ArticlePDF Available

Social enterprises and non-market capitals: A path to degrowth?

Authors:

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to look at alternatives to the classic for-profit shareholding enterprise and to suggest how such alternatives might be supported within the current economic system. Another aim is to link the social enterprise and degrowth discourses. We first re-define the economy as including non-monetised sectors (the core economy and the economy of nature) and discuss the liminal zone of not-for-profit and not-only-for profit organisations. We then look at social enterprise definitions from a degrowth perspective and explain why the dimensions of scale, place, environment and provisioning patterns need more space in the social enterprise discourse. After that, we define non-market capitals as capitals taken out of the market and placed under local/member/democratic control and explain their importance in a degrowth economy. We give examples of non-market capitals and suggest a model involving mutual support between primary and secondary social enterprises. Finally, we suggest areas where more research is needed in this emerging field of inquiry.
This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached
copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research
and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution
and sharing with colleagues.
Other uses, including reproduction and distribution, or selling or
licensing copies, or posting to personal, institutional or third party
websites are prohibited.
In most cases authors are permitted to post their version of the
article (e.g. in Word or Tex form) to their personal website or
institutional repository. Authors requiring further information
regarding Elsevier’s archiving and manuscript policies are
encouraged to visit:
http://www.elsevier.com/copyright
6
Author's personal copy
Social enterprises and non-market capitals: a path to degrowth?
Nadia Johanisova
a
,
*
, Tim Crabtree
b
,EvaFra
nková
a
a
Faculty of Social Studies, Masaryk University, Jo
stova 10, Brno 61500, Czech Republic
b
Wessex Community Assets, 1 Watton Gardens, Bridport, Dorset DT6 3DG, United Kingdom
article info
Article history:
Received 24 November 2010
Received in revised form
23 December 2011
Accepted 2 January 2012
Available online 9 January 2012
Keywords:
Social enterprise
Degrowth
Non-market capitals
Sectoral models
Sustainability
abstract
The aim of this paper is to look at alternatives to the classic for-prot shareholding enterprise and to
suggest how such alternatives might be supported within the current economic system. Another aim
is to link the social enterprise and degrowth discourses. We rst re-dene the economy as including
non-monetised sectors (the core economy and the economy of nature) and discuss the liminal zone
of not-for-prot and not-only-for prot organisations. We then look at social enterprise denitions
from a degrowth perspective and explain why the dimensions of scale, place, environment and
provisioning patterns need more space in the social enterprise discourse. After that, we dene non-
market capitals as capitals taken out of the market and placed under local/member/democratic
control and explain their importance in a degrowth economy. We give examples of non-market
capitals and suggest a model involving mutual support between primary and secondary social
enterprises. Finally, we suggest areas where more research is needed in this emerging eld of
inquiry.
Ó2012 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
1. Introduction
Sustainable degrowth, a key goal of the European degrowth/
décroissance movement, builds on a conuence of several
respected and robust streams of thinking (Schneider et al., 2010).
1
It has been dened as an equitable downscaling of production
and consumption that increases human well-being and enhances
ecological conditions at the local and global level(Schneider
et al., 2010). An underlying assumption is that the current main-
stream economic paradigm, with its emphasis on economic
growth as a major policy goal, is outdated and destructive. Various
reasons have been given for this view (van den Bergh, 2009;
Fournier, 2008). A crucial one involves the fact that economic
growth correlates with growth of energy and material throughput
(Jackson, 2009), which are unsustainable in the long-term and are
reaching their limits today (e.g. global warming, peak oil). While
the term remains contested and ambiguous (van den Bergh, 2011;
Kallis, 2011), we tend to agree with Kallis that degrowth (or
sustainabledegrowth, which in our perspective are synonyms)
should not be reduced to the vision of an economy with
a declining GDP. While degrowth approaches probably will result
in a GDP decline, the concept itself can be more usefully seen as an
umbrella keyword, a multi-faceted framework that gives purpose
and connects different policies and citizensinitiatives(Kallis,
2011: 874).
Having said that, it is also important to acknowledge that the
institutions and mechanisms fuelling GDP growth itself are
deeply ingrained in the current economic system. Kennedy
(1995), Hoogendijk (1991), Douthwaite (1999:chapter1),
Harvey (2007) and others have discussed its ramied conse-
quences, fuelled by a structural and deepening dependence on
debt, which include a pressure to grow regardless of the
consequences. This pressure is sometimes dubbed the growth
imperative.
The prevailing actor in the current economic system, the
shareholder-owned prot-led company, is induced to grow
by these external pressures, exacerbated by the neoliberal
*Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: johaniso@fss.muni.cz (N. Johanisova), tim.crabtree@
phonecoop.coop (T. Crabtree), eva.slunicko@centrum.cz (E. Fra
nková).
1
These include, according to Schneider et al. (2010): culturalist critiques of
development (e.g. Polanyi, Norberg-Hodge), the quest for democracy (e.g. Illich),
environmentalism and ecology (e.g. Odum), voluntary simplicity (e.g. Thoreau) and
bioeconomics/ecological economics (e.g. Georgescu-Roegen and many others).
With a grain of salt, we might add to this lineage the classical economists (Smith,
Ricardo, Malthus and J.S. Mill) who did not expect economic growth to go on
forever. Only one of them, however, J.S. Mill, believed that the ensuing steady-state
economy would improve the art of livingand foster a fairer distribution of wealth
and income (Zweig, 1979).
Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect
Journal of Cleaner Production
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jclepro
0959-6526/$ esee front matter Ó2012 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2012.01.004
Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e16
7
Author's personal copy
deregulation of the last decades. The system favours large and
ever-growing companies,
2
which due to their economic strength
and inuence are able to evade local standards and taxes and
externalise an ever-growing proportion of their costs onto other
players, such as their workers, nature and future generations
(Korten, 1995; Martinez-Alier, 2002:10e15). By creating (via
advertising) effective demandfor spurious products, they may
miss real and basic needs in communities, especially those
unbacked by purchasing power. While supercially such
a system is effective, in reality it is deeply ineffective due to its
many negative social and environmental externalities
(Douthwaite, 2000: 211). Growth thus continues while basic
needs go unmet and vulnerable groups are forced into the
money economy, fostering calls for more economic growth
(Korten, 1995: Chapter 3).
As discussed in Johanisova and Wolf (in press), the typical
company limited by shares, which forms the bulk of the larger
players in todays economies, is in addition pressured to grow due
both to its explicit goal (maximising nancial returns on produc-
tion) and to more subtle principles inherent in its inner structure.
These include factors such as a non-democratic management
structure (in the sense that shareholder votes depend on number of
shares, the so-called one-euro-one-vote principle), the absence of
a ceiling on investments, share transferability and lack of owner-
ship transparency which leads to a concentration of shareholder
power and to structural marginalisation of stakeholders (workers,
local community, the environment) other than the majority
shareholders. This in turn makes it easier for the company to
externalise its costs, become more efcient in narrow nancial
terms and remain competitive on the market, while focussing on
prots from (potentially spurious) production and the growth of
the scale of this production.
An economy where such companies prevail is obviously not
conductive to sustainable degrowth. However, there are no simple
remedies because the for-prot share company is part of a system
which rewards and reinforces its problematic behaviour. A for-
prot company which would not comply with the prevailing
model of growth and cost-externalisation would be in danger of
being expunged from the system (Harvey, 2007; Parrish, 2007). An
economic organisation explicitly aiming for other goals than (only)
prot and growth, and thus producing positive externalities which
make it less efcient, would be in similar danger.
An important part of the degrowth research agenda is therefore
an analysis of both the available alternatives to only-for-prot
enterprises and of institutions and mechanisms enabling the
functioning of these alternative enterprises in the current economic
environment. In this paper we try to link the existing discourse on
social enterprise (which we see as a crucial alternative to the for-
prot share company) with the degrowth paradigm, and to look
at some approaches and support mechanisms which might make it
easier for social enterprises to survive economically in the current
economic system without compromising their ethical goals. As
social enterprises, embedded in support mechanisms which enable
their survival, slowly take root and thrive, they will hopefully start
changing the economic system itself from below and slowly build
a base for a degrowth economy.
In the following sections, to prepare the ground for this
discussion, we rst take a closer look at what constitutes the
economyfrom a mainstream and then from a more holistic
perspective, broadening the concept to include economieshith-
erto largely ignored by mainstream economic textbooks (section 2).
In section 3, we pay special attention to the concept of social
enterprise and try to look at it from a degrowth perspective. In
section 4, we discuss another economic concept, capitalor
capitals, and introduce the concept of non-market capitalsand
primaryand secondarysocial enterprises. Some examples of
what we see as non-market capitals are then given, and we suggest
a tentative model of an alternative economy, more suited to
a degrowth world. Finally in section 5, we briey look at some
ambiguities and dangers inherent in the model in a world where
mainstream economic structures predominate and pressure to
converge with mainstream business practices remains strong.
2. What is the economy?
The economyis an ambiguous term notoriously hard to dene,
mirroring the equally ambiguous subject which mainstream
economic science purports to study. While orthodox economics at
rst sight appears to describe paths to a material provisioning of
society, i.e. approaches to the fullment of its material needs, the
marketsit postulates involve not only material goods, but also
living beings (Schumacher, 1993/1973), services (which can and
often do include e.g. healthcare, childcare, education and culture),
human work, nance and land (landbeing a shorthand for nature,
see also Daly and Cobb, 1990:97e120). Drawing all these disparate
entities into the marketmeans subjecting them to the main-
stream economic discourse, with its model of perfect market
competition and controversial central concepts such as economic
efciency(or efciency of production, dened as the relationship
of output and input in money terms, with no place for other less
visible inputs and impacts of a transaction). In this discourse, the
economyexpands to include ever-greater portions of our lives
and of our world, subsuming them to a market logic and re-dening
them as commodities.
However, the economyneed not be identical with the
market. Many heterodoxeconomists have grappled with this issue
and have tried to dene what the economystands for. Karl
Polanyi (2001/1944: 49e56), basing his work on ethnological and
historical research on non-modern cultures, was one of the rst to
ascertain that traditionally in human societies most material
human needs
3
were met via reciprocity (i.e. mutual gifting),
redistribution (those who have share with those who have not) and
householding (non-monetised production for own use). The
market as we know it today played a marginal role. For Polanyi, the
2
It can be argued that, on the contrary, it is heavily regulated markets that
squeeze out small businesses, as these cannot afford compliance costs. Here
however we must specify what type of regulation we have in mind, as the term
regulationcan hide vastly different approaches. The regulatory frameworks
which have been removed in the past, legitimated by the neoliberal paradigm, have
included restraints on corporate mergers and acquisitions, environmental and
labour legislation and international investment regulation (Korten, 1995: 64, Singh,
2007). This has led to the emergence of large players on the economic scene, and,
paradoxically, to pressure on a different type of regulation, e.g. to protect the large
corporationsclients or to limit tax evasion. Examples from the Czech Republic and
United Kingdom (Johanisova, 2005: Chapter 3.5.) include the introduction of strict
hygiene rules which disproportionately affect small rural social enterprises, see also
note 22 on European banking regulations which disable the founding of new credit
unions and ethical banks. Singh (207: 46e48) discusses onerous transfer pricing
regulations in the United States.
3
Here we might discuss whether the economyis only about satisfying material
human needs. According to the human needs matrix of Manfred Max-Neef (1992),
we all have nine basic needs (subsistence, protection, affection, understanding,
participation, idleness, creation, identity and freedom), which can be satised in
various ways (e.g. in being and having modes, by material and non-material
means). Max-Neefs list is thus non-hierarchical and there is no strict dichotomy
between materialand non-material. However, other authors emphasise the
primacy and importance of making sure basic material needs (water, food, clothing
and energy) are met on a local level in a world faced by instability and declining
resource availability (e.g. Douthwaite, 1996:47e51, de Rivero, 2001:186e187).
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e168
8
Author's personal copy
market continues to be subordinate to society (embeddedis his
often quoted expression) even in modern times, and it is imperative
for our survival that it continue to do so. As Joseph Stiglitz makes
clear in a foreword to the 2001 edition of Polanyis The Great
Transformation (p.xv): Polanyi saw the market as part of the
broader economy, and the broader economy as part of a still
broader society.
In her model of the three-layer cake with icing (Fig. 1), Hazel
Henderson (1999) echoes Polanyis claim of embeddedness of the
market economy and makes the point that the private sector is
actually dependent on the public sector, and this in turn depends
on the sweat-equity or core
4
economy. This sphere includes
childcare and care for the elderly in the family, housework, food
growing, volunteering, mutual aid among friends and neighbours
etc.
5
We can see this layer, placed below and supporting the money
economy of the market and the state, as a sphere where Polanyis
reciprocity, redistribution and householding have been to a large
extent relegated: essential for the functioning of the system,
predominantly performed by women, and invisible from a main-
stream economic perspective. However, Hendersons three-layer
cake with icing model makes the further point that all three: the
market, the public and the core economies, are dependent on the
economy (productsand services) of nature (Mother Nature
Layer).
6
Nature satises our needs directly (via the core economy)
and indirectly (via the state and market economy). This level has
become slightly more visible from a mainstream economic
perspective in recent decades, but efforts to quantify the economy
of nature (and thus to bring its non-market productsinto the
orthodox economics eld of vision) are meeting with limited
success (see e.g. Kutá
cek, 2009). It is our contention that efforts at
dening the shadow pricesof processes within the core and
natural economies will always be problematic and that orthodox
economics, rather than subsuming these areas under its sphere of
inuencevia quantication, must explicitly acknowledge their
existence, otherness and essential unquantiability. This will
hopefully open the door to a dialogue between orthodox economics
and other research/knowledge systems.
Returning to the concept of the economy,wehavenow
expanded it to include, in addition to the private/market and the
public monetised spheres, also the non-monetised layers of the
economy of nature and the core economy, and have suggested that
the two latter essentially support the former. From this perspective,
the economyceases to be identical both with the market and the
monetised sphere, and the non-monetised spheres, instead of
being aberrations or externalities which need to be internalised,
become entities important in their own right. This chimes in with
authors like Ivan Illich, who saw the process of commodication
(monetisation)
7
of needs satisfaction as a process whereby scarcity,
far from being banished, is actually created (or manufactured)as
people lose the means and skills to provide for themselves outside
the monetised sphere (Illich, 1973). It also echoes the calls of
contemporary Third World authors like Ashish Kothari (2009), who
asks that non-industrial lifestyles and non-human life formsbe
given respect and space to ourish.
Hendersons cake model (Fig. 1) equates the monetised layer
principally with the private and public sectors, and leads clear
dividing lines between the monetised and non-monetised spheres.
However, the reality is not so simple and if we disregard natures
economy for a moment, looking only at the constellation of
Fig. 1. Hazel Hendersons expanded model of the economy: Three-layer cake with icing (Henderson, 1999: 11).
4
In the sense of Cahn (2004).
5
A similar point has been made by Vandana Shiva (1989), Mary Mellor (1997), J.
K. Gibson-Graham (2003), and many others, especially those writing from a femi-
nist perspective.
6
See also the work of Herman Daly, who has linked the insight of the human
economy embedded in the ecosystem with the issue of optimum scale of material
and energy throughput (e.g. Daly, 1996: 49).
7
As an example of commodication creating scarcity, Illich (1973:42e43) gives
the example of complex social, legal and economic pressures in Mexico and the USA
in the 1960s and 1970s which made self-building of houses by their owners/
occupiers much more difcult than previously. As the number of self-build houses
fell and dependency on the market sector deepened, scarcity of housing was arti-
cially created.
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e16 9
9
Author's personal copy
10
Author's personal copy
decision-making arena to a wider spectrum of stakeholders. These
and other aspects (more fully discussed in Johanisova and Wolf, in
press) discourage a one-sided commitment to growth in social
enterprises.
12
Thinking further about what a social enterprise in a degrowth
worldmight look like, we may also think about the dimensions of
scale, place, the environment, and provisioning patterns which
have been left out in the social enterprise denition discussed
above. As regards scale and place: there is a huge difference
between a small, locally rooted enterprise, albeit a for-prot one,
and a large corporation. A small, locally-rooted enterprise can be
seen as producing positive externalities,
13
including stable and
long-term employment (Douthwaite, 1996:35e37). If such a local
enterprise satises the real and basic needs of a community, and
uses - as much as possible - local resources and products, aspiring
to localised provisioning patterns, we can see it as being truly
efcient: not in the narrow nancial sense mentioned in section 2,
but, instead, efcient in materials and energy use, an important
aspect in a degrowth society. Our emphasis on local basic needs
satisfaction in a degrowth economy is also fuelled bya concern that
communities provide for themselves in the face of possible energy
supply and nancial system discontinuities or collapses, which may
well occur in the future (Douthwaite, 1996:47e51). Last but not
least, we believe that the environmental dimension in the social
enterprise ethos is just as important as the social aspect. Besides
emphasis on local material and energy ows this may take many
forms (from organic farming to building insulation, depending on
the activities of the enterprise, see also Johanisova, 2008).
For the purposes of this paper, then, we dene social enterprises
loosely as organisations involved at least to some extent in the
market, with a clear social, cultural and/or environmental purpose,
rooted in and serving primarily the local community and ideally
having a local and/or democratic ownership structure (one-
member-one-vote rather than one-euro-one-vote). Where a social
enterprise serves another social enterprise rather than serving the
needs of the public/customers/clients directly, we suggest the term
secondary social enterprise. We will return to this concept in the
following section.
4. Non-market capitals: beyond capitals as commodities
In section 2, we have tried to broaden the mainstream economic
concept of the economyto include the non-monetised (core)
sphere of human activity (which would comprise items d/, e/and in
part also items f/and g/) and the economy of naturewhich we
then abstracted from in section 3. However, in reality, as in the
Henderson cake model, nature satises our material needs directly
(via subsistence in the core economy) and indirectly (via the
monetised economy). Nature also satises many of our non-
material needs. Therefore, it is important, from a degrowth
economics perspective, to keep all the three layers, the monetised,
core and nature economies, continually in mind.
The process called economic developmentin the South, (or
progressin the West, see Norberg-Hodge, 1991) is in practice
often identical with the process of commodication discussed by
Ivan Illich (1973), Williams (2005) and others. This process entails
the shift of needs satisfaction from the core economy to the
monetised/market layer of the cake, and is intimately linked to
economic growth (in terms of GDP). For example, when self-build
from local materials is made illegal or difcult, as the example in
note 8 (taken from Illich) describes, the scale of the core economy
dwindles (less houses are built manually by their prospective
owners) and the scale of the monetised economy (and thus the
GDP) expands (more houses are built in exchange for money by
professional builders: they have become commodities). A similar
commodication process happens when childcare is delegated to
paid childminders, home cooking makes way for professional
catering institutions, etc.
In the mainstream economic tradition, the commodication
process is taken for granted and linked to specialisation, efciency,
wealth creation and usually viewed as unambiguously positive.
14
Critics such as Illich (1973), Norberg-Hodge (1991) or Williams
(2005) are more concerned with its seamy side, involving de-
skilling, social exclusion, loss of cultural diversity and the articial
creation of scarcity. From the perspective of these critics and of the
Henderson cake model, we may see the commodication process as
expanding the monetised cake layer but diminishing the core
(reciprocity and subsistence) layer and often contributing to
a shrinking of the nature economy layer as well. We might contend
that the commodication process creates wealth (at least for some)
Fig. 2. Sectoral economic model according to Pestoff, adapted by Hun
cová (2004:
104 e105), based on Pestoff (1995) and Laville et al. (1999: 7, Table 4), distinguishes
a core non-prot sector, indicated by the white circle, and surrounds this with a grey
area. The white circle (non-prot groups) and the grey area (hybridgroups, including
social enterprise) together form the social economy.
12
We are not against growth of social enterprises per se, when the growth
enables the enterprise to better full its role. A problem from a degrowth
perspective is the systemic pressure to grow, inherent in the strictly for-prot
business organisational structure. However, we do feel that growth beyond
a certain limit is a risk factor for social enterprises and can lead to dilution of some
of its principles or even to reversion to a mainstream model, as discussed in section
5(see also Johanisova, 2005:52e53).
13
Externalityis a mainstream economic term describing an impact (positive or
negative) of an economic transaction on a third party, which/who has not taken
part in the transaction. In the neoclassical economic model, externalitiesneed to
be internalised, i.e. their nancial value needs to be quantied and the parties to
the transaction need to pay (negative externalities) or receive (positive externali-
ties) compensation. This is the logic behind the effort to create shadow pricesin
the spheres of core and natural economies discussed in section 2.
14
Mainstream economists can take their cue from Adam Smith in his Wealth of
nations, who thus dismisses the non-specialised work of a country weaver, who
cultivates a small farm:.the habit of sauntering and of indolent careless
application, which is .acquired by every country workman who is obliged to
change his work and his tools every half an hour .renders him almost always
slothful and lazy, and incapable of any vigorous application even on the most
pressing occasions.(Heilbroner, 1986: 165).
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e16 11
11
Author's personal copy
in the monetised sector (top cake layers) while at the same time
fostering poverty in the non-monetised sectors (bottom cake
layers).
15
A critical approach towards the commodication process
is espoused also by the degrowth movement (Fournier, 2008).
In an important contribution to the commodication discussion,
Karl Polanyi (2001/1944: Chapter 6) has criticised the commodi-
cation of the factors of production in economic theory and practice:
the creation of markets for nancial capital, human labour and
land. He calls these the ctitious commodities:
.They could, of course, not really be transformed into
commodities, as actually they were not produced forsale on the
market. But the ction of their being so produced became an
organising principle of society. Of the three, one stands out:
labour is the technical term used for human beings.All along
the line, human society has become an accessory of the
economic system.(Polanyi, 2001: 79)
By economic systemPolanyi obviously means the production
process postulated by economic theory and encapsulated in the
well-known production model (Fig. 3).
The production model, which has been with us since at least
Adam Smith, describes the process of commodity production. To
produce a commodity, the producer needs access to land and
natural resources, to human labour and to capital (usually
subsuming manufactured or xed capital - machines, buildings, etc.
and nancial capital: money). These have been called factors of
production and, more recently, they have been dubbed capitals.
16
Polanyis point is that, while there is a certain logic in desig-
nating a manufactured product as a commodity, the mainstream
economic discourse postulates markets not only for manufactured
products, but also for labour, nance and land.
17
However, he
emphasises that labour cannot be divided from the human being,
and land from nature, and since we cannot manufacture either, it is
neither moral nor in practice possible to reduce them to
commodities tradable in a deregulated market. Similarly money
cannot be left to a deregulated market without grave dangers to
business enterprises and to society. Polanyis views on capitals not
being true commodities was shared in a sense by Gandhi (Parekh,
1991) who, drawing on the Hindu spiritual tradition, was essen-
tially against private ownership of capital assets and land, because
they had been handed down to us from the past, as a gift born of co-
operation, sharing, mutual concern and self-sacrice.
18
Conversely,
for Gandhi the principle of private property of capitals stressed
selshness, exclusive ownership and narrow individualism
(Johanisova, 2007: 46). Thus, for Gandhi, it was more appropriate to
view land and other capital assets as being held in trust for future
generations and to develop their ownership structures accordingly.
Polanyis and Gandhis thinking forms a theoretical framework
for a useful concept, the non-market capital, which we would like
to introduce in this paper. The idea of non-market capitals has been
pioneered by Bruyn (1992), who was inuenced by Polanyis
thinking. He sees them as restoring the economic base of the
community and returning economic controls into the hands of the
local peopleand denes them as capitals taken out of the market
and placed under democratic control. Rather than top-down state
control, however, the capitals (such as land, nance, workspace or
housing, physical equipment, knowledge, etc.) are to be controlled
democratically on a non-prot basis, ideally by the local commu-
nity. By taken out of the marketBruyn does not necessarily mean
Fig. 3. The production diagram, found in most mainstream economic textbooks, features land, labour and capital (manufactured and nancial) as independent and inter-
changeable factors of production: means towards the end of production of commodities, whose consumption is seen as the sole source of utility(another ambiguous term often
equated with satisfaction or happiness).
15
This would lead to a discussion on what is wealth and poverty, which is beyond
the scope of this article, but see Johanisova (2007):178e184.
16
The term capital itself has different meanings in different disciplines and
discourses. In classical and neoclassical economics, as mentioned in the text, capital
has traditionally been equated with nance needed to start or expand an enterprise
and with the premises and tools needed to produce products and services. Ekins
(1992:48e61) has reframed the traditional factors of production as ecological
capital, human capital, manufactured capital and social/organisational capital,
emphasised their intrinsic (as opposed to purely instrumental) value and the fact
that all of them need continuous (monetised and non-monetised) investment to
keep them viable. In our paper, we are in agreement with this approach but take
a more empirical, if restricted view of capitalsas any resources needed for human
needs satisfaction in the monetised and liminal zones (see sections 2 and 3).
17
The existence of markets for factors of production is in fact one of the
assumptions of the perfect competition model in neoclassical economics.
18
This view of capitals as handed-down gifts rather than resources ties in with
the traditional economic relationship of reciprocity, or mutual gift-giving, identied
by Polanyi and mentioned in section 2. If we look at our economic relationship with
nature in this perspective, we might ask what we are giving back.
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e1612
12
Author's personal copy
that the capitals are accessible to enterprises (or to people) without
any cost. However, the costs are withdrawn from the dominance of
the market logic of prot maximisation and from an exclusive focus
on the monetised sphere. They are subjected instead to local needs
as dened by the local community and determined on the basis of
a holistic approach, i.e. taking into account social equity and envi-
ronmental sustainability as well as the whole economy as depicted
by the Henderson cake model (Fig. 1).
The concept of non-market capitals can be useful on both
a theoretical and practical level in the degrowth-social enterprise
discourse. On a theoretical level, it can serve as an umbrella term
conating, illuminating and arguably legitimating many forms of
support which social enterprises access in practice and which, in
the mainstream economic perspective, can appear as subsidies
which give them an unfair advantage over other enterprises. All
producers, it is implied in the mainstream discourse, should
compete on a level playing eld, otherwise deformations of the
market will result, leading to inefciency and malfunctioning of the
market mechanism. However, the perfect competition model of the
economy which fuels this discourse, like the current emphasis on
economic growth, is problematic (Beinhocker, 2006). As mentioned
above, an efciententerprise can in fact be very inefcient if we
take its externalities into account. Conversely, a social enterprise
may not be as efcientin this narrow nancial sense, because it
produces positive externalities. Without some form of non-market
support it may not be able to survive economically. The concept of
non-market capitals legitimises this perspective on the economy
and operationalises it in the sense of acknowledging a non-
marketsphere, thus drawing the non-monetised and liminal
zones of the economy into the picture.
On a more practical level, the concept of the non-market capital
is useful because it applies Polanyis and Gandhis assertion that
capitals cannot, with impunity, be conceptualised as commodities,
to the real world. It enables us to see that, both in the past and
today, many ingenious ways have been devised by local commu-
nities to protect, safeguard and enhance capitals, and to make them
available for provisioning processes in the non-monetised and
liminal economic spheres, which escape the doubtful market logic
of nancial efciency. In the following paragraphs, we give several
examples of currently existing institutionalstructures which either
have been dened, or can be re-dened, as safeguarding and
distributing non-market capitals.
As Bruyn (1992) has pointed out, land (or premises) can become
a non-market capital via a type of institution pioneered in the
United States and called a community land trust.
19
Essentially,
community land trusts (in the United Kingdom sometimes desig-
nated as community property trusts or development trusts) are
democratically governed, locally owned non-prot institutions
which have in their ownership land to be used for public benet.
Often this land is used to build affordable housing for local citi-
zens.
20
In other cases, the land is affordably rented to an organic
farm to provide food security for the community, or the trust owns
workspace which it rents to a social enterprise.
21
A similar
approach has been used in the village of Hostetin in Moravia in the
Czech Republic, where a foundation (the Veronica Foundation)
owns the land and premises of a small fruit-juice plant, built to
utilise genetically valuable landraces of fruit in the region
(Johanisova, 2005, 2008). In a wider sense, in countries like the
Czech Republic, where local authorities even in small villages retain
some ownership of land and buildings, such local authorities can
(and in some cases to a limited extent do) support local traders,
farms, renewable energy and food processing units, pubs, farmers
markets, community groups etc. through renting workspace and
land on a non-market basis, e.g. at prices lower than market prices,
designated in some cases to cover maintenance only. From
a degrowth perspective, the land-and-assets as non-market capi-
tals can facilitate localised production and consumption, the exis-
tence of small-scale enterprises and the satisfaction of real and
basic needs. It must be emphasised however that communal
ownership of assets for the common good, especially of land and
natural resources, is a very old approach which has been practiced
for millennia the world over (see e.g. The Ecologist, 1992; Neeson,
1993; Sarukhán and Larson, 2001; Ostrom, 1990). The non-
market capital approach can in this light also be seen as
a modern incarnation and extension of this traditional type of
communal ownership, known as the commons (Johanisova, 2004).
As regards money and nance, there are many institutions
which can be seen as based on the non-market capital approach.
These include ethical banks and communal currency systems.
Bruyn (1992) suggests a locally operating credit union (credit co-
operative) as the prototype non-market source of capital. Credit
unions eschew the mainstream economic credit model of a bank as
an enterprise sellingmoney (which later however returns to its
seller, as in fact it was only lent) for prot to a client. Instead,
credit unions are built on the model of a group pooling their
resources with each having the possibility to borrow from this pool.
One benet of localised credit unions (i.e. operating in a certain
region only) is the fact that local savings are re-investedlocally (See
also Douthwaite, 1996). Another is democratic self-governance and
the fact that, with higher reserves and no investment in problem-
atic development projects, credit unions are less involved in the
money must growpressure which is one of the principal drivers
of economic growth (Hoogendijk, 1991; Douthwaite, 2000).
22
In addition to credit unions, a wide array of other ethical
banking institutions exist. One of the best-known examples of an
ethical bank was (we intentionally use the past tense as the Mon-
dragon system has grown in scale and drifted towards the main-
stream in recent decades) the Mondragon bank (Caja Laboral) in
Mondragon in the Basque country in Spain (see e.g. Douthwaite,
1996:160e170, 338e341, Mathews, 1999). The bank was owned
by local producer co-operatives which together with their staff
banked with it. The bank in return supported its member co-
operatives in various ways, including extension of seed capital,
cheap credit and expert advice when the co-operative was in
trouble.
Knowledge as a non-market capital was also prominent within
the intricate system of umbrella groups in the Czechoslovakian
agricultural co-operative movement (which included thousands of
village credit unions) before the 1948 Communist takeover. The
umbrella groups, again owned by the member co-operatives,
provided access to agricultural expertise for their members and
19
The rst community land trust in the United States was established in 1967 by
the civil rights movement (Conaty et al., 2005). In the United States there are in
addition land trusts which own land in order to protect its natural value and keep it
undeveloped.
20
While theoccupier has a legalclaim on the house (andmay own it or partof it), the
land itself remains the property of the trust. When the occupier wishes to sell the
house, in some models he must do so to the community land trust at a below-market
price designed to balance the interests of the occupier and the trust (Conaty et al.,
2005). Thus the issue ofrising land prices is avoided and the house remains affordable.
21
For more on the burgeoning community land trust movement in the United
Kingdom, see www.communitylandtrust.org.uk.
22
In the European Union today, thanks to onerous banking regulations, newcredit
unions and ethical banks are very difcult if not impossible to set up. One of the
reasons is the very high capital needed at start-up. Countries like the United
Kingdom, Ireland and Poland are only able to maintain their small credit unions
because of an exemption from the Second EU Banking Directive (Johanisova, 2005).
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e16 13
13
Author's personal copy
helped new co-operatives start up (Feierabend, 1952). The system
helped small farmers survive, countering the pressure towards land
ownership concentration inherent in the capitalist model of agri-
cultural production.
Finally, non-market capital repositories, often unmarked by the
mainstream, exist within the core economy in countries of the
global South. For instance, in the Bangladeshi Nyakrishi Andolon
organic agriculture movement, comprising tens of thousands of
households, sophisticated seed-saving knowledge is applied via
a three-tiered seed-saving system consisting of households,
community seed centres and regional seed-preservation centres.
Seeds as capitals very much in the sense of Gandhi (see section 4)
go mostly unmarked by mainstream economic thinking, yet their
preservation on a non-market basis is crucial for enhancing the
independence of traditional communities from the market system
(Anonymous, 2006).
We have attempted to introduce the concept of non-market
capitals, whereby institutions such as local communities, munici-
palities, social enterprise umbrella groups, community land trusts
and ethical banks take out capitals (such as land, premises,
knowledge, seeds, nancial capital
23
) from the market and place
them under local/member/democratic control to serve the
common good and hopefully help satisfy basic needs in a socially
equitable and environmentally sustainable manner. While in some
cases these institutions serve individuals, households and families
(as with most credit unions), in other cases they function on
a second-tier level and help support other social enterprises, i.e.
those that provide goods and services directly. We might call the
latter primary social enterprisesand the former secondary social
enterprises.Fig. 4 illustrates in simplied form this tentative
model of collaboration (as opposed to the mainstream emphasis on
competition) within an emerging degrowth economy.
In this model, primary (local, on-the-ground) social enterprises
providing basic goods and services which meet local needs are
owners of (or represented on the boards of) secondary social
enterprises. These secondary social enterprises provide secondary
business services as well as non-market capitals: land/premises/
natural resources, manufactured capital, nancial capital and
knowledge/skills. An important principle here is subsidiarity and
democratic governance: the secondary social enterprise does not
try to usurp the autonomy of the primary social enterprises, but
remains their servant. It is also, in an ideal case, nancially sup-
ported by them: the services of the secondary social enterprise are
not free, but are carefully calculated to ensure the nancial viability
of the secondary enterprise. The primary and secondary social
enterprises thus support each other. Essentially, this is a mutual aid
(or reciprocity) model, with organisations rather than individuals
as the main protagonists (Johanisova, 2007).
Of the examples of institutions providing non-market capitals
already discussed, many would qualify as secondary social enter-
prises. The Mondragon bank supporting its member co-operatives
is an obvious example, as were the umbrella groups of the Czech
agricultural co-operative movement. A community land trust may
qualify as a secondary structure if it supports e.g. local farming
enterprises instead of householders. The regional seed preservation
centres of the Nyakrishi movement might also qualify as secondary
social enterprises, albeit in a predominantly non-monetised
setting.
As with the concept of non-market capitals, it should be quite
clear that the reciprocal social enterprise model is not meant to
introduce a new, previously unheard-of institutional structure. On
the contrary, it is meant to acknowledge and legitimate already
existing relationships of mutual collaboration which exist e.g.
within the co-operative movement and which have gone
unmarked by the mainstream economic discourse, and thus
hopefully enable their further self-reection, development and
renement. It is also meant to provide one tentative alternative to
mainstream economic models, focussed on growth and competi-
tion. One weakness of our model is the absence of explicit links to
the non-monetised and natural environments (the core economy
and natures economy) which all the enterprises involved depend
on. This is partly compensated by our denition of a social enter-
prise, which assumes an explicit focus on social and/or environ-
mental goals and localised provisioning patterns.
5. Some ambiguities and issues for further research
Although we have tried to present our model of a potential
degrowth economy in clear lines and bright colours, the reality has
its shadows and many ambiguities remain. For example, as Smith
and Stenning (2005) have pointed out in their research in post-
socialist economies, economic power can deform relationships in
informal and non-market economic systems and lead to exploita-
tion, black market, corruption and even maa practices.
Another difcult issue which needs to be discussed in relation to
a potential social enterprise future is the tendency of successful
alternative economic structures to revert to a mainstream model.
Examples abound. We have mentioned the Mondragon co-
operatives, which have been criticised for gradually losing their
ethos in the face of international competition (Johanisova, 2007:
70e71). In the United Kingdom, the best known case is that of the
British building societies, which emerged in the 18th century as
small workerssavings mutuals and ended up large, successful but
mainstream and demutualised in the late 20th century.
24
Even
enterprises which retain their democratic structure in the face of
Fig. 4. Reciprocal social enterprise model according to Tim Crabtree. Inspired by the
work of Jules Pretty, the Institute of Community Economics (USA), and by the Mon-
dragon Co-operatives (Spain).
23
Labour is not mentioned here but we might argue that the staff of co-
operatively owned social enterprises would constitute non-market labour, as the
workers are at the same time owners of the enterprise. Similarly, we might see
volunteering as non-market labour, given as a gift.
24
Northern Rock, one of the nancial institutions which went bankrupt during
the current nancial crisis, was one such (demutualised) building society.
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e1614
14
Author's personal copy
success may still, with time, become prot-making institutions
with little regard for the products and services being produced and
for the sustainability of the production process. How do explicit
social and environmental objectives get written into the objects of
an enterprise, and take long-term precedence over simple prot
maximisation?
Often the gradual usurpation of power by a secondary social
enterprise or umbrella group originally set up by the primary social
enterprises is part of the problem. Stampfer (2001) describes such
a situation in the German and Austrian credit union movement,
which has a history dating back to the nineteenth century. As
members have stopped identifying with their local credit union and
withdrawn from the decision-making process, the decision-making
power of the local entities was eroded and many have lost their
autonomy to the powerful federations.
Another issue is that the system of mutual support institutions
described in this paper may be accused of unfair economic
practice. In the mainstream economic discourse, nurtured by the
perfect competition model, there is a pressure to minimise all
subsidies (as well as taxes, transfer payments, etc.) in order to
mitigate alleged market deformations. Enterprises are expected to
compete on a level playing eld with the best ei.e. most nan-
cially efcient eand to win in this competition by delivering the
cheapest products and service to the consumer. From a degrowth
perspective, it should again be emphasised that efciency, as
mentioned above, cannot be measured solely in money terms as
the relationship between inputs and outputs. Such an approach
misses the many positive externalities which a business appear-
ing less efcient may bring, such as stable and local employment,
social capital, or food security. Similarly, effective production in
nancial terms may hide negative externalities, such as worker
exploitation, environmental pollution or food miles. In reality,
there never has been a level playing eld because of varying
social and environmental conditions and different scales and aims
of the players. The perfect competition model is an abstraction
which may be useful but must remain one policy tool among
many.
Non-market capitals in the shape of cheaper rent for workspace,
a cheap loan, or access to business advice, may, however, be seen as
unfair competition not only by market purists, but by enterprises
who for some reason do not have access to or are barred from
accessing them. Who will benet and who will not? Here it will be
important to explicitly discuss the issues of public interest vs.
private interest and develop clear guidelines and transparent
organisational structures to ensure that undue benet is not being
gained by primary social enterprises with the ability to access non-
market capitals from a second (or third) tier organisation.
6. Conclusions
In this paper, we have rst tried to provide a framework for
discussing the concept of the economyfrom a degrowth
perspective. In particular, we have tried to de-link the term from its
usual connotations of market and money economy and, building on
the previous work of various authors, have expanded it to include
the non-monetised layer of the economy of nature and the core
economy. Further, we have emphasised the existence of economic
sectors in the liminal zone between the monetised and non-
monetised economies and have suggested that an analysis of this
zone is an important part of the degrowth research agenda. We
have focused especially on the concept of social enterprise which
has emerged in the last few decades and we contend that the
dimensions of scale, place, the environment and provisioning
patterns should be accorded more importance in the social enter-
prise discourse from a degrowth perspective.
Based on the work of Polanyi, Gandhi, Bruyn and others, we
have then dened non-market capitals as capitals taken out of the
market and placed under democratic local control. These non-
market capitals (such as accessible small loans or lower-than-
market rent for premises) can be an important survival strategy
for both primary and secondary social enterprises, which, due to
their production of positive externalities, could not otherwise
compete in a globalised market. We suggest that community land
trusts, credit unions, co-operative umbrella groups and village seed
banks are all instances of institutions safeguarding non-market
capital. In a future degrowth economy, primary and secondary
social enterprises might mutually support each other, thus gradu-
ally changing the economic institutional structure to one more
favourable to a degrowth scenario.
To move forward, we need more research on the reasons why
many social enterprises, especially secondary social enterprises,
have failed in the past, while others have ourished. We also need
to clearly dene the line between public and private interest in
order to develop clear guidelines and transparent organisational
structures of future social enterprises.
Acknowledgement
This paper was supported by Grant No. MUNI/A/0931/2009 of
the Faculty of Social Studies of the Masaryk University, Brno, Czech
Republic.
References
Anonymous, 2006. A message from Bangladesh Online at: http://www.
farmingsolutions.org/successtories/stories.asp?id¼16 (accessed 04.26.10.).
Beinhocker, E.D., 2006. The Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity and the Radical
Remaking of Economics. Harvard Business School Press, Harvard.
Borzaga, C., Defourny, J. (Eds.), 2001. The Emergence of Social Enterprise. Routledge,
London.
Borzaga, C., Galera, G., Nogales, R. (Eds.), 2008. Social Enterprise: a New Model for
Poverty Reduction and Employment Generation: An Examination of the
Concept and Practice in Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States.
EMES European Research Network and UNDP Regional Centre for Europe and
the CIS, Bratislava.
Bruyn, S., 1992. A new direction for community development in the United States.
In: Ekins, P., Max-Neef, M. (Eds.), Real-Life Economics: Understanding Wealth
Creation. Routledge, London, pp. 372e381.
Cahn, E., 2004. No More Throwaway People: The Co-production Imperative.
Essential Books, Washington, D.C.
Conaty, P., Birchall, J., Bendle, S., Foggit, R., 2005. Common Ground for Mutual Home
Ownership: Community Land Trusts and Shared-equity Co-operatives to Secure
Permanently Affordable Homes for Key Workers. New Economics Foundation,
The Housing Corporation, CDS Co-operatives, London.
Daly, H., 1996. Beyond growth: The economics of sustainable development. Beacon
Press, Boston.
Daly, H., Cobb, J., 1990. For the Common Good: Redirecting the Economy towards
Community, the Environment and a Sustainable Future. Green Print, London.
de Rivero, O., 2001. The Myth of Development. The Non-Viable Economies of the
21st Century. Zed Books, London.
Douthwaite, R., 1996. Short Circuit: Strengthening Local Economies for Security in
an Unstable World. Lilliputt Press, Dublin.
Douthwaite, R., 1999. The Ecology of Money. Schumacher Society, Green Books,
Dartington, U.K.
Douthwaite, R., 2000. The Growth Illusion: How Economic Growth Has Enriched
the Few, Impoverished the Many and Endangered the Planet. Lilliput Press,
London.
Ekins, P., 1992. Wealth beyond Measure. Gaia Books, London.
Feierabend, K., 1952. Agricultural Cooperatives in Czechoslovakia. Mid-European
Studies Center, New York.
Fournier, V., 2008. Escaping from the economy: the politics of degrowth. Interna-
tional Journal of Sociology and Social Policy 28 (11/12), 528e545.
Gibson-Graham, J.K., 2003. An ethics of the local. Rethinking Marxism 15 (1),
49e74.
Harvey, D., 2007. The Limits to Capital. Verso, London.
Heilbroner, R.L., 1986. The Essential Adam Smith. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Henderson, H., 1999. Beyond Globalization: Shaping a Sustainable Global Economy.
Kumarian Press, Connecticut.
Hoogendijk, W., 1991. The Economic Revolution: Towards a Sustainable Future by
Freeing the Economy from Money-making. Green Print, London/Jan van Arkel,
Utrecht.
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e16 15
15
Author's personal copy
Hun
cová, M., 2004. Ekonomický Rozm
er Ob
canské Spole
cnosti (The Economic
Dimension of Civil Society). Univerzita J.E. Purkyn
e, Fakulta sociáln
e ekono-
mická, Ústí nad Labem (In Czech).
Illich, I., 1973. Tools for Conviviality. Harper and Row, New York.
Jackson, T., 2009. Prosperity without Growth eEconomics for a Finite Planet.
Earthscan, London.
Johanisova, N., 2004. Local and ethical enterprise as an important part of
a sustainable Future. In: Woltron, et al. (Eds.), Wege in Den Postkapitalismus.
Edition Selene, Club of Vienna, Vienna, pp. 253e261.
Johanisova, N., 2005. Living in the Cracks: a Look at Rural Social Enterprises in
Britain and the Czech Republic. Feasta, Dublin.
Johanisova, N., 2007. A Comparison of Rural Social Enterprises in Britain and
the Czech Republic. Faculty of Social Studies, Masaryk University, Brno.
Online at: http://is.muni.cz/th/38023/fss_d/%20-%2042k (accessed
04.26.10.). (In English).
Johanisova, N., 2008. Towards an eco-social enterprise? In: Third Sector and
Sustainable Social Change: New Frontiers for Research: ISTR Eigth International
Conference. Universitat de Barcelona, Spain Online at: www.istr.org/
conferences/barcelona/WPVolume/Johanisova.pdf (accessed 04.26.10.).
Johanisova, N., Wolf, S., in press. Economic democracy: a path for the future? Futures.
Kallis, G., 2011. In defence of degrowth. Ecological Economics 70, 873e880.
Kennedy, M., 1995. Interest and Ination-free Money: Creating an Exchange
Medium that Works for Everybody and Protects the Earth. New Society,
Philadelphia.
Korten, D., 1995. When Corporations Rule the World. Earthscan, London.
Kothari, A., 2009. A sympathetic critique of the Bhaduri-Patkar model. Economic
and Political Weekly 19 (12), 76e77.
Kutá
cek, S., 2009. Theories of Externalities and Their Application on Selected
Segment of Transport. Faculty of Economics and Administration, Masaryk
University, Brno. Online at: http://https://is.muni.cz/auth/th/11271/esf_d/
DIZERTACE_Kutacek_velka-obhajoba.pdf?fakulta¼1423;obdobi¼4784
(accessed 04.26.10.). (In Czech).
Laville, J.L., Borzaga, C., Defourny, C., Evers, A., Lewis, J., Nyssens, M., Pestoff, V.,1999.
Third system: a European denition Paper produced in the framework of the
pilot action Third system and employmentof the European Commission.
Online at: http://www.istr.org/networks/europe/laville.evers.etal.pdf (accessed
04.26.10.).
MacGillivray, A., Conaty, P., Wadhams, C., 2001. Low Flying Heroes: Micro-social
Enterprise below the Radar Screen. New Economics Foundation, London.
Martinez-Alier, J., 2002. The Environmentalism of the Poor ea Study of Ecological
Conicts and Valuation. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, U.S.A.
Mathews, R., 1999. Jobs of Our Own: Building a Stake-holder Society. Comerford and
Miller, London.
Max-Neef, M., 1992. Development and human needs. In: Ekins, P., Max-Neef, M.
(Eds.), Real-life Economics: Understanding Wealth Creation. Routledge, London,
pp. 197e214.
Mellor, M., 1997. Women, nature and the social construction of economic man.
Ecological Economics 20, 129e140.
Neeson, J.M., 1993. Commoners: Common Right, Enclosure and Social Change in
England. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Norberg-Hodge, H., 1991. Ancient Futures: Learning from Ladakh. Rider, London.
Ostrom, E., 1990. Governing the Commons eThe Evolution of Institutions for
Collective Action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Parekh, B., 1991. Gandhis Political Philosophy: a Critical Examination. Macmillan,
Basingstoke.
Parrish, B.D., 2007. Sustainability Entrepreneurship: Innovations in the Logics of
Organising Paper at Corporate responsibility research conference, 15e17 July
2007, Devonshire Hall, University of Leeds, UK.
Pestoff, V.A., 1995. Reforming Social Services in Central Eastern Europe and Eleven
Nation Overview. GRYF, Krakow (Quoted in Hun
cová, 2004.).
Polanyi, K., 2001. The Great Transformation. Beacon Press, London.
Robertson, J., 1990. Future Wealth: A New Economics for the 21
st
Century. Cassell,
London.
Salamon, L.M., Anheier, H.K., 1997. Dening the Non-prot Sector: a Cross-national
Analysis. John Hopkins Nonprot Sector Series. Manchester University Press,
Manchester.
Samuelson, P., Nordhaus, W., 1991. Ekonomie. Svoboda, Prague.
Sarukhán, J., Larson, J., 2001. When the commons become less tragic: land tenure,
social organisation, and fair trade in Mexico. In: Burger, J., Ostrom, E.,
Norgaard, R.B., Policansky, D., Goldstein, B.D. (Eds.), Protecting the Commons: A
Framework for Resource Management in the Americas. Island Press, Wash-
ington, pp. 45e69.
Schneider, F., Kallis, G., Martinez-Alier, J., 2010. Crisis or opportunity? Economic
degrowth for social equity and ecological sustainability. Introduction to this
special issue. Journal of Cleaner Production 18 (6), 511e518.
Schumacher, E.F., 1993. Small Is Beautiful: a Study of Economics as if People Mat-
tered. Vintage, London.
Shiva, V., 1989. Staying Alive: Women, Ecology and Development. Zed Books,
London.
Singh, K., 2007. Why investment matters: The political economy of international
investments. Fern, Moreton-in-Marsh, U.K.
Smith, A., Stenning, A., 2005. Beyond household economies: articulations and spaces
of economic practice in post socialism. Progress in Human Geography 30 (2),
190e213.
Stampfer, J., 2001. The structural erosion of the co-operative principle and the
chances of reversing the trend. In: Mayo, E., Guene, Ch. (Eds.), Banking and
Social Cohesion: Alternative Responses to a Global Market. Jon Carpenter,
Charlbury, U.K, pp. 103e123.
The Ecologist, 1992. Whose common future? The Ecologist, Special Issue 22 (4),
121e210.
Trainer, T., 1995. The Conserver Society: Alternatives for Sustainability. Zed Books,
London.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2009. The GDP paradox. Journal of Economic Psychology 30
(2), 117e135.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2011. Environment versus growth eA criticism of
degrowthand a plea for a-growth. Ecological Economics 70, 881e890.
Williams, C.C., 2005. A Commodied World? Mapping the Limits of Capitalism. Zed
Books, London.
Zweig, K., 1979. Smith, Malthus, Ricardo and Mill: the forerunners of limits to
growth. Futures 11 (6), 510e523.
N. Johanisova et al. / Journal of Cleaner Production 38 (2013) 7e1616
16
... Hauser et al. (2015, p. 81) refer to the effect as the "democratization of capital investment", which generates self-efficacy. In addition, social-ecological value is created through the activism of a community to advocate for nature conservation and direct activities against increasing the issues of the climate crisis (Dixon, 2014;Johanisova et al., 2013). It can be deduced that ECs make financial decisions regardless of high expected returns as long as the non-financial values satisfy the member's expectations (Holstenkamp et al., 2018). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
Germany's energy system is undergoing significant transformations driven by the Energiewende, a comprehensive transition to renewable energy sources. This thesis investigates the role of energy cooperatives (ECs) in this transition, specifically examining whether they serve as social-ecological transformative actors challenging the traditional Energy Economy and contributing to an Energy Democracy. Utilizing an analytical framework based on the social-ecological transformation and the concepts of Energy Democracy and Energy Economy, a systematic review was conducted on the empirical state of German ECs. The findings reveal that while ECs possess transformative elements such as regionality, collaboration, and environmental consciousness, they do not significantly challenge established social-ecological inequalities. ECs exhibit a high degree of social exclusivity and face substantial barriers in influencing political and economic contexts. Consequently, although ECs are not fully transformative actors, they do contribute to the advocacy for a decentralized and collectively managed energy system, embodying the principles of Energy Democracy within the constraints of the existing capitalistic driven Energiewende.
... The prevailing type of organisation of production and service provision in the growth-based economy is a large and growing business motivated by profit and owned by shareholders (Johanisova et al. 2013;Roman-Alcalá 2017). Such organisations are always in pursuit of minimising costs and maximising profit. ...
Book
Full-text available
As a research field, social movement and political project, degrowth is a multifaceted phenomenon. It brings together a range of practices including alternative forms of living and transformative initiatives in civil society, business and the state. Yet no comprehensive theory of degrowth transformations has so far been developed. Deep Transformations fills this gap. It develops a theory of degrowth transformations drawing on insights from multiple fields of knowledge, such as political economy, sociology and philosophy. The book offers a holistic perspective that brings into focus transformation processes on various scales and points to various mechanisms that can facilitate degrowth. These include, for instance, eco-social policies, transformative initiatives in business and civil society and alternative modes of being in and relating with the world.
... When analysing the source literature, it can be concluded that the problem of degrowth is intensely developing and attracting more and more supporters, as evidenced by the increasing number of publications covering this subject matter (Latouche, 2009;Van den Bergh et al., 2012, Capasso, 2021, Van den Bergh, 2011Jakob et al., 2014;Kallis et al., 2012;Johanisova et al., 2013;Sekulova et al., 2013). Officially, there are as many as 50 exponents of degrowth, originating from the world of politics, science, literature, and non-governmental organizations, and who contribute to the dissemination of this idea worldwide (Biagini et al., 2017), including: M. Bookchin, P. Kropotkin, L. Tolstoy, Gandhi, A. Camus, S. Jevons, G. Orwell, B. Commoner and I. Illich. ...
Article
Full-text available
The article addresses the problem of degrowth, approached as a socio-economic process reducing human pressure on the environment (the detoxification of nature) by setting alternative economic goals and recognising other boundaries (ecological and social) in the socio-economic development. Its main purpose is to systematise knowledge about degrowth and attempt to answer the question whether the concept of degrowth has a chance of becoming a new real paradigm of socio-economic development in the 21st century. A critical analysis of the source literature covering the problem of socio-economic development paradigm and the concept of degrowth was the starting point of the research. The empirical study relating to the problem of shortening food supply chains in Poland serves as an example illustrating the practical implication of degrowth. The conducted analysis showed that the concept of degrowth may become a new paradigm of socio-economic development in the 21st century. It requires, however, further changes in the institutional system as a controlled process of changes.
... In the past, only a few scholars have dared to challenge the inherent 'growth fetish' (Hamilton 2004) of OMS openly (Egri and Pinfield 1999, Kallio 2007, Shrivastava 1994, Stead and Garner Stead 1994. However, the rapid proliferation of degrowth and post-growth discourses within many academic circles along with drastically worsening ecological conditions over recent years have also reactivated the debate within critical organizational research (see, for instance, Banerjee et al. 2020, Fournier 2008, Johnsen et al. 2017, Johanisova et al. 2013, Nesterova 2019, Nyberg and Wright 2020, Rätzer et al. 2018 CSR scholarship with the sustainable development discourse, and green growth more recently, serves as a comfortable background that prevents the asking of tougher questions around the relation of growth critique and corporate activity. Indeed, is degrowth fundamentally incompatible with CSR in a capitalist system that is hell-bent on growing, no matter the disastrous consequences it spurs? ...
Chapter
Full-text available
Continuous economic growth has been raised as one of three grand taboos of the corporate social responsibility (CSR) discourse (Kallio 2007) and remains fundamentally neglected to this day. This neglect represents not only a fundamental weakness of scholarly pursuits within CSR, but also contains existential consequences for human and non-human life on this planet (IPCC 2021), due to the largely unquestioned notion of ever-growing economic activity of corporate business. Within this brief entry, I will argue that work within CSR has overwhelmingly followed the hegemonic neoclassical conviction of limitless economic growth on a finite planet in its theorizing and practice. On the one hand, CSR can thus be positioned within an overarching discursive field of what is commonly referred to as green or sustainable growth, which ultimately stabilizes the hegemonic pursuit of economic growth as desirable and necessary. On the other, the multidisciplinary degrowth discourse has emerged within the previous decade as a new academic paradigm and social movement, which not only questions business-as-usual notions of growth, but also strives to create alternative social imaginaries and to prefigure alternative economic systems, organizations and livelihoods that refute the reliance on growth. Accordingly, this entry aims to offer food for thought for scholars and practitioners alike, by elaborating on what can be described as initial key coordinates that may help to orient our thinking and practice towards organizing for degrowth. This entry should therefore be read as a plea and an opportunity for organization and management scholarship (OMS) generally, and CSR authors in particular, to take issues around growth seriously if they wish to ask the big questions and further a project that maintains a liveable planet for future generations.
... An example of this is the social enterprise Belu (see Box 13.1), which has stated that in order to minimise its carbon footprint, it will not export its products outside the country, making an active choice to grow less in order to remain sustainable (Belu, 2021). A degrowth economy would furthermore entail a radically hybrid form of enterprise, most likely a type of social enterprise or eco-social enterprise ( Johanisova et al., 2013;Johanisova and Fraňková, 2017). Yet others argue that the not-for-profit enterprise model is a necessary step towards sustainability (Hinton, 2021), challenging the way in which most business and a major share of hybrids operate today. ...
... An example of this is the social enterprise Belu (see Box 13.1), which has stated that in order to minimise its carbon footprint, it will not export its products outside the country, making an active choice to grow less in order to remain sustainable (Belu, 2021). A degrowth economy would furthermore entail a radically hybrid form of enterprise, most likely a type of social enterprise or eco-social enterprise ( Johanisova et al., 2013;Johanisova and Fraňková, 2017). Yet others argue that the not-for-profit enterprise model is a necessary step towards sustainability (Hinton, 2021), challenging the way in which most business and a major share of hybrids operate today. ...
... This concerns whether monetary values (such as income, profit, and gross domestic product) can directly deliver human wellbeing or if it contributes to meeting needs through Intermediate Ends, such as healthcare, education, food, and housing. Social ecological economic approaches favor positioning money as an Intermediate Means, rather than an end (Spash, 2017). 2 A few sustainable business scholars have also begun to consider whether profit should be treated as a means or an end in itself (e.g., Johanisova et al., 2013;Schaeffer et al., 2015), but it is unclear how profit-as-a-means can be implemented or evaluated. For the purposes of the analysis below, I use the simple accounting definition of profit as the financial surplus that remains from revenues after business expenses are covered (Boyte-White, 2018). ...
Research
Full-text available
This paper examines the implications of the argument that sustainable businesses should see profit as a means, not an end. It develops a heuristic conceptual framework that identifies two main ways in which a business can treat profit as an end: first, through voluntary objectives; and secondly, through private financial rights. To illustrate the usefulness of this framework, these indicators are applied to examine a range of theoretical approaches, incorporation structures, and third-party certifications that have been developed with the aim of making business sustainable. The application of the framework reveals inconsistencies, ambiguities, and shortfalls of these approaches in their treatment of profit, and outlines ways to advance the theory and practice of sustainable business.
Article
Full-text available
The aim of this extended review essay is to discuss the potential relevance of degrowth-aligned social-ecological transformation for the specific context of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE). We frame this discussion around three recent books which we consider especially useful for this debate: The Future is Degrowth by Schmelzer et al. (2022, in Czech 2023) for an up-to-date and comprehensive overview of the concept of degrowth; Marx in the Anthropocene by Saito (2023) for an ecologically grounded debate on anticapitalist strategies stemming from writings of late Marx; and The Political Economy of Middle Class Politics and the Global Crisis in Eastern Europe by Gagyi (2021) that empirically analyses the specific position of the CEE semiperiphery and its implications for a radical social-ecological transformation. We introduce and interlink the main ideas of these books and discuss their implications for the degrowth movement in the CEE context. We argue that to deeply transform our socio-metabolic relation with nature, it is crucial to cultivate and expand spaces of reproductive autonomy, and link them to struggles of labour and social movements. We conclude by emphasising the role of internationalism from below.
Article
Full-text available
Human–Computer Interaction (HCI) researchers have increasingly been questioning computing’s engagement with unsustainable and unjust economic growth, pushing for identifying alternatives. Incorporating degrowth, post-development, and steady-state approaches, post-growth philosophy offers an alternative not rooted in growth but in improving quality of life. It recommends an equitable reduction in resource use through sensible distributive practices where fulfillment is based on values including solidarity, cooperation, care, social justice, and localized development. In this paper, we describe opportunities for HCI to take a post-growth orientation in research, design, and practice to reimagine the design of sociotechnical systems toward advancing sustainable, just, and humane futures. We aim for the critiques, concerns, and recommendations offered by post-growth to be integrated into transformative HCI practices for technology-mediated change.
Article
Full-text available
This is a chapter (Local and Ethical Enteprise as an important part of a Sustainalbe Future, p. 253 - 261) in a book (Woltron, Klaus, Hermann Knoflacher, Agnieszka Rosik-Kolbl, eds., 2004: Wege in den Postkapitalismus, Edition Selene, Vienna). The book emerged from a symposium by the same name organised by the Club of Vienna in 2004. The chapter summarises some ideas on local and community enterprises and briefly discusses a Czech case-study of an eco-social enterprise in the Czech Republic. the Hostetin apple-juice plant Most of he other chapters are in Czech. Howevet, the book also contains chapters in English (eg by Richard Douthwaite and by Mathias Binswanger)
Book
This edited volume reports the findings of scholars from a dozen Central and Eastern European universities, who collaborated in the Public Economy and Public Sector group of UCEMET, an academic exchange network run jointly by the School of Business, Stockholm University and the Krakow Academy of Economics. This comparative study of social service reforms in post-Communist countries focuses on the initial phase of the transformation process. It documents how social policy needs were either met through emergency measures, adjustments within existing institutions or institutional building. CEE countries replaced an employment based, institutional welfare state that provided universal coverage with a residual social safety net system reserved for the ‘deserving poor’. The latter model was actively promoted by the IMF, World Bank and European Union and resulted initially in rapidly increasing levels of poverty. However, there was notable variation between the countries and social policy arenas. Three distinct patterns emerged at the sectoral or meso-level: incremental change in old-age security and family assistance, radical change in unemployment programs and rapid decline in healthcare and housing. This volume documents that these different trajectories depend on the prior existence of basic state institutions and whether the state withdrew for fiscal or ideological reasons.
Article
We humans live by stories, says David Korten, and the stories that now govern our society set us on a path to certain self-destruction. In this profound new book, Korten shares the results of his search for a story that reflects the fullness of human knowledge and understanding and provides a guide to action adequate to the needs of our time. Korten calls our current story Sacred Money and Markets. Money, it tells us, is the measure of all worth and the source of all happiness. Earth is simply a source of raw materials. Inequality and environmental destruction are unfortunate but unavoidable. Although many recognize that this story promotes bad ethics, bad science, and bad economics, it will remain our guiding story until replaced by one that aligns with our deepest understanding of the universe and our relationship to it. To guide our path to a viable human future, Korten offers a Sacred Life and Living Earth story grounded in a cosmology that affirms we are living beings born of a living Earth itself born of a living universe. Our health and well-being depend on an economy that works in partnership with the processes by which Earth's community of life maintains the conditions of its own existence - and ours. Offering a hopeful vision, Korten lays out the transformative impact adopting this story will have on every aspect of human life and society.
Article
The two schools of economic thought which have prevailed in the Latin American setting, neo-liberal monetarism and the more interventionist state-centered developmentalism promoted by the Economic Commission for Latin America, have not been able to satisfy the legitimate needs of the Latin American masses. A new perspective is called for which aims at an adequate satisfaction of human needs. Furthermore, if future development cannot be sustained through the expansion of exports or through substantial injection of foreign capital, an alternative development must generate a capacity for greater self-reliance. We are proposing an orientation which would enable us to create conditions for a new praxis based on Human Scale Development. Such development is focused and based on the satisfaction of fundamental human needs, on the generation of growing levels of self-reliance, and on the construction of organic articulations of people with nature and technology, of global processes with local activity, of the personal with the social, of planning with autonomy, and of civil society with the state. -from Author
Article
British rule and Indian responses critique of modern civilization Indian civilization and national regeneration metaphysics theory of morality Ahimsa Satyagraha theory of the state partition and the nationalist discourse a critical appreciation.