ArticlePDF Available

Does better labor standard compliance pay? Linking labor standard compliance and supplier competitiveness

Authors:
  • Université Paris-Est Créteil - Université Paris 12

Abstract and Figures

Faced with growing demands for responsibility in global supply chains, multinational companies are increasingly regulating labour and other conditions of their suppliers through codes of conduct and monitoring. While research in this area has been expanding rapidly, there remain significant gaps in knowledge. One such gap relates to the link between labor standard compliance and competitiveness of supplier firms. This paper seeks to fill the gap by examining whether the supplier's level of labor compliance affects its likelihood of attracting and retaining buyers. Based on the original survey and panel data from Cambodia's garment sector, the paper shows that better labor standard compliance is a necessary condition for producing for reputation-conscious buyers but not a sufficient condition for attracting them as other criteria such as price, quality, and delivery time are driving buyers' sourcing decisions. Nevertheless, producing for a certain buyer type and respecting certain labour standards increases the supplier's likelihood of staying in a long-term relationship with the buyer, which is also critical to the supplier's competitiveness.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
Does better labor standard compliance pay?
Linking labor standard compliance and supplier competitiveness
Chikako Oka
chika.oka@rhul.ac.uk
School of Management
Royal Holloway University of London
Egham, Surrey
TW20 0EX, UK
Abstract
Faced with growing demands for responsibility in global supply chains,
multinational companies are increasingly regulating labour and other conditions of their
suppliers through codes of conduct and monitoring. While research in this area has been
expanding rapidly, there remain significant gaps in knowledge. One such gap relates to
the link between labor standard compliance and competitiveness of supplier firms. This
paper seeks to fill the gap by examining whether the supplier’s level of labor
compliance affects its likelihood of attracting and retaining buyers. Based on the
original survey and panel data from Cambodia’s garment sector, the paper shows that
better labor standard compliance is a necessary condition for producing for reputation-
conscious buyers but not a sufficient condition for attracting them as other criteria such
as price, quality, and delivery time are driving buyers’ sourcing decisions. Nevertheless,
producing for a certain buyer type and respecting certain labour standards increases the
supplier’s likelihood of staying in a long-term relationship with the buyer, which is also
critical to the supplier’s competitiveness.
I. Introduction
In the past decade, the focus of the debate concerning labor standards appears to
have shifted from the desirability to the efficacy of various forms of labor regulation,
notably private and non-governmental schemes in global supply chains (Sabel et al.,
2001; Elliot and Freeman, 2003; Weil 2005; Barrientos and Smith, 2007; Locke et al.
2007). While the burgeoning literature has examined various means by which labor
conditions can be improved in global supply chains, there remain significant gaps in
knowledge. One such gap relates to the link between labor standard compliance and
competitiveness of supplier firms.
The lack of research in this area is partly explained by the fact that scholars
studying the subject tended to focus on the plight of workers toiling under dismal
2
conditions and various means to regulate unscrupulous firms rather than ways to
motivate firms to improve labor conditions (e.g. Esbenshade, 2004; Seidman, 2008).
Another reason behind the dearth of studies linking labor standards and competitiveness
lies in the difficulties in accessing the firm-level data on working conditions and
productivity in global supply chains. Considering that many supplier firms still view
labor standard compliance solely as a cost, it is of great importance to examine whether
and to what extent improving labor conditions can also help enhance supplier
competitiveness.
This paper looks at the nexus between labor standard compliance of supplier firms
and their potential for attracting and retaining buyers. For supplier firms to survive and
prosper, it is important to attract and retain buyers who give sufficient margins and
constant orders. In the apparel industry, buyers are increasingly concentrated and
competition among suppliers all over the world has become ever fiercer, putting
constant downward pressures on price. Moreover, as the industry is marked by seasonal
volatility, lack of orders during low seasons could be detrimental to the survival of
supplier firms. Having reliable buyers with long-term relationship can help smooth out
these risks. By examining the link between the supplier’s labor standard compliance and
its chance of attracting and retaining buyers, this paper seeks to shed light on the link
between labor standard compliance and competitiveness of supplier firms.
To address these issues, this study uses two sets of data. First is a self-designed
survey of 14 major buyers conducted by the author in 2008 that asked detailed questions
regarding the process and mechanism of controlling labor standard compliance of
suppliers. Second, firm-level data of nearly 400 firms in Cambodia’s garment sector
from 2006 to 2010 was obtained from Better Factories Cambodia (BFC), operated by
the International labor Organization (ILO). BFC has been monitoring Cambodia’s
garment export factories since 2001 with a view to encouraging continuous
improvement.1 One of the unique features of the program is that BFC monitors can
access to virtually all exporting garment factories in the country as the Cambodian
government requires all garment factories seeking export licenses to submit to BFC
monitoring. Such unprecedented access and comprehensive data give an excellent
1More information about Better Factories Cambodia can be found on their website:
http://www.betterfactories.org
3
opportunity to explore the link between labor standard compliance and competitiveness
of supplier firms.
The next section considers the nexus between human resource practices and firm
performance. Section III discusses the result of the buyer survey to understand how
buyers try to ensure the level of labor standard compliance in their supplier factories.
Section IV builds an analytical framework to understand the process of buyer-supplier
matching and relationship formation. Section V describes the data and provides
summary statistics while Section VI analyzes the regression results. The last section
concludes that labor standard compliance and competitiveness of supplier firms appear
to be linked in a nuanced and subtle manner.
II. Human Resource Practices and Firm Performance
One potential channel by which human resource practices can help improve
competitiveness of supplier firms is productivity. There is voluminous literature that
examines the effect of so called “high-performance” or “high-commitment” work
systems (e.g. selection, incentives, training, job enrichment, participation, teamwork
etc.) on various measures of firm performance (e.g. Ichinowski et al., 1997; Shaw,
2006).
Work systems can affect productivity through at least two channels: employees’
skills and commitment. According to the human capital theory, workforce is a means of
production, which needs to be invested and maintained just as physical capital (Becker,
1975). Hence, firms can improve performance through investing in employees and
encouraging them to acquire knowledge and skills. From the organizational behavioral
perspectives, high-performance work systems would motivate employees and make
them more loyal and cooperative, contributing to productivity (Pheffer, 2007).
While existing research on high-performance work systems mainly focuses on
firms in advanced economies, Locke and Romis (2007) has conducted a matched pair
case study of two garment factories producing for Nike in Mexico. They show that one
factory has higher productivity and better wages than the other factory with otherwise
similar characteristics because the former adopted the lean production system
4
characterized by multi-skilled workers and autonomous work teams as well as human
resource management that trained and empowered workers.
While such work systems normally exceed the minimum legal requirements, the
logic can be applied to the issue of labor standard compliance. Factory managers may
well see productivity-enhancing effects of complying with labor standards through
increased worker motivation and effort or other efficiency gains. Robertson et al. (2011)
argue that such efficiency gains from human resource innovations may well be behind
the broad-based progress in labor standard compliance in Cambodia’s garment sector.
This paper looks at the other channel by which labor standards and
competitiveness of supplier firms may be linked: attracting and retaining buyers.
Previous research examining the link between buyers and labor conditions in supplier
firms has focused on the nature of buyer-supplier relationship. Notably, researchers
have found that established and collaborative relationship with buyers tends to have
positive impact on labor conditions in supplier firms (Frenkel & Scott, 2002; Locke and
Romis 2007; Locke et al. 2009). Nonetheless, the other side of the story regarding how
labor standard compliance may affect the chance of attracting and retaining buyers has
not been investigated.
Oka (2010a) has shown using the firm-level data from Cambodia’s garment sector
that factories producing for reputation-conscious buyers systematically outperform
other factories with regard to labor standard compliance. She has identified three
mechanisms by which buyer types may be related to the level of compliance: external
pressures by NGOs and the media, buyers’ proactive engagement, and suppliers’ own
efforts. Nonetheless, the direction of causality was not tested partly due to the short time
period covered. Robertson et al. (2011) corroborated the findings about the effect of
buyer types on compliance across various labor standards. Yet, they did not assess
whether and how labor standard compliance may affect buyer variables. This article
seeks to fill the gap by examining whether better labor compliance attracts and retain
buyers, using the updated dataset through end-2010 and the original buyer survey
discussed below.
5
III. Buyer Survey Results
The author conducted a buyer survey on 9-10 October 2008 in Phnom Penh,
Cambodia during the Buyers Forum, a bi-annual event where major buyer
representatives gather to exchange views with other buyers and stakeholders and to
build consensus. In total, 14 responses from compliance staff were collected, of which 9
BFC member buyers, 4 non-BFC buyers, and 1 sourcing agent.2 These 13 buyers
account for 45 percent of Cambodia’s garment export value in 2006.
This buyer survey sought to complement the Cambodia Buyer Survey conducted
in 2004 by Foreign Investment Advisory Service (FIAS), a joint facility of the
International Finance Corporation (IFC) and the World Bank.3 The objective of the
FIAS survey was to gauge the importance of labor standard issues in buyers’ sourcing
decisions and to help devise sustainable strategies for Cambodia in the post-quota era.
The survey targeted senior sourcing staff from 15 of the largest US and EU buyers
accounting for about 45 percent of Cambodia’s garment exports.
One of the key results of the FIAS survey was that labor standards figured
prominently in buyers’ decisions in selecting a country to source from, although it had
to be balanced with traditional sourcing criteria such as price, quality, and delivery time.
While the FIAS survey provided an interesting insight into buyers sourcing decisions,
it fell short of delving into how buyers ensure labor standard levels of their supplier
factories. The buyer survey conducted by the author sought to fill this gap by asking
detailed questions regarding the process and mechanism of controlling the level of labor
standard compliance in supplier firms.
Buyer responses reported in Table 1 show that all of the surveyed buyers check
compliance levels of their potential supplier factories before placing orders and rate
compliance performance of existing supplier factories, showing buyers’ great attention
to labor standard issues. Almost all the buyers use the compliance rating to identify poor
2 With the assistance of ILO-BFC, the author distributed questionnaires to 16 participating buyer
representatives, of which 12 returned completed forms during the forum. Subsequently, the author
contacted 15 other buyers who did not participate in the forum, of which 2 completed the questionnaire
on-line.
3 The FIAS Buyer survey results can be found here: http://www.betterfactories.org/content/documents/
Cambodia%20Corporate%20Social%20Responsibility.pdf
6
performers rather than good performers, confirming that buyers tend to use sticks rather
than carrots to reduce labor standard violations in their supply chains.
As for the monitoring procedure, all the surveyed buyers have some kind of
procedure to ensure an acceptable level of compliance. “Zero tolerance” means that
violations of certain standards, often fundamental issues such as child labor lead to
immediate cancellation of orders. “Three strikes” suggests that factories are required to
achieve an acceptable level of compliance in three audits, or they lose orders.
“Continuous improvement” indicates that buyers work closely with factories to solve
problems on a continuous basis. Some buyers combine different procedures.
The surveyed buyers occasionally issue warnings to supplier factories that certain
non-compliance leads to cancellation of orders and such warnings mainly concerned
child labor, forced (or involuntary) labor, wage and contract issues. Nonetheless,
cancellation of orders is a rare event. Only four buyers have ever resorted to this option,
of which one buyer temporarily withheld orders in Cambodia.
The buyer survey results show that major buyers try to control the compliance
level of suppliers through pre-order sorting and post-order monitoring. As shown in
Figure 1, buyers check the compliance level of their potential suppliers before placing
orders and select suppliers based on their criteria (pre-order sorting). When factories do
not pass an initial audit, most buyers require them to provide a corrective action plan
and submit themselves for follow-up visits. Once orders have been placed, supplier
factories will be regularly monitored by the buyer’s compliance staff or third-party
auditors who verify whether suppliers continue to satisfy the required standards (post-
order monitoring).
If the supplier factory continues to satisfy the buyer in terms of compliance as
well as other criteria, the factory continues to receive orders. Otherwise, in theory, the
factory will lose orders and need to go through the pre-order sorting process again. In
reality, however, the buyer survey suggests that once orders have been placed, except
for egregious violations, labor compliance rarely affects buyers’ sourcing decisions.
This underlines the importance of pre-order sorting over post-order monitoring.
7
IV. Analytical Framework
Based on the above findings and relevant literature, this section builds an
analytical framework of buyer-supplier matching and relationship formation in the
apparel industry to understand how labor standard compliance enters into the picture.
The process can be conceptualized in three stages: (i) mode of transaction, (ii) sorting,
and (iii) duration of relationship as shown in Figure 2. First, given a combination of
sourcing criteria (price, quality, delivery time, as well as labor and other standards),
buyers decide whether to transact directly with their supplier firms or indirectly through
sourcing agents (in some cases, buyers use both channels). Second, buyers or agents
select supplier firms based on their sourcing criteria. Third, once the buyer and the
supplier enters into a business relationship, the duration can vary from one season to a
number of years, depending on the extent to which the supplier continues to satisfy the
buyer’s needs.
Whether the firm gets selected as a supplier and forms a long-term relationship
with the buyer is likely to depend on, among other things, the type of buyers the
supplier is dealing with. Buyers in the apparel industry can be broadly classified into
two types: specialty retailers and mass merchandisers. Specialty retailers specialize in
certain apparel products and target certain market segments whereas mass
merchandisers offer a variety of products including non-apparel products and appeal to
the mass market. The major difference between the two is quality requirements:
specialty retailers tend to demand more rigorous quality standards than mass
merchandisers.
Buyers also differ in terms of reputation-consciousness. The Resource
Dependency Theory posits that those organisations dependent on other actors for critical
resources are more vulnerable to their demands (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). Similarly,
those buyers that derive most of their profits from branding are dependent on image and
social legitimacy, which can be easily tarnished by negative publicity surrounding
dismal working conditions and child labour in their supply chains. Hence, those
reputation-conscious buyers are more likely to carefully select and monitor their
suppliers to minimise potential problems and safeguard their reputation.
8
In the first stage, buyers choose the mode of transaction based on the level of
asset-specific investment required. From the perspective of Transaction Cost Economics
(TCE), when transaction requires a higher degree of asset specificity, or non-
transferable investment in one’s partner, this raises a switching cost, inducing
commitment and reducing opportunism (Williamson, 1975 & 1985). Thus, buyers
requiring stringent quality and/or labor standards are likely to prefer a direct relationship
that enables them to better control supplier opportunism, whereas buyers with more
emphasis on price and quantity prefer using sourcing agents who can find the cheapest
suppliers that satisfy the buyer’s conditions (Oka, 2010b). In TCE terms, the former is a
hybrid (between hierarchy and market) form of an inter-organizational relationship
while the latter is a market-based relationship (Williamson, 1991). Accordingly,
specialty retailers, especially reputation-conscious ones with stringent quality and labor
requirements are likely to transact directly with suppliers while mass merchandisers
with emphasis on cost tend to transact indirectly through sourcing agents.
In the second stage of supplier sorting, buyers or agents select suppliers based on
their sourcing criteria. While mass merchandisers are more demanding in terms of price,
specialty retailers tend to be more difficult about quality and delivery time. In addition
to these traditional sourcing criteria, buyers increasingly demand their suppliers to
satisfy labor, environmental, and other standards. Most buyers require suppliers to
respect their codes of conduct, which sometimes exceed the legal requirements.
Reputation-conscious specialty retailers are likely to select their suppliers more
carefully than other buyers given their emphasis on various standards.
In the third stage of relationship formation, buyers requiring more stringent
standards are likely to favor long-term relationship for the same reason they prefer
direct transaction: better controlling supplier opportunism through repeated transactions
and longer time horizons. Switching cost is higher especially for those buyers who
select their suppliers carefully and invest in the relationship. On the other hand, the
supplier’s relationship with mass merchandisers is likely to be shorter as mass
merchandisers often rely on agents to pick suppliers from one season to another, making
it difficult to form a long-term relationship.
For the survival and competitiveness of supplier firms, at least three things appear
to be important as shown in Figure 3: (i) to attract new buyers, (ii) to attract buyers who
9
give higher margins, and (iii) to form a long-term relationship so that supplier firms can
have diversified sources of business, make profits, and count on future orders from
reliable buyers. What remains unexamined is the link between labor standard
compliance and these aspects of business outcomes, shown as the dotted arrow in
Figure 3. To shed light on this possible link, this paper tries to answer the following
questions: (i) Do better complying factories (i.e. violating fewer labor standards) attract
more buyers? (ii) Do buyers who give higher margins require a higher level of labor
standard compliance from their new suppliers? (iii) What kind of factories tend to be in
a long-term relationship with their buyers?
V. Data and Summary Statistics
The data for this study draws on the firm-level data collected by ILO BFC. Pairs
of BFC monitors conduct un-announced visits of all exporting garment factories every 8
months on average. While monitoring started in 2001, the data has been systematically
stored only since December 2005. Thus, this study covers the data from December 2005
to December 2010. During this period, 1868 factory inspections were conducted for a
total of 396 factories. In addition to the compliance data, BFC collects information on
firm characteristics such as the number of employees, unions, country of ownership, as
well as the name of buyers sourcing from the factories.
Compliance Measures
BFC monitors assess nearly 400 checklist items of labor standards, which are
based on the Cambodian labor law and the international core labor standards. These are
grouped into the following categories: contracts, wages, hours, leave, welfare,
occupational safety and health (OSH), labor relations, and fundamental rights. Given
that monitored standards for hours and leave are few and that they measure similar
issues (i.e. the number of hours/days worked), they are combined together to form one
category, hours-leave. Similarly, welfare is joined with OSH to form OSH-welfare, as
welfare has only few monitored standards and the majority of them are closely related to
OSH (e.g. drinking water and toilets). Fundamental rights need to be treated separately
since violation of fundamental rights occurs only rarely, but one incidence of non-
compliance has serious implications. Hence, non-compliance of fundamental rights is
10
measured by a binary variable (whether or not violation occurred) rather than a
continuous variable (how many violations occurred).
As for monitoring procedures, un-announced visits span an entire day or longer
for larger establishments. The process includes on-site inspection, meetings with human
resource managers, union leaders, and shop stewards as well as interviews with workers.
Copies of pay slips and hour records are collected for verification. BFC monitors assess
each checklist item and determine whether a factory complies with a specified standard
or not. Figure 4 shows the evolution of compliance rates, where a 100 indicates a full
compliance for the category. While we can observe overall progress across issue areas,
some violations remain stubbornly common, notably excessive overtime.
Buyer Variables
As monitoring is industry-wide, compliance and basic firm characteristic data are
available for all exporting garment factories, but this is not the case for buyer variables.
While most major buyers have joined BFC, not all buyers have, meaning that BFC does
not possess complete information about which buyer is sourcing from which factory.
Moreover, some buyers joined BFC later, making it difficult to analyze their
relationship with suppliers over time. To circumvent this problem, this study limits the
analysis to those buyers who have been the original members of BFC since 2006.
Specifically, the study examines seven specialty retailers and three mass merchandisers,
and together they account for more than half of Cambodia’s export volume.
All of them are globally famous buyers who have invested in corporate social
responsibility efforts, so I call them reputation-conscious buyers. But, the degree of
reputation-consciousness is likely to vary. For instance, while all of them joined BFC at
the outset, not all of them have joined other highly regarded multi-stakeholder
initiatives such as the Fair Labor Association (FLA) and the Ethical Trading Initiative
(ETI). 4 Buyers join these initiatives to show their commitment to better working
conditions and to safeguard their reputation, so the membership signals a high degree of
reputation-consciousness. In fact, all the seven specialty retailers are members of either
the FLA or the ETI while none of the three mass merchandisers are, suggesting that
4 See Oka (2010a) for discussion on the FLA and the ETI.
11
both quality and labor standards required by these specialty retailers are likely to be
higher than mass merchandisers.
There is no obvious measure for margins buyers give to supplier firms as such
information is well-guarded. Based on the field-based interviews of factory mangers,
however, the author has gathered convincing information that mass merchandisers tend
to give supplier firms much lower margins than specialty retailers. One manager of a
factory producing for Nike said that they would never produce for Walmart as margins
would be too low. While all buyers tend to squeeze suppliers in the fiercely competitive
apparel industry, mass merchandisers are generally known to be more aggressive than
specialty retailers given their emphasis on cost leadership.
To evaluate the compliance pattern of suppliers producing for different buyer
types, the following buyer dummies have been created. A specialty retailer dummy
takes the value of one if the observation belongs to a supplier producing for an original
BFC buyer classified as a specialty retailer, and zero otherwise. A mass merchandiser
dummy is created in the similar manner. There is some overlap, suggesting that some
factories produce for both types of buyers.
To focus on the compliance level required by buyers for new suppliers and to
separate the effect of pre-order sorting from changes in the post-order period,
observations where the supplier entered into a business relationship with a buyer for the
first time have been singled out as “newsuppliers. As there is no buyer information
prior to 2006, those suppliers that already produced for the original BFC buyers in 2006
are considered as pre-existing suppliers. When the supplier produced for the same buyer
at least once, these observations are classified as “oldsuppliers. Figure 5 shows the
average number of non-compliance items for new suppliers by buyer types. As for the
duration of buyer-supplier relationship, it is considered “long” when the relationship
lasted at least from 2006 to 2010, covering the entire period of this study. Otherwise,
the relationship is considered to be “short.”
Table 2 provides the summary statistics regarding the number of non-compliance
items for different buyer and supplier variables. We can observe that fewer numbers of
violations are reported for suppliers of specialty retailers (27.3) than those of mass
merchandisers (32) but the latter is still better than the full sample average (37.9). New
suppliers of specialty retailers violate fewer items (23.5) than the average, which is not
12
surprising as they tend to be newer observations. 55 percent of observations belonging
to the suppliers of specialty retailers are in long-term relationship, compared to 23
percent for the suppliers of mass merchandisers. Generally, suppliers in long-term
relationship have fewer violations than the average.
For regressions, other firm characteristics known to impact the level of
compliance are also considered, namely the size and age of the firm, foreign ownership,
and the number of unions in the establishment. The firm size is measured by the number
of employees in the establishment. The age of the firm is proxied by the number of
monitoring visits by the ILO since 2001, given the lack of original data and the regular
interval of monitoring visits.
VI. Regression Results
First, in order to assess whether better complying factories attract more reputation-
conscious buyers, I estimate an Ordinary Least Square (OLS) with fixed effects. Fixed
effects use the time-series dimension of panel data to measure the expected change in
the dependent variable given a unit change in an independent variable within cases (i.e.
factory in this case). As we are interested in the effect of non-compliance items on the
number of buyers, fixed effects models are appropriate. Given the data limitation, buyer
numbers are limited to original BFC member buyers. To focus on the effect of non-
compliance items on buyer numbers (not the other way around), the non-compliance
variables are lagged by one period. Standard errors are clustered on factory to take into
account repeated factory observations.
Column (1) in Table 3 show the results for the full sample: non-compliance items
under Wage, Hours-Leave, OSH-Welfare, and fundamental rights have the expected
negative signs although only non-compliance under Hours-Leave reaches statistical
significance. In other words, factories with fewer violations categorized under Hours-
Leave tend to attract more reputation-conscious buyers in the following year. Violations
under Contract and Labor Relations have the positive signs and those under Contract are
statistically significant, which is difficult to explain. In terms of firm characteristics, the
firm size is highly significant and positively related to buyer numbers; as firms increase
the number of employees and thus production capacity, they seek to attract more buyers.
13
Column (2) shows the results for the limited sample of factories producing for
mass merchandisers and specialty retailers who are the original BFC members. While
violations under Contract lose significance, non-compliance items under Hours-Leave
retain significance. Reasons behind the significance of Hours-Leave can vary. On one
hand, buyers may like to source from factories that manage work scheduling well. On
the other hand, factories that respect standards on hours and leave may be underutilizing
their production capacity and seek to attract more buyers to increase their capacity
utilization. The equivocal findings and small R-squared suggest that the level of labor
standard compliance is not driving buyers’ sourcing decisions.
Second, to assess whether different types of buyers (giving different margins)
require varying degrees of compliance levels from their new suppliers, I estimate a
series of Ordinary Least Square (OLS) with the number of non-compliance items under
each issue category as the dependent variable and new supplier variables as independent
variables. To focus on the effect of pre-order sorting and to control for changes in the
post-order period, both new and old supplier dummies are included along with other
controls and run for both the full sample and the limited sample of selected specialty
retailers and mass merchandisers. The results are reported in Table 4.
When run for the full sample, new suppliers of both specialty retailers and mass
merchandisers generally have fewer violations than the other factories not producing for
reputation-conscious buyers, indicating more rigorous pre-order sorting of these buyers.
New suppliers of both specialty retailers and mass merchandisers have expected
negative signs and are statistically significant for Contract, Wage, Hours-Leave and
OSH-Welfare though not for Labor Relations and Fundamental Rights. Labor Relations
and Fundamental Rights are likely to be qualitatively different from other issue areas as
they are driven by sector-wide forces rather than firm-level factors. Robertson et al.
(2011) also found that the buyer variables did not matter to the level of compliance with
regard to union issues and core labor standards. As for the limited sample, new
suppliers of specialty retailers retain statistical significance across issue categories while
new suppliers of mass merchandisers lose significance, suggesting that new suppliers of
specialty retailers systematically have fewer labor standard violations than those of
mass merchandisers.
14
Lastly, to understand the characteristics of factories likely to be in long-term
relationship, I estimate a logit regression, where the dependent variable is a “long-term”
dummy that takes the value of one when the factory and the buyer stay in relationship
continuously from 2006 to 2010. The sample is limited to the original BFC buyers
because the duration of relationship for other buyers is unknown. Results reported in
Table 5 show that the most significant predictors of long-term relationship are the size
and age of factory (p<0.01): larger and older factories tend to retain buyers longer. The
size of the factory is likely to indicate the presence of firm network and firm capacity.
The significance of age is not surprising given that newer factories could not be
classified as long-term suppliers.
The next most significant variable is the specialty retailer dummy (p<0.05):
factories producing for specialty retailers are much more likely to be in long-term
relationship than the suppliers of mass merchandisers, controlling for factory
characteristics and labor standard compliance levels. This is consistent with the
assumption that reputation-conscious specialty retailers prefer long-term relationship to
better control their suppliers, given the rigorous standards they require.
As for labor standard compliance, OSH-Welfare and fundamental rights are
significant at p<0.05 level with the expected negative signs, meaning factories with
fewer violations under OSH-Welfare and no incidence of violation of fundamental
rights tend to be in long-term relationship. It is interesting to note that violation of
fundamental rights, which was not related to the buyer variables in the earlier estimates,
is significantly associated with the duration of relationship. It suggests that factors that
attract buyers may well be quite different from factors that retain them, which requires
further research. Hours-Leave has the expected negative sign but lacks significance
while Contract and Wage have the wrong signs.
All in all, the regression results indicate a nuanced picture of how labor standard
compliance may be related to supplier competitiveness. First, Hours-Leave is the only
issue category whose number of non-compliance items is significantly and negatively
related to buyer numbers. The equivocal findings suggest that changes in the level of
labor standard compliance are not driving buyers’ sourcing decisions. Second, the labor
standard compliance level required for a new supplier of reputation-conscious buyers—
either specialty retailers or mass merchandisersis much higher than the level required
15
by other buyers. Specialty retailers are even more stringent about the compliance level
than mass merchandisers. Third, suppliers of specialty retailers are significantly more
likely to be in long-term relationship than those of mass merchandisers, after controlling
for firm characteristics and labor standard compliance. Those factories respectful of
OSH-Welfare and fundamental rights are more likely to be in long-term relationship.
VII. Conclusion
While the literature on labor standards in global supply chains has been growing,
it has mostly focused on how to regulate suppliers through codes of conduct, monitoring,
or other means, and few studies have examined whether better labor standard
compliance could affect the competitiveness of supplier firms. The potential benefit
could notably arise from efficiency-enhancing effects of respecting labor standards as
well as from attracting and retaining reputation-conscious buyers that give higher
margins and prefer long-term relationship. This paper has tried to shed light on the
second lesser known aspect using the survey and firm-level data from Cambodia’s
garment sector.
The buyer survey results indicate that most buyers verify the level of labor
standard compliance before placing orders, but once orders have been placed, except for
egregious violations of “zero-tolerance” issues such as child and forced labor, they
rarely affect buyers’ sourcing decisions. In short, the question of labor standard
compliance appears to figure more prominently at the pre-order stage than the post-
order stage.
The regression estimates suggest that better labor standard compliance is a
necessary condition for producing for reputation-conscious buyers—specialty retailers
in particularbut not a sufficient condition for attracting them as other criteria such as
price, quality, and delivery time are driving buyers’ sourcing decisions. Nevertheless,
producing for reputation-conscious specialty retailers and respecting labor rights and
complying with OSH standards increases the supplier’s likelihood of staying in long-
term relationship, which is also critical to the supplier’s competitiveness.
One of the limitations of this paper is that the buyer information is not available
for the full sample, reducing the scope of inquiry and the power of inference.
16
Nonetheless, the study covers the majority of buyers in terms of export volume and the
core message is unlikely to be affected by this. Another limitation relates to the lack of
separation between the direct effect of buyers’ labor standard requirements and the
indirect effect of other requirements such as quality. The observed compliance level of
the supplier is likely to reflect a combination of the two effects rather than the sole
effect of the buyer selecting the supplier’s level of labor standard compliance. Moreover,
while non-compliance items cover a wide range of issues, different degrees of severity
is not taken into account in this paper. The author plans to address these issues in the
future work.
Notwithstanding these caveats, this paper makes an important contribution to the
literature on labor standards in global supply chains by investigating, probably for the
first time, the link between labor standard compliance and competitiveness of supplier
firms from the perspective of buyer-supplier matching and relationship formation.
17
Figure 1. Pre-order sorting and post-order monitoring
Figure 2. The process of buyer-supplier matching and relationship formation
Sourcing Criteria Stage I Stage II Stage III
Figure 3. The potential link between labor standard compliance and competitiveness of
supplier firms
Mode of
Transaction
Direct
Indirect
Sorting
In
Out
Duration of
Relationship
Long
Short
Price
Quality
Delivery
Labor/other
Standards
Attract new
buyers
Attract buyers with
higher margins
Supplier’s
Competitiveness
labor standard
compliance
Form a long-term
relationship
Place Orders
Post-order
Monitoring
Not Acceptable
Pre-order
Sorting
Acceptable
18
Figure 4. Evolution of compliance rates by issue category
Figure 5. average number of non-compliance items for new suppliers
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
2007 2008 2009 2010
Speciality
Mass
Industry
average
Others
19
Table1. Responses to the buyer survey regarding labor standard compliance of supplier factories
Survey Questions
Number
Valid
Missing
1. Compliance Check
Does your company check compliance levels of factories before placing orders?
14
0
Yes
12
Partially Yes
2
No
0
2 Compliance Rating
2-a. Does your company rate compliance performance of supplier factories?
14
0
Yes
14
No
0
2-b. If yes to above, how does your company use the rating?
(multiple answers possible)
13
1
To identify poor performers and encourage them to improve
13
To identify very poor performers and reduce/cancel orders
3
To identify good performers and reward them with more orders
2
3. Monitoring Procedure
Which procedure, if any, does your company use to ensure an acceptable level of
compliance at supplier factories? (multiple answers possible)
13
1
Zero Tolerance
6
Three Strikes
6
Continuous Improvement
7
4. Warning
4-a. How often does your company issue warnings to supplier factories in
Cambodia that certain non-compliance leads to cancellation of orders?
13
1
Often
1
Sometimes
6
Rarely
5
Never
1
4-b. If yes to above, regarding which issues? (multiple answers possible)
9
5
Child labor, Forced labor
5
Wage
4
Contract
3
Overtime, Disputes/Strikes, FoA, Welfare
2
Leave, Safety & Health, Discrimination
1
5. Cancellation of Orders
Has your company ever cancelled orders because of compliance problems in
Cambodia?
14
0
Yes
4
No
10
20
Table 2. Summary statistics of buyer and supplier variables
Number of non-
compliance items Number of
Observations Share (%)
Full Sample
37.9
1959
100
Limited Sample (suppliers of reputation-conscious buyers)
Suppliers of specialty retailers
All suppliers (average)
27.3
509
26.0
of which
New suppliers
23.5
81
15.9
Long-term relationship
25.7
280
55.0
Suppliers of mass merchandisers
All suppliers (average)
32
745
38.0
of which
New suppliers
32.1
191
25.6
Long-term relationship
29
171
23.0
21
Table 3. Labor standard non-compliance and the number of reputation-conscious buyers
(1)
(2)
Number of Reputation-Conscious Buyers
Full Sample
Limited Sample
Number of non-compliance items under:
Contract (lagged)
0.031**
0.024
(0.014)
(0.019)
Wage (lagged)
-0.014
-0.009
(0.009)
(0.014)
Hours-Leave (lagged)
-0.018**
-0.029**
(0.008)
(0.012)
OSH-Welfare (lagged)
-0.001
0.002
(0.004)
(0.005)
Labor Relations (lagged)
0.003
0.006
(0.009)
(0.012)
Fundamental Rights (lagged)
-0.035
-0.037
(0.072)
(0.100)
Size of factory
0.580****
0.478****
(Log of total number of employees)
(0.111)
(0.146)
Age of factory
0.041
0.071*
(Number of ILO monitor visits)
(0.035)
(0.038)
Year controls
Yes
Yes
Constant
-2.987****
-1.987*
(0.85)
(1.053)
Number of observations
1478
908
R-squared (within)
0.085
0.092
F-value
(12, 345)
(12, 213)
5.29
4.35
Prob>F
0.000
0.000
Note: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01, ***<0.001.
Robust standard errors in the parentheses.
22
Table 4-a. Labor standard non-compliance of new suppliers
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Contact Wage Hours-Leave
Full
Sample
Limited
Sample
Full
Sample
Limited
Sample
Full
Sample
Limited
Sample
New suppliers of specialty retailers
-0.731***
-0.513**
-0.836***
-0.639**
-1.004***
-0.559*
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.241)
(0.246)
(0.286)
(0.256)
(0.331)
(0.312)
New suppliers of mass merchandisers
-0.302*
0.081
-0.913****
-0.373*
-0.974****
-0.116
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.171)
(0.204)
(0.204)
(0.205)
(0.231)
(0.227)
Old suppliers of specialty retailers
-0.579**
-0.122
-1.387****
-0.729***
-1.462****
-0.508
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.247)
(0.263)
(0.289)
(0.274)
(0.361)
(0.352)
Old suppliers of mass merchandisers
-0.641***
-0.155
-1.137****
-0.354
-1.296****
-0.138
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.192)
(0.220)
(0.213)
(0.216)
(0.264)
(0.291)
Size of factory
-0.705****
-0.746****
-0.667***
-0.549**
-0.541**
-0.441*
(Log of total number of employees)
(0.142)
(0.184)
(0.227)
(0.202)
(0.221)
(0.234)
Age of factory
0.034
0.039
-0.001
-0.044
0.055
-0.000
(Number of ILO monitor visits)
(0.042)
(0.047)
(0.047)
(0.048)
(0.058)
(0.058)
Foreign ownership
-0.537
-0.418
-1.700*
-0.857
-2.098**
-1.516***
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.449)
(0.353)
(1.004)
(0.668)
(0.991)
(0.434)
Number of unions
0.006
0.049
0.037
0.110
-0.175
-0.012
(0.075)
(0.080)
(0.101)
(0.091)
(0.107)
(0.103)
Year controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Constant
10.833****
10.134****
13.008****
9.780****
16.290****
13.270****
(0.953)
(1.240)
(1.675)
(1.511)
(1.702)
(1.621)
Number of observations
1862
1060
1862
1060
1862
1060
R-squared
0.176
0.132
0.187
0.110
0.280
0.258
F-value
(12, 385)
(12, 229)
(12, 385)
(12, 229)
(12, 385)
(12, 229)
21.66
10.84
16.11
6.95
31.61
18.70
Prob>F
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
Note: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01, **** p<0.001.
Robust standard errors in the parentheses.
23
Table4-b. Labor standard non-compliance of new suppliers
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
OSH-Welfare
Labor Relations
Fundamental Rights
Full Sample
Limited Sample
Full Sample
Limited Sample
Full Sample
Limited Sample
New suppliers of specialty retailers
-4.823****
-3.722****
-0.405
-0.394
-0.078
-0.050
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.884)
(0.926)
(0.270)
(0.267)
(0.287)
(0.320)
New suppliers of mass merchandisers
-2.240****
-0.921
-0.065
-0.078
-0.226
-0.245
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.567)
(0.600)
(0.200)
(0.218)
(0.215)
(0.285)
Old suppliers of specialty retailers
-6.009****
-3.718****
-0.703***
-0.476*
-0.199
-0.004
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.883)
(0.896)
(0.254)
(0.256)
(0.236)
(0.299)
Old suppliers of mass merchandisers
-4.351****
-0.187***
-0.499***
-0.370
-0.074
0.037
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.696)
(0.732)
(0.190)
(0.233)
(0.186)
(0.274)
Size of factory
-2.824****
-3.394****
-0.234
-0.380*
0.151
0.096
(Log of total number of employees)
(0.599)
(0.675)
(0.170)
(0.216)
(0.134)
(0.238)
Age of factory
0.391**
0.197
-0.030
-0.097*
-0.105**
-0.142**
(Number of ILO monitor visits)
(0.167)
(0.189)
(0.043)
(0.052)
(0.043)
(0.060)
Foreign ownership
-3.151
-0.508**
-0.529
-1.415*
-1.003***
-1.206**
(1=yes, 0=no)
(2.192)
(2.103)
(0.081)
(0.831)
(0.337)
(0.562)
Number of unions
0.352
0.605*
-0.097
-0.086
-0.036
-0.138
(0.292)
(0.321)
(0.081)
(0.090)
(0.090)
(0.106)
Year controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yese
Constant
48.49****
51.87****
8.604****
10.72****
-0.488
-1.589
(4.357)
(4.826)
(1.189)
(1.806)
(0.860)
(1.627)
Number of observations
1862
1060
1862
1060
1862
1060
R-squared (pseudo for (5) & (6))
0.297
0.237
0.144
0.169
0.040
0.050
F-value
(12, 385)
(12, 229)
(12, 385)
(12, 229)
(12, 385)
(12, 229)
(Wald Chi-squared for (5) & (6))
36.15
18.63
16.03
9.88
72.66
53.76
Prob>F
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
(Prob > Chi-squared for (5) & (6))
Note: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01, **** p<0.001. Robust standard errors in the paraentheses. (5) and (6) are logit regressions.
24
Table 5. Long-term relationship, buyer type, and labor standard non-compliance
Long-term Relationship
Suppliers of specialty retailers
1.015**
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.402)
Suppliers of mass merchandisers
0.202
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.386)
Number of non-compliance items under:
Contract
0.021
(0.057)
Wage
0.016
(0.051)
Hours-Leave
-0.007
(0.046)
OSH-Welfare
-0.043**
(0.018)
Labor Relations
0.033
(0.044)
Incidence of non-compliance with
Fundamental rights
-0.633**
(1=yes, 0=no)
(0.322)
Size of factory
0.855***
(Log of total number of employees)
(0.290)
Age of factory
0.226***
(Number of ILO monitor visits)
(0.073)
Year controls
Yes
Constant
-0.725
(2.203)
Number of observations
1061
Pseudo R-squared
0.199
Prob > Chi squared
0.000
Note: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01, **** p<0.001.
Robust standard errors in the parentheses.
25
References
Barrientos, S. and S. Smith. (2007) Do workers benefit from ethical trade? Assessing
codes of labor practice in global production systems. Third World Quarterly 28
(4): 713-729.
Becker, G. S. (1975) Human Capital. Columbia University Press: New York.
Elliott, K. A. and R. B. Freeman. (2003) Can Labor Standards Improve Under
Globalization? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics
Esbenshade, J. (2004) Monitoring Sweatshops: Workers, Consumers and the Global
Apparel Industry. Philadelphia: Temple University.
Frenkel, S. J. and D. Scott. (2002) Compliance, collaboration, and codes of labor
practice: the ADIDAS connection. California Management Review 45(1): 29-49.
Ichinowski, C., K. Shaw and G. Prennushi. (1997) The effects of human resource
management practices on productivity: A study of steel finishing lines.
American Economic Review 86 (3): 291-313.
Locke, R. M., F. Qin, and A. Brause. (2007) Does monitoring improve labor standards?
Lessons from Nike. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61(1): 3-31.
Locke, R. M. and M. Romis. (2007) Improving work conditions in global supply chain.
MIT Sloan Management Review, 48(2): 54–62.
Locke, R., M. Amengual. and A. Mangla. (2009) Virtue out of Necessity? Compliance,
commitment, and the improvement of labor conditions in global supply chains.
Politics and Society, 37 (3): 319-351.
Oka, C. (2010a) Accounting for the Gaps in Labour Standard Compliance: The Case of
Cambodia’s Garment Sector. European Journal of Development Research,
22(1): 59-78.
Oka, C (2010b) Channels of Buyer Influence and Labour Standard Compliance: The
Case of Cambodia’s Garment Sector. Advances in Industrial and Labour
Relations, 17: 153-183.
Pfeffer, J. (2007) Human resources from an organizational behavior perspective: Some
paradoxes explained. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (4): 115-134.
Pfeffer, J and G. R. Salancik. (1978) The External Control of Organizations: A
Resource Dependence Perspective. New York: Harper & Row.
26
Robertson, R., R. Dehejia, D. Brown, D. Ang. (2011) Labor law compliance and human
resource management innovation: Better Factories Cambodia. Better Work
Discussion Paper No. 1, International Labour Organisation, Geneva.
Seidman, G. (2008) Transnational labor campaigns: Can the logic of the market be
turned against itself? Development and Change 39(6): 991-1003.
Sabel, C., D. O’Rourke and A. Fung. (2001) Can We Put an End to Sweatshops?
Boston: Beacon Press.
Shaw, K. (2006) The value of innovating human resource management practices. In
America at Work: Choices and Challenges, ed. Lawler. E. and J. O’Tooles, 227-
39. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Weil, D. (2005) Public enforcement/private monitoring: Evaluating a new approach to
regulating the minimum wage. Industrial and Labor Relations Journal 58(2):
238-257.
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust
Implications. New York: Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets,
Relational Contracting, New York: Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete
structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 269-296.
... In multi-stakeholder initiatives (MSIs), incentives are at play that could mitigate governance failures associated with other approaches to private regulation. Buyers have a reputational incentive to participate (Oka 2012), manufacturers have the potential for increased orders, and governments see potential for economic gains. Unions also have an incentive, knowing that this forum for social dialogue puts pressure on their employers to be accountable to buyers. ...
... The research has been largely quantitative, using data primarily from audit reports. On the one hand, evidence shows support for BW, contending that it has led to improvements for hundreds of thousands of workers (Polaski 2009;Rossi 2015), and has had a positive impact on wages and human resource innovation (Robertson 2011), factory survival (Brown, Dehejia, and Robertson 2011), verbal abuse (Rourke 2014), sexual harassment (Lin, Babbitt, and Brown 2014), profit maximization (Brown et al. 2015), factory performance (Brown, Dehejia, and Robertson 2013;Asuyama, Fukunishi, and Robertson 2017), communication and relations between workers and managers (Pike and Godfrey 2015), the public labor inspectorate system (Dupper, Fenwick, and Hardy 2016), compliance within factories supplying to reputation-conscious buyers (Oka 2012), and women's empowerment at the workplace and household levels (Pike and English 2020). ...
... Although the empirical analysis highlights the importance of PICCs as a joint mechanism for enforcing labor standards in global supply chains, it also reinforces concerns about the sustainability of BW (Oka 2010;Bair and Gereffi 2014). The presence of the ILO as a type of standing reference group in BW implementation and monitoring helped to establish a continuous working program, treating its mandate as ''enforceable objectives, rather than as aspirations'' (Davies et al. 2011: 136). ...
Article
Using a six-year study of Better Work Lesotho (BWL), this article examines whether the ILO’s Better Work initiative leads to improvements in labor standards compliance. Data include 55 focus group discussions conducted with 426 workers during four waves of data collection between 2011 and 2017. In-depth qualitative research with workers before, during, and after BWL reveals the root causes underlying noncompliance. Findings indicate that improvements across a number of compliance areas are enabled by collective worker voice mechanisms established by BWL at the factory level. Workers also highlight additional positive impacts of these improvements beyond the workplace. The author concludes that worker voice is essential to long-term sustainable improvements in labor standards compliance. This study makes an empirical and a methodological contribution by demonstrating the importance of worker voice in both the implementation of Better Work and its evaluation and impact.
... Aside from H&M, they include Nike, Levi's, Old Navy, Adidas, Calvin Klein, Gap, Puma, Clarks, Marks & Spencer, Tesco, Inditex, N Brown Group, Tchibo, Next, New Look, C&A, Walmart, and others. According to Oka (2012), buyer types in the apparel industry can be broadly classified into two kinds: Specialty retailers and mass merchandisers. Specialty retailers, like H&M and Nike, specialize in certain apparel products and target certain market segments, whereas mass merchandisers, like Being a specialty buyer may explain in part H&M's launch of its industrial relations initiative in 2016. ...
... Specialty retailers, like H&M and Nike, specialize in certain apparel products and target certain market segments, whereas mass merchandisers, like Being a specialty buyer may explain in part H&M's launch of its industrial relations initiative in 2016. Buyers like H&M may prefer sourcing from better compliant suppliers to safeguard their reputation, as these buyers derive most of their profits from branding that is, in turn, dependent on their image and social legitimacy (Oka, 2012). Oka (2010: 4) further emphasizes that "reputation-conscious buyers are more likely to carefully select and monitor their suppliers to minimize potential problems and to safeguard their reputation". ...
... Specialty retailers have larger supplier factories too that are more likely to have a union. Finally, as international buyers tend to not reward better compliance through increased orders, making compliance a cost of doing business borne by suppliers, Oka (2012) suggests buyers share the burden through offering long-term contracts or guarantees for stable orders, if not premium prices or increased orders. ...
Book
Full-text available
The young trade union movement in Cambodia has gone through difficult challenges, including a tough political environment and a conflict-ridden industrial relations system, as it struggles towards transforming itself into a legitimate movement that genuinely represents workers' interests. Nonetheless, since 2010, posiitve developments have had taken place within the movement, including: the gradual emergence of worker activism, the existence of more union structures and processes that promote internal democracy, improved capacity in negotiation and social dialogue, and organizing initiatives in the informal economy. In recent years, the increasing role of buyers and trade unions in improving working conditions has been noted as well. Nonetheless, due to mutually reinforcing economic and political factors, a highly fragmented trade union movement endures in the country. The book tracks and examines these developments and the new and continuing challenges that unions in Cambodia face. It underscores that despite the existence of an institutional framework that promotes a labour rights regime, which has been facilitated by the US-Cambodia textile trade agreement, the EU's Everything But Arms scheme, and the Better Factories Cambodia, paradoxically, industrial relations remain conflict-ridden. But, as the growth and dynamics of the labour movement are linked with Cambodia's economic growth and political landscape, trade unions' struggle towards independence and relevance will continue to intensify in the coming years. The book reflects on how trade unions may be able to meet this goal.
... This review was not able to identify other rigorous empirical studies -only case studies and anecdotal evidence. Much of the literature frequently highlighted the dearth of rigorous empirical studies in this field (Distelhorst and Locke, 2018, p.698;Croucher et al., 2013, p.24;Oka, 2005, p.5, ILO, 2016. The benefits of labour standards compliance for firm performance are summarised in Table 4. ...
Article
Full-text available
This helpdesk review has drawn primarily on evidence from systematic reviews and synthesis studies focused on (i) the impact of labour standards on labour/firms’ performances and (ii) policies and programmes from other governments/development actors that promote beneficial effects of labour standards on firms. This review provides examples of policies and programmes from governments and development organisations that support businesses to improve their financial performance while improving standards compliance and work practices.
Technical Report
Full-text available
The purpose of this report is to explore why social and environmental sustainability initiatives designed to incentivise garment producers by presenting win-win business cases have not scaled up to make widespread impact. The production of this report entailed interviewing representatives from garment brands and retailers, producers, and programme implementers. Based on these interviews and reviewing documentary records, this report scrutinises the design of business case sustainability initiatives, considers various scaling challenges, and presents recommendations to help scale these initiatives as well as to make greater impact on sustainability in the global garment industry.
Article
Do purchasing practices support or undermine the regulation of labor standards in global supply chains? This study offers the first analysis of the full range of supply chain regulatory efforts, integrating records of factory labor audits with purchase order microdata. Studying an apparel and equipment retailer with a strong reputation for addressing labor conditions in its suppliers, the authors show that the retailer persuaded factories to improve and terminated factories with poor labor compliance. However, the authors also find that purchase orders did not increase when labor standards improved. If anything, factories whose standards worsened tended to see their orders increase. Contrary to the conventional wisdom, this “missing middle” in incentives for compliance appears unrelated to any cost advantage of noncompliant factories. Instead, lack of flexibility in supplier relationships created obstacles to reallocating orders in response to compliance findings.
Article
What is the relationship between trade and social institutions in the developing world? The research literature is conflicted: Importing firms may demand that trading partners observe higher labor and environmental standards, or they may penalize higher standards that raise costs. This study uses new data on retailers and manufacturers to analyze how firm‐level trade responds to information about social standards. Contrary to the “race to the bottom” hypothesis, it finds that retail importers reward exporters for complying with social standards. In difference‐in‐differences estimates from over 2,000 manufacturing establishments in 36 countries, achieving compliance is associated with a 4% [1%, 7%] average increase in annual purchasing. The effect is driven largely by the apparel industry—a long‐term target of anti‐sweatshop social movements—suggesting that activist campaigns can shape patterns of global trade.
Chapter
Full-text available
As part of the Core Labour Standards Plus (CLS+) initiative, this case study analyses the status of compliance with international labour and social standards, implication of non-compliance, and power relationships in global supply chains with a particular focus on the export-oriented industries of Pakistan. Pakistan textile sector accounts for about 60 per cent of Pakistan's export, provides employment to 40 per cent of the industrial workforce, contributes nearly one-quarter of the total industrial output, and has the logest production chain.
Article
Full-text available
Comprising networked organizations that span advanced and developing countries, the athletic footwear sector is at the cutting edge of globalization. An important dimension of corporate responsibility is setting and maintaining labor standards for contractors' employees in countries where workers have little or no legal protection against exploitation. This article examines how adidas, the industry's number two firm, has utilized a code of labor practice to regulate the labor standards of its main manufacturing suppliers. A comparative analysis of a matched sample of two contractors in China shows that although the code requirements were met in both cases, relationships with adidas not only differed but also made a difference. Compared with compliance type relationships, collaborative global firm-contractor ties encourage higher workplace performance and better employment relations in contractor factories.
Article
Full-text available
This paper combines institutional economics with aspects of contract law and organization theory to identify and explicate the key differences that distinguish three generic forms of economic organization-market, hybrid, and hierarchy. The analysis shows that the three generic forms are distinguished by different coordinating and control mechanisms and by different abilities to adapt to disturbances. Also, each generic form is supported and defined by a distinctive type of contract law. The cost-effective choice of organization form is shown to vary systematically with the attributes of transactions. The paper unifies two hitherto disjunct areas of institutional economics-the institutional environment and the institutions of governance-by treating the institutional environment as a locus of parameters, changes in which parameters bring about shifts in the comparative costs of governance. Changes in property rights, contract law, reputation effects, and uncertainty are investigated.
Article
Full-text available
Given the continued growth in the globalization of production, working conditions in global supply chains have come under increased scrutiny. Although there has been much debate about corporate codes of conduct and monitoring procedures, the question of how buyers influence their suppliers’ working conditions at the factory level remains poorly understood. Using a unique data set based on monitoring by the International Labour Organization (ILO) and original survey data collected in Cambodia's garment sector, this study shows that the main channel linking buyers and supplier compliance performance is the nature of their relationships. Market-based relationships mediated through sourcing agents are systematically associated with poorer compliance performance. In particular, when a reputation-conscious buyer is sourcing from a factory, it has a positive effect on compliance, and their presence appears to condition relationship variables. Deterrence and learning channels are not supported by the evidence. The findings signal the need to pay more attention to the nature of buyer–supplier relationships if we seek to improve labor standard compliance. Market-based relationships motivate neither buyers nor suppliers to invest their time and resources to tackle the root causes of poor working conditions. Rather, the results here indicate the need to develop collaborative relationships marked by open dialogue, trust, and commitment, which in turn help to foster an environment supportive of continuous improvement in working conditions.
Chapter
In the last 30 years, there has been a dramatic change in firms’ choices of human resource management (HRM) practices towards what are often labeled “innovative” or “high-performance” practices. These new practices often include greater teamwork, greater participation by employees in decision making, more information sharing among employees, greater training and education, and, often, new forms of incentive pay to complement these changes. In fact, these new practices represent a “technology shock” that is similar to the “technology shock” of new information technologies.
Article
Many multinational companies attempt to monitor working conditions in suppliers' factories in developing countries through corporate codes of conduct, along with monitoring to determine compliance with these codes. There is considerable debate about the merits of this approach. As part of a larger research project on globalization and labor standards, the authors conducted a comparison of two Mexican garment factories that supply Nike Inc. Both plants (referred to as Plant A and Plant B) received very similar scores on a Nike factory audit, and both manufacture T-shirts for Nike and other companies. Workers in both plants are unionized. However, a closer examination revealed that working conditions in the two factories are in some respects quite different. Compared to workers in Plant B, workers in Plant A earn more per week, report greater job satisfaction and have greater say in workplace decisions. Furthermore, in Plant A overtime is voluntary and kept within Nike workweek limits, but in Plant B both forced overtime and excessive overtime occur. What factors contribute to these differing working conditions? The authors conclude that, while there are a number of differences between the factories, a key variable is the way each plant is managed. Plant A has made the transition to lean manufacturing, and, in the process, workers received training and were empowered to participate in more decisions on the shop floor. Quality, worker productivity and worker salary all increased at Plant A. The authors conclude that global brands could help improve working conditions in sup ply chain factories by working with suppliers to help them introduce new management systems.
Article
Corporate codes of labour practice have proliferated as a result of trade union and ngo campaigns against poor labour conditions in global production. Analysis of global production systems highlights the complexity of commercial networks and the wider social and institutional environment in which codes operate. It posits tensions between a corporate approach focusing on compliance with outcome standards and a civil society approach focusing on process rights. A detailed study of codes operated by companies in the UK Ethical Trading Initiative finds that codes have led to improvements in outcome standards but little change in process rights for workers. The authors conclude that corporate codes have a role to play in improving labour standards, but are currently doing little to challenge existing commercial practices or embedded social relations that underpin poor labour standards in global production systems.
Article
Private, voluntary compliance programs, promoted by global corporations and non-governmental organizations alike, have produced only modest and uneven improvements in working conditions and labor rights in most global supply chains. Through a detailed study of a major global apparel company and its suppliers, this paper argues that this compliance model rests upon misguided theoretical and empirical assumptions concerning the power of multinational corporations in global supply chains; the role information (derived from factory audits) plays in shaping the behavior of key actors (i.e., global brands, transnational activist networks, suppliers, purchasing agents, etc.) in these production networks; and the appropriate incentives required to change behavior and promote improvements in labor standards in these emergent centers of global production. We argue that it is precisely these faulty assumptions and the way they have come to shape various labor compliance initiatives throughout the world - even more than a lack of commitment, resources, or transparency by global brands and their suppliers to these programs - that explains why this compliance-focused model of private voluntary regulation has not succeeded. In contrast, this paper documents that a more commitment-oriented approach to improving labor standards co-exists, and in many of the same factories, complements the traditional compliance model. This commitment-oriented approach, based upon joint problem solving, information exchange, and the diffusion of best-practices, is often obscured by the debates over traditional compliance programs but it exists in myriad factories throughout the world and has led to sustained improvements in working conditions and labor rights at these workplaces.