ArticlePDF Available

Group decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations based on DEA and stochastic simulation

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper proposes an integrated approach to group decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations using data envelopment analysis (DEA) and stochastic simulation. A novel output-oriented CCR DEA model is proposed to obtain the priority vector for the consistency fuzzy preference relation, in which each of the alternatives is viewed as a decision-making unit. Meanwhile, we design a consistency adjustment algorithm for the inconsistent fuzzy preference relation. Furthermore, we build an optimization model to get the weights of each fuzzy preference relation based on maximizing group consensus. Then, an input-oriented DEA model is introduced to obtain the final priority vector of the alternatives. Finally, a stochastic group preference analysis method is developed by analyzing the judgments space, which is carried out by Monte Carlo simulation. A numerical example demonstrates that the proposed method is effective.
This content is subject to copyright. Terms and conditions apply.
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Group decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations
based on DEA and stochastic simulation
Jinpei Liu
1
Qin Xu
2
Huayou Chen
3
Ligang Zhou
3,4
Jiaming Zhu
3
Zhifu Tao
3
Received: 27 December 2016 / Accepted: 15 October 2017
ÓThe Natural Computing Applications Forum 2017
Abstract This paper proposes an integrated approach to
group decision making with interval fuzzy preference rela-
tions using data envelopment analysis (DEA) and stochastic
simulation. A novel output-oriented CCR DEA model is
proposed to obtain the priority vector for the consistency
fuzzy preference relation, in which each of the alternatives is
viewed as a decision-making unit. Meanwhile, we design a
consistency adjustment algorithm for the inconsistent fuzzy
preference relation. Furthermore, we build an optimization
model to get the weights of each fuzzy preference relation
based on maximizing group consensus. Then, an input-ori-
ented DEA model is introduced to obtain the final priority
vector of the alternatives. Finally, a stochastic group
preference analysis method is developed by analyzing the
judgments space, which is carried out by Monte Carlo sim-
ulation. A numerical example demonstrates that the pro-
posed method is effective.
Keywords Group decision making (GDM) Interval fuzzy
preference relation Data envelopment analysis (DEA)
Stochastic simulation
1 Introduction
Group decision-making (GDM) problems can be defined as
decision situations where a group of decision makers or
experts try to achieve a common solution to a problem
consisting of two or more possible alternatives [9]. In the
group decision-making process, each decision maker pro-
vides his/her preference information which includes mul-
tiplicative preference relation [27], fuzzy preference
relation [8], interval multiplicative preference relation
[19,21], interval fuzzy preference relation [2], linguistic
preference relation [5], intuitionistic fuzzy preference
relation [10], hesitant fuzzy preference relation [31], and
interval-valued hesitant fuzzy preference relation [13].
The fuzzy preference relations were widely used to express
decision-makers’ preferences on decisionalternatives. How to
derive priority vector from the fuzzy preference relation has
become a hot issue of study. Since then, many prioritization
methods with fuzzy preference relation have been developed,
such as the eigenvector method [17], the goal programming
methods [6], the least deviation method (LDM) [26], the Chi
square method (CSM) [16], and fuzzy linear programming
method (FLPM) [29]. Wu [18] proposed an integrated method
of multi-attribute decision making (MADM) based on data
envelopment analysis (DEA).
&Jinpei Liu
liujinpei2012@163.com
Qin Xu
xuqin2013@aliyun.com
Huayou Chen
huayouc@126.com
Ligang Zhou
shuiqiaozlg@126.com
Jiaming Zhu
502470059@qq.com
Zhifu Tao
zhifut_0514@163.com
1
School of Business, Anhui University, Hefei 230601, Anhui,
China
2
MOE Key Laboratory of Intelligence Computing and Signal
Processing, Anhui University, Hefei 230601, Anhui, China
3
School of Mathematical Sciences, Anhui University,
Hefei 230601, Anhui, China
4
Institute of Manufacturing Development, Nanjing University
of Information Science and Technology, Nanjing 210044,
China
123
Neural Comput & Applic
DOI 10.1007/s00521-017-3254-7
In group decision-making process, because of the deci-
sion-makers’ time pressure and vague knowledge, the
decision makers sometimes cannot estimate their preference
information over alternatives with exact numerical values,
and use interval fuzzy preference relations. To solve this
problem, Chen and Zhou [4] developed a group decision-
making method with interval fuzzy preference relations
based on consistency induced generalized continuous
ordered weighted averaging (C-IGCOWA) operator. Xu and
Cai [25] developed a method based on the uncertain power
average operators for group decision making with interval
fuzzy preference relations. Gong et al. [7] constructed two
multi-objective optimization models in consensus interval
preference decision making. These methods all translate the
interval preference information into a single representative
value or obtain the priority vector based on some program-
ming models. However, each of these methods may lose
information which given by decision makers.
Recently, Zhu and Xu [30] developed a stochastic
preference analysis (SPA) method for single interval
preference relation, which can avoid information loss. The
SPA method brings in several outcomes including the
expected priority vector and confidence degree to aid the
decision makers to make better decisions. In fact, an
interesting and important issue to be solved is how to
develop a stochastic group preference analysis (SGPA)
method for group decision making with interval fuzzy
preference relations. Up to now, there have been no
investigations about this issue.
In this paper, we propose a new approach to group
decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations
using data envelopment analysis (DEA) and stochastic
simulation, which can avoid information loss during deci-
sion making. A new output-oriented CCR DEA model is
proposed to get the priority vector for the consistency fuzzy
preference relation, in which each of the alternatives is
viewed as a decision-making unit (DMU). Meanwhile, a
consistency adjustment algorithm is designed for the
inconsistent fuzzy preference relations. Then, we build an
optimization model to yield the weights of each fuzzy
preference relation based on maximizing group consensus.
Furthermore, an input-oriented DEA model is developed to
obtain the final priority vector of the alternatives, and a
stochastic group preference analysis (SGPA) method is
developed by analyzing the judgments space, which is
carried out by Monte Carlo simulation. Finally, a numerical
example is shown to verify the proposed method.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2
introduces some basic concepts, such as fuzzy preference
relation, interval fuzzy preference relation, and additive
consistency. In Sect. 3, a CCR DEA model for the priority
vector from fuzzy preference relation is proposed. A con-
sistency adjustment algorithm of fuzzy preference relation
is developed in Sect. 4. In Sect. 5, an input-oriented DEA
model is introduced to obtain the final priority vector of the
alternatives, and a stochastic group preference analysis
(SGPA) method is developed by analyzing the judgments
space, which is carried out by Monte Carlo simulation. A
numerical example is illustrated to show the applications of
our group decision-making method in Sect. 6. In the last
section, we draw our conclusions.
2 Preliminary
In this section, we briefly review some fundamental con-
cepts including fuzzy preference relation, additive consis-
tent fuzzy preference relation [15], and interval fuzzy
preference relation [24].
Group decision-making problems are characterized by
the participation of two or more experts in decision mak-
ing, in which the set of alternatives to the problem is
presented. Unless otherwise mentioned, it is assumed that
X¼fx1;x2;...;xngis the set of alternatives, and D¼
fd1;d2;...;dmgis the set of decision makers or experts. In
the decision-making process, each expert provides his/her
opinions over alternatives in X¼fx1;x2;...;xngby means
of preference relation. Let w¼ðw1;w2;...;wnÞTbe the
priority vector, where wireflects the importance degree of
the alternative xi. All the wi(i¼1;2;...;n) are no less
than zeros and sum to one, i.e.,
wi0;i¼1;2;...;n;X
n
i¼1
wi¼1:
Definition 1 [12]. A fuzzy preference relation Ron a set
of alternatives Xis represented by a fuzzy set on the pro-
duct set XX, which is characterized by the membership
function:
lR:XX0;1:
When the number of alternatives is finite, the preference
relation Ris represented by an nnmatrix R¼ðrij Þnn,
where rij ¼lRðxi;xjÞ,i;j¼1;2;...;n.rij denotes the
preference degree of the alternative xiover the alternative
xjwith
rij þrji ¼1;rii ¼0:5;0rij 1 for all i;j¼1;2;...;n:
Definition 2 [15]. A fuzzy preference relation R¼
ðrijÞnnis additive consistent if
rij ¼rik rjk þ0:5;for all i;j;k¼1;2;...;n;ð1Þ
and such a fuzzy preference relation is given by [11,22]
rij ¼0:5ðwiwjþ1Þ;for all i;j¼1;2;...;n:ð2Þ
Neural Comput & Applic
123
In 2004, Xu [24] developed the interval fuzzy prefer-
ence relation, which can be defined as follows:
Definition 3 [24,28]. An interval fuzzy preference rela-
tion ~
Ris defined as ~
R¼ð
~
rijÞnn, which satisfies that
~
rij ¼½rL
ij;rU
ij ;0rL
ij rU
ij 1;rL
ij þrU
ji ¼rU
ij þrL
ji ¼1;
for all i;j¼1;2;...;n;
where ~
rij indicates the interval-valued preference degree of
the alternative xiover the alternative xj,rL
ij and rU
ij are the
lower and upper limits of ~
rij, respectively.
3 Priority vector based on DEA
3.1 Data envelopment analysis
Data envelopment analysis (DEA) is a nonparametric
programming technique, which has been successfully
employed for assessing the relative performance of a set of
decision-making units (DMUs) [3].
Suppose that there are nDMUs, denoted as DMUi
(i¼1;2;...;n), to be evaluated. Each DMU has sdifferent
inputs xil and mdifferent outputs yik (xil 0, yik 0,
l¼1;2;...;s,k¼1;2;...;m). Let Xi¼ðxi1;xi2;...;xisÞT
be the input vector and Yi¼ðyi1;yi2;...;yimÞTbe the out-
put vector of DMUi. Then, the following output-oriented
CCR model can be used to evaluate the efficiency of
DMUp(p¼1;2;...;n):
max bp
s:t:Pn
i¼1liyik bpypk;k¼1;2;...;m
Pn
i¼1lixil xpl;l¼1;2;...;s
bpfree;li0;i¼1;2;...;n
8
>
<
>
:
ð3Þ
Denoting l¼ðl1;l2;...;lnÞT,Xi¼ðxi1;xi2;...;xisÞT,
Yi¼ðyi1;yi2;...;yimÞT,X¼
x11 x12 ... x1s
x21 x22 ... x2s
... ...
xn1xn2... xns
0
B
B
@1
C
C
Aand
Y¼
y11 y12 ... y1m
y21 y22 ... y2m
... ...
yn1yn1... ynm
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A;then the model (3) can be
rewritten as
max bp
s:t:
YTlbpYp
XTlXp
l0;bpfree
8
>
<
>
:
ð4Þ
In model (4), an imaginary composite unit is con-
structed, which outperforms each DMUi,lirepresents the
proportion for which DMUiis used to construct the com-
posite unit, and an efficiency score can be generated for the
DMUpby maximizing outputs with limited inputs.
According to model (4), the composite unit consumes at
most the same inputs as DMUpand produces at least bp
times outputs of DMUpwith bp1. The inverse of optimal
objective function value of model (4), 1.b
p, is the effi-
ciency score of DMUp, and DMUpis not efficient if
bp[1.
Meanwhile, the input-oriented DEA model to evaluate
alternative DMUp(p¼1;2;...;n) is as follows:
min hp
s:t:
YTlYp
XTlhpXp
l0;hpfree
8
>
<
>
:
ð5Þ
In model (5), an imaginary composite unit is also con-
structed that outperforms each DMU and an efficiency
score can be generated for the DMUpby minimizing inputs
with limited outputs. The composite unit produces at least
the same outputs as DMUpand invests at most hptimes
inputs of DMUpwith hp1. The optimal objective func-
tion value, h
p, is the efficiency score of DMUpin model
(5), and DMUpis not efficient if hp\1.
3.2 Deriving priority weight vector using DEA
In this section, we propose a CCR DEA model to derive the
priority weight vector from the fuzzy preference relation.
For a fuzzy preference relation matrix R¼ðrij Þnnon the
alternative set X¼fx1;x2;...;xng, each alternative may be
viewed as a decision-making unit (DMU), each column of
R¼ðrijÞnncan be viewed as an output. A dummy input
that takes the value of 0.5 for all the alternatives is
employed. The relationships between inputs, outputs, and
the fuzzy preference matrix R¼ðrij Þnnare shown in
Table 1.
We build the following output-oriented CCR model to
evaluate the efficiency score of alternative xp
(p¼1;2;...;n).
max bp
s:t:Pn
i¼1lirik bprpk;k¼1;2;...;n
0:5Pn
i¼1li0:5
bpfree;li0;i¼1;2;...;n
8
>
<
>
:
ð6Þ
Theorem 1 For an additive consistent fuzzy preference
matrix R ¼ðrijÞnn,the optimal solution of model (6)is b
p
(p¼1;2;...;n)and r:f1;2;...;ng!f1;2;...;ngis a
permutation, such that b
rð1Þb
rð2Þ  b
rðnÞ.Then,
Neural Comput & Applic
123
the priority vector satisfies that wrð1Þwrð2Þ  wrðnÞ,
and it can be derived by the following formulas:
(1) wrð1Þ¼nþ1
n1
nb
rð1ÞPn
p¼1
1
b
p.
(2) wrðpÞ¼wrð1Þþb
rð1Þb
rðpÞ
b
rðpÞ, for all p¼2;...;n.
Proof If R¼ðrijÞnnis an additive consistent fuzzy
preference relation, from Eq. (2), the model (6) can be
rewritten as
max bp
s:t:Pn
i¼1liðwiwkþ1Þbpðwpwkþ1Þ;k¼1;2;...;n;
Pn
i¼1li1;
bpfree;li0;i¼1;2;...;n:
8
<
:ð7Þ
Without loss of generality, it is assumed that
w1w2  wn. Then, we have wiwkþ10 and
wpwkþ10. Thus, the objective function bpis maxi-
mal if and only if the constraint Pn
i¼1li1 reduces to
equality, i.e., Pn
i¼1li¼1.
Since 0 w1wkþ1w2wkþ1  wn
wkþ1 for any k2f1;2;...;ng, from the first constraint of
model (7), it is obvious that the optimal solution is l
1¼
l
2¼¼l
n1¼0 and l
n¼1. Then, the first constraint
of model (7) becomes wnwkþ1
wpwkþ1bp;k¼1;2;...;n. Thus,
the optimal objective function value of model (7) follows
that
b
p¼min wnw1þ1
wpw1þ1;wnw2þ1
wpw2þ1;...;1
wpwnþ1

¼wnw1þ1
wpw1þ1:
ð8Þ
Since w1w2  wn, we have b
1b
2  b
n.
Therefore,
max
1pnfb
pb
1¼wnw1þ1:ð9Þ
The efficiency score of alternative xpis 1
b
p¼wpw1þ1
wnw1þ1.
Then, the sum of efficiency scores of all alternatives is
X
n
p¼1
1
b
p
¼X
n
p¼1
wpw1þ1
wnw1þ1¼nþ1nw1
wnw1þ1:ð10Þ
From Eqs. (9) and (10), we have
w1¼nþ1
nmax
1pnfb
pg1
nX
n
p¼1
1
b
p
:ð11Þ
According to Eqs. (8), (9), we also have
wp¼w1þ
max
p¼1;2;;nfb
pgb
p
b
p
;for all p¼2;...;nð12Þ
According to the Eqs. (11) and (12), the expressions of
Theorem 1 are established.
In fact, the Theorem 1 provides a new method for
deriving the priority weight vector using the proposed DEA
model for the additive fuzzy preference relation.
Example 1 For an additive consistent fuzzy preference
matrix:
R¼
0:50:525 0:55 0:525
0:475 0:50:525 0:5
0:45 0:475 0:50:475
0:475 0:50:525 0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A:
According to model (5), we can evaluate the efficiency
score of alternative x2from the following linear
programming.
max bp
s:t:
0:5l1þ0:475l2þ0:45l3þ0:475l40:475bp
0:525l1þ0:5l2þ0:475l3þ0:5l40:5bp
0:55l1þ0:525l2þ0:5l3þ0:525l40:525bp
0:525l1þ0:5l2þ0:475l3þ0:5l40:5bp
Pn
i¼1li1
bpfree;l1;l2;l3;l40
8
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
:
The optimal solution of above linear programming is
l
1¼1,b
2¼1:0476, l
2¼l
3¼l
4¼0. The efficiency
score of alternative x2is 1b
2¼0:9545. Similar, alterna-
tives x1,x2, and x3can be evaluated, and b
1¼1, b
3¼1:1,
b
4¼1:0476. So, we have b
1\b
2¼b
4\b
3,rð1Þ¼
3;rð2Þ¼2;rð3Þ¼4 and rð4Þ¼1. According to Theo-
rem 1, we have w3w2w4w1, and the priority vector
of alternative set X¼fx1;x2;x3;x4gis that
w¼ð0:30;0:25;0:20;0:25ÞT.
Table 1 Inputs and outputs of DEA about R¼ðrijÞnn
Output 1 Output 2  Output nDummy input
DMU1r11 r12  r1n0.5
DMU2r21 r22  r2n0.5
     
DMUnrn1rn2 rnn 0.5
Neural Comput & Applic
123
4 The consistency adjustment of fuzzy preference
relation
In fact, Theorem 1 cannot work for inconsistent fuzzy
preference relation. So it is necessary for us to design a
consistency adjustment algorithm.
According to the Definition 2, the additive consistency
index of additive fuzzy preference can be given as follows:
Definition 4 Assume that R¼ðrijÞnnis a fuzzy prefer-
ence relation given by an expert, we define the additive
consistency index of Ras follows:
CIðRÞ¼ ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2
nðn1ÞX
n
i¼1X
n
j¼iþ1
1
nX
n
k¼1
ðrik rjk rij þ0:5Þ2
!
v
u
u
t;
ð13Þ
where 0 CIðRÞ1.
The smaller the value of CIðRÞ, the stronger the degree
of additive consistency of the fuzzy preference relation
R¼ðrijÞnnis. It is obvious that CIðRÞ¼0 if and only if R
is an additive consistent fuzzy preference relation.
Definition 5 Let R¼ðrijÞnnbe a fuzzy preference
relation given by an expert. Given a threshold value CI, if
the additive consistency index of Rsatisfies
CIðRÞCI:
Then, the fuzzy preference relation Ris of
acceptable consistency.
The value of CI can be determined according to the
decision-makers’ preferences and the practical situations
[1,20]. In this paper, it is supposed that CI¼0:1.
For a given fuzzy preference relation R, the following
theorem provides a method to obtain a corresponding
additive consistent fuzzy preference relation.
Theorem 2 For a fuzzy preference relation R ¼ðrijÞnn,
let
R¼ð
rijÞnn,where
rij ¼
0:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rjl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=nþ0:5;
for all i;j¼1;2;...;n:
ð14Þ
Then,
Ris an additive consistent fuzzy preference
relation.
Proof Since 0 rij 1, for all i;j¼1;2;...;n, we have
0:50:5Qn
l¼1rjl

1=n
Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=n
0:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rjl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=n
þ0:50:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=n
Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=nþ0:5:
Thus, we can get
0
rij ¼
0:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rjl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=nþ0:51
for all i;j¼1;2;...;n:
Furthermore, for any i;j;k¼1;2;...;n, it follows that
rik
rjk þ0:5¼
0:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rkl
ðÞ
1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=nþ0:5
0
@1
A
0:5Qn
l¼1rjl

1=nQn
l¼1rkl
ðÞ
1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=nþ0:5
0
@1
Aþ0:5
¼
0:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rkl
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rjl

1=nþQn
l¼1rkl
ðÞ
1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=n
þ0:5
¼
0:5Qn
l¼1ril
ðÞ
1=nQn
l¼1rjl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl
ðÞ
1=nþ0:5¼
rij:
From the Definition 2,
Ris an additive consistent fuzzy
preference relation.
If the given fuzzy preference relation does not satisfy
the acceptable consistency, from the Theorem 2, a con-
sistency adjusting algorithm is proposed as follows:
Algorithm 1 Input The original individual fuzzy prefer-
ence relation R¼ðrijÞnn, the controlling parameter
h0;1Þ, and the threshold CI.Output The adjusted fuzzy
preference relation RðCÞ¼ðrðCÞ
ij Þnnand the consistency
index CIðRðCÞÞ.
Step 1 Let Rð0Þ¼ðrð0Þ
ij Þnn¼ðrijÞnn, and c¼0.
Step 2 Calculate the consistency index CIðRðcÞÞ, based
on Eq. (13).
Step 3 If CIðRðcÞÞCI, then go to step 6; otherwise, go
to the next step.
Step 4 Let
RðcÞ¼ð
rðcÞ
ij Þnn, where
rðcÞ
ij ¼
0:5Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
il

1=nQn
l¼1rðcÞ
jl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
hl

1=nþ0:5:
Neural Comput & Applic
123
Step 5 Apply the following strategy to construct a new
fuzzy preference relation Rðcþ1Þ¼ðrðcþ1Þ
ij Þnn.
rðcþ1Þ
ij ¼hrðcÞ
ij þð1hÞ
rðcÞ
ij ;ð15Þ
where h0;1Þ.Let c¼cþ1, and return to Step 2.
Step 6 End.
From Algorithm 1, we have the following theorem.
Theorem 3 Algorithm 1 is convergent. That is,
CIðRðcþ1ÞÞCIðRðcÞÞand lim
c!1 CIðRðcÞÞ¼0.
Proof From Step 5 of Algorithm 1 and Eq. (15), we have
rðcþ1Þ
ij ¼hrðcÞ
ij þð1hÞ
rðcÞ
ij ¼hrðcÞ
ij þð1hÞ
0:5Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
il

1=nQn
l¼1rðcÞ
jl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
hl

1=nþ0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
From Eq. (13), we obtain
CIðRðcþ1ÞÞ¼
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2
nðn1ÞX
n
i¼1X
n
j¼iþ1
1
nX
n
k¼1
ðrðcþ1Þ
ik rðcþ1Þ
jk rðcþ1Þ
ij þ0:5Þ2
!
v
u
u
t:
ð16Þ
where
rðcþ1Þ
ik rðcþ1Þ
jk rðcþ1Þ
ij þ0:5¼hrðcÞ
ik þð1hÞ
0:5Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
il

1=nQn
l¼1rðcÞ
kl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
hl

1=nþ0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
AhrðcÞ
jk
ð1hÞ
0:5Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
jl

1=nQn
l¼1rðcÞ
kl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
hl

1=nþ0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
hrðcÞ
ij ð1hÞ
0:5Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
il

1=nQn
l¼1rðcÞ
jl

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rðcÞ
hl

1=nþ0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
þ0:5¼hrðcÞ
ik rðcÞ
jk rðcÞ
ij þ0:5

Therefore,
CIðRðcþ1ÞÞ
¼ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2
nðn1ÞX
n
i¼1X
n
j¼iþ1
1
nX
n
k¼1
ðrðcþ1Þ
ik rðcþ1Þ
jk rðcþ1Þ
ij þ0:5Þ2
!
v
u
u
t
¼hffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2
nðn1ÞX
n
i¼1X
n
j¼iþ1
1
nX
n
k¼1
ðrðcÞ
ik rðcÞ
jk rðcÞ
ij þ0:5Þ2
!
v
u
u
t
¼hCIðRðcÞÞ:
Thus, it is obvious that CIðRðcÞÞ¼hcCIðRð0ÞÞ. Moreover,
from h0;1Þ, we can obtain that limc!1 CIðRðcÞÞ¼0.
According to Theorem 3, it is obvious that any fuzzy
preference relation with unacceptable consistency can be
transformed into an acceptable consistent fuzzy preference
relation.
5 The group decision-making method
Let D¼fd1;d2;...;dmgbe the set of decision makers or
experts, and ~
RðkÞ¼ð
~
rij;ðkÞÞnnbe the interval fuzzy pref-
erence relation provided by expert dk(k¼1;2;...;m)on
the alternative set X¼fx1;x2;...;xng. For each of the
matrices of the interval fuzzy preference relation
~
RðkÞ¼ð
~
rij;ðkÞÞnn, discrete values for the judgments are
randomly generated from the uniform distribution of the
provided interval values. Assume that rij;ðkÞis randomly
generated from the uniform distribution of ½rL
ij;ðkÞ;rU
ij;ðkÞ,
(ij;i¼1;2;...;n;j¼1;2;...;n;k¼1;2;...;m), and
rji;ðkÞ¼1rij;ðkÞ. Then, we obtain the fuzzy preference
relation RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nn, which is generated from ~
RðkÞ¼
ð~
rij;ðkÞÞnnprovided by dk(k¼1;2;...;m). Suppose that
k¼ðk1;k2;...;kmÞTis the weighting vector, in which kk
can reflect the importance degree of RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nn.
Moreover, the weighting vector satisfies kk0 and
Pm
k¼1kk¼1.
5.1 Determining weights of RðkÞbased on group
consensus
In this subsection, we develop an optimal model to cal-
culate the weights of RðkÞ(k¼1;2;...;m).
Definition 6 Let RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nn(k¼1;2;...;m)be
fuzzy preference relations. If
rc
ij ¼X
m
k¼1
kkrij;ðkÞ;for all i;j¼1;2;...;nð17Þ
then Rc¼rc
ij

nnis called the synthetic preference rela-
tion of RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nn, and kkis the weights of RðkÞ,
which satisfies kk0 and Pm
k¼1kk¼1.
The corresponding additive consistent fuzzy preference
RðkÞ¼ð
rij;ðkÞÞnnof RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nncan be obtained by
Eq. (14), where
rij;ðkÞ¼
0:5Qn
l¼1ril;ðkÞ

1=nQn
l¼1rjl;ðkÞ

1=n

Pn
h¼1Qn
l¼1rhl;ðkÞ

1=n
þ0:5;for all i;j¼1;2;...;n:
ð18Þ
Neural Comput & Applic
123
If the weighting vector of
RðkÞ¼ð
rij;ðkÞÞnnis
k¼ðk1;k2;...;kmÞT, from Definition 6, we can get the
synthetic preference relation
Rc¼
rc
ij

nn, where
rc
ij ¼X
m
k¼1
kk
rij;ðkÞ;for all i;j¼1;2;...;n:ð19Þ
Theorem 4 The synthetic preference relation
Rc¼
rc
ij

nnis an additive consistent fuzzy preference relation.
Proof According to Theorem 2,
RðkÞ¼ð
rij;ðkÞÞnnis
additive consistent, so for all i;j;s¼1;2;...;nand
k¼1;2;...;m, we have 0
rij;ðkÞ1,
rij;ðkÞþ
rji;ðkÞ¼1,
and
ris;ðkÞ
rjs;ðkÞþ0:5¼
rij;ðkÞ. Since
rc
ij ¼Pm
k¼1kk
rij;ðkÞ,
kk0 and Pm
k¼1kk¼1, it is obvious that 0
rc
ij 1 and
rc
ij þ
rc
ji ¼X
m
k¼1
kk
rij;ðkÞþ
rji;ðkÞ

¼X
m
k¼1
kk¼1:
Moreover, we can get
rc
is
rc
js þ0:5¼X
m
k¼1
kk
ris;ðkÞX
m
k¼1
kk
rjs;ðkÞþ0:5
¼X
m
k¼1
kk
ris;ðkÞ
rjs;ðkÞþ0:5

¼X
m
k¼1
kk
rij;ðkÞ¼
rc
ij:
Thus,
Rc¼
rc
ij

nnis an additive consistent fuzzy
preference relation.
The definition of compatibility degree between two
fuzzy preference relations was given by Xu [23] as follows:
Definition 7 Assume that A¼aij

nnand B¼bij

nn
are two fuzzy preference relations. The compatibility
degree between Aand Bis defined as follows:
CðA;BÞ¼ 1
n2X
n
i¼1X
n
j¼1
jaij bijj:
Inspired by Definition 7, a new definition of compati-
bility degree is defined as follows:
Definition 8 Let A¼aij

nnand B¼bij

nnbe two
fuzzy preference relations, then
CðA;BÞ¼ 1
n2X
n
i¼1X
n
j¼1
ðaij bijÞ2ð20Þ
is called the compatibility degree between Aand B.
As we can see, the compatibility degree of fuzzy pref-
erence relations Aand Bcan reflect the total difference
between Aand B. According to Definition 8, the compat-
ibility degree between
Rcand Rccan be written as follows:
CðRc;
RcÞ¼ 1
n2X
n
i¼1X
n
j¼1X
m
k¼1
kkrij;ðkÞX
m
k¼1
kk
rij;ðkÞ
!
2
¼1
n2X
n
i¼1X
n
j¼1X
m
k¼1
kkrij;ðkÞ
rij;ðkÞ

!
2
¼X
m
k1¼1X
m
k2¼1
kk1kk2
1
n2X
n
i¼1X
n
j¼1
rij;ðk1Þ
rij;ðk1Þ

rij;ðk2Þ
rij;ðk2Þ

!:
ð21Þ
The compatibility degree between
Rcand Rc, which
reflects group consensus, can measure the agreement
between the individual fuzzy preference relation and the
synthetic preference relation. The smaller the value of
CðRc;
RcÞ, the better the group consensus is.
Let E¼ek1k2
ðÞ
mm, where ek1k2¼1
n2Pn
i¼1Pn
j¼1rij;ðk1Þ
rij;ðk1ÞÞrij;ðk2Þ
rij;ðk2Þ

,i;j¼1;2;...;n. Then, Eis
called the compatibility information matrix. In particular, if
k1¼k2¼k, then ekk ¼1
n2Pn
i¼1Pn
j¼1rij;ðkÞ
rij;ðkÞ

2.
Therefore, we can obtain the following optimal model to
calculate the weights vector of RðkÞ(k¼1;2;;m) based
on group consensus:
min CðRc;
RcÞ¼kTEk
s:t:QTk¼1
k0
ð22Þ
where Q¼ð1;1;...;1ÞTand k¼ðk1;k2;...;kmÞT.
By solving the model (22), we can obtain the optimal
solution k
ksatisfying k
k0 and Pm
k¼1k
k¼1, which can
reflect the importance degree of RðkÞ(k¼1;2;...;m).
5.2 The final priority vector derived by DEA
In group decision making, although we can get the priority
vector wðkÞ¼ðw1k;w2k;...;wnk ÞTfrom fuzzy preference
relation RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nnusing Theorem 1, and calculate
the weights of RðkÞbased on model (22)(k¼1;2;...;m),
we need to develop a method to derive the final priority
vector.
In this subsection, a dual DEA model is developed to
derive the final priority weight vector from kkand the pri-
ority vectors wðkÞ¼ðw1k;w2k;;wnkÞT(k¼1;2;...;m).
The dual model of the input-oriented DEA is as follows:
Neural Comput & Applic
123
max Z¼vTYp
s:t:
uTXp¼1
uTXTvTYT0
u0;v0
8
>
<
>
:;ð23Þ
where u¼ðu1;u2;...;usÞT,v¼ðv1;v2;...;vmÞT. For
alternative set X¼fx1;x2;...;xng, each alternative may be
viewed as a decision-making unit, each priority vector
wðkÞ¼ðw1k;w2k;...;wnkÞTcan be viewed as an output. The
dummy inputs take the value of 1=nfor all the alternatives.
The relationships among inputs, outputs, and the priority
vectors wðkÞ¼ðw1k;w2k;...;wnkÞTare shown in Table 2.
From Table 2and dual model (23), we build the fol-
lowing DEA model to evaluate the efficiency score of the
alternative xpðp¼1;2;...;nÞ.
max Zp¼m1wp1þm2wp2þþmmwpm
s:t:
u11
n¼1
v1w11 þv2w12 þvmw1m1
v1w21 þv2w22 þvmw2m1

v1wn1þv2wn2þvmwnm 1
u1;v1;v2;...;vm0
8
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
:
ð24Þ
Because each output has different importance degree with
the weighting vector k¼ðk1;k2;;kmÞT.Letvi¼v1ki
k1
(i¼1;2;...;m), then model (24) can be rewritten as follows:
max Zp¼m1
k1
k1wp1þk2wp2þþkmwpm

s:t:
u11
n¼1
m1
k1
k1w11 þk2w12 þþkmw1m
ðÞ1
m1
k1
k1w21 þk2w22 þþkmw2m
ðÞ1

m1
k1
k1wn1þk2wn2þþkmwnm
ðÞ1
u1;v1;v2;...;vm0
8
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
:ð25Þ
If we evaluate different alternatives based on model
(25), the DEA models have the same optimal solution m
1,
which satisfies
max
i¼1;2;;n
m
1
k1
k1wi1þk2wi2þþkmwim
ðÞ

¼1:
Then, the optimal objective function value of model (25)
is Z
p¼m
1Pm
i¼1
ki
k1wpi. Thus, the final weight of each
alternative can be calculated by
wi¼Z
i
Pn
p¼1Z
p
;i¼1;2;...;n:ð26Þ
5.3 The stochastic group decision-making method
Since fuzzy preference relation is a special case of interval
fuzzy preference relation, we propose a stochastic group
preference analysis (SGPA) method by analyzing the group
preference relations space.
Let nbe a set of random variables, where n¼fnij;ðkÞ:
i;j¼1;2;...;n;i\j;k¼1;2;...;mg,nij;ðkÞsatisfies
uniform distribution in ~
rij;ðkÞ¼½rL
ij;ðkÞ;rU
ij;ðkÞ.~
R¼
~
rij;ðkÞji;j¼1;2;...;n;k¼1;2;...;m

is the interval
preference relation, and fðnij;ðkÞÞis the probability density
function of nij;ðkÞ, where nij;ðkÞis the judgments of xiover xj
provided by expert dk(k¼1;2;...;m).
For n, it is assumed that wðnÞis the corresponding final
priority vector. Inspired by Zhu and Xu [30], we provide a
ranking function, which is defined as follows:
RankiðwðnÞÞ¼1þX
n
k¼1
dðwðnÞ
k[wðnÞ
iÞ¼r;ð27Þ
where the rank of xiis r,dðtrueÞ¼1, and dðfalseÞ¼0.
Moreover, the Eq. (27) defines a group preference relations
space Rr
iðnÞ.
Rr
iðnÞ¼fn2~
RjrankiðwðnÞÞ¼1þX
n
k¼1
dðwðnÞ
k[wðnÞ
iÞ¼rg:
ð28Þ
According to the final priority weights vector wðnÞand
the probability density function fðnÞ, we can obtain the
expected priority vector of the alternative set
X¼fx1;x2;...;xng:
Table 2 Inputs, outputs, and
the priority vectors Output 1 (d1) Output 2 (d2) Output m(dm) Dummy input
DMU1w11 w12  w1m1=n
DMU2w21 w22  w2m1=n
     
DMUnwn1wn2 wnm 1=n
Neural Comput & Applic
123
EðwðnÞÞ¼Z~
R
fðnÞwðnÞdn:ð29Þ
From EðwðnÞÞ, we further get the expected rank of
xiði¼1;2;;nÞ, which can be computed as follows:
Ranke
i¼1þX
n
k¼1
dðEðwðnÞÞk[EðwðnÞÞiÞ;ð30Þ
where EðwðnÞÞkis the kth component of EðwðnÞÞ.
Moreover, a probability measure is defined to describe
the confidence degree of the expected rank, which can
reflect the probability that the group receives the expected
rank.
pe
i¼Zn:rankiðwðnÞÞ¼EðriÞ
fðnÞdn:ð31Þ
In conclusion, to get the expected priority vector and the
associated confidence degree in group decision making
with interval fuzzy preference relations, the following steps
are involved:
Step 1 The expert group fd1;d2;...;dmggive their
interval fuzzy preference relations ~
RðkÞ¼ð
~
rij;ðkÞÞnn
(i;j¼1;2;...;n;k¼1;2;...;m) on the alternative set
X¼fx1;x2;...;xng, respectively.
Step 2 Obtain the fuzzy preference relation matrices
RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nn,(k¼1;2;...;m), which generated
from ~
RðkÞ¼ð
~
rij;ðkÞÞnn, where rij;ðkÞis randomly gener-
ated from the uniform distribution of ½rL
ij;ðkÞ;rU
ij;ðkÞ,(ij;
i¼1;2;...;n;j¼1;2;...;n;k¼1;2;...;m), and
rji;ðkÞ¼1rij;ðkÞ.
Step 3 Transform RðkÞ¼rij;ðkÞ

nn(k¼1;2;...;m) into
acceptable consistent fuzzy preference relations
RðCÞ
ðkÞ¼rðCÞ
ij;ðkÞ

nn(k¼1;2;...;m) according to Algo-
rithm 1, and calculate k¼ðk1;k2;...;kmÞT, which is the
weight vector of fRð1Þ;Rð2Þ;...;RðmÞgaccording to
model (22).
Step 4 Compute the priority vector wðkÞ¼
ðw1k;w2k;...;wnkÞTof RðCÞ
ðkÞ¼rðCÞ
ij;ðkÞ

nnaccording to
Theorem 1 (k¼1;2;...;m).
Step 5 Obtain the final priority vector w¼
ðw1;w2;...;wnÞTaccording to model (25) and Eq. (26).
Step 6 Repeat the Step 2-Step 5 Ntimes, and execute
stochastic simulation to get the outcomes of SGPA, i.e.,
EðwðnÞÞ, ranke
iand pe
i.
In order to determine the proper number of iterations in
stochastic simulation process, Pula [14] introduced a gen-
eral method based on Kolmogorov’s inequality. Let
j0¼min j1
e2P1
k¼j
2k
2k\d
no
, where eis simulation error, d
is the expected accuracy. Then, the required number of
iterations is N¼2j01. Especially, when e¼0:01,
d¼0:072, then j0¼11 and N¼210 ¼1024:
The process is shown in Fig. 1.
6 Numerical example
In this section, the proposed group decision-making
method is used to evaluate four candidates fx1;x2;x3;x4g
for a chair professor position. The numerical example is
implemented in Matlab.
Assume that there are four interval fuzzy preference
relations ~
Rð1Þ,~
Rð2Þ,~
Rð3Þ, and ~
Rð4Þgiven by the experts d1,
d2,d3, and d4, respectively, which are shown as follows:
~
Rð1Þ¼
½0:5;0:5½0:6;0:7½0:6;0:7½0:3;0:4
½0:3;0:4½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:6½0:2;0:3
½0:3;0:4½0:4;0:5½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:6
½0:6;0:7½0:7;0:8½0:4;0:5½0:5;0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
~
Rð2Þ¼
½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:6½0:6;0:7½0:3;0:4
½0:4;0:5½0:5;0:5½0:7;0:7½0:2;0:4
½0:3;0:4½0:3;0:3½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:6
½0:6;0:7½0:6;0:8½0:4;0:5½0:5;0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
~
Rð3Þ¼
½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:7½0:7;0:9½0:3;0:5
½0:3;0:5½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:7½0:2;0:4
½0:1;0:3½0:3;0:5½0:5;0:5½0:5;0:6
½0:5;0:7½0:6;0:8½0:4;0:5½0:5;0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
~
Rð4Þ¼
½0:5;0:5½0:6;0:7½0:7;0:8½0:3;0:4
½0:6;0:7½0:5;0:5½0:6;0:7½0:2;0:3
½0:2;0:3½0:3;0:4½0:5;0:5½0:7;0:8
½0:3;0:4½0:7;0:8½0:2;0:3½0:5;0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A
Let the threshold value CI ¼0:1, and execute stochastic
group preference analysis according to Step 1–Step 6.
According to Monte Carlo simulation, the obtained EðwðnÞÞ
are shown in Table 3with different number of iterations.
From Table 3, when the number of iterations is equal or
greater than 160,EðwðnÞÞis robust. The outcomes of SGPA are
shown in Table 4with the number of iterations being 1024.
Moreover, Fig. 2shows the confidence degrees of the
four candidates for each rank by a three-dimensional col-
umn chart.
From the expected priority vector EðwðnÞÞwith the
number of iterations being 500, the rank of four candidates
is x4x1x2x3. As we can see, x4is the best candi-
date. Meanwhile, if the expected rank has high confidence
degree, the expected rank should be reliable. Particularly,
x4is the best alternative with 0.930 confidence degree.
Neural Comput & Applic
123
Chen and Zhou [4] proposed an approach to group decision
making based on IGCOWA operator. If we apply Chen and
Zhou’s method to this example, when the BUM function
QðyÞ¼y2, the attitudinal character of Q is k¼1
3. Then, the
expected value fuzzy preference relations FQð~
RðkÞÞof ~
RðkÞ
(k¼1;2;3;4) are derived based on OWA operator as follows:
FQð~
Rð1ÞÞ¼
0:50:6333 0:6333 0:3333
0:3667 0:50:5333 0:2333
0:3667 0:4667 0:50:5333
0:6667 0:7667 0:4667 0:5
0
B
B
B
@1
C
C
C
A;
FQð~
Rð2ÞÞ¼
0:50:60:6333 0:3333
0:40:50:70:2667
0:3667 0:30:50:5333
0:6667 0:7333 0:4667 0:5
0
B
B
B
@1
C
C
C
A;
FQð~
Rð3ÞÞ¼
0:50:5667 0:7667 0:3667
0:4333 0:50:5667 0:2667
0:2333 0:4333 0:50:5333
0:6333 0:7333 0:4667 0:5
0
B
B
B
@1
C
C
C
A;
FQð~
Rð4ÞÞ¼
0:50:6333 0:7333 0:3333
0:3667 0:50:6333 0:2333
0:2667 0:3667 0:50:7333
0:6667 0:7667 0:2667 0:5
0
B
B
B
@1
C
C
C
A:
From Eqs. (31) and (32) in Chen and Zhou [4], it is
assumed that c¼0:5, we get the collective fuzzy prefer-
ence relations matrix A¼ðaijÞ44, i.e.,
(1)
R
(2)
R
()m
R
()
(1) ,(1)ij nn
Rr
×
=
()
(2) ,(2)ij nn
Rr
×
=
()
() ,()mijm
nn
Rr
×
=
Obtain the weight vector
of preference relationships
according to model (22)
12
(, , , )
T
m
λλλ λ
=
()
,1,2,,
k
Rk m=
Consistency adjustment
according to Algorithm 1
()
() ()
(1) ,(1)ij nn
Rr
ΓΓ
×
=
()
() ()
(2) ,(2)ij nn
Rr
ΓΓ
×
=
()
() ()
() ,()mijm
nn
Rr
ΓΓ
×
=
Obtain the priority vector
based on Theorem 1
(1) 11 1
(,, )
T
n
ww w=
(2) 12 2
(,, )
T
n
www=
() 1
(,, )
T
mmnm
www=
Obtain the final weights
according to Model (25)
and Eq. (26)
12
(, ,, )
T
n
www w=
Obtain the expected
priority vector
and the associated
confidence degree
according to stochastic
simulation
()
()Ew
ξ
e
i
p
Fig. 1 Group decision-making method based on DEA and stochastic simulation
Table 3 Expected priority vector EðwðnÞÞwith different number of
iterations
Number of iterations EðwðnÞÞ
EðwðnÞÞ1EðwðnÞÞ2EðwðnÞÞ3EðwðnÞÞ4
40 0.2649 0.2251 0.2219 0.2879
80 0.2664 0.2251 0.2193 0.2891
120 0.2658 0.2261 0.2193 0.2887
160 0.2657 0.2263 0.2192 0.2886
200 0.2659 0.2268 0.2187 0.2885
240 0.2661 0.2270 0.2185 0.2882
280 0.2663 0.2258 0.2190 0.2887
320 0.2666 0.2253 0.2195 0.2885
360 0.2666 0.2252 0.2195 0.2886
400 0.2664 0.2256 0.2194 0.2886
440 0.2665 0.2252 0.2194 0.2887
480 0.2667 0.2251 0.2193 0.2888
520 0.2668 0.2251 0.2194 0.2886
560 0.2669 0.2251 0.2194 0.2884
600 0.2669 0.2251 0.2194 0.2884
640 0.2669 0.2246 0.2197 0.2885
680 0.2668 0.2250 0.2194 0.2885
720 0.2667 0.2248 0.2197 0.2886
760 0.2666 0.2247 0.2198 0.2887
800 0.2665 0.2253 0.2195 0.2885
840 0.2666 0.2253 0.2195 0.2884
880 0.2666 0.2252 0.2196 0.2884
920 0.2667 0.2254 0.2195 0.2883
960 0.2666 0.2255 0.2195 0.2884
1000 0.2666 0.2255 0.2195 0.2884
Table 4 Outcomes of SGPA
with the number of iterations
being 1024
EðwðnÞÞRanke
ipe
i
x10.2666 2 0.908
x20.2255 3 0.550
x30.2195 4 0.572
x40.2884 1 0.930
Neural Comput & Applic
123
A¼
0:50:5996 0:6512 0:3265
0:4004 0:50:5885 0:2531
0:3488 0:4115 0:50:5519
0:6735 0:7469 0:4481 0:5
0
B
B
@1
C
C
A:
According to A, we obtain the priority vector
w¼ð0:2564;0:2284;0:2343;2806ÞT. Thus, x4x1
x2x3. The obtained result is in accordance with those
given by the proposed method in this paper.
From the above examples, one can see that our proposed
method and Chen and Zhou’s method can derive the same
ranking result. Chen and Zhou’s method translates four
interval fuzzy preference relations into a collective fuzzy
preference relations matrix, and this procedure may lead to
decision information loss. On the other hand, sometimes
the collective fuzzy preference relations matrix is not
consistent. The group decision-making method based on
compatibility given in Zhou et al. [28] also has these
weaknesses.
Meanwhile, our proposed method has several desirable
properties. First, it can avoid information loss by stochastic
simulation. Second, the weights of preference relation
generated from each interval fuzzy preference relations are
derived by group consensus. Third, our method includes an
effective consistency adjustment algorithm, it can address
inconsistent cases. Finally, the confidence degrees of
ranking results are given.
7 Conclusion
We have proposed a new approach to group decision
making with interval fuzzy preference relations using data
envelopment analysis (DEA) and stochastic simulation.
The advantage of the developed approach is that it can
avoid information loss.
A new output-oriented CCR DEA model is proposed to
obtain the priority vector for the consistency fuzzy pref-
erence relation, where each of the alternatives is viewed as
a decision-making unit (DMU). Meanwhile, a consistency
adjustment algorithm is designed for the inconsistent fuzzy
preference relations. Then, we build an optimization model
to yield the weights of each fuzzy preference relation based
on maximizing group consensus. Moreover, an input-ori-
ented DEA model is introduced to obtain the final priority
vector of the alternatives. We further develop a stochastic
group preference analysis (SGPA) method by analyzing the
judgments space, which is carried out by Monte Carlo
simulation. The proposed approach is verified by a
numerical example.
Fig. 2 Confidence degrees of
the four candidates
Neural Comput & Applic
123
Future research should, in the authors’ opinion, focus on
further extensions of the SGPA such as the use of interval
linguistic group decision making.
Acknowledgements The work was supported by National Natural
Science Foundation of China (Nos. 71501002, 61502003, 71371011,
71771001, 71701001) and Anhui Provincial Natural Science Foun-
dation (Nos. 1508085QG149, 1608085QF133).
Compliance with ethical standards
Conflict of interest The authors declare that they have no conflict of
interest.
References
1. Aguaro
´n J, Moreno-Jime
´nez JM (2003) The geometric consis-
tency index: approximated thresholds. Eur J Oper Res
147:137–145
2. Bentkowska U, Bustince H, Jurio A, Pagola M, Pekala B (2015)
Decision making with an interval-valued fuzzy preference rela-
tion and admissible orders. Appl Soft Comput 35:792–801
3. Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the effi-
ciency of decision making units. Eur J Oper Res 2(6):429–444
4. Chen H, Zhou L (2011) An approach to group decision making
with interval fuzzy preference relations based on induced gen-
eralized continuous ordered weighted averaging operator. Expert
Syst Appl 38(10):13432–13440
5. Dong Y, Xu Y, Li H (2008) On consistency measures of lin-
guistic preference relations. Eur J Oper Res 189:430–444
6. Fernandez E, Leyva JC (2004) A method based on multiobjective
optimization for deriving a ranking from a fuzzy preference
relation. Eur J Oper Res 154:110–124
7. Gong Z, Xu X, Zhang H, Ozturk UA, Herrera-Viedma E, Xu C
(2015) The consensus models with interval preference opinions
and their economic interpretation. Omega 55:81–90
8. Herrera-Viedma E, Herrera F, Chiclana F, Luque M (2004) Some
issues on consistency of fuzzy preference relations. Eur J Oper
Res 154(1):98–109
9. Kacprzyk J (1986) Group decision making with a fuzzy linguistic
majority. Fuzzy Sets Syst 18(2):105–118
10. Liao H, Xu Z (2014) Priorities of intuitionistic fuzzy preference
relation based on multiplicative consistency. IEEE Trans Fuzzy
Syst 22(6):1669–1681
11. Ma J, Fan ZP, Jiang YP, Mao JY, Ma L (2006) A method for
repairing the inconsistency of fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy
Sets Syst 157(1):20–33
12. Orlovsky SA (1978) Decision-making with a fuzzy preference
relation. Fuzzy Sets Syst 1:155–167
13. Pe
´rez-Ferna
´ndez R, Alonso P, Bustince H, Dı
´az I, Montes S
(2016) Applications of finite interval-valued hesitant fuzzy
preference relations in group decision making. Inf Sci
326:89–101
14. Pula W (1985) On the accuracy of calculation of probability by
simulation method. In: Proc. Conf. Mathematical Method in
Technology Poland
15. Tanino T (1984) Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision
making. Fuzzy Sets Syst 12:117–131
16. Wang YM, Fan ZP, Hua Z (2007) A chi square method for
obtaining a priority vector from multiplicative and fuzzy prefer-
ence relations. Eur J Oper Res 182(1):356–366
17. Wang YM, Parkan C (2005) Multiple attribute decision making
based on fuzzy preference information on alternatives: ranking
and weighting. Fuzzy Sets Syst 153:331–346
18. Wu DD (2009) Performance evaluation: an integrated method
using data envelopment analysis and fuzzy preference relations.
Eur J Oper Res 194(1):227–235
19. Wu J, Chiclana F (2014) A social network analysis trust–con-
sensus based approach to group decision-making problems with
interval-valued fuzzy reciprocal preference relations. Knowl-
Based Syst 59(2):97–107
20. Xia M, Xu Z, Chen J (2013) Algorithms for improving consis-
tency or consensus of reciprocal [0,1]-valued preference rela-
tions. Fuzzy Sets Syst 216:108–133
21. Xia M, Chen J (2015) Studies on interval multiplicative prefer-
ence relations and their application to group decision making.
Group Decis Negot 24(1):1–30
22. Xu ZS, Chen J (2008) Some models for deriving the priority
weights from interval fuzzy preference relations. Eur J Oper Res
184:266–280
23. Xu ZS (2002) Research on compatibility and consistency of fuzzy
complementary judgment matrices. J PLA Univ Sci Technol
3(2):94–96
24. Xu Z (2004) On compatibility of interval fuzzy preference rela-
tions. Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 3:217–225
25. Xu Z, Cai X (2010) Uncertain power average operators for
aggregating interval fuzzy preference relations. Group Decis
Negot 21(3):381–397
26. Xu ZS, Da QL (2005) A least deviation method to obtain a pri-
ority vector of a fuzzy preference relation. Eur J Oper Res
164:206–216
27. Zhang H (2016) Group decision making based on multiplicative
consistent reciprocal preference relations. Fuzzy Sets Syst
282(1):31–46
28. Zhou LG, He YD, Chen HY, Liu JP (2014) Compatibility of
interval fuzzy preference relations with the COWA operator and
its application to group decision making. Soft Comput
18:2283–2295
29. Zhu B, Xu Z (2014) A fuzzy linear programming method for
group decision making with additive reciprocal fuzzy preference
relations. Fuzzy Sets Syst 246(4):19–33
30. Zhu B, Xu Z (2014) Stochastic preference analysis in numerical
preference relations. Eur J Oper Res 237(2):628–633
31. Zhu B, Xu Z, Xu J (2013) Deriving a ranking from hesitant fuzzy
preference relations under group decision making. IEEE Trans
Cybern 44(8):1328–1337
Neural Comput & Applic
123
... Kao and Liu [26] applied DEA model to derive the order of alternatives and applied it to the case of robot selection. Combined IFPRs with DEA method, Liu et al. [27] proposed a novel DEA model for the priority weight vector derivation. ...
... For example, Qian and Feng [32] derived the consistent FPRs by utilizing a convergent iterative algorithm, but all elements of the original FPR matrix are changed in the iterative process, and then the adjusted FPRs with acceptable consistency cannot represent the evaluation information of DMs. Likewise, Liu et al. [27]'s method damaged the initial preference values of DM in the process of consistency-improving, and all elements of the original FPR are revised. Lee [33] proposed a method to construct FPRs that satisfy additive consistency and order consistency, but the method cannot guarantee the constructed FPRs are acceptable for DMs, and the obtained results will decrease the satisfaction degree of DMs. ...
... Consequently, the input-oriented CCR DEA model can be utilized to derive the priority weights of alternatives. Lastly, the difference between our CCR DEA model and the existing literature is that this DEA model is input-oriented, while most of the existing literature is output-oriented, such as [27,34,41]. Deriving the weights of alternatives by input-oriented CCR DEA model not only enriches the existing research, but also provides a simple and convenient way to generate the rankings of alternatives. ...
Article
Owing to the uncertainty and vagueness of practical decision-making problems, it is more convenient for decision-makers (DMs) to express evaluation information with fuzzy preference relations (FPRs) than precise numerical values. As two important issues in the decision-making process with FPRs, improving consistency and acquiring the priority weights are worth further studying. In this paper, we first provide an approach for constructing the FPR with multiplicative consistency, and then an algorithm of improving consistency is presented to generate an acceptable FPR, in which the initial evaluation information is retained to the largest extent through the local adjustment strategy. Then, an input-oriented CCR DEA model is developed to derive the priority weight vector of alternatives, which is followed that a DEA cross-efficiency model is constructed to discriminate multiple DEA efficient DMUs. Subsequently, the complete rankings of alternatives can be generated by a novel DEA-driven decision-making method. Finally, a numerical example is proposed to verify the feasibility and effectiveness of the developed method. The advantages of the developed method are performed by comparative analysis and sensitivity analysis.
... Then, Chen et al. [23] thought that Lee's [22] method has some drawbacks and further gave an improved GDM method. Liu et al. [24] proposed a consistency adjustment algorithm about the original inconsistent FPRs to make the consistency level of the given FPR acceptable. Ma et al. [25] studied an algorithm to repair the inconsistency of FPRs with strict comparison information, which preserved the original preference of DM as much as possible. ...
... In recent years, data envelopment analysis (DEA) is also a popular method for deriving priority weights. To determine the priority vector for the consistent FPRs, Liu et al. [24] proposed an output-oriented DEA model. Wang et al. [31] proposed a new DEA method for determining priority in the analytic hierarchy process (AHP). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper aims to develop a novel decision-making method with interval type-2 trapezoidal fuzzy preference (IT2TrFPR), which can deal with the complex decision information presented in the form of interval type-2 trapezoidal fuzzy numbers. In this paper, we mainly propose a novel interval type-2 trapezoidal fuzzy decision-making method with local consistency adjustment strategy and data envelopment analysis (DEA). Considering the harm of fog-haze pollution to the environment and human life, we apply the decision-making method to the problem about influence factors of for-haze weather. Firstly, we introduce the definition of IT2TrFPR that sufficiently expresses the uncertainty of original decision-making information. After that, we show the definition of the order consistency and additive consistency for IT2TrFPR. Considering that the original IT2TrFPR given by decision-makers usually does not satisfy the characteristic of consistency, to transform the unacceptable additive consistent IT2TrFPRs into acceptable ones, we design a consistency-improving algorithm that uses the local adjustment approach to preserve the original decision-making information as much as possible and avoids the original information loss. Then, an output-oriented interval type-2 trapezoidal fuzzy DEA model and the concept for quasi interval type-2 trapezoidal fuzzy priority weight are developed to derive the interval type-2 trapezoidal fuzzy priority weight vector (IT2TrFPW) and obtain the final ranking result of alternatives. Finally, the effectiveness of the proposed decision-making method is demonstrated by a numerical example of selecting the most crucial fog-haze influence factor. Meanwhile, we also conduct a comparative analysis by comparing our method with the existing methods to show some merits of the proposed method.
... In order to get the priority vector from the FPR, Liu et al. [28] constructed an output-oriented CCR model, which is helpful to avoid the loss of information. Nevertheless, this method only reflects self-efficiency. ...
Article
Full-text available
Probabilistic linguistic preference relation (PLPR) is an effective tool for decision-makers (DMs) to express their preferences in the decision-making process. However, the preferences provided by DMs may be inconsistent, which may lead to unreasonable decision-making results. Therefore, this paper proposes a group decision-making (GDM) method with PLPRs based on a consistency improvement algorithm and an improved multiplicative data envelopment analysis (DEA) model. For a given inconsistent PLPR, we first propose an optimization model to obtain a complete consistent PLPR. And then we use the proposed consistency adjustment algorithm to get a PLPR with acceptable consistency. Subsequently, we develop a transformation function that can transform PLPRs into multiplicative preference relations (MPRs). Furthermore, we put forward an improved multiplicative DEA model to obtain the priority vector of MPR, and the reliable ranking order of all alternatives is determined. Finally, a numerical example of cold storage construction for storing fresh products is presented to show the effectiveness and applicability of the proposed GDM method.
... The game cross-efficiency model proposed by Liang [14,15] not only improved the division of evaluation results but also improved the credibility of the evaluation result by introducing game theory. This model and its improved model have been widely applied in system efficiency evaluation [16][17][18][19][20][21][22], but there are also shortcomings in the slow convergence speed and the unique evaluation results. For the concept of system competition, Liu et al. [23], based on the game cross-efficiency model, proposed an aggressive game cross-efficiency model, which improved convergence speed and evaluation results discrimination. ...
Article
Full-text available
To solve the problem of regional water system evaluation, this paper proposes a system efficiency evaluation method based on the game cross-efficiency model and conducts an empirical analysis. First, autopoiesis is introduced as the theoretical basis. The characteristics of the authigenic system are combined with a regional water system, and the connotation and characteristics of the regional water system are defined. Second, based on the competitive relationship between regional water systems, the existing game crossover efficiency model is improved. A crossover efficiency model of other games is proposed to evaluate the efficiency of regional water systems. Then, the Pearl River Delta urban agglomeration is selected as the research object. The effects of four systematic evaluation methods based on the DEA method are compared horizontally to find the optimal system efficiency evaluation method. Finally, the characteristics of the regional water system in the Pearl River Delta are systematically analysed through the evaluation results, and the present situation of the regional water system is fully explained.
... According to available information, three critical flaws in the existing approaches to consistency measurement are evident: (1) Most established research focused on the preference for numerical expression, while preference for linguistic expression represents the minority of studies [39][40][41][42][43][44][45][46]. (2) Due to the complex normalization process and calculation procedure, these methods [47][48][49][50][51] necessitate the transformation of numerous elements, which may cause loss of original data. ...
Article
Full-text available
With the rapid development of the economy, the competition among enterprises is increasingly intensifying and the internal contradictions of the enterprise are prominent, which pose many challenges to the sustainable development of small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). Therefore, the scientific assessment of an enterprise’s sustainable development capability is important, as it reflects the current development status and the potential future opportunities. Hesitant fuzzy linguistic preference relations (HFLPRs), a combination of linguistic term sets and hesitant fuzzy preference relations are useful in solving group decision-making (GDM) problems. HFLTS can tackle situations in which decision makers (DMs) consider multiple potential linguistic terms at the same time than a single term for an indicator, alternative, variable, etc., to express their preferences without the use of numerical values. This paper introduces a new GDM approach under the hesitant fuzzy linguistic environment based on a multiplicative consistency adjustment algorithm and a Charnes-Cooper-Rhodes Data Envelopment Analysis (CCR-DEA) model to assess the sustainable development of SMEs. First, the concepts of HFLPR and multiplicative consistency, including the consistency index and consistency checking approach, are reviewed. Then, a new consistency-improving method for achieving an acceptable HFLPR is introduced, which ensures that each HFLPR satisfies the requirements for multiplicative consistency. After this transformation, an innovative CCR-DEA model is developed using the input–output technique to determine the final ranking of alternatives and to achieve an optimal decision-making solution. Finally, the hesitant fuzzy linguistic decision-making method is intended to be used to assess the economic growth of SMEs. The advantages and applicability of the proposed approach are determined by comparative analysis.
Article
Interval additive preference relations (IAPRs) provide a valuable framework for representing uncertain pairwise comparisons among alternatives in group decisionmaking (GDM). Conventional GDM methods that incorporate IAPRs often treat preference values as uniform entities and establish dedicated conflict or consensus mechanisms for amalgamating individual opinions while overlooking the stochastic preferences and lacking the flexibility to address diverse decision requirements. Therefore, to account for the stochastic characteristics in both preference representation and group preference aggregation, this paper introduces a innovative double stochastic preference analysis for GDM with IAPRs. In the initial phase, the methodology entails the extraction of stochastic additive preference relations (SAPRs) from the provided IAPRs. Subsequently, a best preference matrix is constructed by applying a logarithmic consistency minimum deviation model to the SAPRs. In the second phase, it involves the synthesis of preference comparison intervals, which encapsulate the collective viewpoints of decision makers. The preference ranking degrees are computed through an algorithm that evaluates the pairwise comparisons between alternatives, ultimately leading to the determination of optimal preference rankings. Further steps encompass the derivation of ranking acceptability indices and preference confidence degrees through a continuous extraction process. This process contributes to the establishment of the final preference rankings. The effectiveness and validity of the proposed method are demonstrated through numerical examples and Monte Carlo simulations.
Article
Multiplicative probabilistic linguistic preference relation (MPLPR) has been widely used by decision-makers (DMs) to tackle group decision-making (GDM) problems. However, due to the complexity of the decision-making circumstance and individual subjectivity of DMs, they often provide inconsistent MPLPRs which often lead to unreasonable decision results. To solve this problem, this paper investigates a novel approach to GDM with MPLPRs based on consistency improvement and upgraded multiplicative data envelopment analysis (DEA) cross-efficiency. First, the concept of sequential consistency of MPLPR is defined. Then, a consistency improvement algorithm is proposed, which can convert any unacceptable consistent MPLPR into an acceptable one. Furthermore, we use geometric averages to transform MPLPR into multiplicative preference relation (MPR). Meanwhile, considering the conservative psychology of DMs, an upgraded multiplicative DEA cross-efficiency model based on the pessimistic criterion is constructed, which can derive the priority vector of MPLPR. Therefore, we can obtain the rational ranking results for all alternatives. Finally, a case analysis of emergency logistics under COVID-19 is provided to illustrate the validity and applicability of the proposed approach.
Article
Full-text available
Interval linguistic term (ILT) is highly useful to express decision-makers’ (DMs’) uncertain preferences in the decision-making process. This paper proposes a new group decision-making (GDM) method with interval linguistic fuzzy preference relations (ILFPRs) by integrating ordinal consistency improvement algorithm, cooperative game, Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) cross-efficiency model, and stochastic simulation. Firstly, the ordinal consistency of ILFPR is developed. For improving the ordinal consistency of an ILFPR, a two-stage integer optimization model is presented to derive an ILFPR with ordinal consistency. Then, a weight-determination method for obtaining DMs’ weights is presented based on cooperative games. Moreover, a DEA cross-efficiency model is presented to obtain the priorities of linguistic preference relation derived from ILFPR. Meanwhile, the expected ranking vector of ILFPR is obtained based on the DEA cross-efficiency model by integrating stochastic preference analysis and Monte Carlo stochastic simulation. Finally, a numerical example of emergency logistics selection illustrates the applicability and credibility of the proposed method.
Article
Faced with complex decision problems, Distribution linguistic preference relation (DLPR) is an effective way for decision-makers (DMs) to express preference information. However, due to the complexity of the decision-making environment, DMs may not be able to provide complete linguistic distribution for all linguistic terms in DLPRs, which results in incomplete DLPRs. Therefore, in order to solve group decision-making (GDM) with incomplete DLPRs, this paper proposes expected consistency-based model and multiplicative DEA cross-efficiency. For a given incomplete DLPRs, we first propose an optimization model to obtain complete DLPR. This optimization model can evaluate the missing linguistic distribution and ensure that the obtained DLPR has a high consistency level. And then, we develop a transformation function that can transform DLPRs into multiplicative preference relations (MPRs). Furthermore, we design an improved multiplicative DEA model to obtain the priority vector of MPR for ranking all alternatives. Finally, a numerical example is provided to show the rationality and applicability of the proposed GDM method.
Article
Full-text available
Preference relations are the most common representation structures of information used in decision making problems because they are useful tool in modelling decision processes, above all when we want to aggregate experts' pref-erences into group preferences. Therefore, to establish rationality properties to be verified by preference relations is very important in the design of good decision making models. There are three fundamental and hierarchical levels of rationality assumptions when dealing with preference relations: the first one requires indif-ference between any alternative and itself, the second one assumes the property of reciprocity in the pairwise comparison between any two alternatives, and the third one is associated with the transitivity in the pairwise comparison among any three alternatives. Furthermore, it would also be desirable to maintain the ratio-nality assumptions on the individual preferences in the aggregation process, so that the collective preferences verify the same ones. However, as this is not always the case, establishing conditions that guarantee the preservation of these rationality properties throughout the aggregation process becomes very important. In this article we address this problem and present a review of the main results that we have obtained about reciprocity and consistency properties of fuzzy pref-erence relations. In particular, we present a characterization of fuzzy consistency based on the additive transitivity property which facilitates the verification of con-sistency in the case of fuzzy preference relations. Using this new characterization we give a method to construct consistent fuzzy preference relations from n−1 given preference values. We also discuss some questions concerning the compatibility be-tween the three levels of rationality, as well as the conflict that appears between the additive consistency property and the scale used to provide fuzzy preferences. Finally, we provide aggregation operators that provide reciprocal and consistent col-lective preference relations when the individual preference relations are reciprocal and consistent.
Article
This paper considers parametric preference orderings in group decision making. Some families of parametric group preference orderings are defined on the basis of three wellknown preference aggregation rules; the sum of individual utilities, the Rawls maximin rule and the Nash bargaining solution function. They have some desirable properties such as monotonicity along with meaningful parameters, and therefore help the group of decision makers understand the present situation objectively and proceed the decision making process smoothly. Thus considering the parametric preference orderings suggested in this paper is an effective approach to group decision making or consensus formation.
Article
The main aim of this paper is to investigate the consistency and consensus of multiplicative consistent reciprocal preference relations. Based on the multiplicative consistency property, a straightforward method to obtain the priority vector for multiplicative consistent reciprocal preference relation is introduced together with some of its desired properties. In addition, some interesting properties on consistency and consensus for reciprocal preference relations are further investigated. A consensus optimization model for group decision making with reciprocal preference relations is proposed, which enables the decision makers reach consensus with the highest overall consensus level. Numerical examples are provided to make a discussion and comparison with some existing similar methods.
Article
In this paper we analyze under which conditions we must use interval-valued fuzzy relations in decision making problems. We propose an algorithm to select the best alternative from a set of solutions which have been calculated with the nondominance algorithm using intervals and different linear orders among them. Based on the study made by Orlovsky in his work about nondominance, we study a characterization of weak transitive and 0.5-transitive interval-valued fuzzy relations, as well as the conditions under which transitivity is preserved by some operators on those relations. Next, we study the case of interval-valued reciprocal relations. In particular, we describe the preservation of reciprocity by different operators and analyze the transitivity properties for these interval-valued reciprocal relations. Finally, we propose to use, in the nondominance algorithm, linear interval orders generated by means of operators which preserve transitivity.
Article
The intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation (IFPR), whose elements are intuitionistic fuzzy values (IFVs), is more powerful than the traditional multiplicative preference relation and the fuzzy preference relation in expressing comprehensive preference information of a decision maker. The aim of this paper is to investigate a new approach to derive the priority weights from an IFPR. To do so, we give a new definition of multiplicative consistent IFPR, which is based on the membership and nonmembership degrees of the intuitionistic fuzzy judgments. After that, a formula, which involves the underlying intuitionistic fuzzy weights of the IFPR, is proposed to construct such a multiplicative consistent IFPR. Based on the formula, some fractional programming models are built to generate the intuitionistic fuzzy priority weighting vector of the IFPR. Several numerical examples are given to illustrate the validity and applicability of the proposed method.
Article
The consistency of interval multiplicative preference relations is studied and applied to group decision making. Weak transitivity for interval multiplicative preference relation is defined by comparing two interval multiplicative preferemnce values using a possibility degree formula. The consistent interval multiplicative preference relation is defined based on interval operations, which provides a convenient means to check whether an interval multiplicative preference relation is consistent. A goal-programming model is established to derive the interval priority weight vector from an interval multiplicative preference relation, which must solve only one model. An algorithm is developed through interaction with decision makers to ensure the transitivity of an interval multiplicative preference relation. The proposed methods are then extended to deal with incomplete interval multiplicative preference relations, which can determine the priority weight vector without estimating missing values. An algorithm is also developed to derive the priority vector from group multiplicative preference relations. This algorithm can help decision makers ensure the weak transitivity of their provided multiplicative preference relations.