ArticlePDF Available

6 Structure, Affect and Identity as Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Competing organizations are often defined by their niche overlap or structural equivalence in resource dependence, but the very structure that defines competitors can also identify cooperators. There is a fine line between competition and cooperation, but current theories give insufficient guidance as to which will take place and also contribute to the belief that cooperation between competitors is illegitimate. We show that the legitimacy of these practices, as well the evaluation of their welfare implications, are context bound. Individuals and societies that have been influenced by different theories of competition could reasonably (and have) reach different conclusions as to the legitimacy of competitor cooperation. We then critique extant ideas as to when competitors will cooperate, which rely on industry structure, and suggest instead that perception and social identity are more important in tipping the cooperate-compete balance. We conclude by showing how our arguments inform an important current stream of management research, on the process of institutional change.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
The Academy of Management Annals
Vol. 2, No. 1, 2008, 275–303
275
ISSN 1941-6520 print/ISSN 1941-6067 online
© 2008 Academy of Management
DOI: 10.1080/19416520802211578
http://www.informaworld.com
6
Structure, Affect and Identity as Bases of
Organizational Competition
and Cooperation
PAUL INGRAM
*
Columbia Business School
LORI QINGYUAN YUE
Columbia Business School
Taylor and FrancisRAMA_A_321324.sgm10.1080/19416520802211578Academy of Management Annals1941-6520 (print)/1941-6067 (online)Original Article2008Taylor & Francis21000000August 2008PaulIngrampi17@columbia.edu
Abstract
Competing organizations are often defined by their niche overlap or structural
equivalence in resource dependence, but the very structure that defines compet-
itors can also identify cooperators. There is a fine line between competition
and cooperation, but current theories give insufficient guidance as to which will
take place and also contribute to the belief that cooperation between competi-
tors is illegitimate. We show that the legitimacy of these practices, as well the
evaluation of their welfare implications, are context bound. Individuals and
societies that have been influenced by different theories of competition could
reasonably (and have) reach different conclusions as to the legitimacy of
*
Corresponding author. Email: pi17@columbia.edu
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
276
The Academy of Management Annals
competitor cooperation. We then critique extant ideas as to when competitors
will cooperate, which rely on industry structure, and suggest instead that percep-
tion and social identity are more important in tipping the cooperate–compete
balance. We conclude by showing how our arguments inform an important
current stream of management research, on the process of institutional change.
Introduction
A common definition of competitors is actors who share an interest in some of
the same resources. In other words, competition derives from occupying simi-
lar positions in resource space. There is broad agreement on this structural
model of competition, even between scholars who approach the issue from
economic versus sociological traditions. There is also a concise set of
approaches for identifying structural similarity, which can be ordered in terms
of the precision in the representation of organizations’ resource requirements.
The coarsest approach is to identify competitors according to broad types,
where the types are often called industries or populations. The second
approach breaks down industries and populations into smaller, more similar
groups on criteria such as location, strategy and organizational form. The
third, most refined approach moves away from categorization and examines
the pattern of resource reliance of organizations more directly. The first stage
of this paper outlines these popular treatments of competition.
We next argue that the same structural conditions that seed competition
also present opportunities for cooperation. As Barnett (2006, p. 1753) puts it,
“rivals are also roommates”. This admits a troubling indeterminacy in the
relationship between the structural position of organizations and the level of
competition between them. Similarity in resource space might lead organiza-
tions to harm or help each other. Put bluntly, the frameworks that economists
and sociologists have built on the foundational idea that structural similarity
equates with competition are shaky.
How is it, then, that various management theories have converged on
structural similarity as the key antecedent of competition when that anteced-
ent seems as likely to bring cooperation? We think this is at least partly due to
the fact that various theories have attributed positive outcomes to competi-
tion as opposed to cooperation between similar organizations. The economic
view of competition derives from the welfare-enhancing assumptions of the
theory of perfect competition, where resources are used most efficiently when
competition is greatest. A kindred sentiment is embedded in sociological
theories that build on the ecological principle that competition increases the
speed at which fit forms come to dominate those that are less fit. These
currently influential theories provide normative backing for the idea that
structurally similar organizations should be autonomous and hostile to each
other. We show, however, that this is a context-specific rather than transcen-
dent idea. Comparisons between economic systems across time and space
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
277
reveal that hostility between structurally similar organizations is not the natu-
ral order, and also suggest that cooperation between potential competitors
may lead to fair and productive economic systems. Other analysis suggests
that the evidence in favor of current models of competition is self-fulfilling, a
function of the diffusion of those models, rather than a reflection of the
real world.
If the sole focus on structural relationships cannot determine competition
or cooperation, what does? We believe that perception and social categoriza-
tion play this role, and that these are feasible targets of strategic manipulation
by entrepreneurs who would benefit from cooperation (or competition)
between structurally similar actors. The balance between competition and
cooperation shifts on these cognitive processes rather than objective relations
to resources. We conclude by applying these ideas to help understand inter-
organizational relations in the context of an important research topic in
management, institutional change.
Structural Approaches for Identifying Competition
Populations and Industries
Competition between organizations and other actors emerges because of a
shared reliance on the same resources. Organizational ecologists identify the
condition of “niche overlap” as the basis of competition (Hannan & Freeman,
1989), meaning simply that a set of organizations rely on some of the same
resources for founding, growth and survival. The ecologists’ empirical strategy
for identifying competition derives from population biology’s
Lotka-Volterra
equations, which assume that the carrying capacity of a focal population (its
number of members in equilibrium) is a negative function of the density of a
competing population (the count of its members). In terms of types of organi-
zations, this is evidenced by a negative impact of the density of one type on the
founding and growth, or a positive effect on the rate of failure, of another type.
This type of cross-population analysis is not the norm in empirical work, but
it is not uncommon: craft unions impinged on industrial unions (Hannan &
Freeman, 1989); Israeli moshavim (collectives of smallholder farms) impinged
on kibbutzim (communal farms) (Simons & Ingram, 2004); Danish organiza-
tions were less likely to be founded if they used the same types of workers as
other industries (Sorensen, 2004).
A kindred and more common application of the ecological approach to
identifying competition is the theory of density dependence, which examines
the influence of a population’s density on its own founding, failure and
growth rate. The argument is that competition within a population rises with
density as more organizations pursue the same resources, and that competi-
tion reduces founding and growth and increases failure (Carroll & Hannan,
2000). There are literally dozens of empirical findings that support the compe-
tition element of the theory of density dependence (Baum, 1996).
1
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
278
The Academy of Management Annals
The ecological procedure of looking for competition within organizations
of a population is similar to the typical earlier practice in industrial econom-
ics, where competitors were seen as organizations in the same industry, or
organizations that serve the same market (Scherer, 1980). These scholars
conceive of industry structure as a central determinant of organizational
performance. Porter’s (1980) five forces model captures the insights of this
field as they are typically employed by management scholars. In this model an
industry is regarded as more competitive if it is closer to the theoretical idea of
perfect competition—a large number of firms, relatively homogenous prod-
ucts, low market concentration, and low entry and exit barriers.
Sub-Population and Sub-Industry Groups
Researchers in both the industrial economics and ecological tradition at some
point moved beyond the obvious simplification of categorizing all organiza-
tions in a population or industry as facing the same competitive pressure. A
number of approaches consider heterogeneity in competitive intensity for
different organizations that may still fit a given industry or population label.
In other words, research has gone on to recognize that the broad categories of
industry and population are made up of sub-groups. The basic premise, that
organizations of the same type compete more intensely, has been applied to
these sub-groups.
The most prominent differentiation of subgroups within organizational
ecology is according to the theory of resource partitioning. This theory begins
with what is an anomaly for theories of non-differentiated competition within
an industry. In many contexts, as the concentration of an industry increases
(that is, as more market share is accounted for by a small set of large organiza-
tions) the number of small organizations also increases. Concentration is an
indicator of the advantage and dominance of very large organizations, and it
strains the undifferentiated view that both larger and smaller organizations
appear to thrive at the same time. The theory of resource partitioning
responds to this apparent anomaly by recognizing the fundamental categories
of generalists and specialists, and arguing that they have distinct patterns of
resource utilization (Carroll, Dobrev, & Swaminathan, 2002).
Generalists, according to the theory, occupy the “center” of the resource
distribution, where there is the greatest concentration of consumer prefer-
ences. These organizations take advantage of economies of scale and offer a
product that appeals to the modal consumer. The archetypal example in the
literature is the mass-market producer of beer (Carroll & Swaminathan,
2000). Specialists occupy less-central places in the resource distribution, away
from the center, and where the products offered by the generalists are less
appealing. Resources are indeed scarce in this periphery, but they may be
sufficient to support small organizations that have high appeal to some
consumers. The archetypal example is the microbrewery, which produces an
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
279
unusual beer on a small scale. The process of concentration, where generalists
increase their dominance over the center of the resource distribution, actually
frees up resource space on the periphery for specialists. Evidence for these
ideas has been found in a number of industries, including newspapers,
breweries, wineries and automobile producers (Carroll, 1985; Carroll &
Swaminathan, 2000; Dobrev, Kim, & Carroll, 2002; Swaminathan, 1995).
Other within-industry or population distinctions have also been used to
identify more intense pools of competition. The most common of these
distinctions is geography, where organizations within an industry or popula-
tion that are in the same city or region are characterized as closer competitors.
Often, co-location distinguishes organizations that may compete more
intensely in input markets (e.g., for land or labor) while they face inter-
regional or national markets for their outputs (Ingram & Lifschitz, 2006;
Sorenson & Audia, 2000). Organizations in an industry or population may
also compete more intensely with others of the same organizational form. For
example, cooperatives in an industry may compete more intensely with other
cooperatives rather than corporations in their industry, because there are
some workers and consumers more willing to engage cooperatives than cor-
porations (Simons & Ingram, 2004). And chain organizations may compete
more intensely with other chains compared to independent organizations,
because chains’ offerings to the market have more commonalities (Ingram &
Baum, 1997). Still other studies identify competitive sub-categories within a
population according to political ideologies (Barnett & Woywode, 2004;
Simons & Ingram, 2004).
In the management literature derived from economics, the approach to
representing competitors by sub-industry groups is well represented by the
strategic group literature. Researchers here assume that organizations are con-
strained by mobility barriers and those in the same industry that adopt the
same or similar strategies form strategic groups (Hoskisson, Hitt, Wan, & Yiu,
1999; Peteraf & Shanley, 1997). In this way, industry is no longer viewed as a
homogeneous unit, but an agglomeration of diverse strategic groups. In some
ways this approach to competition has been most explicit about the concern
we raise in this paper—that structural similarity may seed either competition
or cooperation (Smith, Grimm, & Wally, 1997). This literature has also
pointed as we do to perception as key to tipping the balance between compe-
tition and cooperation. As Hoskisson et al. (1999) argued, “the fundamental
question is whether firms are actually
aware
of their mutual dependence
within their particular groups” (p. 427; our emphasis).
Resource–Space Overlap and Structural Equivalence
While the own- and cross-density effects at the population are consistent with
the niche overlap arguments of competition, more direct evidence comes
from McPherson (1983). McPherson operationalizes niche overlap between
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
280
The Academy of Management Annals
voluntary associations by the degree of demographic overlap among the
members they aimed to attract. Thus, niche overlap, at least in terms of par-
ticipants, was measured directly rather than simply inferred from a density
coefficient. This niche overlap measure was correlated with the negative
influence of organizations on each other’s growth. Baum and Singh (1994)
pursue a very similar approach in estimating competition between Toronto
daycare centers as a function of the overlap in the ages of children that they
accepted. A larger set of papers used the logic that more similar organizations
are likely to rely on similar resources, what has come to be called localized
competition. For example, Baum and Mezias (1992) show that Manhattan
hotels experienced more competition from other hotels that were similar in
location, size, and price.
Network analysis offers yet another approach for identifying structural
similarity as a basis for competition with the concept of structural equivalence.
Structurally equivalent actors are those that are the same or similar in terms of
relations to others. Two actors that occupy the same network positions have
access to the same resources from the network, and may therefore be closer
competitors. This idea is the foundation of network theories of competitive
advantage, which emphasize that unique structural positions are privileged
and sheltered from competition (Burt, 1992). Podolny, Stuart and Hannan
(1996) explicitly link the structural-equivalence concept to niche overlap by
using the overlap of patent citations by semiconductor firms as a measure of
competitive crowding. Ingram, Robinson and Busch (2005) use structural
equivalence in interstate networks as an indicator of competition in global
trade. Bothner (2003) operationalizes competition in the computer industry
using structural equivalence of firms through sales channels. And work from
industrial economics employs the structural-equivalence concept to measure
competition in network industries such as airlines (Borenstein, 1992).
In summary, a number of influential accounts hold that competition
derives from shared dependence on the same resources. Most macro evidence
for this position shows that organizations that seem to occupy the same niche
because they are of the same broad type exert negative influences on each
others’ performance. Others have refined this argument by applying it to
smaller groupings, showing that competition is greater between organizations
that are more similar, and which can be expected to use more of the same
resources. Subsequent studies have been able to explicitly measure niche over-
lap in terms of the demographics of target participants of organizations. Yet
another approach for identifying resource overlap is through overlap in
network position, what is called structural equivalence. Figure 6.1 shows the
basis of competition between two organizations as the overlap in the resources
they require, where resources can be broadly defined in terms of customers,
employees, endorsements, physical space, knowledge inputs, or anything else
necessary for their founding, growth, or survival.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
281
Figure 6.1 Niche Overlap Theory of Competition
Structural Opportunities for Cooperation
Figure 6.2 presents variants of Figure 6.1 and illustrates our argument that
cooperation as well as competition may derive from niche overlap. Case 1
presents the circumstance where organizations may find a basis for coopera-
tion because they compete in some areas, but not in others. We label this
symbiosis after Hawley (1950), because the basis of cooperation is the differ-
ences between organizations, particularly the differences in the resources they
require. Symbiosis is a common form of inter-organizational cooperation, but
it falls outside of our focus in this essay on cooperation that derives from the
same basis of competition. Nevertheless, we mention it in the interest of docu-
menting the full set of cooperative opportunities that derive from considering
niche overlap. In this case, apparent competitors may cooperate because they
are not really, or not completely, competitors. One influential niche-referent
theory that predicts symbiosis is Carroll’s (1985) resource partitioning model,
which suggests that generalists and specialists within the same industry may
co-exist and even stimulate each other. Other common examples are organiza-
tions that appear to operate in the same industry, but are really quite differen-
tiated, such as biotechnology firms and pharmaceutical firms that cooperate to
take advantage of the research and development capability of the former and
the marketing resources of the latter (McKelvey, Alm, & Riccaboni, 2003). Also
notable are peer industry networks (PINs) such as the one that Zuckerman and
Sgourev (2006) document among remodelers. PINs include small businesses in
the same industry and are motivated by the similarity of experience that
organizations in the same industry share, but they are organized around
companies that operate in different geographic markets and therefore are not
direct competitors.
Figure 6.1 Niche Overlap Theory of Competition.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
282
The Academy of Management Annals
Figure 6.2 Niche Overlap and Opportunities for Cooperation between A and B.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
283
Figure 6.2 Niche Overlap and Opportunities for Cooperation between A and B
Growth Commensalism
Cases 2 and 3 illustrate our main interests, the opportunities for cooperation
between organizations that derive from niche overlap. If organizations
compete because they rely on the same set of resources, they may cooperate to
grow those resources or to exclude others from accessing them. Case 2 shows
the growth case. One obvious opportunity for competitors to “increase the
pie” is through collusion. In the next section we take up the cooperation
between competitors historically, and show that collusive arrangements have
often been more legitimate than they are currently in Western economies.
However, there are still plenty of legitimate opportunities for cooperation
between competitors, even in terms of maintaining prices. Ingram and
Roberts (2000) showed that Sydney hoteliers employed a form of tacit price
coordination that amounted to using social sanctions to penalize managers
who would cut their prices and thereby create trouble for their competitor/
friends at other hotels. This was not illegal, even though Australian anti-trust
law explicitly foresaw and outlawed informal price-fixing agreements (includ-
ing a “‘nod and wink’ understanding that can take place anywhere—in the
pub, on the golf course, or at an association meeting or social occasion”
[ACCC, 1997, sec. 1]). The difference is that in tacit price coordination, there
is no agreement to limit price competition. The mechanism through which
cooperation emerges is simply a norm against doing something that harms the
social group. Tacit collusion may also emerge without any communication or
social relations between competitors, simply through the mutual recognition
of self interest (Jacquemin, 1987).
Another well researched form of competitors cooperating to maintain prices
is mutual forbearance between firms that meet as competitors in multiple mar-
kets (Baum & Greve, 2001; Bernheim & Whinston, 1990; Boeker, Goodstein,
Stephan, & Murmann, 1997). This cooperation takes a form of log-rolling,
where two organizations that have differential stakes in two markets (each mar-
ket is key for one firm, secondary for the other) forego intense competition as
secondary competitors to allow the other to exploit its key market. Log-rolling
is also the route for some non-collusive forms of growth commensalism. For
example, the Sydney hoteliers referred customers to their friends’ hotels when
their own hotels were full. Given that friends reciprocated the practice, this
created a type of inter-temporary exchange that allowed hotels to smooth their
business and helped their customers at the same time.
Research and development (R&D) consortia are an emerging form of
growth commensalism, where competitors collaborate to share the research
outcome as well as the associated risk. The cost of R&D projects is often
beyond a single company’s affordability. The joint research consortium
encourages technology innovation by dispersing the cost of R&D across a
number of firms. The most renowned consortium is probably SEMATECH,
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
284
The Academy of Management Annals
the association of US semiconductor producers that formed in response to
Japanese competition (Grindley, Mowery, & Silverman, 1994).
Many other important non-collusive instances of growth commensalism
involve sharing knowledge. In fact, knowledge sharing is a particularly poi-
gnant illustration of our main thesis because it is organizations that are most
similar to you—your closest competitors according to niche overlap theory—
that are the best source of knowledge that is relevant to you. A number of
learning curve studies have documented learning from the operational experi-
ence of competitors (Baum & Ingram, 1998; Darr, Argote, & Epple, 1995;
Ingram & Simons, 2002). Ingram and Lifschitz (2006) show that collaboration
in R&D among shipbuilders on the Clyde River helped that area to obtain the
unofficial status of “shipbuilding capital of the world” in the late nineteenth
century. In a contemporary context, Almeida and Kogut (1999) argue that
Silicon Valley is advantaged among all locations of semiconductor research in
the USA by the degree of knowledge sharing among firms in the industry,
firms that would typically be characterized as competitors. Close competitors
often share the common knowledge stock that enables them to better under-
stand, evaluate, and internalize the know-how of each other. This is parallel to
the organizational learning theorists’ argument that “absorptive capacity” is an
important determinant of learning effectiveness (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990).
Other forms of growth commensalism can be captured by the label “build-
ing and protecting public goods”. In industries such as fishing, where there are
obvious “tragedy of the commons” problems, cooperation between competi-
tors is well documented. Holm (1995) writes about collective action in the
Norwegian fishery, and Johnson and Libecap (1982) document cooperation to
manage shared resources among Gulf of Mexico shrimpers. Medieval
merchant guilds acted as institutions to maintain trading standards, and thus
the collective reputation of a town’s sellers, just as professional associations do
currently (Greif, Milgrom, & Weingast, 1994). In corporatist economies like
Germany, employer associations represent competitors in an industry in
collective bargaining with labor. Also, early hotel chains in the USA cooper-
ated to establish the Cornell hotel school to provide the human resource that
they relied on to manage their establishments (Ingram, 1998). Industry
associations may help their members navigate the law, as when the Tobacco
Institute protected cigarette manufacturers from lawsuits and hostile regula-
tions (Miles, 1982).
Recently, corporate social responsibility is emerging as a prime stimulus
for growth commensalism, because the public has been increasingly con-
cerned about social problems like global warming, environmental protection,
sustainable growth, and fair trade. If firms in an industry depend on collec-
tive perceptions of the industry, they all face sanctions when one violates
expectations of social responsibility. Barnett and King (2006) termed this the
“reputational commons”. They found that all firms in the chemical industry
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
285
shared sanctions from shareholders in response to an individual firm’s
accident. Evidencing the value of collective action in this circumstance, the
industry’s self-regulatory program, Responsible Care, was able to ameliorate
the industry-wide harm.
Exclusion Commensalism
Case 3, exclusion commensalism, refers to the instance where two (or more)
competitors may cooperate to protect the resources they jointly rely on from a
third competitor. Some of the instances we have given of growth commensal-
ism also have exclusionary elements. For example, in the absence of natural
barriers to entry, collusive arrangements between competitors will be success-
ful only if new entrants can be forestalled. And competitor cooperation to
manage public goods may also be motivated partly on exclusion. Dennen
(1976) shows how ranchers in the American west collaborated to run their
cattle on Federal land and excluded newcomers from the roundup. Many
examples of industry cooperation sharing knowledge and developing technol-
ogy can be characterized as the basis of advantage for a local industry over
some related industry elsewhere (Almeida & Kogut, 1999; Grindley et al.,
1994; Ingram & Lifschitz, 2006).
Organizations have also adopted various types of political strategies to
exclude competitors from their terrain. McWilliams, Fleet and Cory (2002)
provide numerous cases of the cooperation among incumbent firms to lobby
for enhanced market entry barriers or standards that they can meet more
easily than potential entrants can. Marvel (1977) documents how the large,
urban, steam-powered manufacturers promoted the passage of Lord Althorp’s
Factory Act of 1833 in Great Britain, which controls child labor use and
prohibits the employment of children less than nine years old in the British
textile industry. Through this legislation, the urban, capital-intensive manu-
facturers achieved the advantage over those small, rural, and water-powered
manufacturers who used significant child labor.
The two commensalistic cases are not equivalent—there is no competitive
exclusion at work in many efforts to build markets, protect the environment,
or negotiate with workers—but it is nevertheless useful to be alert to the
possibility that efforts to protect or grow the resources that competitors
depend on simultaneously involve excluding some other competitors from
those resources. The possibility of exclusion is also notable as it plays an
important role in the identity processes which we argue below are important
for tipping the orientations of resource-sharing organizations from competi-
tion to cooperation.
Deflating the Taboo against Cooperation between Competitors
Given the preceding listing of the ways that competitors may cooperate, the
obvious question is “when will they do these things?”. Before we turn to that,
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
286
The Academy of Management Annals
however, we give treatment to the question of “is cooperation between
competitors legitimate?”. As we explained in the opening of this essay, this
question confronts many empirical accounts of cooperation among competi-
tors. Indeed, scholars such as Barnett (2006) draw a firm line between
commensalism that aims to increase demand as opposed to restrict supply,
and legitimize the former by focusing analysis on it. Without advocating or
ignoring any public policy position, we aim in this section to show that the
opportunity for cooperation between competitors should not be seen as
dependent on weak or flawed anti-trust policies. It is true that many forms of
such cooperation are currently inhibited by anti-trust law, but we nevertheless
encourage a value-neutral view of both growth and exclusion commensalism.
Theories that emphasize competitor independence, particularly the
economic theory of perfect competition, have been so influential that they
have created a self-fulfilling dynamic to discourage commensalism. Inherent
in the theory of perfect competition is a Darwinian notion that competition is
a mechanism of efficiency, which is the basis of the privileged moral standing
of that relationship in contemporary debates. But organizational theorists are
well aware that the fittest do not always survive (Barnett, 1997), and in any
case, fitness in the economic realm is a social concept which is not always
applied to favor lower costs. In Manhattan, there is an active lobby against
retail concentration based partly on the argument that the practice reduces
competition and raises costs. Yet the same people who object to chain stores
are also likely to object to proposals to build new apartments in their neigh-
borhoods, an initiative which increases the supply of homes to the benefit of
buyers but also increases competition for those that already own homes. Even
among activists, then, attitudes regarding competition depend on whether you
are a buyer or a seller.
Again, we make no general claim regarding the welfare implications of
cooperation among competitors, but we want to deflate the assumption that
hostility between those that rely on the same resources represents some kind
of natural order. It is useful for this purpose to go back in economic history
and consider the circumstances before anti-trust laws took hold. Interestingly,
it is not necessary to go back very far, even in the two Anglo-Saxon economies
that are most associated with the influential theories of competition.
Consider Britain
Collusion had a murky legal status until the passage of the Restrictive Trade
Practices Act in 1956; before that point the relationships between business
organizations did not resemble pure competition. Cooperation took a variety
of forms, ranging from gentlemen’s agreements to formal associations coordi-
nated by specialized organizations. Firms organized cartels with other firms
operating within the same line of business and established board interlocks
with those connected by vertical exchange relationships. These cooperative
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
287
networks controlled price, mitigated competition, and maintained existing
market structures. The cooperative network was not rare. As cited by Florence
(1953), the interlock relationship alone linked firms that employed as many as
one-third of workers in British midland metal and metal using industries in
1948. And while some economic historians attribute the industrial decline of
Britain to this system of “gentlemanly capitalism” (e.g., Hannah, 1976), others
see the seeds of Britain’s nineteenth-century dominance in the commensalism
that system entailed. For example, Ingram and Lifschitz (2006) present empir-
ical evidence that the decline of the once-great Clyde River shipbuilding
industry was attributable at least in part to institutional reforms, including
anti-trust law, that undermined the efficacy of positive relations between
competing shipbuilders. These changes may have helped some British buyers
of ships, but given that shipbuilding is a global industry, and the Clyde River
industry was replaced by foreign competitors at a direct cost of more than
100,000 shipbuilding jobs in Glasgow, it is hard to argue that the British
economy was helped by discouraging cooperation among competitors in this
instance.
Consider the United States
In the early age of American industrial development voluntary cooperation
between firms was widespread. As documented by Kolko (1965) in response to
market competition in the 1870s, American companies organized numerous
cooperative alliances to fix rates, maintain existing market share, and control
internecine competition. One cooperative pool was initiated in 1870 by the
existing railroad companies in the Iowa area in order to exclude new competi-
tors from entering their market. This type of cooperation was widespread. In
1874, William H. Vanderbilt of the New York Central organized a pool of
major lines in the East. In 1875, a number of southern railroads created two
cooperative associations. In 1876, seven major lines formed the Southwestern
Railway Association to maintain rates. Besides mitigating direct competition
with each other, railroad companies had also managed to cooperate in labor
management. In June and July 1877, these companies agreed to cut the wages
of railroad workers by 10% in response to an economic depression. Besides
railroads, cartels existed in a wide range of other industries, such as mining,
metals, paint, paper, lumber, and footwear (Schneiberg & Hollingsworth,
1989). In fact, the free market competition ideal did not become prevalent in
the USA till the end of the nineteenth century, when anti-trust law made
cartels illegal (Dobbin, 1999). Even then, the zenith of unbridled competition
in the USA lasted only a short time. By 1925, a number of Supreme Court
decisions had enabled trade associations to share operational and price data.
Carrott (1970) argued that judicial policy was driven by a shift in public and
business sentiment: While “[t]he operator of the late nineteenth century was
normally very independent and suspicious of his competitors” (p. 323),
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
288
The Academy of Management Annals
business and government leaders had concluded by the early 1920s that the
“vigorous insistence on maintaining competition would deny business the
necessary knowledge to establish stability in an increasingly complex econ-
omy” (pp. 337–338).
These briefs indicate that successful industrial development is not purely
based on competition. Neoclassical economists’ ideals of competition are
based on a stylized reading of the British and American economic history
(Dobbin, 1999). The reality is that during earlier eras, cartels were widely
organized and perceived as legitimate (Dobbin & Dowd, 1997; Hartz, 1948;
Kolko, 1965). To account for the discrepancies between economic theory and
economic reality, Andrew Shonfield (1965) suggested “Classical economics,
which was largely a British invention, converted the British experience—or
rather what the British hoped would eventually emerge from the trend which
they had detected in their own story—into something very like the Platonic
idea of capitalism” (p. 71).
Analyses of contemporary markets also indicate that uninhibited competi-
tion is not a natural state. MacKenzie, Muniesa and Siu (2007) take up the
idea of performativity in economics, which suggests that economics (like
other sciences) may not just describe but also create what it studies. As Michel
Callon (1998) puts it: “economics… performs, shapes and formats the econ-
omy, rather than observing how it functions” (p. 2). A paradigmatic example
of how performativity may create competition is presented by Garcia-Parpet
(2007), who examines the introduction of a computerized market for table
strawberries in France and shows that the market was shaped by an influential
advisor to reflect the economic ideal of a perfectly competitive market. In
other words, the market was an artifact of the theory of economics, not a
reflection of how markets “naturally” work. In an experimental setting, Frank,
Gilovich and Regan (1993) found that students trained in economics are less
likely to cooperate in prisoner’s dilemma games than are others. Similarly,
Shapira and Madsen (1974) show that children educated according to a
utopian socialist philosophy were more likely to cooperate in games than chil-
dren raised in a modern capitalist education system. In the field of manage-
ment, Ferraro, Pfeffer and Sutton (2005) suggest that the assumptions of
economics become taken for granted and normatively valued through instru-
ments such as business education and media reports, independent of their
empirical validity.
None of this is meant to support a conclusion that cooperation between
resource-sharers is preferable to competition. Rather, we suggest that the
reverse conclusion, which is currently more prevalent, is unjustified. Even a
brief reflection on economic history highlights the possibility that commen-
salistic relations between potential competitors are not a recipe for disaster.
Analysis of contemporary economic behavior supports the idea that actors
and markets may exhibit more competition than they would in the absence of
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
289
influential theories that trumpet the value of competition. Without certain
theories, cooperation between competitors might be more common.
What Tips the Balance Between Cooperation and Competition?
Although it has gone under-exploited, the fact that competition and coopera-
tion derive from the same relationships to resources has not been unrecog-
nized in the literature. Indeed, there have been some impassioned
announcements of the significance for research and practice of unpacking the
simultaneous pressures on competition and cooperation (Astley & Fombrun,
1983; Pennings, 1981). The efforts so far to explain when competitors will
cooperate have so far been mostly structural. For example, the strategic group
theorists perceive organizational performance as a function of two sources—
the structure of an industry and the position of an organization within the
industry (McGahan & Porter, 1997). The structure of the industry (e.g.,
strength of the market, barriers to entry, favorable regulation) affects all
members of the industry, and so represents an opportunity for them to coop-
erate. Position within the industry is the source of advantage of individual
organizations, and is therefore what they compete over. Following this
structural framework, Barnett (2006) proposes that when organizations
perceive
industry structure to be a more important input to their success, they
are more likely to cooperate with competitors. We agree with this, with the
emphasis we have added on the word
perceive
. But the small literature has
mostly emphasized structure rather than the perception of structure. Extant
accounts of competitor cooperation highlight the relative overlap of their
resources and the interdependence between overlapping and non-overlapping
activities (Katz, 1986; Khanna, Gulati, & Nohria, 1998), whether they have
financial stakes in each other (Baum & Ingram, 1998; Darr et al., 1995), and
the number and size of competitors (French, 1986; Jacquemin, 1987).
Three reasons cause us to emphasize perception over structure as determi-
native. First, strategic decision makers are cognitively constrained, which
means that their identification of competitors depends on mental models of
competition that imperfectly reflect the underlying industry structure (Porac
& Thomas, 1990). When managers identify similar others as competitors
(Baum & Lant, 2003; Porac, Thomas, Wilson, Paton, & Kanfer, 1995), they
are systematically biased in a number of important ways. Their cognitive
models identify a smaller set of others as competitors than would an objective
analysis of niche overlap (Porac & Thomas, 1990). Further, they are likely to
underestimate inter-population competition, and overestimate the impor-
tance of geographic co-location as a determinant of competition (Baum &
Lant, 2003; Porac & Thomas, 1990). If managers can’t reliably translate
industry structure into understandings of competition, then industry struc-
ture must be an unreliable predictor of how they chose to behave towards
their competitors.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
290
The Academy of Management Annals
Second and related, there are a number of empirical accounts that show
variance in competitors’ willingness to cooperate
within
a given industrial
structure. Tjosvold (1997) examines the cooperative orientation of Vancouver
dentists—a set of business people who operate within the same industry.
Among these structural equivalent professionals, there was substantial varia-
tion in whether they were oriented towards cooperation or competition with
other dentists. Some dentists had shared purpose, sympathy for, and saw
interdependence with other dentists, and some did not. Those that did
engaged other dentists more openly and were more successful in solving busi-
ness problems through cooperation. Furthermore, in cases we will document
later, the emergence of cooperation is not always coincident with a change in
industry structure. There is no grand test that allows us to say whether more
variance in cooperation between competitors is explained by within- as
opposed to between-industry factors, but our read of the evidence indicates
that the former is more important and is certainly more important than has
been recognized by the structural emphasis of the literature to date.
Third, even when the structure of an industry creates an interest in coop-
eration between competitors, there remains a collective action problem which
is not easily solved by structural factors (King, Lenox, & Barnett, 2002).
Investments to create a favorable industry structure are a classic example of a
free-rider problem, because all members of the industry will benefit regardless
of their contributions. Often, structural conditions for resolving free-rider
problems don’t exist (Olson, 1965), and in these cases, an interest in coopera-
tion would be insufficient to create cooperation among competitors. The
empirical literature on collective action relies heavily on “extra-rational”
incentives to cooperate, exactly the factors that we consider below.
If industry structure does not explain whether competitors will cooperate,
what does? Deutsch (1973) argues that cooperation is more likely when actors
perceive their goals as related. The trick, simply, is recognizing a shared inter-
est. Niche overlap alone is insufficient to generate the perception of shared
interest—indeed, the literature on competitive categorization shows that
business people over-estimate the conflict of interest with the others that most
obviously overlap with their niches (Baum & Lant, 2003). What is necessary is
some other interest in common besides an interest in the same resources. This
“something else in common” could be summarized under the label “shared
identity”. We see two main mechanisms that encourage competitors to recog-
nize shared identity: shared affective relationships and salient out-group
comparisons.
Shared Affective Relationships
Positive affect towards a competitor provides an interest in the other’s
outcomes that can seed a cooperative orientation even in face of zero-sum
resource concerns. In the language of collective action, affect may provide
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
291
rival incentives, a social reward to cooperators that may tip the balance
between the resources available from cooperating or competing. In identity
terms, the affective relationship may shift actors’ categorization of each other
from “competitors” to “friends” or “kin”. As Montgomery (1998) shows in a
prisoners’ dilemma experiment, a simple change of the role of a player from
business person to friend can induce cooperation. The influence of affect in
the context of competitor friendships was described by Ingram and Roberts
(2000) as inducing hotel managers to sometimes forego a competitive oppor-
tunity to help a friend. This was not pure altruism as it was coupled with an
expectation that the friend would reciprocate the favor. Consistent with this,
Furseth (2006) found that friendships were common among competing
managers in Norwegian clothing retail stores, and that these friendships
reduced price competition substantially.
Kinship may be an even stronger source of sympathy and empathy among
competitors. Family relations between competitors were the foundation of
long-standing commensalistic systems in British banking and industry (Lisle-
Williams, 1984; Ingram & Lifschitz, 2006). The intergenerational spans of
those arrangements facilitate an orientation towards long-run interests, one of
the distinct advantages of kinship over other affective relationships. When
competitors are oriented to the long run, opportunities for cooperation are
more attractive (Axelrod, 1984).
We admit that some social relations can be endogenous results of structural
relations. For example, in the study of Sydney hotels, Ingram and Roberts
(2000) found that if a manager of a focal hotel identifies a target hotel as direct
competitor, she is more likely to report friendship with managers of the target
hotel. In his book,
Marriage Alliance in Late Medieval Florence,
Molho (1994)
shows that marriage is channeled by social stratification: the ruling class
married almost exclusively from within their own city and social level and thus
created a tight weave of interconnections. But competitors are not always
friends or relatives; the affective network is not identical to the structure of
niche overlap. The point we highlight here is that the different degrees of shared
affective relations tip the balance between competition and cooperation.
Another intriguing source of affect, broadly defined, between competitors
is suggested by Podolny and Scott-Morton (1999) who add social identity to
an economic cartel model. They show that new entrants with high social status
were less likely to be preyed on by British shipping cartels. They conclude that
the high status entrants were viewed as more trustworthy by incumbents in
the industry, and seen as more likely to uphold the “moral community” of the
cartel. A moral community is a concept introduced by Granovetter (1995) as
important to cartel stability. According to Granovetter, moral communities
imply trust, normative capacity and a willingness to forego opportunism. Just
as kinship and friendship, prominence or membership in an elite social group
can be the basis of a moral community.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
292
The Academy of Management Annals
Podolny and Scott-Morton (1999) also found that social status is more
important in cartel incumbents’ evaluation of the likelihood to cooperate of
young firms than older firms. They interpret the finding from the information
asymmetry perspective: older firms already have a long-enough history to
demonstrate their cooperative inclination and thus status is relatively minor in
reducing the uncertainty associated with older firms. Opportunism associated
with information asymmetry is one of the biggest threats toward interorgani-
zational cooperation. Friendship, kinship, and social status help to mitigate
this problem by transferring tacit, nuanced, and trust-worthy information and
helping organizations to better evaluate cooperators’ attributes and motiva-
tion. Social bonds also reduce opportunism because they generate loyalty,
trust, and commitment, which are key components of successful cooperation
(Pesamaa & Hair, 2007).
Salient Outgroup
Sherif, Harvey, White, Hood, and Sherif’s (1961) Robber’s Cave experiment
begins with two separate groups of boys at camp. Initially, the groups are
unaware of each other. The boys in the groups act as boys at camp do—they
have friends and enemies within their group, they think highly of some of
their group mates and are unimpressed with others. In the second part of the
experiment the groups are introduced to each other as rivals. The introduc-
tion of the rival groups shifts relations within the original groups, such that
ingroup solidarity and cooperation increase. This experiment lays the founda-
tion for a large literature that links the ingroup–outgroup effect to identity
and cooperation. Subsequent experiments show that even small distinctions
between groups strengthen identity within the groups: common features of
the focal group may become more salient with the introduction of “others”
with whom to draw contrasts (Brewer & Kramer, 1986; Hogg & Terry, 2000;
Tajfel & Turner, 1985) and contributions to collective action of the ingroup
increase (Bornstein, Erev, & Rosen, 1990; Erev, Bornstein, & Galili, 1993).
The ingroup–outgroup effect is a likely mechanism to promote exclusion
commensalism. As the bottom panel in Figure 6.2 shows, that form of coop-
eration presents a natural candidate to serve as the outgroup. Ingram and
McEvily (2007) illustrate just this process in an analysis of cooperation
among food cooperatives (coops). Coops’ identity and their recognition of
their shared interests were triggered by the entrance to their niche of a new
competitor, the natural foods chain Whole Foods. Whole Foods targeted
some of the same customers as the coops, but it was obviously distinct from
them, particularly as it was a for-profit corporation rather than a coop. Such
stark distinctions of organizational form or ideology are likely bases to divide
competitors into ingroups and outgroups because they allow the engineers of
cooperation to make resonant claims that “
we
are alike but
they
are different
from us”.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
293
For the food coops, their cooperation took the form of Cooperative
Grocers Associations, which were voluntary groups that aimed to improve the
coops’ collective position by joint purchasing to reap economies of scale, as
well as joint learning via the sharing of data and advice. Demonstrating the
galvanizing effect of Whole Foods, individual coops were more likely to join
Cooperative Grocers Associations if they recognized that corporate Goliath as
their primary competitor.
This result is also useful to illustrate our claim that commensalism hinges
ultimately on identity processes and not the structure of industries. It is true
that the entrance of Whole Foods represented a structural change for the
coops, and created an incentive to engage in exclusion commensalism by
offering a new competitor that could be excluded. But even though Whole
Foods is the giant of natural foods retailing, it does not dominate the niche,
and for the average coop the niche overlap provided by other corporate
competitors was greater than that of Whole Foods. Yet, Ingram and McEvily
(2007) found that niche overlap from corporate competitors (measured with
or without Whole Foods) did not predict coop commensalism. It was not the
structural conditions that formed the motivation for coops to band together,
but the salience of a single organization that reminded them of what they have
in common.
Weber (1978, p. 342) observes that industries may divide into ingroups and
outgroups based on almost any characteristic of the competitors, but some
distinctions are more resonant than others. As the economy is again on a
trend of globalization, with markets and exchange more likely to be across
national boundaries, firms are more likely to encounter competitors from
other nations. Although scholars are still debating whether globalization is a
homogenizing force and creates world-wide convergence (Guillen, 2001),
their debate is anchored on the common ground that nationality has become
more salient when the scope of competition goes beyond national boundary.
Researchers find that the characteristics of nationality are particularly
resonant for dividing competitors (Zaheer, 1995). Cross-border comparisons
may facilitate competitor cohesion within countries, resulting in competition
between national groups and cooperation within those groups.
The stimulus of global competition for competitor cooperation can also be
seen clearly in American anti-trust policy. US anti-trust law does not apply to
any activities of US companies that effect only foreign markets: “Nothing
contained in the Sherman Act [15 USC. 1 et seq.] shall be construed as declar-
ing to be illegal an association entered into for the sole purpose of engaging in
export trade and actually engaged solely in such export trade, or an agree-
ment made or act done in the course of export trade by such association” (15
USC. CHAPTER 2 Subchapter II § 62). The National Cooperative Research
Act of 1984, the legislation that enabled the formation of research consortia,
was stimulated by concerns over foreign competition. The statement of
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
294
The Academy of Management Annals
implementation of the Act from the US Department of Justice observes that
“[c]ooperative research and development efforts may… enable American
business and industry to keep pace with foreign competitors…” (Barnett,
Mischke, & Ocasio, 2000, p. 351). Informal collusive arrangements also reflect
an own-nation preference, as evidenced by Podolny and Scott-Morton’s
(1999) finding that British shipping cartels were less aggressive towards
market entrants from Britain.
The case of hoteliers at Niagara Falls illustrates how national identity can
be the basis of exclusion commensalism. Ingram and Inman (1996) describe
the structure of resource relations: there were two populations of hotels divided
by the Niagara River, one in Canada, the other in the USA. Consistent with
hotel industries elsewhere, the evidence here was that the a key determinant of
competitive intensity was geographic proximity—a Canadian hotel competed
more intensely with another Canadian hotel next door than it did with a US
hotel across the river. Nevertheless, cooperation between competitors was
within the national communities. This cooperation involved a number of
informal (and sometimes shady) projects, such as when US hoteliers paid cab
drivers to kidnap tourists from the Canadian side of the River and drop them
on the American side. The model that both populations seemed to work under
was that the first goal was to get tourists on
their
side of the border, at which
point they would compete with their countrymen to win the business. National
identity, evoked by institutional entrepreneurs and enforced by artful cross
border comparisons, was very important in producing the perception of shared
interest amongst the hoteliers within each hotel population.
Institutional Change
So far we have explained the structural preconditions for cooperation between
competitors, why such cooperation has been slighted as illegitimate, and the
perception and identity process that distinguish competitors from coopera-
tors. In this section we relate these arguments to a very compelling and
current topic in management, that of institutional change. In doing so, we aim
to show some of the likely opportunities for scholars to apply the ideas we
have presented as they seek to explain important phenomena.
The most pressing challenge for all forms of institutional arguments that
are prominent throughout the social sciences is to explain the origin and
change of institutions, and management scholars have a significant role to
play in this effort because organizations are important for institutional
change. Institutional change presents an obvious opportunity for growth
commensalism. All competitors for a given resource are affected by the soci-
etal rules that govern its production, distribution and consumption. Thus, the
possibility of favorable institutional change is a textbook example of Barnett’s
(2006) argument that opportunities to improve industry structure are oppor-
tunities for cooperation between competitors. It is also, however, a textbook
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
295
example of our critique of the industry structure explanation for competitor
cooperation as being insufficient resolution of the free-rider problem. Because
institutions affect all members of an industry or other category of competitors,
it is hard to exclude any member from the benefits of institutional change.
This non-excludability undermines contributions as each competitor may
free-ride on the institution-change efforts of others.
The significance of this problem has led scholars of institutional change to
draw on social movement research for explanations as to when individuals and
organizations will mobilize despite opportunities to free-ride (Rao, Morill, &
Zald, 2000). Repeatedly, these efforts have highlighted determinants of social
identity as underlying cooperation to change institutions. A fundamental inhi-
bition to institutional change is that institutions themselves are constitutive of
the identities of actors and associated with incentives for compliance, making
them self-reinforcing and durable. This suggests that competitors may not be
alert to the opportunity to change the institutions that constrain them because
they take those institutions for granted. New entrants to an industry or
resource space are outside of this reified system, and often trigger efforts at
institutional change (Davis, Diekmann, & Tinsley, 1994; Ingram, 1998; Rao,
Monin, & Durand, 2003).
The social movement literature emphasizes the significance of affective ties
as a source of rival incentive to promote cooperation (Dani & McAdam,
2003). Ingram and Rao (2004) show this effect in organizational efforts to
change institutions in a study of the battle between independent and chain
stores over the regulatory environment of retailing. They show that indepen-
dents were more influential over tax laws when they were more homogenous
and therefore more cohesive. Note that similarity between small businesses,
according to most economic and sociological theories, would be the basis of
intense competition due to niche overlap—in the case of independent retailers
fighting chains, similarity was instead the basis of cohesion and successful
collective action.
The social movement literature also highlights the role of institutional
entrepreneurs in promoting mobilization (Rao, 2007). Often, these entrepre-
neurs apply rhetoric to convince competitors that they have common inter-
ests, or that their interests diverge from some outside group (Benford & Snow,
2000). In other words, they manipulate identities, and bring into being the
conditions that lead to cooperation among competitors. These entrepreneurs
illustrate our thesis that competition and cooperation may be socially
constructed. Studies of social movement identity management have focused
on efforts to forge allegiances between competing organizations by presenting
their identities as compatible (Clemens, 1993; Ingram & Rao, 2004). However,
institutional entrepreneurs may also facilitate the ingroup–outgroup effect
when they strengthen identities by emphasizing differences between their
organization and outsiders or rivals, a technique that Gamson (1992) labels
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
296
The Academy of Management Annals
“adversarial framing”. For example, Barnett and Woywode (2004) document
adversarial framing in the political cartoons of Viennese newspapers in the
interwar years.
Conclusion
Competition is an important mechanism that governs the development of our
society. Not only does competition stimulate self-improvement, but also the
very same ground that brings up competition also nurtures cooperation,
which may not necessarily jeopardize social efficiency. Understanding the co-
existence of competition and cooperation is crucial to a better understanding
of a variety of empirical phenomenon, ranging from technology innovation to
institutional change. Deflating the taboo against the cooperation between
competitors also contributes to the policy makers’ decision when designing
policies that aim at developing a more viable business community.
For studies about competition, we suggest that cooperation is an often
neglected aspect of relationships between competitors. Competition and
cooperation are like the two pans on a balance scale. Structural architecture is
indeterminate as to whether the scale will tip to the competition side or to the
cooperation side. What matters is actually the weight that organizational
executives put on each pan, which is a mixture of their personal judgment,
perception, and identity. Additionally, when social institutions like anti-trust
laws and theories of competition put a thumb on one side or the other, they
too may tip the balance.
These ideas have three important implications for scholars. First, scholars
should be clear that the structural relationship of niche overlap has indetermi-
nate implications. This point is consistent with economic sociologists’ critique
of the hard structuralism in which the architecture of network positions alone
does not provide sufficient account of social outcomes because diverse, even
divergent, interpretation can flow across the very same structure (Krippner,
2001; Krippner & Alvarez, 2007). But many managerial theorists still assume
that niche overlap produces only competition. Even those that have
approached competition from the perspective of perception and cognition
share the same tendency to downplay the cooperative implications of struc-
tural similarity (e.g., Porac et al., 1995). In this paper we have shown that
niche overlap begets both competition and cooperation. Researchers need to
look beyond the resource structure to social structure to know whether to
expect competition or cooperation.
Second, researchers should be cautious of the performativity of successful
theories. For example, in their study of the development of financial econom-
ics, MacKenzie and Millo (2003) show that, when first introduced in 1973, the
Black–Scholes–Merton option-pricing model achieved only a modest match
with empirical data. But as more and more people applied the model into their
option-pricing calculation, the markets gradually altered and converged
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
297
toward the model’s assumptions. When the model was retested in the middle
of 1980s, it had achieved an excellent fit. Thus, taking a longitudinal look to
trace the theory–reality discrepancy over time helps researchers to realize the
self-fulfilling circle of theories. In this paper, we employ the same method and
show that the illegitimacy of the cooperation between competitors is a fairly
recent social construction.
Third, and finally, researchers should use multiple methods to conduct
richer and more localized analysis of inter-organizational relationships. Most
of the research supporting the view that niche overlap creates competition has
been conducted with archival methods. It is not surprising that archival
approaches identify the relevance of the structure of resource dependence
because that is typically the only dimension of inter-organizational relations
that they can identify. Studies that compliment data on niche overlap between
organizations with information on how the organizations see and think about
each other often reach different conclusions. Most often, the data that expose
the influences that may turn potential competitors into cooperators have
come from surveys and interviews of managers, and from historical analyses
of the rhetorical arguments that institutional entrepreneurs have used to
convince organizations that they have shared interests, and to mobilize them
to act on those interests.
Acknowledgements
We thank Michael Barnett, Joel Baum, Art Brief, Ray Horton, Huggy Rao and
Jim Walsh for helpful comments and advice.
Endnote
1. There is some controversy over the theory of density dependence as a whole but
it is mostly associated with the argument as to how legitimacy varies with density.
The competition component of the theory is seen as well supported.
References
Almeida, P., & Kogut, B. (1999). Localization of knowledge and the mobility of
engineers in regional networks.
Management Science, 45
(7), 905–917.
Astley, W.G., & Fombrun, C.J. (1983). Collective strategy: Social ecology of organiza-
tional environments.
Academy of Management Review, 19,
645–671.
Australian Competition and consumer commission (ACCC). (1997).
Rural Guideline
and the Trade Practices Act.
Canberra: ACCC.
Axelrod, R. (1984).
The evolution of cooperation.
New York: Basic Books.
Barnett, M.L. (2006). Finding a working balance between competitive and communal
strategies.
Journal of Management Studies, 43,
1753–1773.
Barnett, M.L., & King, A.A. (2006).
Good fences make good neighbors: An institutional
explanation of industry self-regulation.
Paper presented at the Academy of
Management Best Conference, Atlanta, GA.
Barnett W.P. (1997). The dynamics of competitive intensity.
Administrative Science
Quarterly, 42,
128–160.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
298
The Academy of Management Annals
Barnett, W.P., Mischke, G.A., & Ocasio, W. (2000). The evolution of collective strate-
gies among organizations.
Organization Studies, 21,
325–354.
Barnett, W.P., & Woywode, M. (2004). From Red Vienna to the Anschluss: Ideological
competition among Viennese newspapers during the rise of national socialism.
American Journal of Sociology, 109,
1452–1499.
Baum, J.A.C. (1996). Organizational ecology. In S.R. Clegg, C. Hardy & W.R. Nord
(Eds.),
Handbook of organizational studies
(pp. 77–114). Thousand Oaks, CA:
Sage.
Baum, J.A.C., & Greve, H.R. (Eds.). (2001).
Advances in strategic managemen (Vol.
18). Multiunit organization and multimarket strategy.
Oxford, UK: JAI/
Elsevier.
Baum, J.A.C., & Ingram, P. (1998). Survival-enhancing learning in the Manhattan
hotel industry, 1898–1980.
Management Science, 44
(7), 996–1016.
Baum, J.A.C., & Lant, T.K. (2003). Hits and misses: Managers’ (mis)categorization of
competitors in the Manhattan hotel industry. In J.A.C. Baum & O. Sorenson
(Eds.),
Advances in strategic management (Vol. 20). Geography and strategy
(pp. 118–155). Oxford UK: JAI/Elsevier.
Baum, J.A.C., & Mezias, S.J. (1992). Localized competition and organizational failure
in the Manhattan hotel industry, 1898–1990.
Administrative Science Quarterly,
36,
187–218.
Baum, J.A.C., & Singh, J.V. (1994). Organizational niches and the dynamics of organi-
zational mortality.
American Journal of Sociology, 100,
346–380.
Benford, R.D., & Snow, D.A. (2000). Framing processes and social movements: An
overview and assessment.
Annual Review of Sociology, 26,
611–639.
Bernheim, B.D., & Whinston, M.D. (1990). Multimarket contact and collusive behavior.
RAND Journal of Economics, 21,
1–26.
Boeker, W., Goodstein, J., Stephan, J., & Murmann, J.P. (1997). Competition in a mul-
timarket environment: The case of market exit.
Organization Science, 8,
126–142.
Borenstein, S. (1992). The evolution of airline competition.
The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 6,
45–74.
Bornstein, G., Erev, I., & Rosen, O. (1990). Intergroup competition as a structural
solution for social dilemmas.
Social Behavior, 5,
247–260.
Bothner, M.S. 2003. Competition and social influence: The diffusion of the sixth-
generation processor in the global computer industry.
American Journal of
Sociology, 108,
1175–1210.
Brewer, M.B., & Kramer, R.M. (1986). Choice behavior in social dilemmas: Effects of
social identity, group size, and decision framing.
Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 50,
543–549.
Burt, R.S. (1992).
Structural holes: The social structure of competition.
Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Callon, M. (1998). Introduction: The embeddedness of economic markets in econom-
ics. In M. Callon (Ed.),
The laws of markets
(pp. 1–57). Oxford: Blackwell.
Carroll, G.R. (1985). Concentration and specialization: Dynamics of niche width in
populations of organizations.
American Journal of Sociology, 90
(6), 1262–1283.
Carroll, G.R., Dobrev, S., & Swaminathan, A. (2002). Organizational processes of
resource partitioning.
Research in Organizational Behavior, 24,
1–40.
Carroll, G.R., & Hannan, M.T. (2000).
The demography of corporations and industries.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation
299
Carroll, G.R., & Swaminathan, A. (2000). Why the microbrewery movement? Organi-
zational dynamics of resource partitioning in the American brewing industry
after Prohibition.
American Journal of Sociology, 106,
715–762.
Carrott, M.B. (1970). The Supreme Court and American trade associations, 1921–1925.
Business History Review, 44,
320–338.
Clemens, E.S. (1993). Organizational repertoires and institutional change: Women’s
groups and the transformation of US politics, 1890–1920.
American Journal of
Sociology, 98,
755–798.
Cohen, W.M., & Levinthal, D.A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on
learning and innovation.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 35,
128–152.
Dani, M., & McAdam, D. (2003).
Social movements and networks: Relational
approaches to collective action.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Darr, E.D., Argote, L., & Epple, P. (1995). The acquisition, transfer, and depreciation of
knowledge in service organizations: Productivity in franchises.
Management
Science, 41
(11), 1750–1762.
Davis, G.F., Diekmann, K.A., & Tinsley, C.H. (1994). The decline and fall of the
conglomerate firm in the 1980s: The deinstitutionalization of an organizational
form.
American Sociological Review, 59,
547–570.
Dennen, R.T, (1976). Cattlemen’s associations and property rights in land in the
American west.
Explorations in Economic History, 14,
423–436.
Deutsch, M. (1973).
The resolution of conflict. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Dobbin, F. (1999). A market is a market is a market: Institutional conditions for the
construction of market mechanisms. BISS Public, 27, 53–72.
Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. (1997). How policy shapes competition: Early railroad found-
ings in Massachusetts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 501–529.
Dobrev, S.D., Kim, T.-K., & Carroll, G.R. (2002). The evolution of organizational
niches: US automobile manufacturers, 1885–1981. Administrative Science
Quarterly, 47, 233–264.
Erev, I., Bornstein, G., & Galili, R. (1993). Constructive intergroup competition as a
solution to the free-rider problem: A field experiment. Journal of Experimental
Social Psychology, 29, 463–478.
Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J., & Sutton, R.I. (2005). Economics language and assumptions:
How theories can become self-fulfilling. Academy of Management Review, 30(1),
8–24.
Florence, P.S. (1953). The logic of British and American industry: A realistic analysis of
economic structure and government. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Frank, R.H., Gilovich, T., & Regan, D.T. (1993). Does studying economics inhibit
cooperation? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 159–171.
French. M. (1986). Structural change and competition in the United States tire indus-
try, 1920–1937. Business History Review, 60, 28–54.
Furseth, P.I. (2006, August). Friends, competition and prices: How friendships among com-
petitors influence the degree of price competition and actual prices. Paper presented
at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, Montreal, Canada.
Gamson, W.A. (1992). Talking politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Garcia-Parpet, M. (2007). The social construction of a perfect market: The strawberry
auction at Fontaines-en-Sologne. In D. MacKenzie, F. Muniesa, & L. Siu (Eds.),
Do economists make markets? On the performativity of economics (pp. 20–53).
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
300 The Academy of Management Annals
Granovetter, M.S. (1995). Coase revisited: Business groups in the modern economy.
Industrial and Corporate Change, 4, 93–131.
Greif, A., Milgrom, P., & Weingast, B.R. (1994). Coordination, commitment and
enforcement: The case of the merchant guild. Journal of Political Economy, 102,
715–776.
Grindley, P., Mowery, D.C., & Silverman, B. (1994). The Lessons of SEMATECH:
Implications for the Design of High-Technology Research Consortia. Journal of
Policy Analysis and Management, 13(4), 723–758.
Guillen, M.F. (2001). Is globalization civilizing, destructive or feeble? A critique of
five key debates in the social-science literature. Annual Review of Sociology, 27,
235–260.
Hannah, L. (1976). The rise of the corporate economy. Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins
University Press.
Hannan, M.T., & Freeman, J. (1989). Organizational ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Hartz, L. (1948). Economic policy and democratic thought: Pennsylvania, 1776–1860.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hawley, A. (1950). Human ecology. New York, NY: Ronald Press.
Hogg, M.A., & Terry, D.J. (2000). Social identity and self-categorization processes in
organizational contexts. Academy of Management Review, 25, 121–140.
Holm, P. (1995). The dynamics of institutionalization: Transformation processes in
Norwegian fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40, 398–422.
Hoskisson, R.E., Hitt, M.A., Wan, W.P., & Yiu, D. (1999). Swings of a pendulum: Theory
and research in strategic management. Journal of Management, 25, 417–456.
Ingram, P. (1998). Changing the rules: Interests, organizations and institutional
change in the US hospitality industry. In M. Brinton & V. Nee (Eds.), The new
institutionalism in sociology (pp. 258–276). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Ingram, P., & Baum, J.A.C. (1997). Chain affiliation and the failure of Manhattan
hotels, 1898–1980. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 68–102.
Ingram, P., & Inman, C. (1996). Institutions, intergroup rivalry, and the evolution of
hotel populations around Niagara Falls. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41,
629–658.
Ingram, P., & Lifschitz, A. (2006). Kinship in the shadow of the corporation: the inter-
builder network in Clyde River shipbuilding, 1711–1990. American Sociological
Review, 71, 334–52.
Ingram, P., & McEvily, B. (2007). Sharper in relief: Opposition, identity and the mainte-
nance of social movement organizations. Working Paper, Columbia Business
School.
Ingram, P., & Rao, H. (2004). Store wars: The enactment and repeal of anti-chain
legislation in the United States. American Journal of Sociology, 110, 446–487.
Ingram, P., & Roberts, P.W. (2000). Friendships among competitors in the Sydney
hotel industry. American Journal of Sociology, 106, 387–423.
Ingram, P., Robinson, J., & Busch, M.L. (2005). The intergovernmental network of
world trade: IGO connectedness, governance, and embeddedness. American
Journal of Sociology, 111, 824–858.
Ingram, P., & Simons, T. (2002). The transfer of experience in groups of organiza-
tions: Implications for performance and competition. Management Science, 48,
1517–1533.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation 301
Jacquemin, A. (1987). The new industrial organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Johnson, R.N., & Libecap, G.D. (1982). Contracting problems and regulation: The case
of the fishery. American Economic Review, 72, 1005–1022.
Katz, M.L. (1986). An analysis of cooperative research and development. RAND
Journal of Economics, 17, 527–543.
Khanna, R., Gulati, R., & Nohria, N. (1998). The dynamics of learning alliances:
Competition, cooperation and relative scope. Strategic Management Journal, 19,
193–210.
King, A., Lenox, M., & Barnett, M.L. (2002). Strategic responses to the reputation com-
mons problem. In A. Hoffman & M. Ventresca (Eds.), Organizations, policy and
the natural environment: Institutional and strategic perspectives (pp. 393–406).
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Kolko, G. (1965). Railroads and regulation, 1877–1916. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Krippner, G.R. (2001). The elusive market: Embeddedness and the paradigm of
economic sociology. Theory and Society, 30(6), 775–810.
Krippner, G.R., & Alvarez, A.S. (2007). Embeddedness and the intellectual projects of
economic sociology. Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 219–240.
Lisle-Williams, M. (1984). Beyond the market: The survival of family capitalism in the
English merchant banks. British Journal of Sociology, 35, 241–271.
MacKenzie, D., & Millo, Y. (2003). Constructing a market, performing theory: The
historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of
Sociology, 109, 107–145.
MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., & Siu, L. (2007). Do economists make markets? On the
performativity of economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Marvel, H. (1977). Factory regulation: A reinterpretation of early English experience.
Journal of Law and Economics, 20(2), 379–402.
McGahan, A.M., & Porter, M.E. (1997). How much does industry matter, really?
Strategic Management Journal, 18, 15–30.
McKelvey, M., Alm, H., & Riccaboni, M. (2003). Does co-location matter for formal
knowledge collaboration in the Swedish biotechnology-pharmaceutical sector?
Research Policy, 32, 483–501.
McPherson, M.J. (1983). An ecology of affiliation. American Sociological Review, 48,
519–532.
McWilliams, A., Fleet, D.D.V., & Cory, K.D. (2002). Raising rivals’ cost through politi-
cal strategy: An extension of resource-based theory. Journal of Management
Studies, 39(5): 707–723.
Miles, R.H. (1982). Coffin nails and corporate strategies. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall.
Molho, A. (1994). Marriage alliance in late medieval Florence. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Montgomery, J.D. (1998). Toward a role-theoretic conception of embeddedness.
American Journal of Sociology, 104, 92–125.
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Pennings, J.M. (1981). Strategically interdependent organizations. In P.C. Nystrom &
W.H. Starbuck (Eds.), Handbook of organizational design (pp. 455–455). New
York: Oxford University Press.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
302 The Academy of Management Annals
Pesamaa, O., & Hair, J.F. (2007). More than friendship is required: An empirical test of
cooperative firm strategies. Management Decision, 45(3), 602–615.
Peteraf, M., & Shanley, M. (1997). Getting to know you, a theory of strategic group
identity. Strategic Management Journal, 18, 165–186.
Podolny, M.J., & Scott-Morton, F.M. (1999). Social status, entry, and predation: The case
of British shipping cartels 1879–1929. Journal of Industrial Economics, 47, 41–67.
Podolny, J.M., Stuart, T.E., & Hannan, M.T. (1996). Networks, knowledge, and niches:
Competition in the worldwide semiconductor industry, 1984–1991. American
Journal of Sociology, 102, 659–689.
Porac, J.F., & Thomas, H. (1990). Taxonomic mental models in competitor definition.
Academy of Management Review, 15, 224–240.
Porac, J.F., Thomas, H., Wilson, F., Paton, D., & Kanfer, A. (1995). Rivalry and the
industry model of Scottish knitwear producers. Administrative Science Quar-
terly, 40, 203–227.
Porter, M.E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York, NY: The Free Press,
Rao, H. (2007). Gadflies & hustlers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. (2003). Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle
cuisine as an identity movement in French Gastronomy. American Journal of
Sociology, 108, 795–843.
Rao, H., Morrill, C., & Zald, M. (2000). Power plays: How social movements and
collective action create new organizational forms. Research in Organizational
Behavior, 22, 237–282.
Scherer, F.M. (1980). Industrial market structure and economic performance. Chicago,
IL: Rand-McNally.
Schneiberg, M., & Hollingsworth, J.R. (1989). Transaction cost economics and trade
associations. In M. Aoki, B. Gustafsson, & O. Williamson (Eds.), The firm as a
nexus of treaties (pp. 320–346). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Shapira, A., & Madsen, M.C. (1974). Between- and within-group cooperation and com-
petition among kibbutz and nonkibbutz children. Developmental Psychology, 10,
140–145.
Sherif, M., Harvey, O.J., White, B.J., Hood, W.R., & Sherif, C.W. (1961). Intergroup
conflict and cooperation: The robbers cave experiment. Norman, OK: Institute of
Group Relations.
Shonfield, A. (1965). Modern capitalism. London: W. Pickering
Simons, T., & Ingram, P. (2004). An ecology of ideology: Theory and evidence from
four populations. Industrial and Corporate Change, 13, 33–59.
Smith, K.G., Grimm, C.M., & Wally, S. (1997). Strategic groups and rivalrous firm
behavior: Towards reconciliation. Strategic Management Journal, 18(2), 149–157.
Sorensen, J. (2004). Recruitment-based competition between industries: A community
ecology. Industrial and Corporate Change, 13, 149–70.
Sorenson, O., & Audia, P.G. (2000). The social structure of entrepreneurial activity:
Geographic concentration of footwear production in the United States, 1940–
1989. American Journal of Sociology, 106, 424–462.
Swaminathan, A. (1995). The proliferation of specialist organizations in the American
wine industry, 1941–1990. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40, 653–680.
Tajfel, H., & Turner, J.C. (1985). The social identity theory of inter-group behavior. In
S. Worchel & L.W. Austin (Eds.), Psychology of intergroup relations (pp. 7–24).
Chicago, IL: Nelson-Hall.
Downloaded By: [Academy of Management] At: 21:42 1 August 2008
Bases of Organizational Competition and Cooperation 303
Tjosvold, D. (1997). Networking by professionals to manage change: Dentists’ cooper-
ation and competition to develop their business. Journal of Organizational
Behavior, 18, 745–752.
Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zaheer, S. (1995). Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management
Journal, 38, 341–363.
Zuckerman, E.W., & Sgourev, S.V. (2006). Peer capitalism: Parallel relationships in the
US economy. American Journal of Sociology, 111, 1327–1366.
... Niche overlap theory was first developed in the field of ecology to describe competition and complementarity within and between species based on the similarity of their resource needs. It has since been transferred to a variety of domains such as social network analysis (Popielarz & Neal, 2007) and organizational studies (Sohn, 2002;Ingram & Yue, 2008;Mascia, Pallotti, & Angeli, 2017). In general, more niche overlap points to stronger competition, whereas less niche overlap indicates possible complementarity. ...
... Finally, geographic markets based on links with extra-provincial cities are considered to determine competition and cooperation for national flows. Table 1 competition matrix (left) and cooperation matrix (right) for the toy example of Fig. 1. 2 The term 'competitive crowding', or 'crowding' in short, has been used to denote the overall pressure of competitive intensity experienced by an actor, both in ecology (e.g., Hurlbert, 1978) and organizational studies (e.g., Ingram & Yue, 2008). ...
... Facing similar challenges and opportunities, competing firms organize similar portfolios of resources. These resources, potentially, are useful to both firms (Ingram & Qingyuan Yue, 2008;Baum & Mezias, 1992). Firms that need access to relevant resources can obtain them from direct competitors not in need of them for a period. ...
Article
Full-text available
The discourse of social organizing in projects centres on temporary-permanent relationships across projects and between projects and embedded organizations. Less explored are temporary-temporary relationships within project ecologies. We investigate the practice of collaborative consumption in project ecologies as a form of such relationships. Specifically, we focus on tensions arising from contradictory logics of cooperation and competition in these temporary and ad-hoc interactions. Based on the case of the construction industry, our results elaborate how coopetitive tensions shape the extent and forms of these ad-hoc temporary interactions among stakeholders to guide innovation in project supply chains. Beyond the limitations of broad strategic collaborations, these innovations promote the prospects for joint specialization, collective commitments, strategic resource dependence and more permeable organizational boundaries. But organizing these ad-hoc strategic interactions also requires additional regulatory frameworks, as well as alternative artifacts, including a digital platform for brokering structural holes in information relating supply and demand. Our study extends stakeholder discourse in project studies through empirical research into emerging forms of temporary ad-hoc stakeholder interactions rather than broad strategic collaborations. Understanding these ad-hoc interactions and associated coopetitive tensions instigates a wider range of social organizing in project ecologies.
... These techniques and their corresponding equations have for example been used to explain and forecast the market penetration of competing technologies (Zenobia et al., 2009). As a modelling technique, the LV framework assumes that the density of competing populations has a negative impact on the establishment, growth, density and carrying capacity of the focal population (Ingram and Yue, 2008), offering a highly mathematical approach towards studying diffusion (Jarvi and Kortelainen, 2017). ...
Article
Full-text available
Based on equilibrium assumptions, traditional ecological models have been widely applied in the fields of management and organization studies. While research using these models is still ongoing, studies have nonetheless struggled with ways to address multiple levels of analysis, uncertainty, and complexity in their analyses. This paper conceptualizes the dynamic co-evolution mechanisms that operate in an ecosystem across multiple organizational scales. Specifically, informed by recent advances in modelling in biology, a general ‘patch-dynamics’ framework that is theoretically and methodologically able to capture disequilibrium, uncertainty, disturbances, and changes in organizational populations or ecosystems, as complex and dynamically evolving resource environments are introduced. Simulation models are built to show the patch-dynamics framework’s functioning and test its robustness. The patch-dynamics framework and modelling methodology integrates equilibrium and disequilibrium perspectives, co-evolutions across multiple organization levels, uncertainties, and random disturbances into a single framework, opening new avenues for future research on topics in the field of management and organization studies, as well as on the mechanisms that shape ecosystems. Such a framework has the potential to help analyse the sustainability and healthiness of the business environment, and deserves more attention in future research on management and organization theory, particularly in the context of significant uncertainty and disturbances in business and management practice. Overall, the paper offers a distinct theoretical perspective and methodology for modelling population and ecosystem dynamics across different scales.
Chapter
Exponential random graph models (ERGMs) are increasingly applied to observed network data and are central to understanding social structure and network processes. The chapters in this edited volume provide a self-contained, exhaustive account of the theoretical and methodological underpinnings of ERGMs, including models for univariate, multivariate, bipartite, longitudinal and social-influence type ERGMs. Each method is applied in individual case studies illustrating how social science theories may be examined empirically using ERGMs. The authors supply the reader with sufficient detail to specify ERGMs, fit them to data with any of the available software packages and interpret the results.
Chapter
Exponential random graph models (ERGMs) are increasingly applied to observed network data and are central to understanding social structure and network processes. The chapters in this edited volume provide a self-contained, exhaustive account of the theoretical and methodological underpinnings of ERGMs, including models for univariate, multivariate, bipartite, longitudinal and social-influence type ERGMs. Each method is applied in individual case studies illustrating how social science theories may be examined empirically using ERGMs. The authors supply the reader with sufficient detail to specify ERGMs, fit them to data with any of the available software packages and interpret the results.
Chapter
Exponential random graph models (ERGMs) are increasingly applied to observed network data and are central to understanding social structure and network processes. The chapters in this edited volume provide a self-contained, exhaustive account of the theoretical and methodological underpinnings of ERGMs, including models for univariate, multivariate, bipartite, longitudinal and social-influence type ERGMs. Each method is applied in individual case studies illustrating how social science theories may be examined empirically using ERGMs. The authors supply the reader with sufficient detail to specify ERGMs, fit them to data with any of the available software packages and interpret the results.
Chapter
Exponential random graph models (ERGMs) are increasingly applied to observed network data and are central to understanding social structure and network processes. The chapters in this edited volume provide a self-contained, exhaustive account of the theoretical and methodological underpinnings of ERGMs, including models for univariate, multivariate, bipartite, longitudinal and social-influence type ERGMs. Each method is applied in individual case studies illustrating how social science theories may be examined empirically using ERGMs. The authors supply the reader with sufficient detail to specify ERGMs, fit them to data with any of the available software packages and interpret the results.
Chapter
Exponential random graph models (ERGMs) are increasingly applied to observed network data and are central to understanding social structure and network processes. The chapters in this edited volume provide a self-contained, exhaustive account of the theoretical and methodological underpinnings of ERGMs, including models for univariate, multivariate, bipartite, longitudinal and social-influence type ERGMs. Each method is applied in individual case studies illustrating how social science theories may be examined empirically using ERGMs. The authors supply the reader with sufficient detail to specify ERGMs, fit them to data with any of the available software packages and interpret the results.
Chapter
Exponential random graph models (ERGMs) are increasingly applied to observed network data and are central to understanding social structure and network processes. The chapters in this edited volume provide a self-contained, exhaustive account of the theoretical and methodological underpinnings of ERGMs, including models for univariate, multivariate, bipartite, longitudinal and social-influence type ERGMs. Each method is applied in individual case studies illustrating how social science theories may be examined empirically using ERGMs. The authors supply the reader with sufficient detail to specify ERGMs, fit them to data with any of the available software packages and interpret the results.
Chapter
Full-text available
Article
We show how the tension between cooperation and competition affects the dynamics of learning alliances. ‘Private benefits’ and ‘common benefits’ differ in the incentives that they create for investment in learning. The competitive aspects of alliances are most severe when a firm's ratio of private to common benefits is high. We introduce a measure, ‘relative scope’ of a firm in an alliance, to show that the opportunity set of each firm outside an alliance crucially impacts its behavior within the alliance. Finally, we suggest why firms might deviate from the theoretically optimal behavior patterns. © 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Article
Provides a systematic presentation of the economic field of industrial organization, which is concerned with how productive activities are brought into harmony with the demand for goods and services through an organizing mechanism, such as a free market, and how variations and imperfections in the organizing mechanism affect the successful satisfying of an economy's wants. Of the three market mechanisms (tradition, central planning, and free markets), the field of industrial organization deals primarily with the market system approach. This book primarily emphasizes the manufacturing and mineral extraction sectors of industrialized economies, with less discussion of wholesale and retail distribution, services, transportation, and public utilities. Beginning with a discussion of the welfare economics of competition and monopoly, the structure of industries in the U.S. and abroad and their determinants are described, including motives for mergers and their effects. Extended analysis of pricing, product policy, and technological innovation then follows. Antitrust, price fixing, related restraints, structural monopolies, regulation, and price discrimination are examined, as are the complex policies governing pricing relationships between vertically linked firms. The role of advertising in product differentiation and the roles of market structure and product variety are identified. Innovation, patents, and their relation to market structure are explored. Overall, this analysis seeks to identify attributes or variables that influence economic performance and to build theories about the links between these attributes and end performance. (TNM)
Article
We show how the tension between cooperation and competition affects the dynamics of learning alliances. 'Private benefits' and 'common benefits' differ in the incentives that they create for investment in learning. The competitive aspects of alliances are most severe when a firm's ratio of private to common benefits is high. We introduce a measure, 'relative scope' of a firm in an alliance, to show that the opportunity set of each firm outside an alliance crucially impacts its behavior within the alliance. Finally, we suggest why firms might deviate from the theoretically optimal behavior patterns. (C) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Article
This article proposes that competition among ideologies can be understood and modeled as an ecology of organizations. It presents a theory of ideological competition among organizations that predicts that competition is strongest among ideologically adjacent organizations-those too different ideologically to enjoy esprit de corps but similar enough to vie for the same base of support. Such competition, the article argues, involves contention over identity, favoring organizations that maintain a distinct ideological position. These ideas are investigated by reference to qualitative and quantitative data from Viennese newspapers over the period 1918 to 1938, a period of considerable social and political change in Vienna. The quantitative evidence is obtained by estimating ecological models of organizational failure and growth. There is also qualitative evidence that actors from various ideological perspectives engaged in strategic framing activity.
Article
Summarizing the facts about the prevailing sizes of industrial firms or plants and the patterns of industrial location in Britain and America, this book also interprets the facts in basic terms such as technical requirements and consumer habits.
Article
Illustrates relational approaches to the study of social movements and collective action. Contributors analyse most recent developments in the analysis of the role of networks as facilitators or constraints of individual recruitment, various forms of interorganizational networks, and the relationship between social networks and the political context in which social movements operate. They also relate the growing attention to social networks by social movement analysis to broader theoretical debates. Both quantitative and qualitative network analysis are considered, and attention is paid to the time dimension and the evolution of networks, through both simulation models and empirical data. Empirical chapters cover both contemporary and historical episodes of collective action, in reference to authoritarian as well as progressive, left-libertarian movements. Chapters focusing on individual networks specify different effects of network embeddedness over participation in different types of collective action (Passy, Anheier). Interorganizational relations are explored by looking at leadership dynamics (Diani), the relationship between categorical traits and network position within coalitions (Ansell), and the role of individuals in linking different organizations both synchronically and diachronically (Osa). Network approaches to the political process illustrate shifts in alliance and conflict networks at a time of regime change (Tilly and Wood), the evolution of social networks during protest cycles (Oliver and Myers), and the role of local elites in shaping protest networks in the community (Broadbent). Theoretical chapters discuss network perspectives on social movements in relation to recent theoretical developments in rational choice theory (Gould), cultural analysis (Mische), and the analysis of social mechanisms (McAdam). A radical case is also made for a reorientation of the whole social movement agenda along network lines (Diani).
Article
An assumption in traditional economics is that managers do not have social relationships (they are "atomists"). Although unreasonable, this assumption is still considered useful by many economists even without empirical proof, i.e. it is a postulate. In this article we present unique findings of bonds of friendship among managers in rival companies and analyze the impact these relationships have on competition and price setting. The analysis builds on personal interviews of 190 store managers in the clothing business in 18 towns and urban areas throughout Norway. We report that managers meet often and exchange business information. Many possess information about aspects of their competitors that are not known publicly; for example, the mark-up factor they apply. Most managers have at least tenuous friendships with all local managers of competing stores competitors, while about one out of four managers know each other very well. The postulate in economics that actors are atomistic is therefore refuted. Furthermore, we find that friendship among managers in competing stores reduce the degree of price competition by between 9 and 15 percent. The empirical material also indicates that strong friendships have more of an effect on reducing the degree of price competition than do weak friendships, and that friendship does not lead to higher prices on local markets.