflin: Bos-
ton, MA.
Schumpeter J. 1934. The Theory of Economic Develop-
ment. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.
Singh H, Montgomery CA. 1987. Corporate acquisition
strategies and economic performance. Strategic Man-
agement Journal 8(4): 377–386.
Singh H, Zollo M. 1997. Knowledge accumulation
mechanisms and the evolution of post-acquisition
integration strategies. Working paper, University of
Pennsylvania.
Spender J-C. 1989. Industry Recipes: An Inquiry into
the Nature and Sources of Managerial Judgement.
Blackwell: New York.
Stuart TE, Podolny JM. 1996. Local search and the
evolution of technological capabilities. Strategic
Management Journal, Summer Special Issue 17:
21–38.
Thompson J. 1967. Organizations in Action. McGraw-
Hill: New York.
Trajtenberg M. 1990. Economic Analysis of Product
Innovation: The Case of CT Scanners. Harvard Uni-
versity Press: Cambridge, MA.
Tushman M, Rosenkopf L. 1992. Organizational deter-
minants of technological change: toward a sociology
of technological evolution. Research in Organiza-
tional Behavior 14: 311–347.
220 G. Ahuja and R. Katila
Utterback J. 1994. Mastering the Dynamics of Inno-
vation: How Companies can Seize Opportunities in
the Face of Technological Change. Harvard Business
School Press: Boston, MA.
Very P, Lubatkin M, Calori R, Veiga J. 1997. Relative
standing and the performance of recently acquired
European firms. Strategic Management Journal
18(8): 593–614.
Walker R. 1995. Patents as Scientific and Technical
Literature. Scarecrow Press: Lanham, MD.
APPENDIX
The list of patents obtained by a firm, and the
patents cited by the firm in the patents obtained
by it, is used as the measure of the firm’s knowl-
edge base. Since a firm’s own patents represent
knowledge created by the firm, their use as
components of the firm’s knowledge base is natu-
ral. However, the use of patents cited by the firm
as a component of the firm’s own knowledge
base may require further explanation.
Patent citations represent an acknowledgement
of the contributions of prior work in the develop-
ment of the current invention. As Jaffe et al.
(1993: 580) note:
The granting of the patent is a legal statement
that the idea embodied in the patent represents
a novel or useful contribution over and above
the previous state of knowledge, as represented
by the citations. Thus, in principle, a citation of
Patent X by Patent Y means that X represents a
piece of previously existing knowledge upon
which Y builds.
A citation thus represents a restriction on an
owner’s rights to exploit her own patent, and is
therefore not likely to be made if the cited patent
Copyright 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 197–220 (2001)
Weber Y, Shenkar O, Raveh A. 1996. National and
corporate cultural fit in mergers/acquisitions: an
exploratory study. Management Science 42(8):
1215–1227.
Wysocki B. 1997a. Why an acquisition? Often, it’s the
people. Wall Street Journal October 6: 1.
Wysocki B. 1997b. Many mergers driven by search for
fresh talent. Chicago Tribune December 28: 67.
does not truly represent knowledge underlying
the current patent.
The legal aspects of the patenting process
also ensure that patents that do truly represent
preexisting knowledge are cited with accuracy
in patents that build upon them. First, all appli-
cants are required by law to acknowledge all
‘prior art’ through citations. Second, to oversee
this process, each patent and its citations must
be cleared by a patent examiner before the
patent is actually granted. The patent examiner,
who is usually an expert in the technological
domain under which the patent falls, conducts
a search of the prior art in the area and adds
any citations that the patent applicant’s own
search may have missed. Since citations circum-
scribe the exploitable domain of the applicant’s
patent, the patent applicant is likely to contest
these citations if they do not accurately rep-
resent prior related knowledge. Together, this
system represents a set of checks and balances
that ensures that patent citations are relatively
robust indicators of knowledge flows
(Trajtenberg, 1990; Jaffe et al., 1993). Thus,
the assignee of a patent is likely to know the
contents of the patents cited by her, at least to
a level of familiarity, and perhaps to mastery.
... Intergenerational knowledge transfer (IKT) is a critical process within organizations that involves the sharing, dissemination, and acquisition of knowledge and expertise between individuals of different generations (Nahapiet & Ghoshal, 1998). It encompasses the transfer of tacit knowledge, explicit knowledge, skills, experiences, and insights from older generations (mentors) to younger generations (mentees) (Ahuja & Katila, 2001). Tacit knowledge, often rooted in personal experiences and insights, is challenging to articulate and codify, making its transfer highly dependent on interpersonal interactions and socialization processes (Nonaka & Takeuchi, 1995). ...
... Technological advancements have also transformed the landscape of IKT by providing digital platforms and tools for virtual collaboration, communication, and knowledge sharing (Hildreth & Kimble, 2002). Virtual mentoring, online communities, and social networking sites offer opportunities for geographically dispersed individuals to connect, exchange ideas, and access expertise across generational boundaries (Ahuja & Katila, 2001). ...
Article
This study examines the dynamics of intergenerational knowledge transfer among young hospital staff. Through a sample of 361 participants, the research investigates the impact of learner motivation, organizational atmosphere, and absorption capacity on knowledge sharing and innovation. Findings reveal a significant positive relationship between learner motivation and both online and offline knowledge transfer, emphasizing the pivotal role of intrinsic drive-in facilitating knowledge exchange. Moreover, the study identifies organizational atmosphere as a moderator, highlighting its influence on the effectiveness of knowledge transfer processes. Additionally, absorption capacity emerges as a critical factor in enhancing the efficacy of knowledge dissemination within healthcare settings. These results underscore the importance of fostering a supportive organizational culture and developing individuals' intrinsic motivation to promote knowledge sharing and innovation among hospital staff.
... When firms acquire or merge with other firms, they can gain access to new resources, technologies and expertise that allow them to innovate quickly and also to generate synergies by amalgamating innovation-related resources (Ahuja and Katila, 2001;Bresciani and Ferraris, 2016;Dezi et al., 2018;Rahman and Lambkin, 2015;Stiebale, 2016;Tunyi and Ntim, 2016). Studying environmental innovation within the context of M&As is interesting for two main reasons. ...
Article
Full-text available
Drawing from the resource-based view (RBV), we examine the effect of environmental innovation on mergers and acquisitions (M&As) announcement returns. Using an international sample of M&As for the period 2003 to 2021 and an event study methodology , we document that acquirers with higher environmental innovation-innovative acquirers-earn average deal announcement abnormal returns that are 0.10 to 0.50 percentage points higher than those earned by their non-innovative counterparts. These results are consistent across three important forms of environmental innovation (i.e., product, process and organizational innovation) and are partly explained by the transfer of environmental innovation from the acquirer to the target. We further find that environmentally innovative acquirers are more likely to engage in majority control and cross-border acquisitions, thus emphasizing the transfer effect. Overall, we contribute to RBV by providing evidence that environmental innovation is a distinctive resource or dynamic capability that is transferable from bidders to targets in the takeover market.
... ‫وينشئ‬ ‫تضيف‬ ‫عندما‬ ‫االبتكار‬ ‫هل‬ ‫السياسة،‬ ‫و‬ ‫التسليم‬ ‫ونظام‬ ‫التسويق‬ ‫و‬ ‫العمليات‬ ‫و‬ ‫اخلدمات‬ ‫و‬ ‫السلع‬ ‫إىل‬ ‫قيمة‬ ‫املؤسسة‬(Müller, Rammer, & Trüby, 2009) . ‫االبتكا‬ ‫يهدف‬ ‫حيث‬ ‫املؤسسة‬ ‫وعملية‬ ‫الداخلي‬ ‫اهليكل‬ ‫حتسني‬ ‫إىل‬ ‫ر‬ ‫السوق‬ ‫يطلبها‬ ‫اليت‬ ‫اخلدمات‬ ‫و‬ ‫السلع‬ ‫وإنشاء‬ ‫ه:‬ ّ ‫أن‬ ‫على‬ ‫يفه‬ ‫تعر‬ ‫مت‬ ‫فقد‬ ‫االبتكاري‬ ‫األداء‬ ‫ا‬ ّ ‫أم‬ ، ‫للمؤسسة"‬ ‫املبتكرة‬ ‫املدخالت‬ ‫و‬ ‫االبتكار‬ ‫جهود‬ ‫خالل‬ ‫من‬ ‫عليه‬ ‫املتحصل‬ ‫"الناتج‬(Ahuja & Katila, 2001) ، ‫وقد‬ ‫األنظمة‬ ‫و‬ ‫العمليات‬ ‫و‬ ‫املنتجات‬ ‫و‬ ‫األجهزة‬ ‫من‬ ‫مناذج‬ ‫الرسومات،‬ ‫و‬ ‫األفكار‬ ‫حيث‬ ‫من‬ ‫املؤسسات‬ ‫ات‬ ‫إجناز‬ ‫ه‬ ّ ‫أن‬ ‫على‬ ‫داه‬ ّ ‫حد‬ ‫اجلديدة.‬ ‫الباحث‬ ‫بطه‬ ‫ور‬ ، ‫ون‬(Zhenxing , Zanzan , Shuo, & Haoyun , 2018, pp. ...
Article
Full-text available
The purpose of this study is to assess the impact of dynamic capabilities in its four dimensions sensing capabilities, learning capabilities, integration and coordination capabilities, reconfiguration capabilities on the performance of SME's with innovative performance as an intermediary role. We used the descriptive and analytical method, by using a questionnaire, which were processed using structural equation modeling based on the Smart PLS 4.0 program. The results concluded that there is a positive effect of sensing capabilities and reconfiguration of resources on innovative performance, and a strong positive effect of innovative performance on performance. On the performance with the presence of innovative performance as a mediating role, while there is no direct influence relationship for the dimensions of the four dynamic capabilities on the performance of SME's. Hence, the study recommends the need to pay attention to developing appropriate strategies and putting them into practice to achieve integration and coordination and improve their learning abilities in a way that improves performance and innovative performance. تهدف هذه الدراسة إلى تقييم تأثير القدرات الديناميكية بأبعادها الأربعة: القدرات الاستشعارية، وقدرات التعلم، وقدرات التكامل والتنسيق، وقدرات إعادة التشكيل على أداء الشركات الصغيرة والمتوسطة، مع قيام الأداء الابتكاري بدور الوسيط. معالجة 88 استبانة صالحة للدراسة باستخدام نماذج المعادلات البنائية المعتمدة على برنامج Smart PLS 4.0. وخلصت الدراسة إلى أن هناك تأثير إيجابي لقدرات الاستشعار وإعادة تشكيل الموارد على أداء الابتكار، وتأثير إيجابي قوي لأداء الابتكار على الأداء، فضلا عن وجود علاقة تأثير غير مباشر لقدرات الكشف وقدرات إعادة التشكيل على الأداء مع وجود الأداء الابتكاري كدور وسيط، وغياب علاقة التأثير المباشر مع أبعاد قدرات الديناميكيات الأربع على أداء المؤسسات الصغيرة والمتوسطة. ومن هنا توصي الدراسة بضرورة الاهتمام بوضع الاستراتيجيات المناسبة ووضعها موضع التنفيذ لتحقيق التكامل والتنسيق وتحسين قدراتهم على التعلم بما يؤدي إلى تحسين الأداء والأداء الابتكاري. اسم المجلة: مجلة البشائر الاقتصادية
Article
Material adverse change (MAC) clauses and contingent earnouts are important contractual mechanisms used to protect acquirers from the risk of adverse selection. Yet, the extant literature has not sufficiently explored the antecedents of their use, in particular within the context of technology acquisitions. In this study, we take advantage of the passage of the American Inventors Protection Act (AIPA), which disseminated information through the publication of patent applications, to explore the impact of innovation disclosures on the design of technology acquisition contracts. Consistent with the view that an increase in the availability of information related to the broader technological landscape reduces the need for contractual protections in acquisition contracts, our analysis demonstrates that deals disproportionately affected by AIPA have less expansive MAC clauses and are less likely to feature contingent earnouts. These results provide new evidence linking the use of MAC clauses and earnouts with acquisitions subject to information frictions.
Article
Collaboration networks are widely recognized as essential channels for accessing innovation resources and facilitating creative activities by enabling the exchange of knowledge and information. However, there is little known about whether and how the similarities and dissimilarities between actors forming ties in a collaboration network can either stimulate or inhibit firms’ breakthrough innovation. This study explores the relationship between degree assortativity in collaboration networks and breakthrough innovation performance, considering the moderating role of knowledge network characteristics. Using a sample of 80,129 semiconductor patents from the United States Patent and Trademark Office database spanning the years 1975 to 2007, we constructed both the internal collaboration network and the knowledge network of firms. To test our hypotheses, we employed a negative binomial regression model. Our findings demonstrate that firms with lower degree assortativity in their collaboration networks tend to exhibit higher levels of breakthrough innovation performance compared to those with higher degree assortativity. Moreover, the number of direct ties in the knowledge network strengthens the negative relationship between collaboration network degree assortativity and breakthrough innovation. Conversely, the number of non-redundant ties in the knowledge network mitigates the negative relationship between collaboration network degree assortativity and breakthrough innovation. This study provides practical guidance for firms aiming to enhance their innovation capabilities by simultaneously developing internal collaboration networks and knowledge networks.
Chapter
Existing theoretical and empirical researchers associated innovation with technological transformations and introduced radical/disruptive products and processes. However, considering the approaches and theories would be limited to manufacturing industries, innovation in service industries with non-technological aspects needs to be noticed. This study emphasises the need for a synthesis approach that could play a major role in building/enhancing service business models/frameworks. These frameworks need a stronger focus on using organizational, strategic, and marketing innovation typologies in formulating service business models resulting in low customer engagement and customer experience management. This chapter discusses various new business models that have evolved their features and benefits. Finally, this study concludes by emphasising the need for incorporating non-technical components when innovating in services and services-based firms.
Article
Purpose Drawing on organizational design theory and organizational learning theory, this paper aims to examine component technology (CT) and the interaction between CT and experiential learning (EL) effects on the degree of integration (DI) of cross-border technological acquisitions. Design/methodology/approach Using a sample of 267 firms consisting of 229 acquirer firms who started cross-border technological acquisitions from developed economies and 38 acquirer firms who initiated cross-border technological acquisitions from emerging economies over the period of 1993–2016, this study adopts a value chain framework to measure the acquirers’ acquisition integration degree for the investigation of the effects of CT and the interaction between CT and EL. Findings First, this paper finds CT in cross-border technological acquisitions exerting a positive influence on the acquirer firm’s likelihood of the DI implementation, in line with the organizational design theory. Second, in view of organizational learning theory, this study finds EL and the combined effect of CT and EL to have an inverse influence on the DI. Practical implications The results imply that the moderating role of EL significantly optimizes decision choices for an acquirer firm for integration implementation strategies in the form of DI, such as full integration (structural integration), partial integration and no integration (structural separation), which appears to be crucial for cross-border technological acquisitions. Originality/value This study contributed to international business strategies by shedding light on the importance of the DI for an acquirer firm that undertakes a cross-border technological acquisition with a CT target firm. This study explains why structural integration might be necessary in cross-border technological acquisitions regardless of the costs of disruption it imposes, as well as the contexts in which it becomes less important or unnecessary. The study disclosed that the increase in the likelihood of DI because of CT depends on the EL of the acquisition company in the host country environment and fluctuates with the prior acquisition knowledge and EL of the host country. Combining two cross-border technological acquisition’s literature streams, such as CT and EL, this study enlightens the importance of organizational learning theory and theory of organization design strategic direction making on acquisition integration implementation strategies.
Article
Knowledge management in universities is a dual process combining continuous learning and development of academic staff with the simultaneous transfer of knowledge to students. Collective capabilities and motivation of university employees to absorb and effectively apply knowledge underlie the so-called university absorptive capacity. However, characteristics perceived by workers and the level of absorptive capacity may contrast with the assessments based on university performance standards. The paper proposes and tests a dual method for judging on university absorptive capacity based on normative and perceived assessments. Methodologically, the study rests on knowledge management, the fundamental theoretical framework that covers the concept of absorptive capacity of an organization. Among the research methods are comparative analysis of university performance indicators and economic statistics. Empirical evidence includes data from the survey of 187 academic staff members of Ural Federal University (Ekaterinburg, Russia) and the Monitoring of Efficiency of Higher Educational Institutions in the RF in 2022–2023. Having performed content analysis, we identified the following evaluation parameters: the current level of employees’ knowledge and the potential for knowledge absorption in the organization. The first part of the methodology presents an algorithm for comparing the growth rates of normative performance indicators of the university in question with those of analogous universities. The second part deals with assessing absorptive capacity based on academic staff’s perceptions. The testing results indicate that there is a discrepancy between the normative and perceived assessments, which allowed us to propose a set of measures for adjusting the HR management model in a university.
Article
Full-text available
Much of the prior research on interorganizational learning has focused on the role of absorptive capacity, a firm's ability to value, assimilate, and utilize new external knowledge. However, this definition of the construct suggests that a firm has an equal capacity to learn from all other organizations. We reconceptualize the Jinn-level construct absorptive capacity as a learning dyad-level construct, relative absorptive capacity. One firm's ability to learn from another firm is argued to depend on the similarity of both firms' (1) knowledge bases, (2) organizational structures and compensation policies, and (3) dominant logics. We then test the model using a sample of pharmaceutical-biotechnology RED alliances. As predicted, the similarity of the partners' basic knowledge, lower management formalization, research centralization, compensation practices, and research communities were positively related to interorganizational learning. The relative absorptive capacity measures are also shown to have greater explanatory power than the established measure of absorptive capacity, R&D spending. (C) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Chapter
In 1937, Ronald H. Coase published The Nature of the Firm, a classic paper that raised fundamental questions about the concept of the firm in economic theory. Coase proposed that the comparative costs of organizing transactions through markets, rather than within firms, are the primary determinants of the size and scope of firms. This volume derives from a conference held in 1987 to commemorate the fiftieth anniversary of the publication of Coase's classic article. The first chapter gives an overview of the volume. It is followed by a re-publication of the 1937 article, and by the three lectures Coase presented at the conference. These lectures provide a lively and informative history of the origins and development of his thought. Subsequent chapters explore a wide range of theoretical and empirical issues that have arisen in the transaction cost economic tradition. They illustrate the power of the transaction cost approach to enhance understanding not only of business firms, but of problems of economic organization generally. Contributors: Ronald H. Coase, Sherwin Rosen, Paul Joskow, Oliver Hart, Harold Demsetz, Scott Masten, Benjamin Klein, Oliver Williamson, and Sidney Winter.
Chapter
The decline in global competitiveness among US firms has been well documented (Franko 1989; Hill, Hitt and Hoskisson 1988; Young 1985). Accompanying this decline has been an increase in merger and acquisition activity that occurred in two surges — one in the late 1960s and one in the 1980s (Ravenscraft and Scherer 1987). Research has shown that acquisition strategies may involve trade-offs. For example, while acquired firms’ shareholders often gain significant abnormal returns, acquiring firms’ shareholders, on average, receive zero or slightly positive returns (Jensen 1988). The purpose of this paper is to examine the potential link between the decline in competitiveness and acquisition and divestiture (refocusing) activity.
Chapter
The study of the relationship between market structure and innovation by economists is a relatively recent phenomenon that can be traced back to the mid-1950s. Prior to that time the bulk of economic analysis took the number of products and their means of production as determined exogenously, just as consumers’ tastes were taken as an exogenous given. With a few exceptions, economists appeared to be unconcerned with the economic incentives that determined the pace and direction of innovation despite the fact that this activity had begun to be institutionalized about 1876, when industrial research laboratories began to be established both in the United States and in Europe. The exceptions include Taussig (1915), Hicks (1932), Galbraith (1952), and most importantly Schumpeter (1961, 1964, 1975). It was Schumpeter who argued most persuasively that it was competition through introduction of new products and methods of production that was far more important than price competition, in the long run. For it was through innovative activity that economic development that resulted in higher per capita income took place.
Article
Historically, acquisition scholars and practitioners have adopted a choice perspective which portrays the corporate executive analyzing acquisition opportunities as a rational decision maker. This paper suggests that the choice perspective be supplemented with a process perspective which recognizes the acquisition process itself as a potentially important determinant of activities and outcomes. A series of research propositions is offered suggesting how four impediments present in the process itself might affect acquisition outcomes.