Figure 3 - uploaded by Bruno Dallago
Content may be subject to copyright.
Labor Productivity per Hour Worked (EU-15 = 100) 

Labor Productivity per Hour Worked (EU-15 = 100) 

Source publication
Article
Full-text available
The unfolding of the crisis in the Eurozone can be explained by the interaction of institutional features and policy failures, and by their interconnection with real and financial imbalances. The crisis has shown that internal divergence in the EZ is based on important structural components which are unsustainable in the long run. Indeed, the crisi...

Context in source publication

Context 1
... a matter of fact, the main differences between European forms of capitalism concern the financial systems and the labor markets, which remained national competences. As far as the financial system is concerned, such variables as the capitalization and liquidity of stock markets and the ratio between risk and debt capital are much higher in the USA and UK than in continental European markets such as Germany, France and Italy. In the latter, banks are more important in financing firms than in the former countries, have a universal nature, and their monitoring of and control over firms is stronger (Dietl 1998; Rajan 2010), in spite of significant changes in the last two decades. In such a way they are often able to detect early risky situations in firms and push them to rescue, thus avoiding default. Although capital re-allocation is slowed down, the rapid contagion by financial crises can also be hindered. In this kind of economic system, though, the risk of private gain from control, entrenched management, and side dealings between banks and firms may be a relatively serious problem and may slow down post-crisis recovery. 6 As a matter of fact, European progress towards truly unified financial markets and taxation has been bumpy to say the least: the most important European instrument so far has been periodical cross-controls by national authorities with some support by the European Union on so-called fiscal paradises within the Union and the control that taxpayers pay taxes in the country where they reside. As to the labor markets, entry and exit flexibility are usually higher in such countries as the USA, UK, and Ireland, and seniority relations and firm specific investments are more important in continental Europe. Due to these features, European labor markets are usually less reactive to financial shocks, thus hindering the contagion of the real economy, although at the price of slower labor re-allocation, youth and long-term structural unemployment. The institutional architecture of the EZ is intended to create opportunities for European countries and increase systemic resilience through an enlarged market and greater financial discipline. However, it also introduced new elements of vulnerability, in particular through the decoupling between fiscal and monetary policies and the asymmetry of mobility and flexibility between financial and labour markets. The common currency exacerbated both outcomes. The institutional asymmetry has to be seen in conjunction with the inherited and new structural imbalances, i.e. the imbalances which derive from the economic history of the member countries, in particular productivity differentials and the relation between public and private finance. Given the institutional architecture, these imbalances have prepared the scene for problematic and asymmetric adaptation to the global crisis. To work properly as it was designed the EZ should have complied with a number of requirements. Among the most important are: a) European integration and globalization should have been compatible: this aim was largely implemented; b) a common monetary policy should have accompanied monetary integration: a goal that was implemented successfully, the ECB having kept inflation around 2%; c) common criteria for fiscal policies should have been identified and enforced upon member countries: the Stabilization and Growth Pact (SGP) has been repeatedly broken by some of its members, even though the EZ16 as a whole exceeded the limit of 3% target only once; d) resources should have flown from strong to weak countries for supporting microeconomic convergence: this was a major failure of the integration process, also because the EU concentrated on macroeconomic issues; and e) domestic microeconomic adaptation and transformation should have been pursued with the support of national governments: another major failure. Overall, and in spite of important successes, the integration process was asymmetric to the disadvantage of the microeconomic side as compared to the macroeconomic one, thus generating an unbalanced integration. This asymmetry is the most critical element of EZ vulnerability, particularly in the long run. There is an interrelation among the above successes and failures that contributes to explain the external and internal vulnerability of the EZ in front of the international crisis. The monetary integration has strengthened the European monetary system, limiting the aggregate vulnerability to exogenous shocks of Member States. Smaller states with limited capacity to manage their currency could rely on the credibility of the Euro and the common monetary policy, while financially weaker economies gained reputation by giving discipline and credibility to their budgets anchored to European shared rules. The monetary integration and the introduction of a common currency thus led to enlargement of markets, easier and smother internal flow of resources, elimination of exchange rate risk and uncertainty, and reduction of transaction costs. Since monetary integration increased the domestic effect of asymmetric shocks, due to the lack of the monetary lever, national sovereignty of fiscal policy was conceived as the main institutional device for national adaptation along with EU budget transfers. The entire system was conceived to strengthen national and European resilience to external shocks. This process of integration and the EZ creation, together with globalization, exposed productivity differentials and made their sustainability hard, at least in the long run. Indeed, traditional coping mechanisms (in particular, the depreciation of the national currency) disappeared. In order to overcome these differentials, policy-makers promoted pro-market policies in favour of profits since the Seventies, thus causing growing distributive disparities which obtained additional peculiar drivers within the EZ. They were intended to provide incentives to investment for fostering productivity convergence. Growing employment and income should have resulted through trickle-down mechanisms, thus boosting demand and production. However, this standpoint disregarded important effects, thus meeting with unforeseen events. Indeed, increasing inequalities have reduced the importance of domestic markets, particularly of domestically produced commodities consumed by the middle-income population and have hampered opportunities for people in general and potential entrepreneurs in particular (e.g. through the polarization of savings that dried up an important source of diffused, small-scale investment). This resulted in segmentation of the economy, the society, and finally the EZ. This outcome had particularly disadvantageous effects in laggard countries. Segmentation within countries in turn depressed demand, production, and savings and fostered public and private debt. Since segmentation was primarily to the disadvantage of the middle class, a politically and economically sensitive domain, policies tried to foster the trickle-down mechanisms by supporting the middle-class consumption through different channels (easy credit, particularly for consumers and housing) Such policies increased the countries’ and economies’ vulnerability. Vulnerability, together with non-convergent fiscal rules at the European level, created the conditions for microeconomic failures hampering macroeconomic convergence and stability. In this frame the crisis has indeed magnified the gap between the vulnerable peripheral EZ member countries and a more resilient core, made up of economies with high private savings, low public debt and strong current account surplus, low disparities, high productivity and low unemployment. These economies, whose prototype is Germany, are competitive internationally and internally and capable of affording microeconomic reforms which further increase their competitiveness. They can thus implement and sustain financial constraints. On the other hand, EZ periphery is undergoing a remarkably severe downturn, which is urgently calling at the time of writing for resolute intervention spanning from ‘internal devaluation’, mainly through wage adjustments (Baldwin and Gros 2010), to credible fiscal action and structural reforms (Draghi 2010), to sovereign default (Rodrik 2010) and debt restructuring (Eichengreen 2011). At a general level of analysis, peripheral economies suffer from low or negative savings, low productivity (Figure 3) and activity rates (mostly to the disadvantage of women), high disparities (Figure 4) and unemployment (with remarkably elevated youth unemployment), rapidly rising ratios of debt to gross domestic product, high fiscal and current account deficits and elevated interest rates. The specifics differ among Greece, which meets all the aforementioned features, Portugal, which has low public and high private debt, Spain, which has low savings and low public debt, Ireland, experiencing a bank and financial system crisis hampering financial stability, and Italy, which has elevated private savings but suffers from high public debt (Table 8). All of them have been unable to comply with structural and microeconomic reforms and to implement and sustain financial constraints, and are consequently uncompetitive both externally and ...

Similar publications

Article
Full-text available
Water security is one of the main challenges that cities around the world face especially in Megalopolis such as Mexico City that struggle to provide safe and accessible fresh water to their inhabitants. The research project presents a Water Shortage Risk Index at the neighbourhood scale for Mexico City. The index is built into four main factors wh...
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes capacity restricted cooperative purchasing (CRCP) situations in which a group of cooperating purchasers face two suppliers with limited supply capacity. To minimize the total purchasing costs, we show that two extreme policies have to be compared: order everything at one supplier and the possible remainder at the other. Interest...
Article
Full-text available
The financial and economic crisis has generated renewed interest, especially among policy-makers, in early-warning systems that could help identifying fiscal and macro-financial vulnerabilities potentially triggering risks. Against this background, this paper presents an early-warning index of fiscal stress, incorporating fiscal, financial and comp...

Citations

... After the asset markets exploded in the US, the debt burden of the European-based private finance companies distributing housing loans in the US market became unsustainable. These institutions held a significant portion of residential mortgagebacked assets in the United States (Dallago and Guglielmetti, 2011). In the EU, governments had to undertake these debt burdens. ...
... Greece was financing its budget and current account deficits with cheap loans. This comfort ended up in severe debts in the long term (Dallago and Guglielmetti, 2011). ...
... Moreover, high inflation figures further reduced the real cost of borrowing in the South (Hall, 2012). Dallago and Guglielmetti (2011) unfolded that while household debts in the incomes of Southern EU countries reached an unsustainable level, the households of Northern EU countries, which constitute the core of the Eurozone, were in a more financially sound position during the crises. Chinn and Frieden (2012) reveal that crises bring more adverse effects to Southern EU countries. ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose- This paper employs the public debt equation of motion, which covers variables that represent a country's competitiveness, such as past public debt, GDP, external balance, real exchange rate, real interest, and inflation, to estimate the public debt of Southern EU countries (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain). The paper is designed to test whether the public debt equation of motion (see Croce and Ramon, 2003; IMF, 2013; Chirwa and Odhiambo, 2018), which is characterized by significant variables representing competitiveness in macroeconomics, can statistically account for the public debt of Southern EU countries after the monetary union period including the EU public debt crisis. Consequently, based on the findings, it will be determined whether the competitiveness problems of Southern EU countries are important in the EU public debt crisis. Methodology- The analysis is performed with the nonlinear autoregressive network with exogenous inputs (NARX) with quarterly data for the period from 2005Q1 to 2021Q4. In NARX, which is a dynamic non-parametric neural network used in time series analysis, the prediction performance of the model is more robust than other neural network models, as the gradient descent approaches the local minimum perfectly (see Lin et al., 1996; Gao and Er, 2005; Diaconescu, 2008). However, it is important to define the parameters correctly in NARX to obtain effective results. In the study, parameters are defined according to the minimum Mean Squared Error values. The feedback Levenberg-Marquardt (LM) algorithm, which produces fast and effective results, is used as the training algorithm. The performance of the training algorithm for robustness is compared with testing and validation. Findings- The analysis results reveal that public debt in Southern EU countries is statistically explained by the public debt equation of motion with a confidence ratio of over 95%. Conclusion- This result implies that the public debt problem in Southern EU countries is associated with their competitiveness (see also Hall and Soskice, 2001; Dallago and Guglielmetti, 2011; Hall, 2012; Lane, 2012; Gros, 2012; Iversen et al., 2016; De Ville and Vermeiven, 2016; Frieden and Walter, 2017). In addition, the analysis goes beyond parametric analyzes that relate economic growth or a few variables with public debt and reveals the importance of inclusive variables and non-parametric analyzes in the estimation of public debt. Keywords: EU public debt crises, Southern EU countries, NARX, competitiveness problems JEL Codes: C45, F35, F45, N14, N24
... Europe and the United States live in dependence on each other, and as a result of it, the European Union is not able to avoid any economic failures, turmoil coming from the United States (Dallago and Guglielmetti, 2011; Wyplosz, 2010). This happened in the case of the 2007 crisis, as well. ...
... Since the Eurozone contains the largest economies of the European Union, the negative impacts cause difficulties in the whole integration. Nevertheless, the crisis in the Eurozone reflected that there are unsustainable structural components in the monetary union, and the gap between the periphery and the more resistant countries became wider as a consequence of the crisis (Dallago and Guglielmetti, 2011). The need for financial resources is urgent. ...
Article
Full-text available
The economic (debt) crisis has become serious in the EU and in the Eurozone especially in the last few months. The European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) was created as an instrument to handle this situation. But the financial contributions of the EU Member States seem not to be enough and China appears as a potential contributor. It is often cited that China offered Portugal and Spain in March 2011 to support their crisis management. However, recently, there are attempts from the side of the EU to convince China take part in the EFSF. Thus the question raised often in Europe is the following: Will China contribute to the EFSF? If yes, what conditions will the country raise? What are the arguments of the Chinese capital both in China and the EU? Consequently, our research is focusing on the impacts of the global financial and economic crisis on the new relations between the European Union and China. China’s enormous reserves enable the Asian financial assistance to European countries in crisis management but there are a number of questions related to this. The main findings of this study are that China can benefit from its European crisis management from many aspects, as the EU is the largest market for the Chinese products. Furthermore, reserve currency diversification and political considerations cannot be neglected, either. But the assistance may have serious risks for China: not only the expected return on investment is at a stake, but internal social and political tensions can emerge from helping the Europeans who still live in significantly higher wealth than most of the Chinese people. Adopting Chinese capital raises questions for the European Union, as well. China may impose such terms by which the EU may become vulnerable and get into a dependent position, then presumably it will be difficult to solve the cooperation.