ArticlePDF Available

Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations

Authors:

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to investigate a novel approach to group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations, which can avoid information distortion and obtain more credible decision making results. An interval transform function is defined, which can transform an intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation into an interval multiplicative preference relation. Then, an interval transform function based data envelopment analysis model is developed to obtain the ranking vector of consistent intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation, in which each of the alternatives is viewed as a decision making unit. Moreover, for any intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations, we propose two DEA cross-efficiency models to get the cross-efficiency values of all alternatives, and we can calculate the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector of the intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation based on the cross-efficiency values. A goal programming model is investigated to derive the weight vector of decision makers. A step-by-step procedure for group decision making approach based on DEA cross-efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations is presented. Finally, numerical examples are given to illustrate the validity and applicability of the proposed method. This is the first attempt of employing the DEA cross-efficiency to the group decision making with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations.
Fuzzy Optimization and Decision Making
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10700-018-9297-0
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency
with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations
Jinpei Liu1,2 ·Jingmiao Song1·Qin Xu3·Zhifu Tao4·Huayou Chen5
© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018
Abstract
The aim of this paper is to investigate a novel approach to group decision making
based on DEA cross-efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations, which
can avoid information distortion and obtain more credible decision making results.
An interval transform function is defined, which can transform an intuitionistic fuzzy
preference relation into an interval multiplicative preference relation. Then, an inter-
val transform function based data envelopment analysis model is developed to obtain
the ranking vector of consistent intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation, in which each
of the alternatives is viewed as a decision making unit. Moreover, for any intuition-
istic fuzzy preference relations, we propose two DEA cross-efficiency models to get
the cross-efficiency values of all alternatives, and we can calculate the normalized
intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector of the intuitionistic fuzzy preference rela-
tion based on the cross-efficiency values. A goal programming model is investigated
to derive the weight vector of decision makers. A step-by-step procedure for group
decision making approach based on DEA cross-efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy
preference relations is presented. Finally, numerical examples are given to illustrate
the validity and applicability of the proposed method. This is the first attempt of
employing the DEA cross-efficiency to the group decision making with intuitionistic
fuzzy preference relations.
Keywords Group decision making ·Intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation ·DEA
cross-efficiency ·Interval transform function
1 Introduction
Group decision making can be simplified as a group of decision makers to make a
choice from a set of alternatives for action in accordance with the opinions provided
BJinpei Liu
liujinpei2012@163.com
Extended author information available on the last page of the article
123
J. Liu et al.
by the members. In group decision making process, the decision makers often need to
provide their preferences over a set of alternatives or criteria by pairwise comparison.
The analytic hierarchy process (AHP) furnishes a convenient framework to derive
multiplicative preference relations (MPRs), which uses a 1/9-9 ratio scale to measure
the intensity of the pairwise comparison (Saaty 1980). Besides, the 0–1 scale is adopted
by the fuzzy preference relation (Herrera-Viedma et al. 2004;Xu2007a) to express
the decision maker’s preference information.
However, in many real decision making environment, it is very difficult for the
decision makers to express their preferences using a single crisp value due to that (1)
the decision makers are lack of knowledge and information associated with the problem
(Xu and Cai 2010) and (2) the decision makers are not confident about their judgment,
i.e., there exists hesitation regarding their preferences (Wu et al. 2018). To circumvent
this issue, Atanassov’s intuitionistic fuzzy set (IFS) was introduced in Atanassov
(1986), which is an extension of Zadeh’s fuzzy set and uses membership degree,
non-membership degree and hesitation degree to express decision maker’s subjective
preference. This IFS provides a powerful framework, which can not only characterize
vagueness, uncertainty, but also represent inevitably imprecise or not totally reliable
judgments well. From then on, the IFSs have been proven to be very meaningful and
practical, and attached great importance by many scholars (Xu and Liao 2015).
Based on IFS, the intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation (IFPR) was defined in Xu
(2007b), which is more powerful and useful than multiplicative preference relation
and the fuzzy preference relation. Xu (2007b) firstly defined the concepts of con-
sistent IFPR, incomplete IFPR and acceptable IFPR. How to derive priority vector
from the fuzzy preference relation has become a hot issue of study. Since then, many
prioritization methods for IFPRs have been developed. Wang (2013) proposed a lin-
ear goal programming model for deriving intuitionistic fuzzy weights from IFPR by
minimizing its deviation from the converted additive consistent IFPR. Besides, a con-
vergent iterative algorithm to improve the consistency of IFPR was developed by Xu
and Xia (2014). Liao et al. (2015) and Meng et al. (2017) introduced two consistency
adjustment methods to yield the acceptable consistent IFPRs respectively. However,
these methods of deriving consistent IFPRs have changed the original evaluation infor-
mation given by the decision makers, which may distort the given decision making
information and make the decision result less reliable.
In addition, Ramanathan (2006) introduced the data envelopment analytic hierarchy
process (DEAHP) model for weight derivation from multiplicative preference relation,
but the DEAHP model is not applicable for some inconsistent MPRs. Then, Wang
et al. (2008) proposed the DEA/AR model, which can overcome the shortcoming of
the DEAHP model. Furthermore, Liu et al. (2017) developed a novel output-oriented
data envelopment analysis (DEA) model to obtain the priority vector for the consistent
fuzzy preference relation. The existing research shows that the DEA cross-efficiency
can overcome the problem of extreme weights and incomplete ranking in traditional
DEA by mutual evaluation of decision making units (DMUs) (Liang et al. 2008). In
fact, an interesting and important issue to be solved is how to develop a DEA cross-
efficiency model to derive the priority weight vector from IFPR, which does not require
repairing the IFPR. Up to now, there has been no investigation about this issue.
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
Recently, Wu et al. (2018) developed the definition of the multiplicative transitivity
of IFPR, and discovered the substantial relationship between interval-valued fuzzy
preference relation and IFPR. Another interesting issue is to discover the substantial
relationship between IFPR and interval multiplicative preference relations (IMPRs).
In this paper, we will propose a new approach to group decision making with IFPRs
based on DEA cross-efficiency, which can avoid information distortion and obtain
more credible decision making result. An interval transform function is defined to
establish the substantial relationship between IFPR and IMPR. Based on the interval
transform function, we develop two DEA cross-efficiency models to get the peer-
evaluation cross-efficiency values of all alternatives, in which each of the alternatives
is viewed as a decision making unit. Then, the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight
vector for the IFPR is derived based on the cross-efficiency values. Furthermore, a
goal programming model is investigated to yield the weights of decision makers.
Finally, a novel approach to group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency
with IFPRs is proposed, which does not need consistency adjustments and can yield a
normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight vector. In particular, when the IFPRs given by
the experts have a poor consistency, our method has better applicability and can derive
more reasonable ranking result than some known methods. This is the first attempt of
employing the theory of DEA cross-efficiency for the ranking of preference relations.
Hopefully, the proposed work is not only a generalization of existing theory but also
an initial step for the development of group decision making based on DEA cross-
efficiency.
The paper is organized as follows. Some basic concepts are introduced in Sect. 2,
such as the multiplicative preference relation, interval multiplicative preference rela-
tion, the intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation and the consistency of MPR, IMPR
and IFPR. In Sect. 3, we define the interval transform function, develop two DEA
cross-efficiency models to get the peer-evaluation cross-efficiency values of all alter-
natives and propose the deriving method of the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight
vector based on cross-efficiency values. In Sect. 4, a goal programming model is inves-
tigated to yield the weights of decision makers and a step-by-step procedure for group
decision making approach is presented. There are numerical examples and compar-
ison analysis in Sect. 5to illustrate the advantages, validity and applicability of the
proposed methods. Finally, Sect. 6concludes the paper, and discusses some future
research directions.
2 Preliminaries
In this section, we provide a brief review on some basic concepts, including multiplica-
tive preference relation (MPR), interval multiplicative preference relation (IMPR), the
intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation (IFPR) and the consistency of MPR, IMPR and
IFPR.
For a decision making problem, it is assumed that X{x1,x2,...,xn}is a finite set
of alternatives. In the process of decision making, the decision maker usually provides
pairwise judgments on any two alternatives over the set X.
123
J. Liu et al.
Definition 1 (Saaty 1980) A reciprocal multiplicative preference relation Ron Xis
characterized by a matrix R(rij)n×nX×Xwith
rij ·rji 1,rij 0,rii 1,i,j1,2,...,n,
where rij is interpreted as the ratio of the preference intensity of alternative xito that
of xj.
The reciprocal multiplicative preference relation is also called the multiplicative
preference relation. And the consistency of MPR has been proposed by Saaty (1977)
as follows:
Definition 2 (Saaty 1977)AMPR R(rij)n×nis consistent if
rik ·rkj rij,i,j,k1,2,...,n.(1)
For a MPR R(rij)n×n, and w(w1,w
2,···,w
n)Tis a normalized priority
weight vector of R, then Ris consistent if and only if
rij wiwj,i,j1,2,...,n,(2)
where wi>0, i1,2,···,n, and n
i1wi1.
In order to express the decision makers’ uncertain preferences, Saaty and Vargas
(1987) introduced the definition of interval multiplicative preference relation.
Definition 3 (Saaty and Vargas 1987; Xia and Chen 2015)AnIMPR ˜
Ris defined as
follows:
˜
R(˜rij)n×n
[1,1] [r
12,r+
12]··· [r
1n,r+
1n]
[r
21,r+
21][1,1] ··· [r
2n,r+
2n]
··· ··· ··· ···
[r
n1,r+
n1][r
n2,r+
n2]··· [1,1]
,
where r
ij,r+
ij >0, such that r
ij r+
ij,r
ijr+
ji 1 and r+
ijr
ji 1, i,j1,2,...,n.
When r
ij r+
ij for all i,j1,2,...,n,˜
Rdegenerates to a MPR.
The consistency of IMPR was defined as follows.
Definition 4 (Wang 2015)AnIMPR ˜
R(˜rij)n×nwith ˜rij [r
ij,r+
ij](i,j
1,2,...,n) is consistent if it satisfies the following transitivity condition:
r
ikr+
ikr
kjr+
kj r
ijr+
ij,i,j,k1,2,...,n.(3)
According to Definition 4, it is evident that IMPR ˜
R(˜rij)n×nwith ˜rij [r
ij,r+
ij]
(i,j1,2,...,n) is consistent if and only if
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
ρ(˜rik)ρ(˜rkj)ρ(˜rij),i,j,k1,2,...,n,(4)
where ρ(˜rij)r
ij ·r+
ij.
In 1986, intuitionistic fuzzy set was introduced by Atanassov (1986), which was
defined as follows.
Definition 5 (Atanassov 1986)Let X{x1,x2,...,xn}be an ordinary finite non-
empty set. An IFS ˜
Aover Xis represented as ˜
A{<x˜
A(x)˜
A(x)>|xX},
where μ˜
A:X[0,1], ν˜
A:X[0,1] and μ˜
A(x)+ν˜
A(x)1, for all xX.
The numbers μ˜
A(x) and ν˜
A(x) represent the membership degree and non-membership
degree of the element xXto ˜
A, respectively. π˜
A(x)1μ˜
A(x)ν˜
A(x) is called
the hesitation degree of xto ˜
A. Obviously, 0 π˜
A(x)1 for all xX.Ifπ˜
A(x)0,
we have μ˜
A(x)+ν˜
A(x)1. Then, ˜
Ais degraded to an ordinary fuzzy set.
For convenience, αμα
αis called an intuitionistic fuzzy value (IFV) (Saaty
1977), where μα
α[0,1] and μα+να1.
Definition 6 (Meng et al. 2017)Letαμα
αbe an IFV, then the score function
and accuracy function of αare defined by S(α)uαvαand H(α)uα+vα,
respectively. Suppose α1and α2are two IFVs, then
(1) If S(α1)>S(α2), then α1is larger than α2, denoted by α1
2;
(2) If S(α1)S(α2), then
(a) If H(α1)>H(α2), then α1
2;
(b) If H(α1)H(α2), then α1α2, which means that α1is equal to α2.
BasedonIFV,Xu(2007b) gave a standard definition of intuitionistic fuzzy prefer-
ence relation, which is shown as follows:
Definition 7 (Xu 2007b) An IFPR over a finite set of alternatives X
{x1,x2,...,xn}is represented by a matrix ˜
P(˜pij)n×n, where ˜pij <
(xi,xj)(xi,xj)(xi,xj)(xi,xj)>for all i,j1,2,...,n. For convenience,
let ˜pij μij
ijbe an IFV, where μij defines the certainty degree that the
alternative xiis preferred to xj,νij indicates the certainty degree that the alter-
native xiis non-preferred to xjand 0 μij
ij 1, 0 μij +νij 1,
μij νji,μji νij,μii νii 0.5 for all i,j1,2,···,n.
Definition 8 (Wu et al. 2018) An IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×nwith ˜pij μij
ij
(i,j1,2,...,n) is multiplicative consistent (multiplicative transitive) if and only
if i,j,k1,2,...,n:
μijμjkμki μikμkjμji ,
(1 νij)(1 νjk)(1 νki )(1 νik)(1 νkj)(1 νji).
Definition 9 (Wang 2013) An intuitionistic fuzzy weight vector ˜w
(˜w1,˜w2,···,˜wn)Twith ˜wiwμ
i,w
ν
iT,0 wμ
i,w
v
i1 and wμ
i+wν
i1
for i1,2,...,nis said to be normalized if it satisfies the following conditions:
123
J. Liu et al.
n
j1,ji
wμ
jwν
i,w
μ
i+n2
n
j1,ji
wν
j,i1,2,...,n.
3 Deriving priority vector of IFPR based on DEA cross-efficiency
In this section, we investigate a new approach of deriving the normalized intuition-
istic fuzzy priority weight vector from IFPR based on DEA cross-efficiency. Unless
otherwise mentioned, it is assumed that Ωis the set of interval values and Ψis the set
of intuitionistic fuzzy values (IFVs).
3.1 Interval transform function of IFPR
In order to extract effective information of the intuitionistic fuzzy value sufficiently, we
propose the definition of interval transform function, which can be defined as follows.
Definition 10 Let αμα
αbe an IFV with μα
α>0. Then, an interval trans-
form function of IFV is a mapping τ:Ψ+Ω+, such that
τ(α)τ(μα
α)μα
1μα
,1να
να,(5)
where Ψ+{
μα
α|μα>0
α>0
α+να1}is the set of IFVs, in which
both the membership degree and the non-membership degree of IFVs are all positive.
The interval transform function defined by Definition 10 can transform an IFV into
an interval value. Then, we show a characterized theorem for the interval transform
function.
Theorem 1 Let ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nbe an IFPR and μij
ij >0.
(1) ˜
H[h
ij,h+
ij]n×nτ(˜pij)n×nis an IMPR.
(2) If ˜
P is multiplicative consistent, then ˜
H[h
ij,h+
ij]n×nτ(˜pij)n×nis a
consistent IMPR.
Proof Let ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nbe an IFPR, μij
ij >0 and ˜
H
τ(˜pij)n×n. From Definition 10,wehave[h
ij,h+
ij]τ(˜pij)[μij
1μij ,1νij
νij ]. Since
μij
ij >0, μij +νij 1, μij νji,μji νij and μii νii 0.5 for all
i,j1,2,...,n,wehaveh
ij μij
1μij ,h+
ij 1νij
νij >0, 1 μij νij and
1νij μij. Thus, h
ij μij
1μij 1νij
νij h+
ij,
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
h
ijh+
ji μij
1μij
·1νji
νji
μij
1μij
·1μij
μij
1,
h
jih+
ij μji
1μji
·1νij
νij
μji
1μji
·1μji
μji
1,(6)
and
h
ii ,h+
iiτ(˜pii )μii
1μii
,1νii
νii 0.5
10.5,10.5
0.5[1,1].(7)
According to Eqs. (6), (7) and Definition 3, it is obvious that ˜
H[h
ij,h+
ij]n×n
is an IMPR.
If ˜
Pis multiplicative consistent, from Definition 8,wehave
μijμjkμki μikμkj μji
(1 νij)(1 νjk)(1 νki )(1 νik)(1 νkj )(1 νji)for all i,k,j1,2,...,n.
(8)
Thus, one can obtain
μijμjkμki (1 νij)(1 νjk)(1 νki)μikμkjμji(1 νik)(1 νkj )(1 νji).
(9)
Equation (9) can be rewritten as
μik
1νki
·1νik
μki
·μkj
1νjk
·1νkj
μjk
μij
1νji
·1νij
μji
.(10)
By Eq. (10), it is obvious that
h
ik ·h+
ik ·h
kj ·h+
kj h
ijh+
ij,i,k,j1,2,...,n.(11)
According to Definition 4,˜
Hτ(˜pij)n×nis a consistent IMPR.
Theorem 1shows that the interval transform function can not only transform the
IFPR into IMPR, but also ensure the consistency of preference relation.
3.2 DEA model of IFPR
DEA is a powerful tool to evaluate the relative efficiency of a set of homogenous deci-
sion making units (DMUs) with multiple inputs and multiple outputs by establishing
a nonparametric linear programming model. In this section, we propose a DEA model
to evaluate the relative efficiency of each alternative from IFPR.
In decision making process, decision maker offers an IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×n
μij
ijn×nover the alternative set X{x1,x2,...,xn}, where μij
ij >0.
Each alternative xican be viewed as an independent DMU, i1,2,...,n. When the
123
J. Liu et al.
Table 1 Inputs and outputs of DEA based on ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×n
Output 1 Output 2 ··· Output nDummy
input
x1DMU1τ(˜p11 )τ(˜p12 ) ··· τ(˜p1n)τ(˜p0)
x2DMU2τ(˜p21 )τ(˜p22 ) ··· τ(˜p2n)τ(˜p0)
··· ··· ··· ··· ··· ··· ···
xnDMUnτ(˜pn1)τ(˜pn2) ··· τ(˜pnn )τ(˜p0)
decision maker believes that alternative xiis better than xj, for any k∈{1,2,...,n},
the certainty degree that the alternative xiis preferred to xkis greater than the certainty
degree that the alternative xjis preferred to xk, i.e., μik μjk, and certainty degree
that the alternative xiis non-preferred to xkis smaller than the certainty degree that the
alternative xjis non-preferred to xk, i.e., νik νjk.Thus,wehave ˜pik μik
ik
˜pjk μjkjk. Furthermore, since μik
1μik μjk
1μjk and 1νik
νik 1νjk
νjk , one can
obtain τ(˜pik)τ(˜pjk). Hence, each row of the IFPR corresponds to a DMU, and
each column of the IFPR can be viewed as an output. Since DEA calculations cannot be
made without inputs, to ensure the fairness of decision making, each decision making
unit is given the same intuitionistic fuzzy input variable ˜p00.5,0.5. Then, the
relationships between inputs, outputs and IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nare
shown in Table 1.
Based on above analysis and the interval transform function τgiven by Defini-
tion 10, we can develop an output-oriented CCR DEA model to evaluate the relative
efficiency of alternative xk(k1,2,···,n) as follows:
Max
μ,φ φk
s.t.
n
i1μiτ(˜pij)φkτ(˜pkj),j1,2,...,n,
n
i1μiτ(˜p0)τ(˜p0),
μi0,i1,2,...,n.
(12)
For an IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nwith μij
ij >0, if μij+νij1, then
μij
1μij 1νij
νij . It follows that τ(˜pij)[h
ij,h+
ij][μij
1μij ,1νij
νij ] degenerates to a real
number. Denoting hij h
ij h+
ij μij
1μij 1νij
νij ,˜
Hτ(˜pij)n×ndegenerates to
aMPRH(hij)n×n. Based on Model (12), we have the following Theorem.
Theorem 2 Let ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nbe a multiplicative consistent IFPR
with μij
ij >0, μij+νij1, and φ
kbe the optimal objective function value of
Model (12). Then, the normalized priority vector of ˜
Hτ(˜pij)n×ncan be derived
by
wk(φ
k)1n
l1
(φ
l)1,k1,2,...,n.(13)
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
Proof Let ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nbe a multiplicative consistent IFPR
with μij
ij >0, μij+νij1. According to Theorem 1,˜
H[h
ij,h+
ij]n×n
τ(˜pij)n×nis a consistent IMPR. Then, we have
h
ijh+
ji 1,h
ikh+
ikh
kjh+
kj h
ijh+
ij,i,j,k1,2,...,n.(14)
Denoting hij h
ij h+
ij μij
1μij 1νij
νij ,fromEq.(14), one can obtain
hijhji 1,hikhkj hij,i,j,k1,2,...,n.
Consequently, ˜
Hτ(˜pij)n×ndegenerates to consistent MPR H(hij)n×n,
where hij τ(˜pij). According to Eq. (2), the priority weight vector of ˜
H
τ(˜pij)n×nsatisfies
hij τ(˜pij)wiwj,i,j1,2,...,n.(15)
From Eq. (15), Model (12) can be rewritten as
Max
μ,φ φk
s.t.
n
i1μiwi/wkφk,j1,2,...,n,
n
i1μi1,
μi0,i1,2,...,n.
(16)
Without loss of generality, it is assumed that w1w2≤ ··· ≤ wn. The objective
function φkis maximal if and only if the constraint n
i1μi1 reduces to equality,
i.e., n
i1μi1.
For any k∈{1,2,···,n},byμk1μ1−··· μk1μk+1 ···− μn,the
first constraint of Model (16) becomes
1+
n
ik,i1
μiwiwk1φk.(17)
Because w1wk1w2wk1≤ ··· ≤ wnwk1, it follows that φkis
maximal if and only if μ1μ2 ···  μn10, μn1. Thus, the optimal
objective function value of Model (12)isφ
kwnwk.
Furthermore, since wi>0, i1,2,...,n, and n
i1wi1, we have wk
(φ
k)1n
l1(φ
l)1,k1,2,...,n.
In fact, Theorem 1provides a method of deriving the priority weight vector of
consistent IFPR using the proposed DEA model. However, when μij+νij  1, this
method is not applicable. In order to solving this problem, based on interval aggregation
function ρ, we propose the following CCR DEA model:
123
J. Liu et al.
Max
μ,φ φk
s.t.
n
i1μiρτ(˜pij)φkρτ(˜pkj),j1,2,...,n,
n
i1μiρ(τ(˜p0))ρ(τ(˜p0)),
μi0,i1,2,...,n.
(18)
where τ(˜pij)[h
ij,h+
ij][μij
1μij ,1νij
νij ] and ρτ(˜pij)h
ij ·h+
ijμij(1νij)
νij(1μij).
In case of ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nbeing a multiplicative consistent IFPR,
according to Theorem 1, it is evident that ˜
H[h
ij,h+
ij]n×nτ(˜pij)n×nis a
consistent IMPR. Moreover, by Eq. (4), we have ρ(τ(˜pik)) ·ρ(τ(˜pkj)) ρ(τ(˜pij)),
i,j,k1,2,...,n, which implies that ˆ
Hρ(τ(˜pij))n×nis a consistent MPR.
According to the proof of Theorem 2, we have the following proposition.
Proposition 1 Let ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nbe a multiplicative consistent IFPR
with μij
ij >0and φ
kbe the optimal objective function value of Model (18). Then,
the priority weight vector of ˆ
Hρ(τ(˜pij))n×ncan be derived by
wk(φ
k)1n
l1
(φ
l)1,k1,2,...,n.(19)
For any multiplicative consistent IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×nover the
alternative set X{x1,x2,...,xn}, the inverse of optimal objective function value of
model (18), (φ
k)1, is the efficiency score of alternative xk,k1,2,...,n. Moreover,
the corresponding priority weight vector of ˜
Pcan be derived by Proposition 1.
3.3 Deriving the intuitionistic fuzzy weights based on DEA cross-efficiency
It is worth noting that deriving priority weight vector based Model (18) is not applicable
for inconsistent IFPR. To resolve this problem, we will develop a new method of
deriving the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector from an IFPR based
on DEA cross-efficiency. The cross-efficiency DEA uses the DMUs to evaluate each
other, and the final efficiency evaluation value of the DMU is obtained from the self-
evaluation and the peer-evaluation (Liang et al. 2008).
Based on Table 1and interval aggregation function ρ, the input-oriented CCR DEA
model is formulated as the following linear programming:
Max αkk
n
r1
ωrkρ(τ(˜pkr ))
s.t.
n
r1ωrkρτ(˜pjr)ηkρ(τ(˜p0))0,j1,2,...,n,
ηkρ(τ(˜p0))1,
ωrk
k0,k1,2,...,n.
(20)
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
For each alternative xk(k1,2,...,n) under evaluation, we can obtain
the optimal objective value (efficiency value) α
kk and a set of optimal weights
η
k
1k
2k,...,ω
nk associated with inputs and outputs.
Note that the optimal weights obtained from Model (20) may not be unique. Inspired
by the benevolent DEA cross-efficiency model and aggressive DEA cross-efficiency
model (Doyle and Green 1994), we propose two new DEA cross-efficiency models
for IFPR. Since τ(˜pij)[h
ij,h+
ij][μij
1μij ,1νij
νij ] and τ(˜p0)1, we construct
the following two mathematical programming model for each alternative xk(k
1,2,···,n).
Max
n
j1
n
r1
urkh
jr
s.t.
vk·n1,
n
r1urkh+
kr α
kkvk0,
n
r1urkh+
kr vk0,j1,2,...,n;j k,
vk,urk 0,k1,2,...,n.
(21)
Min
n
j1
n
r1
urkh
jr
s.t.
vk·n1,
n
r1urkh+
kr α
kkvk0,
n
r1urkh+
kr vk0,j1,2,...,n;j k,
vk,urk 0,k1,2,...,n.
(22)
In Models (21) and (22), α
kk is the target efficiency of alternative xk, which is
obtained from Model (20). As can be seen, Model (21) aims to maximize the lower
bound of overall cross-efficiency values of all alternatives and Model (22)aimsto
minimize the lower bound of overall cross-efficiency values of all alternatives. The
second equality constraint of Models (21) and (22), n
r1urkh+
kr α
kkvk0, is used
to ensure that the upper bound efficiency value of alternative xkis equal to its optimal
efficiency α
kk, i.e., n
r1urkh+
kr vkα
kk.
By solving Models (21) and (22), we can obtain the optimal weights u
(u
1k,u
2k,...,u
nk)Tand v
k, which are the associated output weights and input weight.
Thus, the cross-efficiency of alternative xj(j1,2,...,n) using the optimal weights
of alternative xk(k1,2,...,n) can be calculated as in Eq. (23),
θ
jk
n
r1
u
rkh
jrv
kand θ+
jk
n
r1
u
rkh+
jrv
k,j1,2,...,n,(23)
where θ
jk and θ+
jk are the lower bound and upper bound of the cross-efficiency,
respectively. Therefore, we get an interval cross-efficiency value of alternative xj,
i.e., ˜
θjk [θ
jk+
jk], which represents the peer-evaluation of alternative xkto alter-
native xj.
123
J. Liu et al.
In Models (21) and (22), while alternative xk(k1,2,...,n) is changed, one can
get the interval cross-efficiency matrix, namely,
Θ(˜
θjk)n×n
[θ
11+
11][θ
12+
12]··· [θ
1n+
1n]
[θ
21+
21][θ
22+
22]··· [θ
2n+
2n]
··· ··· ··· ···
[θ
n1+
n1][θ
n2+
n2]··· [θ
nn+
nn]
.
Furthermore, we aggregate the cross-efficiency values of alternative xj(j
1,2,...,n) based on Eq. (24), and obtain the average cross-efficiency value ˜
θj.
˜
θjθ
j+
j1
n
n
k1
θ
jk,1
n
n
k1
θ+
jk ,j1,2,...,n.(24)
Based on the average cross-efficiency values of all alternatives, we can calculate
the intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector ˜w(˜w1,˜w2,..., ˜wn)Twith ˜wj
!wμ
j,w
ν
j"(j1,2,...,n), based on the following formulas:
wμ
jθ
j
ψ,w
ν
j1
ψ
n
r1,r j
θ+
r,j1,2,...,n,(25)
where ψn
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$.
It is worth noting that the intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector obtained from
Eq. (25) satisfies the following theorem.
Theorem 3 For any IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×n, its intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector
˜w(˜w1,˜w2,..., ˜wn)T,which is obtained from Eq. (25), is normalized.
Proof According to Formula (25), since 0 θ
jθ+
j1, it follows that wμ
j,
wν
i[0,1] and
wμ
j+wν
jθ
j+n
r1,r jθ+
r
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$θ
j+n
r1,r jθ+
r
n
r1θ+
r
1.
Note that n
i1,i jθ
i
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$n
r1,r jθ+
r
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$,wehave
n
i1,i jwμ
iwν
j.
For any j1,2,...,n,wehave
wμ
j+n2
θ
j+(n2) n
r1θ+
r+max
k#θ+
kθ
k$
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$,
and
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
n
i1,i j
wν
in
i1,i jn
r1,riθ+
r
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$(n1) n
r1θ+
rn
i jθ+
i
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$.
Thus, on can get
wμ
j+n2
n
i1,i j
wν
i
max
k#θ+
kθ
k$(θ+
jθ
j)
n
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$0.
The Proof is completed.
Based on the afore-mentioned discussion, we have the ranking method of IFPR
˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×n, which involves the following steps:
Step 1 For IFPR ˜
P(˜pij)n×nμij
ijn×n, use Model (20) to obtain α
kk,
k1,2,···,n.
Step 2 Set α
kk in the DEA cross-efficiency Models (21)or(22), and solve the
Model (21) or Model (22) to obtain the optimal solutions u
1k,u
2k,...,u
nk,v
k,
k1,2,...,n.
Step 3 Use Formula (23) to compute the lower bound and upper bound of the
cross-efficiency, then get the interval cross-efficiency matrix Θ(˜
θjk)n×n, where
˜
θjk [θ
jk+
jk], j,k1,2,...,n.
Step 4 Calculate the average cross-efficiency value ˜
θj[θ
j+
j] of alternative xj
based on formula (24), j1,2,...,n.
Step 5 Calculate the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector ˜w
(˜w1,˜w2,..., ˜wn)Tby using formula (25), where ˜wiwμ
i,w
ν
i.
Step 6 Rank the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weights ˜wjin descending
order, j1,2,...,n.
Step 7 Rank the alternatives xj(j1,2,...,n) according to the ranking of
˜wj,j1,2,···,n.
Step 8 End.
Example 1 Consider the alternative set X{x1,x2,x3,x4}, and the IFPR ˜
Pgiven by
the decision maker is as follows.
˜
P
0.5,0.5
0.6,0.2
0.8,0.2
0.6,0.3
0.2,0.6
0.5,0.5
0.5,0.3
0.3,0.5
0.2,0.8
0.3,0.5
0.5,0.5
0.3,0.6
0.3,0.6
0.5,0.3
0.6,0.3
0.5,0.5
Step 1 According to Model (20), we can get the relative efficiency value of xk,
k1,2,3,4, i.e.,
α
11 1
22 0.4082
33 0.2857
44 0.6236.
123
J. Liu et al.
Step 2 Set α
kk in the cross-efficiency DEA Model (21), and solve the Model (21)
to obtain the optimal solutions.
u
11 0.2500,u
21 0.0000,u
31 0.0000,u
41 0.0000,v
10.2500;
u
12 0.0000,u
22 0.0328,u
32 0.0297,u
42 0.0000,v
20.2500;
u
13 0.0000,u
23 0.0000,u
33 0.0000,u
43 0.1071,v
30.2500;
u
14 0.1208,u
24 0.0000,u
34 0.0323,u
44 0.0000,v
40.2500.
Step 3 Based on formula (23), we get the interval cross-efficiency matrix
Θ
[1.0000,1.0000] [0.6717,1.0000] [0.6429,1.0000] [1.0000,1.0000]
[0.2500,0.6667] [0.2500,0.4082] [0.1837,0.4286] [0.2500,0.6236]
[0.2500,0.2500] [0.1750,0.2500] [0.1837,0.2857] [0.2500,0.2500]
[0.4286,0.6667] [0.3093,0.5833] [0.4286,0.4286] [0.4009,0.6236]
.
Step 4 From Θ, we can get the average cross-efficiency value of each alternative
respectively based on Formula (24), i.e.,
˜
θ1[0.8286,1.0000],˜
θ2[0.2334,0.5318],
˜
θ3[0.2147,0.2589],˜
θ4[0.3918,0.5755].
Step 5 According to Formula (25), we get the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority
weight vector, i.e.,
˜w(0.3294,0.5431,0.0928,0.7293,0.0853,0.8378,0.1558,0.7119)T.
Step 6 Based on Definition 6, we can get the ranking of normalized intuitionistic
fuzzy priority weight vector, which is as follows:
˜w1>˜w4>˜w2>˜w3.
Step 7 Thus, the rank of the alternatives xjaccording to the ranking of ˜wj(j
1,2,3,4) is as follows:
x1>x4>x2>x3.
Similarly, if we use Model (22) instead of Model (21) in Step 2, we can get
Θ
[0.3750,1.0000] [0.6124,0.6124] [0.6429,1.0000] [0.6771,1.0000]
[0.2500,0.2500] [0.1531,0.4082] [0.1837,0.4286] [0.2500,0.4514]
[0.1071,0.2500] [0.1531,0.1531] [0.1837,0.2857] [0.1762,0.2500]
[0.2500,0.5833] [0.2624,0.4082] [0.4286,0.4286] [0.3363,0.6236]
,
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
Moreover, we have the average cross-efficiency value of four alternatives
˜
θ1[0.5768,0.9031],˜
θ2[0.2092,0.3846],
˜
θ3[0.1550,0.2347],˜
θ4[0.3193,0.5109].
Further, we can get
˜w(0.2626,0.5146,0.0952,0.7506,0.0706,0.8189,0.1454,0.6931)T.
It can be seen that we have the same ranking result of the derived intuitionistic
fuzzy priority weights, which is ˜w1>˜w4>˜w2>˜w3.
In a comparison of our method with some existing ranking methods of IFPR, our
proposed method has the following advantages.
First, the given IFPRs need an inconsistency repairing process to yield the accept-
able consistent IFPRs in Xu and Xia (2014), Liao et al. (2015) and Meng et al. (2017).
The inconsistency repairing have changed the original evaluation information given
by the decision maker, which can distort the given decision making information and
make the decision result less reliable. As to our ranking method, it is based entirely
on the original preference information given by decision maker and does not require
the consistency adjustment, so the result is more credible.
Second, in Wu et al. (2018), Liao and Xu (2014) and Wang (2013), it is assumed that
there exist specific relationships between the priority weight vector and the consistent
IFPRs. Then, the optimization models are established based on these assumptions to
get the priority weight vector. Since these assumptions are based on consistent IFPR,
the obtained priority weight vectors are always unreasonable for some inconsistent
IFPRs. Besides, these assumptions are not unique. By contrast, our approach does
not need to make any assumptions in advance, so it can avoid the risk of assumption
dependent.
Third, in our ranking method, the DEA cross-efficiency models combine the results
of self-evaluation and peer-evaluation to get the final efficiency value of each alterna-
tive, which makes the ranking result fairer.
4 Group decision making with intuitionistic fuzzy preference
relations
Let D{d1,d2,...,dm}be the set of decision makers and X{x1,x2,...,xn}
be the set of alternatives. Suppose that dlprovides his/her preference on X
{x1,x2,...,xn}using IFPR ˜
P(l)(˜p(l)
ij )n×n!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×n,l1,2,...,m,
and λ(λ1
2,...,λ
m)Tis the weight vector of decision makers satisfying λl0
and m
l1λl1, in which λlcan reflect the importance degree of dl.
In order to measure the similarity between two IFPRs, the definition of compatibility
degree was introduced by Xu (2013) as follows.
123
J. Liu et al.
Definition 11 Let ˜
P(l)!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×nand ˜
P(k)!μ(k)
ij (k)
ij "n×nbe two
IFPRs, given by two decision makers dland dk,k,l1,2,...,m. Then, we call
c(˜
P(k),˜
P(l))n
i1n
j1μ(k)
ij μ(l)
ij +v(k)
ij v(l)
ij
max%n
i1n
j1[(μ(k)
ij )2+(ν(k)
ij )2],n
i1n
j1[(μ(l)
ij )2+(ν(l)
ij )2]&
the compatibility degree of ˜
P(l)and ˜
P(k).
It can be seen easily that the greater the value of c(˜
P(k),˜
P(l)), the nearer the
two IFPRs ˜
P(k)and ˜
P(l)will be. Moreover, we have 0 c(˜
P(k),˜
P(l))1, and
c(˜
P(k),˜
P(l))1 if and only if ˜
P(k)˜
P(l), which means that ˜
P(l)and ˜
P(k)are
perfectly compatible.
Besides, based on the proposed interval transform function τ,˜
P(l)(˜p(l)
ij )n×n
!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×ncan be transformed into IMPR ˜
H(l)[h(l),
ij ,h(l),+
ij ]n×n, where
τ(˜p(l)
ij )h(l),
ij ,h(l),+
ij μ(l)
ij
1μ(l)
ij
,1ν(l)
ij
ν(l)
ij ,l1,2,...,m,i,j1,2,...,n.
(26)
Then, the IFPRs provided by mdecision makers can be aggregated into a synthetic
interval preference relation Hs[hs,
ij ,hs,+
ij ]n×n, where
hs,
ij
m
'
l1h(l),
ij λland hs,+
ij
m
'
l1h(l),+
ij λl,i,j1,2,...,n.(27)
It is evident that Hsis an IMPR. Note that the closer Hsand each of ˜
H(l)(l
1,2,...,m), the more representative the synthetic preference relation Hsis. Thus,
we develop the following goal programming to obtain the weight vector of decision
makers.
Min J
n
i1
n
ji+1
m
l1ε(l),+
ij +ε(l),
ij +γ(l),+
ij +γ(l),
ij
s.t.
ln h(l),
ij m
l1λlln h(l),
ij ε(l),+
ij +ε(l),
ij 0,i<j,i,j1,2,...n,l1,2,...,m,
ln h(l),+
ij m
l1λlln h(l),+
ij γ(l),+
ij +γ(l),
ij 0,i<j,i,j1,2,...n,l1,2,...,m,
m
l1λl1,
λl
(l),+
ij
(l),
ij (l),+
ij (l),
ij 0,i<j,i,j1,2,...n,l1,2,...,m.
(28)
As can be seen, the objective function J, which reflects group consensus, can
measure the agreement between the individual preference relations and the synthetic
preference relation. Especially, when all ˜
P(l)(1,2,...,m) are perfectly compatible,
the following result holds:
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
Theorem 4 For any l,k∈{1,2,...,m},c(˜
P(l),˜
P(k))1if and only if J 0,
where J is the optimal objective function value of Model (28).
Proof (Sufficiency) If c(˜
P(l),˜
P(k))1 for any l,k∈{1,2,...,m}, then ˜
P(1)
˜
P(2)  ···  ˜
P(m). According to Eq. (26), we have h(1),
ij h(2),
ij  ···  h(m),
ij
and h(1),+
ij h(2),+
ij  ···  h(m),+
ij ,i,j1,2,...n. Thus, all deviation variables
ε(l),+
ij ,ε(l),
ij ,γ(l),+
ij and γ(l),
ij are equal to 0 in Model (28), and therefore J0.
(Necessity) If J0, then it is evident that h(1),
ij h(2),
ij  ···  h(m),
ij and
h(1),+
ij h(2),+
ij  ···  h(m),+
ij ,i,j1,2,···n. Based on Eq. (26), we have ˜
P(1)
˜
P(2) ···˜
P(m). Thus c(˜
P(l),˜
P(k))1 holds for any l,k∈{1,2,...,m}.
In conclusion, the process of group decision making method based on DEA cross-
efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations can be summarized as follows:
Step 1 Use interval transform function τto translate ˜
P(l)(˜p(l)
ij )n×n
!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×ninto ˜
H(l)[h(l),
ij ,h(l),+
ij ]n×nbased on Eq. (26), l
1,2,...,m;
Step 2 Solve Model (28) to get the optimal weight vector λ(λ1
2,...,λ
m)T
of decision makers;
Step 3 Aggregate ˜
H(l)[h(l),
ij ,h(l),+
ij ]n×ninto the synthetic preference relation
Hs[hs,
ij ,hs,+
ij ]n×nbased on Eq. (27);
Step 4 For multiplicative preference relation Hs[hs,
ij ,hs,+
ij ], obtain the nor-
malized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector ˜(˜1,˜2,..., ˜n)Tbased
on the ranking method of IFPR in Sect. 3.3, where ˜iμ
i,ν
i,i1,2,...,n;
Step 5 Rank the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weights ˜iin the descend-
ing order based on Definition 6,i1,2,...,n.
Step 6 Rank the alternatives xi(i1,2,...,n) according to the ranking of ˜i,
i1,2,···,n.
Step 7 End.
Let ˜
P(l)(˜p(l)
ij )n×n!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×n(l1,2,...,m)bemIFPRs, which are
given by mdecision makers respectively, over the alternative set X{x1,x2,...,xn},
where μij
ij >0. Generally speaking, when all the decision makers think that
alternative xiis better than xj, for any k∈{1,2,...,n}, then μ(l)
ik μ(l)
jk and ν(l)
ik
ν(l)
jk,l1,2,...,m. Then, we have the following theorem.
Theorem 5 Let ˜
P(l)(˜p(l)
ij )n×n!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×n(l1,2,...,m)bemIFPRs,
which are given by mdecision makers respectively. If for any k∈{1,2,...,n}and
l∈{1,2,...,m},μ(l)
ik μ(l)
jk and ν(l)
ik ν(l)
jk hold, then ˜i≥˜j,i,j1,2,...,n.
123
J. Liu et al.
Proof Let ˜
P(l)(˜p(l)
ij )n×n!μ(l)
ij (l)
ij "n×n(l1,2,...,m)bemIFPRs. From
Eqs. (26) and (27), we have τ(˜p(l)
ik )[h(l),
ik ,h(l),+
ik ][μ(l)
ik
1μ(l)
ik
,1ν(l)
ik
ν(l)
ik
], τ(˜p(l)
jk)
[h(l),
jk ,h(l),+
jk ][μ(l)
jk
1μ(l)
jk
,1ν(l)
jk
ν(l)
jk
], hs,
ik
m
(
l1h(l),
ik λland hs,+
jk
m
(
l1h(l),+
jk λl.
If μ(l)
ik μ(l)
jk and ν(l)
ik ν(l)
jk for all k∈{1,2,...,n}and l∈{1,2,...,m},it
follows that hs,
ik hs,
jk and hs,+
ik hs,+
jk . Assume that u(u
1k,u
2k,...,u
nk)T
and v
kare the optimal weights obtained by Model (21)or(22), since
θ
jk
n
r1
u
rkhs,
ik v
k,and θ+
jk
n
r1
u
rkhs,+
ik v
k,j1,2,...,n,
we have θ
ik θ
jk and θ+
ik θ+
jk. According to Eq. (24), it is evident that θ
i
θ
jand θ+
iθ+
j.FromEq.(25), we have μ
iθ
i
ψ,μ
jθ
j
ψ,ν
i1
ψn
r1,riθ+
r
and ν
j1
ψn
r1,r jθ+
r, where ψn
r1θ+
r+1
n2max
k#θ+
kθ
k$. Thus, the score
function of ˜iand ˜jare S(˜i)1
ψ(θ
in
riθ+
r) and S(˜j)1
ψ(θ
j
n
r jθ+
r), respectively. Consequently, we have
S(˜i)S(˜j)1
ψ(θ
iθ
j)+(θ+
iθ+
j)0,
which implies that ˜i≥˜j.
Theorem 5shows that the obtained priority vector from our method is in accord
with the decision makers’ preferences. In other words, the ranking result can reflect
the preference of all the decision makers.
5 Numerical examples and comparison analysis
5.1 Numerical example
In the background of knowledge economy, the competition in the market is not just the
competition between enterprises, but the competition between supply chain alliances.
The supply chain is a complex system built by interdependent organizations and pro-
cesses, and the evaluation criteria of the supply chain involve customer service level,
financial status, innovation level, production flexibility, etc. The evaluation process is
somewhat subjective as the experts may not be very familiar with all the situation of
the supply chains they evaluated. Thus, it is suitable for the decision makers to use the
IFPRs to express their evaluation information. There are five decision makers d1,d2,
d3,d4and d5who provide their IFPRs on four supply chains {A1,A2,A3,A4}.After
doing some pairwise comparisons, the decision makers offer five IFPRs as follows:
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
˜
P(1)
0.50,0.50
0.50,0.20
0.70,0.10
0.50,0.30
0.20,0.50
0.50,0.50
0.60,0.20
0.30,0.60
0.10,0.70
0.20,0.60
0.50,0.50
0.30,0.60
0.30,0.50
0.60,0.30
0.60,0.30
0.50,0.50
,
˜
P(2)
0.50,0.50
0.60,0.20
0.60,0.20
0.60,0.30
0.20,0.60
0.50,0.50
0.50,0.20
0.30,0.50
0.20,0.60
0.20,0.50
0.50,0.50
0.20,0.60
0.30,0.60
0.50,0.30
0.60,0.20
0.50,0.50
,
˜
P(3)
0.50,0.50
0.55,0.25
0.65,0.20
0.35,0.55
0.25,0.55
0.50,0.50
0.40,0.25
0.55,0.30
0.20,0.65
0.25,0.40
0.50,0.50
0.60,0.20
0.55,0.35
0.30,0.55
0.20,0.60
0.50,0.50
,
˜
P(4)
0.50,0.50
0.60,0.30
0.70,0.20
0.60,0.30
0.30,0.60
0.50,0.50
0.50,0.40
0.30,0.40
0.20,0.70
0.40,0.50
0.50,0.50
0.30,0.60
0.30,0.60
0.40,0.30
0.60,0.30
0.50,0.50
,
˜
P(5)
0.50,0.50
0.60,0.30
0.75,0.15
0.60,0.20
0.30,0.60
0.50,0.50
0.45,0.20
0.60,0.20
0.15,0.75
0.20,0.45
0.50,0.50
0.40,0.40
0.20,0.60
0.20,0.60
0.40,0.40
0.50,0.50
.
Step 1 BasedonEq.(26), ˜
P(1),˜
P(2),˜
P(3),˜
P(4) and ˜
P(5) are transformed into ˜
H(l)
(l1,2,3,4,5) respectively, where
˜
H(1)
[1.0000,1.0000] [1.0000,4.0000] [2.3333,9.0000] [1.0000,2.3333]
[0.2500,1.0000] [1.0000,1.0000] [1.5000,4.0000] [0.4286,0.6667]
[0.1111,0.4286] [0.2500,0.6667] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.4286,0.6667]
[0.4286,1.0000] [1.5000,2.3333] [1.5000,2.3333] [1.0000,1.0000]
,
˜
H(2)
[1.0000,1.0000] [1.5000,4.0000] [1.5000,4.0000] [1.5000,2.3333]
[0.2500,0.6667] [1.0000,1.0000] [1.0000,4.0000] [0.4286,1.0000]
[0.2500,0.6667] [0.2500,1.0000] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.2500,0.6667]
[0.4286,0.6667] [1.0000,2.3333] [1.5000,4.0000] [1.0000,1.0000]
,
˜
H(3)
[1.0000,1.0000] [1.2222,3.0000] [1.8571,4.0000] [0.5385,0.8182]
[0.3333,0.8182] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.6667,3.0000] [1.2222,2.3333]
[0.2500,0.5385] [0.3333,1.5000] [1.0000,1.0000] [1.5000,4.0000]
[1.2222,1.8571] [0.4286,0.8182] [0.2500,0.6667] [1.0000,1.0000]
,
123
J. Liu et al.
˜
H(4)
[1.0000,1.0000] [1.5000,2.3333] [2.3333,4.0000] [1.5000,2.3333]
[0.4286,0.6667] [1.0000,1.0000] [1.0000,1.5000] [0.4286,1.5000]
[0.2500,0.4286] [0.6667,1.0000] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.4286,0.6667]
[0.4286,0.6667] [0.6667,2.3333] [1.5000,2.3333] [1.0000,1.0000]
,
˜
H(5)
[1.0000,1.0000] [1.5000,2.3333] [3.0000,5.6667] [1.5000,4.0000]
[0.4286,0.6667] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.8182,4.0000] [1.5000,4.0000]
[0.1765,0.3333] [0.2500,1.2222] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.6667,1.5000]
[0.2500,0.6667] [0.2500,0.6667] [0.6667,1.5000] [1.0000,1.0000]
.
Step 2 By solving Model (28), we get the optimal weight vector of five decision
makers, i.e., λ(0.0883,0.3689,0.0941,0.2657,0.1830)T;
Step 3 Using Eq. (27), ˜
H(l)(l1,2,3,4,5) are aggregated into the synthetic
preference relation
Hs
[1.0000,1.0000] [1.4196,3.0567] [2.0316,4.5796] [1.3142,2.3333]
[0.3271,0.7044] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.9616,3.0000] [0.5949,1.5000]
[0.2184,0.4922] [0.3333,1.0399] [1.0000,1.0000] [0.4286,0.9154]
[0.4286,0.7609] [0.6667,1.6809] [1.0924,2.3333] [1.0000,1.0000]
.
Step 4 According to the ranking method for IFPR in Sect. 3.3 with Model (21), we
obtain the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy priority weight vector
˜(0.2798,0.5975,0.1036,0.7164,0.0694,0.7929,0.1318,0.7133)T.
Meanwhile, if we use Model (22) instead of Model (21), we have
(0.1866,0.5155,0.1043,0.7059,0.0646,0.7889,0.0923,0.6918)T.
Step 5 Based on Definition 6, the ranking of the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy
priority weight vector ˜in the descending order is as follows:
˜10.2798,0.5975>˜40.1318,0.7133>˜
20.1036,0.7164>˜30.1318,0.7133
Additionally, the ranking of is
˜
10.1866,0.5155>˜
40.0923,0.6918>˜
20.1043,0.7059>˜
30.0646,0.7889
As can be seen, ˜and have the same ranking results.
Step 6 The final ranking of the four alternative supply chains is A1>A4>A2>
A3.
Step 7 Thus, A1is the best supply chain.
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
5.2 Comparison analysis
This subsection further compares our method with several existing representative
methods, which were developed in Wang (2013), Meng et al. (2017), Xu (2012) and Wu
et al. (2018). First of all, we use these methods to solve the above problem respectively.
(1) Using Wang (2013)’s Method. Using the linear goal programming model (4.18)
in Wang (2013), we obtain the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight vector:
˜w(0.4701,0.4709,0.0749,0.6250,0,0.9034,0.1549,0.6626)T.
Moreover, the score functions of the four weights are obtained as follows:
S(˜w1)−0.0008,S(˜w2)−0.5501,S(˜w3)−0.9034,S(˜w4)−0.5077.
So, the final ranking is A1>A4>A2>A3, which is the same as that derived by
our approach.
(2) Using Meng et al. (2017)’s Method. The intuitionistic fuzzy prior-
ity weight vector is derived using Meng et al. (2017)’s method, i.e.,
˜w(0.6146,0.2560,0.3686,0.3861,0.2469,0.5385,0.4080,0.4286).
From Zhang and Xu (2012)forIFVs,wehave
L(˜w1)0.6588,L(˜w2)0.4930,L(˜w3)0.3800,L(˜w4)0.4911.
Hence, the ranking is A1>A2>A4>A3, which is different from the results
derived by our approach, as well as the Wang (2013)’s method as the positions of the
supply chain A2and A4are changed.
Furthermore, we will use the method in Wu et al. (2018) and Xu (2012) to obtain
the priority vector of synthetic IFPR, which is yielded by aggregate the five IFPRs,
i.e., ˜
P(l),l1,2,...,5.
(3) Using Xu (2012)’s Method. We can get the priority weight vector,
˜w([0.2845,0.3059],[0.2290,0.2597],[0.1971,0.2251],[0.2369,0.2617])T.
The following possibility degree matrix is construct to rank the priority weights.
P
0.51 1 1
00.510.4111
000.50
00.5889 1 0.5
.
By summing all elements in each line of P,wehave p13.5000,p2
1.9111,p30.5000,p42.0889. Hence, the ranking of the four alternative supply
chains is A1>A4>A2>A3, which is the same as that derived by our approach.
123
J. Liu et al.
(4) Using Wu et al. (2018)’s Method. The crisp priority vector is obtained by using
the arithmetic mean operator:
w10.8750,w
20.4430,w
30.1250,w
40.5570.
And thus the final ranking of the four alternative supply chains is A1>A4>A2>
A3, which is the same as that derived by our approach.
The above numerical example shows that our approach produces the same ranking
order, i.e., A1>A4>A2>A3, with Xu’s, Wu et al.’s and Wang’s methods, while
Meng et al.’s method derives a slightly different order in which the positions of A2
and A4are changed, which is a further proof of the credibility and reliability of our
approach.
We further illustrate the advantages of our method by the Example 2 compared with
the four existing representative methods.
Example 2 Let ˜
Pbe an IFPR on alternative set X{x1,x2,x3,x4}, and
˜
P
0.50,0.50
0.35,0.55
0.40,0.40
0.35,0.55
0.55,0.35
0.50,0.50
0.70,0.10
0.60,0.20
0.40,0.40
0.10,0.70
0.50,0.50
0.70,0.20
0.55,0.35
0.20,0.60
0.20,0.70
0.50,0.50
.
Using our approach, we have
˜w(0.1145,0.7653,0.2034,0.5490,0.1106,0.6983,0.1101,0.7397)T,
then the ranking order is x2>x3>x4>x1.
Using Wang (2013)’s Method, we have
S(˜w1)−0.6237,S(˜w2)0.1239,S(˜w3)−0.6237,S(˜w4)−0.6761,
by which the ranking order is x2>x1x3>x4.
UsingXu(2012)’s method, we have
p11.5309,p23.5000,p32.2753,p40.6938,
which means that the ranking order is x2>x3>x1>x4.
UsingWuetal.(2018)’s Method, we have
w10.2250,w
20.8750,w
30.2750,w
40.6250,
by which the ranking order is x2>x4>x3>x1.
Using Meng et al. (2017)’s Method, since ˜
Phas poor consistency, and it can be
adjusted to a multiplicative consistent IFPR ˜
T.
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
˜
T
0.5000,0.5000
0.2799,0.7066
0.3747,0.4243
0.4372,0.3443
0.7066,0.2799
0.5000,0.5000
0.5906,0.2227
0.6517,0.1695
0.4243,0.3747
0.2227,0.5906
0.5000,0.5000
0.5646,0.4161
0.3443,0.4372
0.1695,0.6517
0.4161,0.5646
0.5000,0.5000
.
Then, from ˜
T,wehave
L(˜w1)0.4526,L(˜w2)0.6891,L(˜w3)0.4680,L(˜w4)0.3910.
Thus, the ranking order is x2>x3>x1>x4.
Comparing the ranking of xi(i1,2,...,4) derived by our approach with those
of Wang (2013), Xu (2012), Wu et al. (2018) and Meng et al. (2017), we find that
these methods generate a different ranking, especially on x1and x4. From the IFPR
matrix ˜
P(˜pij)4×4,wehave ˜p41 0.55,0.35, which means the certainty degree
that x4is preferred to x1is 0.55, while the certainty degree of x4is non-preferred to
x1is 0.35. It is obvious that x1should not be superior to x4. Therefore, the ranking
result of our method is more reasonable than that of Xu (2012), Wu et al. (2018),
Wang (2013) and Meng et al. (2017) in this case. What’s more, from the multiplicative
consistent IFPR ˜
T(˜
tij)4×4adjusted from ˜
P,wehave˜
t41 0.3443,0.4372,
which is quite different from ˜p41 0.55,0.35. The distortion of the given decision
making information makes the decision result less reliable.
As can be seen, compared with Xu (2012), Wu et al. (2018), Wang (2013) and
Meng et al. (2017), our proposed method has the following advantages:
(1) In Meng et al. (2017)’s method, the inconsistent IFPRs need to be repaired to yield
the acceptable consistent IFPRs, which can distort the given decision making
information and make the decision result less reliable. Besides, the inconsistency
repairing process is complex and tedious. As to our method, the decision making
process is based entirely on the original preference information given by decision
makers and does not require consistent improving. Thus, our method can avoid
information distortion and the result is more credible.
(2) In Wu et al. (2018)’s method and Xu (2012)’s method, the priority vector of IFPR
is given in the form of interval, which is not normalized. From Theorem 3,we
find that our method can yield the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight vector.
(3) InWuetal.(2018)’s method and Wang (2013)’s method, it is assumed that there
exist some relationships between priority weight vector and consistent IFPRs,
then the optimization models are established based on these assumptions to get the
priority weight vector. Since these assumptions are based on consistent IFPR, the
obtained priority weight vectors are always unreasonable for some inconsistent
IFPRs. Besides, these assumptions are not unique. By contrast, our approach
does not need to make any assumptions in advance, so it can avoid the risk of
assumption dependent.
In summary, our method does not need consistency adjustment, making any assump-
tions and can yield a normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight vector. In particular, when
the IFPR given by the decision maker has a poor consistency, our method has better
applicability and can derive more reasonable ranking result than some known methods.
123
J. Liu et al.
6 Conclusions
This paper has been studying group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency
with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations.
Firstly, the defined interval transform function has established the substantial rela-
tionship between IFPRs into IMPRs, and it has been proved that the transform function
can ensure the consistency of the relationship. Then, an interval transform function
based DEA model is developed to obtain the ranking vector of consistent IFPR, in
which each of the alternatives is viewed as a DMU. Moreover, for any IFPR, we pro-
posed two DEA cross-efficiency models to get the peer-evaluation cross-efficiency
values of all alternatives, and we can calculate the normalized intuitionistic fuzzy
weight vector of the IFPR based on the cross-efficiency values. Because the proposed
normalized intuitionistic fuzzy weight vector derivation method from IFPR does not
need repairing the given IFPR, it can avoid information distortion and obtain more cred-
ible decision making results. A goal programming model is investigated to derive the
weights of decision makers. Meanwhile, a step-by-step procedure for group decision
making approach based on DEA cross-efficiency with intuitionistic fuzzy preference
relations is presented. Finally, the proposed approach is verified by numerical exam-
ples and the comparison analysis, by which one can find the advantages of the new
method.
To the best of our knowledge, employing the theory of DEA cross-efficiency to the
group decision making with IFPRs are completely new to the literature and have not
been studied elsewhere before. Probably, we also can use the DEA cross-efficiency
model to any other decision making environments, such as triangular fuzzy preference
relations, trapezoidal fuzzy preference relation.
Acknowledgements The work was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos.
71501002, 61502003, 71871001, 71771001, and 71701001), Anhui Provincial Natural Science Foundation
(Nos. 1608085QF133, 1508085QG149), Anhui Provincial Philosophy and Social Science Planning Youth
Foundation (No. AHSKQ2016D13).
References
Atanassov, K. T. (1986). Intuitionistic fuzzy sets. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 20(1), 87–96.
Doyle, J., & Green, R. (1994). Efficiency and cross-efficiency in DEA: Derivations, meanings and uses.
Journal of the Operational Research Society, 45(5), 567–578.
Herrera-Viedma, E., Herrera, F., Chiclana, F., & Luque, M. (2004). Some issues on consistency of fuzzy
preference relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 154(1), 98–109.
Liang, L., Wu, J., Cook, W. D., & Zhu, J. (2008). The DEA game cross-efficiency model and its nash
equilibrium. Operations Research, 56(5), 1278–1288.
Liao, H., & Xu, Z. (2014). Priorities of intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation based on multiplicative
consistency. IEEE Transactions on Fuzzy Systems, 22(6), 1669–1681.
Liao, H., Xu, Z., Zeng, X., & Merigo, J. M. (2015). Framework of group decision making with intuitionistic
fuzzy preference information. IEEE Transactions on Fuzzy Systems, 23(4), 1211–1227.
Liu, J., Xu, Q., Chen, H., Zhou, L., Zhu, J., & Tao, Z. (2017). Group decision making with interval fuzzy
preference relations based on DEA and stochastic simulation. Neural Computing and Applications.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00521-017-3254-7.
123
Group decision making based on DEA cross-efficiency with…
Meng, F., Tang, J., & Xu, Z. (2017). A 0-1 mixed programming model based method for group deci-
sion making with intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 112,
289–304.
Ramanathan, R. (2006). Data envelopment analysis for weight derivation and aggregation in the analytic
hierarchy process. Computers & Operations Research, 33(5), 1289–1307.
Saaty, T. L. (1977). A scaling method for priorities in hierarchical structures. Journal of Mathematical
Psychology, 15(3), 234–281.
Saaty, T. L. (1980). The analytic hierarchy process. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Saaty, T. L., & Vargas, L. G. (1987). Uncertainty and rank order in the analytic hierarchy process. European
Journal of Operational Research, 32(1), 107–117.
Wang,Z. (2013). Derivation of intuitionistic fuzzy weights based on intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations.
Applied Mathematical Modelling, 37(9), 6377–6388.
Wang, Z. (2015). A note on “A goal programming model for incomplete interval multiplicative preference
relations and its application in group decision-making”. European Journal of Operational Research,
247(3), 867–871.
Wang, Y., Chin, K. S., & Poon, G. K. K. (2008). A data envelopment analysis method with assurance region
for weight generation in the analytic hierarchy process. Decision Support Systems, 45(4), 913–921.
Wu, J., Chiclana, F., & Liao, H. (2018). Isomorphic multiplicative transitivity for intuitionistic and
interval-valued fuzzy preference relations and its application in deriving their priority vectors. IEEE
Transactions on Fuzzy Systems, 26(1), 193–202.
Xia, M., & Chen, J. (2015). Studies on interval multiplicative preference relations and their application to
group decision making. Group Decision and Negotiation, 24(1), 115–144.
Xu, Z. (2007a). A survey of preference relations. International Journal of General Systems, 36(2), 179–203.
Xu, Z. (2007b). Intuitionistic preference relations and their application in group decision making. Informa-
tion Sciences, 177(11), 2363–2379.
Xu, Z. (2012). An error-analysis-based method for the priority of an intuitionistic preference relation in
decision making. Knowledge-Based Systems, 33, 173–179.
Xu, Z. (2013). Compatibility analysis of intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations in group decision making.
Group Decision and Negotiation, 22(3), 463–482.
Xu, Z., & Cai, X. (2010). Recent advances in intuitionistic fuzzy information aggregation. Fuzzy Optimiza-
tion and Decision Making, 9(4), 359–381.
Xu, Z., & Liao, H. (2015). A survey of approaches to decision making with intuitionistic fuzzy preference
relations. Knowledge-Based Systems, 80(5), 131–142.
Xu, Z., & Xia, M. (2014). Iterative algorithms for improving consistency of intuitionistic preference rela-
tions. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 65(5), 708–722.
Zhang, X., & Xu, Z. (2012). A new method for ranking intuitionistic fuzzy values and its application in
multi-attribute decision making. Fuzzy Optimization and Decision Making, 11(2), 135–146.
Affiliations
Jinpei Liu1,2 ·Jingmiao Song1·Qin Xu3·Zhifu Tao4·Huayou Chen5
Jingmiao Song
1253732255@qq.com
Qin Xu
xuqin2013@aliyun.com
Zhifu Tao
zhifut_0514@163.com
Huayou Chen
huayouc@126.com
1School of Business, Anhui University, Hefei 230601, Anhui, China
123
J. Liu et al.
2Edward P. Fitts Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering, North Carolina State
University, Raleigh, NC 27695-7906, USA
3School of Computer Science and Technology, Anhui University, Hefei 230601, Anhui, China
4School of Economics, Anhui University, Hefei 230601, Anhui, China
5School of Mathematical Sciences, Anhui University, Hefei 230601, Anhui, China
123
... In the realm of GDM, three prominent methodologies emerge: direct information integration (DII), CRP, and social network analysis (SNA). Concerning the strategy of DII, Liu, Song et al. (2019) proposed an interval transformation function to handle consistent intuitionistic APRs, two DEA cross-efficiency models specifically for calculating normalized priority weight vectors. Zhang and Chen (2021) developed optimization models to effectively manage incomplete q-rung orthopair APRs and to generate acceptable multiplicative q-rung orthopair APRs, including an optimization model for achieving a desirable level of consensus. ...
... • The distribution of individual DM weights has been a persistent theme in the field of GDM. Scholars often tend to allocate fixed weights (Jin et al., 2021;Liu, Song et al., 2019). However, fixed weight assignments are biased. ...
Article
Interval additive preference relations (IAPRs) provide a valuable framework for representing uncertain pairwise comparisons among alternatives in group decisionmaking (GDM). Conventional GDM methods that incorporate IAPRs often treat preference values as uniform entities and establish dedicated conflict or consensus mechanisms for amalgamating individual opinions while overlooking the stochastic preferences and lacking the flexibility to address diverse decision requirements. Therefore, to account for the stochastic characteristics in both preference representation and group preference aggregation, this paper introduces a innovative double stochastic preference analysis for GDM with IAPRs. In the initial phase, the methodology entails the extraction of stochastic additive preference relations (SAPRs) from the provided IAPRs. Subsequently, a best preference matrix is constructed by applying a logarithmic consistency minimum deviation model to the SAPRs. In the second phase, it involves the synthesis of preference comparison intervals, which encapsulate the collective viewpoints of decision makers. The preference ranking degrees are computed through an algorithm that evaluates the pairwise comparisons between alternatives, ultimately leading to the determination of optimal preference rankings. Further steps encompass the derivation of ranking acceptability indices and preference confidence degrees through a continuous extraction process. This process contributes to the establishment of the final preference rankings. The effectiveness and validity of the proposed method are demonstrated through numerical examples and Monte Carlo simulations.
... Arya and Yadav (2019) proposed the intuitionistic fuzzy data envelopment analysis (IFDEA) and dual IFDEA (DIFDEA) models based on α and β-cuts, and the index ranking approach is used to rank the DMUs. Liu et al. (2019) proposed two DEA cross-efficiency models to get the cross-efficiency values of all alternatives and the priority weight vector of the intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation. Edalatpanah (2019) proposed a ranking approach for solving the intuitionistic fuzzy DEA model. ...
Article
Full-text available
Fuzzy DEA is a performance measurement tool that is used to assess the performance of DMUs in highly uncertain environments. In this article, the Intuitionistic fuzzy DEA (IFDEA) model is proposed based on the triangular intuitionistic fuzzy numbers (TIFNs). The weighted Possibility mean for TIFN is used to compare and rank the TIFN. The weighted possibility mean approach is proposed to solve the IFDEA model, and the IFDEA model is converted into its equivalent crisp DEA model to assess the relative efficiencies of the DMUs. One advantage of the proposed approach is that the attitude of the decision-maker is considered while measuring the efficiency of the DMUs. The weight or risk factor $$\delta \in [0,1]$$ δ ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] indicates whether the decision-maker is a risk-taker, neutral, or adverse. The crisp DEA model is a LP problem that is solved by using an existing LP method with different risk factors to determine the efficiency score of the DMUs. The DMUs are ranked based on the overall efficiency score of the DMUs, which is the arithmetic mean of the efficiency scores of the DMUs with different risk factors. Two numerical examples are given here to demonstrate the validity and applicability of the proposed technique and to compare the performance of the DMUs in the proposed approach with the exciting ranking approach and the expected value approach. A case study on the agriculture sector has been conducted in order to evaluate the agricultural performance of Indian states using the IFDEA model. According to the results of the IFDEA model, 15 (53.57%) out of the 28 Indian states were found to be efficient.
... Hatami-Marbini et al. (2017) proposed a lexicographic multi-objective linear programming (MOLP) approach in which a fully fuzzy DEA model is transformed into a MOLP problem. Intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations and DEA cross-efficiency were used by Liu et al. (2019) to investigate a novel method of group decision making that may reduce information asymmetry and produce better decision-making outcomes. Azar et al. (2016) introduced a new fuzzy additive model to determine the CSW in DEA, and it is the focus of this study. ...
Article
Full-text available
A mathematical technique called data envelope analysis is used to determine the relative efficiency of decision-making units (DMU) with numerous inputs and outputs. Compared to other DMUs, it determines how efficient the DMU is at delivering a specific level of output based on the amount of input it uses. The transportation problem is a linear programming problem for reducing the net transportation cost or maximizing the net transportation profit of moving goods from a number of sources to a number of destinations. In this manuscript, a multi-objective transportation problem is examined in which all the parameters, such as transportation cost, supply, and demand are uncertain with hesitancy and triangular Fermatean fuzzy numbers are used to represent these uncertain parameters. Using Fermatean fuzzy data envelope analysis, a new technique for determining the common set of weights is presented. The fully Fermatean fuzzy multi-objective transportation problem is then solved using a novel data envelopment analysis-based approach. To this end, two different Fermatean fuzzy efficiency scores are derived, first by considering the sources as targets and changing the destinations, and second by considering the destinations as targets and changing the sources. Next, a unique Fermatean fuzzy relative efficiency is determined for each arc by combining these two different Fermatean fuzzy efficiency scores. As a result, a single-objective Fermatean fuzzy transportation problem is constructed, which can be solved using existing techniques. A numerical illustration is provided to support the suggested methodology, and the performance of the proposed method is compared with an existing technique
Chapter
In the present study, we highlight the importance of taking hesitation into account when calculating the efficiencies of firms or decision-making units (DMUs) with intuitionistic fuzzy (IF) data. Most of the previous studies related to the calculation of efficiencies of DMUs with IF data have ignored the hesitation present in IF variables. The present study uses the technique of data envelopment analysis (DEA) to calculate the relative efficiencies of DMUs. It develops a new model for the calculation of IF efficiencies in the form of intervals. We conclude that the hesitation is indirectly related to the efficiencies of DMUs and deduce a formula to calculate the reduced efficiencies. We also present a method for ranking firms. Lastly, an example is illustrated to verify the working of the developed model.KeywordsIntuitionistic fuzzy numberIntuitionistic fuzzy setsHesitationEfficiencyInterval efficiency
Chapter
Fairness concern behavior, a well-known cognitive bias, refers to a person’s attitude of dissatisfaction for unequal pay-offs in someone’s favor. Against environmental pollution, many firms are focused on green manufacturing to maintain sustainable development. The adoption of online shopping by customers around the globe has altered the dynamics of competitiveness in the retail supply chain (SC). Considering the above facts, the effect of fairness concern on optimal prices and channel members’ profits in a two-level dual channel SC is investigated. Here, we consider an SC comprising a green manufacturer and a fair-minded retailer where the manufacturer produces and sells the green product through both offline and online channels to consumers. Due to uncertainty in the real world, the fuzziness is associated with market demand, price elasticity, and the coefficient of greenness. The fuzzy objectives and constraints are reduced to crisp ones using expectation and possibility measures, respectively. Both centralized and decentralized models (with and without cognitive bias) are formulated and solved by the Stackelberg game for the optimal prices and product greenness level. The models’ optimal solutions are analyzed and compared with the deterministic models numerically. The effects of the fairness concern coefficient on the optimal prices, product greenness level, and channel members’ profits are investigated. The sensitivity analyses are presented to study the effects of the fuzzy degree of customers’ sensitivity toward greenness on channel members’ profits. Retailer’s fairness is harmful to the manufacturer but beneficial for her own profit. Finally, some conclusions and managerial insights are presented.KeywordsGame theoryFuzzy theoryFairness concernGreen supply chain
Article
Full-text available
This paper proposes an integrated approach to group decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations using data envelopment analysis (DEA) and stochastic simulation. A novel output-oriented CCR DEA model is proposed to obtain the priority vector for the consistency fuzzy preference relation, in which each of the alternatives is viewed as a decision-making unit. Meanwhile, we design a consistency adjustment algorithm for the inconsistent fuzzy preference relation. Furthermore, we build an optimization model to get the weights of each fuzzy preference relation based on maximizing group consensus. Then, an input-oriented DEA model is introduced to obtain the final priority vector of the alternatives. Finally, a stochastic group preference analysis method is developed by analyzing the judgments space, which is carried out by Monte Carlo simulation. A numerical example demonstrates that the proposed method is effective.
Article
Full-text available
Intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations (IFPRs) are used to deal with hesitation while interval-valued fuzzy preference relations (IVFPRs) are for uncertainty in multi-criteria decision making (MCDM). This article aims to explore the isomorphic multiplicative transitivity for IFPRs and IVFPRs, which builds the substantial relationship between hesitation and uncertainty in MCDM. To do that, the definition of the multiplicative transitivity property of IFPRs is established by combining the multiplication of intuitionistic fuzzy sets and Tanino’s multiplicative transitivity property of fuzzy preference relations (FPRs). It is proved to be isomorphic to the multiplicative transitivity of IVFPRs derived via Zadeh’s Extension Principle. The use of the multiplicative transitivity isomorphism is twofold: (1) to discover the substantial relationship between IFPRs and IVFPRs, which will bridge the gap between hesitation and uncertainty in MCDM problems; and (2) to strengthen the soundness of the multiplicative transitivity property of IFPRs and IVFPRs by supporting each other with two different reliable sources, respectively. Furthermore, based on the existing isomorphism, the concept of multiplicative consistency for IFPRs is defined through a strict mathematical process, and it is proved to satisfy the following several desirable properties: weak–transitivity, maxmax– transitivity, and center-division–transitivity. A multiplicative consistency based multi-objective programming (MOP) model is investigated to derive the priority vector from an IFPR. This model has the advantage of not losing information as the priority vector representation coincides with that of the input information, which was not the case with existing methods where crisp priority vectors were derived as a consequence of modelling transitivity just for the intuitionistic membership function and not for the intuitionistic non-membership function. Finally, a numerical example concerning green supply selection is given to validate the efficiency and practicality of the proposed multiplicative consistency MOP model.
Article
Full-text available
Preference relations are the most common representation structures of information used in decision making problems because they are useful tool in modelling decision processes, above all when we want to aggregate experts' pref-erences into group preferences. Therefore, to establish rationality properties to be verified by preference relations is very important in the design of good decision making models. There are three fundamental and hierarchical levels of rationality assumptions when dealing with preference relations: the first one requires indif-ference between any alternative and itself, the second one assumes the property of reciprocity in the pairwise comparison between any two alternatives, and the third one is associated with the transitivity in the pairwise comparison among any three alternatives. Furthermore, it would also be desirable to maintain the ratio-nality assumptions on the individual preferences in the aggregation process, so that the collective preferences verify the same ones. However, as this is not always the case, establishing conditions that guarantee the preservation of these rationality properties throughout the aggregation process becomes very important. In this article we address this problem and present a review of the main results that we have obtained about reciprocity and consistency properties of fuzzy pref-erence relations. In particular, we present a characterization of fuzzy consistency based on the additive transitivity property which facilitates the verification of con-sistency in the case of fuzzy preference relations. Using this new characterization we give a method to construct consistent fuzzy preference relations from n−1 given preference values. We also discuss some questions concerning the compatibility be-tween the three levels of rationality, as well as the conflict that appears between the additive consistency property and the scale used to provide fuzzy preferences. Finally, we provide aggregation operators that provide reciprocal and consistent col-lective preference relations when the individual preference relations are reciprocal and consistent.
Article
Intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations (IFPRs) are important and powerful that can express the decision makers’ preferred and non-preferred judgements simultaneously. To rank objects reasonably, consistency analysis is necessary. Thus, this paper defines a new multiplicative consistency concept for IFPRs that is a natural extension of the crisp case. Using the new concept, 0–1 mixed programming models are constructed to judge the consistency of IFPRs and to determine missing values in incomplete IFPRs. Considering the inconsistent case, an approach to deriving multiplicative consistent IFPRs is presented. To address group decision making with IFPRs, a consensus index is proposed to measure the agreement degree between individual IFPRs. Then, an approach to group decision making with IFPRs is presented that can address the inconsistent and incomplete IFPRs. Finally, two practical examples are provided to show the efficiency and feasibility of the new theoretical results, and a comparison analysis is performed.
Article
In a recently published paper by Liu et al. [Liu, F., Zhang, W.G., Wang, Z.X. (2012). A goal programming model for incomplete interval multiplicative preference relations and its application in group decision-making. European Journal of Operational Research 218, 747–754], two equations are introduced to define consistency of incomplete interval multiplicative preference relations (IMPRs) and employed to develop a goal programming model for estimating missing values. This note illustrates that such consistency definition and estimation model are technically incorrect. New transitivity conditions are proposed to define consistent IMPRs, and a two-stage goal programming approach is devised to estimate missing values for incomplete IMPRs.
Article
Group decision making is an essential activity in various fields of operations research and management science. This paper focuses on the intuitionistic fuzzy group decision making problem in which all the experts use the intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations (IFPRs) to express their preferences. To start our discussion, we first propose the novel framework of intuitionistic fuzzy group decision making and clarify the difficulties in deriving the final result which is accepted by all individuals in the group. Next, a consistency checking method, which is based on the multiplicative consistency, is developed to check the consistency of each IFPR furnished by the group of experts. For those IFPRs that do not have the acceptable consistency, an iterative procedure is proposed to improve the consistency. Furthermore, after introducing a novel consensus measure, an interesting consensus-reaching procedure is developed to help the group to find a solution which is accepted by most members in the group. Finally, in order to make our approaches more applicable, a step-by-step algorithm is given. A numerical example concerning the selection of outstanding Ph.D. students for the China Scholarship Council is given to illustrate and validate the proposed approaches.
Article
The intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation (IFPR), whose elements are intuitionistic fuzzy values (IFVs), is more powerful than the traditional multiplicative preference relation and the fuzzy preference relation in expressing comprehensive preference information of a decision maker. The aim of this paper is to investigate a new approach to derive the priority weights from an IFPR. To do so, we give a new definition of multiplicative consistent IFPR, which is based on the membership and nonmembership degrees of the intuitionistic fuzzy judgments. After that, a formula, which involves the underlying intuitionistic fuzzy weights of the IFPR, is proposed to construct such a multiplicative consistent IFPR. Based on the formula, some fractional programming models are built to generate the intuitionistic fuzzy priority weighting vector of the IFPR. Several numerical examples are given to illustrate the validity and applicability of the proposed method.
Article
Intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations (IFPRs) have attracted more and more scholars’ attentions in recent years due to their efficiency in representing experts’ imprecise cognitions. With IFPRs, people can express their opinions over different pairs of alternatives from positive, negative and hesitative points of view. This paper presents a comprehensive survey on decision making with IFPRs with the aim of providing a clear perspective on the originality, the consistency, the prioritization, and the consensus of IFPRs. Finally, some directions for future research are pointed out.
Article
The consistency of interval multiplicative preference relations is studied and applied to group decision making. Weak transitivity for interval multiplicative preference relation is defined by comparing two interval multiplicative preferemnce values using a possibility degree formula. The consistent interval multiplicative preference relation is defined based on interval operations, which provides a convenient means to check whether an interval multiplicative preference relation is consistent. A goal-programming model is established to derive the interval priority weight vector from an interval multiplicative preference relation, which must solve only one model. An algorithm is developed through interaction with decision makers to ensure the transitivity of an interval multiplicative preference relation. The proposed methods are then extended to deal with incomplete interval multiplicative preference relations, which can determine the priority weight vector without estimating missing values. An algorithm is also developed to derive the priority vector from group multiplicative preference relations. This algorithm can help decision makers ensure the weak transitivity of their provided multiplicative preference relations.
Article
Consistency of preference relations is an important research topic in decision making with preference information. The existing research about consistency mainly focuses on multiplicative preference relations, fuzzy preference relations and linguistic preference relations. Intuitionistic preference relations, each of their elements is composed of a membership degree, a non-membership degree and a hesitation degree, can better reflect the very imprecision of preferences of decision makers. There has been little research on consistency of intuitionistic preference relations up to now, and thus, it is necessary to pay attention to this issue. In this paper, we first propose an approach to constructing the consistent (or approximate consistent) intuitionistic preference relation from any intuitionistic preference relation. Then we develop a convergent iterative algorithm to improve the consistency of an intuitionistic preference relation. Moreover, we investigate the consistency of intuitionistic preference relations in group decision making situations, and show that if all individual intuitionistic preference relations are consistent, then the collective intuitionistic preference relation is also consistent. Moreover, we develop a convergent iterative algorithm to improve the consistency of all individual intuitionistic preference relations. The practicability and effectiveness of the developed algorithms is verified through two examples.